Varian Chapter24 Monopoly
Varian Chapter24 Monopoly
Monopoly
Pure Monopoly
• A monopolized market has a single seller.
• The monopolist’s demand curve is the
(downward sloping) market demand curve.
• So the monopolist can alter the market
price by adjusting its output level.
Pure Monopoly
$/output unit
Higher output y causes a
p(y)
lower market price, p(y).
Output Level, y
Why Monopolies?
• What causes monopolies?
– a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service
Why Monopolies?
• What causes monopolies?
– a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service
– a patent; e.g. a new drug
Why Monopolies?
• What causes monopolies?
– a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service
– a patent; e.g. a new drug
– sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway
Why Monopolies?
• What causes monopolies?
– a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service
– a patent; e.g. a new drug
– sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway
– formation of a cartel; e.g. OPEC
Why Monopolies?
• What causes monopolies?
– a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service
– a patent; e.g. a new drug
– sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway
– formation of a cartel; e.g. OPEC
– large economies of scale; e.g. local utility
companies.
Pure Monopoly
• Suppose that the monopolist seeks to
maximize its economic profit,
( y) p( y)y c( y).
• What output level y* maximizes profit?
Profit-Maximization
( y) p( y)y c( y).
At the profit-maximizing output level y*
d( y) d dc( y)
p( y)y 0
dy dy dy
so, for y = y*,
d dc( y)
p( y)y .
dy dy
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
y* y
(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
y* y
(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
y* y
(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
c(y)
y* y
(y)
At the profit-maximizing
output level the slopes of
the revenue and total cost
curves are equal; MR(y*) = MC(y*).
Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of
revenue as the output level y increases;
d dp( y)
MR( y) p( y)y p( y) y .
dy dy
Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of
revenue as the output level y increases;
d dp( y)
MR( y) p( y)y p( y) y .
dy dy
dp(y)/dy is the slope of the market inverse
demand function so dp(y)/dy < 0. Therefore
dp( y)
MR( y) p( y) y p( y)
dy
for y > 0.
Marginal Revenue
E.g. if p(y) = a - by then
R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2
and so
MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0.
Marginal Revenue
E.g. if p(y) = a - by then
R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2
and so
MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0.
a p(y) = a - by
a/2b a/b y
MR(y) = a - 2by
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the rate-of-change of total
cost as the output level y increases;
dc( y)
MC( y) .
dy
E.g. if c(y) = F + ay + by2 then
MC( y) a 2by.
$ Marginal Cost
c(y) = F + ay + by2
F
$/output unit y
MC(y) = a + 2by
a
y
Profit-Maximization; An Example
At the profit-maximizing output level y*,
MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and
c(y) = F + ay + by2 then
MR( y*) a 2by* a 2by* MC( y*)
Profit-Maximization; An Example
At the profit-maximizing output level y*,
MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and if
c(y) = F + ay + by2 then
MR( y*) a 2by* a 2by* MC( y*)
and the profit-maximizing output level is
aa
y*
2(b b )
Profit-Maximization; An Example
At the profit-maximizing output level y*,
MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and if
c(y) = F + ay + by2 then
MR( y*) a 2by* a 2by* MC( y*)
and the profit-maximizing output level is
aa
y*
2(b b )
causing the market price to be
aa
p( y*) a by* a b .
2(b b )
Profit-Maximization; An Example
$/output unit
a p(y) = a - by
MC(y) = a + 2by
a
y
MR(y) = a - 2by
Profit-Maximization; An Example
$/output unit
a p(y) = a - by
MC(y) = a + 2by
a
y* y
aa
2(b b ) MR(y) = a - 2by
Profit-Maximization; An Example
$/output unit
a p(y) = a - by
p( y*)
aa
ab
2(b b ) MC(y) = a + 2by
a
y* y
aa
2(b b ) MR(y) = a - 2by
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
• Suppose that market demand becomes less
sensitive to changes in price (i.e. the own-
price elasticity of demand becomes less
negative). Does the monopolist exploit this by
causing the market price to rise?
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
d dp( y)
MR( y) p( y)y p( y) y
dy dy
y dp( y)
p( y) 1 .
p( y) dy
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
d dp( y)
MR( y) p( y)y p( y) y
dy dy
y dp( y)
p( y) 1 .
p( y) dy
Own-price elasticity of demand is
p( y) dy
y dp( y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
d dp( y)
MR( y) p( y)y p( y) y
dy dy
y dp( y)
p( y) 1 .
p( y) dy
Own-price elasticity of demand is
p( y) dy 1
so MR( y) p( y) 1 .
y dp( y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
1
MR( y) p( y) 1 .
Suppose the monopolist’s marginal cost of
production is constant, at $k/output unit.
For a profit-maximum
1
MR( y*) p( y*) 1 k which is
k
p( y*) .
1
1
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
k
p( y*) .
1
1
E.g. if = -3 then p(y*) = 3k/2,
and if = -2 then p(y*) = 2k.
So as rises towards -1 the monopolist
alters its output level to make the market
price of its product to rise.
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
1
Notice that, since MR ( y*) p( y*)1 k ,
1
p( y*) 1 0
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
Notice that, since MR ( y*) p( y*)1 k ,
1
1 1
p( y*) 1 0 1 0
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
1
Notice that, since MR ( y*) p( y*)1 k ,
1 1
p( y*) 1 0 1 0
1
That is, 1
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
Notice that, since MR ( y*) p( y*)1 1 k ,
1
p( y*) 1 0 1 0
1
1
That is, 1 1.
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price
Elasticity of Demand
1
Notice that, since MR ( y*) p( y*)1 k ,
1 1
p( y*) 1 0 1 0
1
That is, 1 1.
So a profit-maximizing monopolist always
selects an output level for which market
demand is own-price elastic.
Markup Pricing
• Markup pricing: Output price is the marginal
cost of production plus a “markup.”
• How big is a monopolist’s markup and how
does it change with the own-price elasticity of
demand?
Markup Pricing
1 k k
p( y*) 1 k p( y*)
1
1 1
is the monopolist’s price.
Markup Pricing
1 k k
p( y*) 1 k p( y*)
1
1 1
is the monopolist’s price. The markup is
k k
p( y*) k k .
1 1
Markup Pricing
1 k k
p( y*) 1 k p( y*)
1
1 1
is the monopolist’s price. The markup is
k k
p( y*) k k .
1 1
E.g. if = -3 then the markup is k/2,
and if = -2 then the markup is k.
The markup rises as the own-price
elasticity of demand rises towards -1.
A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly
• A profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from
(y*) to (1-t)(y*).
• Q: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)(y*),
maximized?
A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly
• A profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from
(y*) to (1-t)(y*).
• Q: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)(y*),
maximized?
• A: By maximizing before-tax profit, (y*).
A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly
• A profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from
(y*) to (1-t)(y*).
• Q: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)(y*),
maximized?
• A: By maximizing before-tax profit, (y*).
• So a profits tax has no effect on the
monopolist’s choices of output level, output
price, or demands for inputs.
• I.e. the profits tax is a neutral tax.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
• A quantity tax of $t/output unit raises the
marginal cost of production by $t.
• So the tax reduces the profit-maximizing
output level, causes the market price to rise,
and input demands to fall.
• The quantity tax is distortionary.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit
p(y)
p(y*)
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit
p(y)
MC(y) + t
p(y*) t
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit
p(y)
p(yt) MC(y) + t
p(y*) t
MC(y)
yt y* y
MR(y)
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit The quantity tax causes a drop
in the output level, a rise in the
output’s price and a decline in
p(y) demand for inputs.
p(yt) MC(y) + t
p(y*) t
MC(y)
yt y* y
MR(y)
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
• Can a monopolist “pass” all of a $t quantity
tax to the consumers?
• Suppose the marginal cost of production is
constant at $k/output unit.
• With no tax, the monopolist’s price is
k
p( y*) .
1
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
• The tax increases marginal cost to
$(k+t)/output unit, changing the profit-
maximizing price to
t (k t )
p( y ) .
1
• The amount of the tax paid by buyers is
p( yt ) p( y*).
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
t (k t ) k t
p( y ) p( y*)
1 1 1
MC(y)
p(ye)
ye y
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit The efficient output level
ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y).
p(y)
CS
MC(y)
p(ye)
ye y
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit The efficient output level
ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y).
p(y)
CS
MC(y)
p(ye)
PS
ye y
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit The efficient output level
ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y).
p(y) Total gains-to-trade is
maximized.
CS
MC(y)
p(ye)
PS
ye y
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
p(y)
p(y*)
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
p(y*)
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
p(y*)
PS MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
p(y*)
PS MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
p(y*)
PS MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit
MC(y*+1) < p(y*+1) so both
seller and buyer could gain
p(y) if the (y*+1)th unit of output
CS was produced. Hence the
p(y*)
PS MC(y) market
is Pareto inefficient.
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
$/output unit Deadweight loss measures
the gains-to-trade not
p(y) achieved by the market.
p(y*)
MC(y)
DWL
y* y
MR(y)
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
The monopolist produces
$/output unit
less than the efficient
quantity, making the
p(y)
market price exceed the
p(y*) efficient market
e DWL
MC(y) price.
p(y )
y* ye y
MR(y)
Natural Monopoly
• A natural monopoly arises when the firm’s
technology has economies-of-scale large
enough for it to supply the whole market at a
lower average total production cost than is
possible with more than one firm in the
market.
Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
ATC(y)
p(y)
MC(y)
y
Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
ATC(y)
p(y)
p(y*)
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
Entry Deterrence by a Natural
Monopoly
• A natural monopoly deters entry by
threatening predatory pricing against an
entrant.
• A predatory price is a low price set by the
incumbent firm when an entrant appears,
causing the entrant’s economic profits to be
negative and inducing its exit.
Entry Deterrence by a Natural
Monopoly
• E.g. suppose an entrant initially captures one-
quarter of the market, leaving the incumbent
firm the other three-quarters.
Entry Deterrence by a Natural
$/output unit Monopoly
ATC(y)
p(y), total demand = DI + DE
DE
DI
MC(y)
y
Entry Deterrence by a Natural
$/output unit Monopoly
An entrant can undercut the
ATC(y) incumbent’s price p(y*) but ...
p(y), total demand = DI + DE
DE
p(y*)
pE DI
MC(y)
y
Entry Deterrence by a Natural
$/output unit Monopoly
An entrant can undercut the
ATC(y) incumbent’s price p(y*) but
p(y), total demand = DI + DE
DE
the incumbent can then
lower its price as far
p(y*)
DI
as pI, forcing
pE
the entrant
pI to exit.
MC(y)
y
Inefficiency of a Natural Monopolist
• Like any profit-maximizing monopolist, the
natural monopolist causes a deadweight loss.
Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
ATC(y)
p(y)
p(y*)
MC(y)
y* y
MR(y)
Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
ATC(y)
Profit-max: MR(y) = MC(y)
p(y) Efficiency: p = MC(y)
p(y*)
MC(y)
p(ye)
y* ye y
MR(y)
Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
ATC(y)
Profit-max: MR(y) = MC(y)
p(y) Efficiency: p = MC(y)
p(y*)
DWL
MC(y)
p(ye)
y* ye y
MR(y)
Regulating a Natural Monopoly
• Why not command that a natural monopoly
produce the efficient amount of output?
• Then the deadweight loss will be zero, won’t
it?
Regulating a Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
At the efficient output
ATC(y) level ye, ATC(ye) > p(ye)
p(y)
MC(y)
ATC(ye)
p(ye)
ye y
MR(y)
Regulating a Natural Monopoly
$/output unit
At the efficient output
ATC(y) level ye, ATC(ye) > p(ye)
so the firm makes an
p(y)
economic loss.
MC(y)
ATC(ye)
p(ye) Economic loss
ye y
MR(y)
Regulating a Natural Monopoly
• So a natural monopoly cannot be forced to
use marginal cost pricing. Doing so makes the
firm exit, destroying both the market and any
gains-to-trade.
• Regulatory schemes can induce the natural
monopolist to produce the efficient output
level without exiting.