Class Notes For Chapter 11
Class Notes For Chapter 11
Chapter 11 Monopoly
Definitions:
A monopoly is the only supplier of a good for which there is no close substitute.
Monopolies are not price takers like competitive firms
Monopoly output is the market output
The monopoly demand curve is the market demand curve
Monopolists can set their prices given market demand.
Because demand is downward sloping, monopolists set prices above
marginal cost to maximize profit.
Why?
1
The teaching notes should be only used by students in Dr. Haozhen Zhang’s class of ECON2020.
1
Quantity demanded, Q, is a function of price; the inverse demand function treats
price as a function of quantity demanded, and is also called the price function. If p(Q)
is the inverse demand function, which shows the price received for selling Q, then the
marginal revenue function is:
Selling one more unit requires the monopolist to lower the price, i.e. dP(Q)/dQ < 0
dP(Q)/dQ < 0 due to the inverse demand curve slope downward. Given a positive
value of Q, MR< p(Q), i.e. MR lies below inverse demand.
Examples:
dR
then, MR ( Q ) = =a−2bQ
dQ
2
Example: Relationship for inverse demand function of
i.e. MC=MR
The sufficient condition for profit maximization:
Example:
The inverse demand function indicates that people are willing to pay p = 24-6=$18 for
6 units of output.
Profit=p(Q)*Q-C(Q)=18*6-36-12=60
4
The monopolist’s profit maximizing choice of output is found where MR=MC.
At the profit-maximizing output, set p according to inverse demand.
As with competitive firms, a monopoly should shut down if the monopolist’s price is
less than its AVC.
In our example, AVC at Q* of 6 is AVC=Q=$6.
Because p = $18 is clearly above $6, the monopoly in this example should produce in
the SR. Profit =(18-8)*6=60
5
Market power is the ability of a firm to charge a price above marginal cost and
earn a positive profit. Monopoly has market power; competitive firms do not.
Market power is related to the price elasticity of demand
This makes the relationship between MR, p, and elasticity of demand quite clear.
Rewrite as
or
Thus, the ratio of price to MC depends only on the elasticity of demand at the
profit maximizing quantity (why? Recall that MR=MC above).
The more elastic the demand curve (the size of ϵ is large), the less a monopoly can
raise its price without losing sales (and vice versa).
Lerner Index
6
The Lerner Index (or price markup) is another way to examine the way in which
elasticity affects a monopoly’s price relative to its MC.
The markup (P − MC)/P is equal to minus the inverse of the elasticity of demand.
If the firm’s demand is elastic, as in (a), the markup is small and the firm
has little monopoly power.
The opposite is true if demand is relatively inelastic, as in (b).
Example.
7
When the iPad was introduced, MC=220, its fixed cost was $2000 million and its
inverse demand function is p=770-11Q, where Q is the millions of iPads sold.
1. MR?
demand p=770-11Q then R = pQ= 770Q-11Q^2, then MR=770-22Q
2. Profit-maximizing price?
p=770-11Q=770-275=495
3. Lerner Index?
=(495-220)/495=0.56
4. Elasticity of demand?
Elasticity=-(1/0.56) = -1.79
Elasticity of the market demand curve depends on consumers’ tastes and options.
Demand becomes more elastic (which implies less market power for the firm):
as better substitutes for the firm’s product are introduced
as more firms enter the market selling a similar product
as other firms that provide the same service locate closer to the firm
As a profit-maximizing monopoly faces more elastic demand, it has to lower its
price.
When moving from a competitive price and quantity to a monopolist’s price and
quantity, because of the higher price, consumers lose B+C and producer gains B−E.
The competitive equilibrium has no DWL, while the monopoly equilibrium has DWL
= C+E.
9
Suppose a specific tax of t dollars per unit is levied, so that the monopolist must
pay t dollars to the government for every unit it sells.
With a tax t per unit, the firm’s effective marginal cost is increased by the amount
t to MC + t. Its optimal production decision is now given by MR=MC+t
E.g. Before-tax cost function is C(Q)
The after-tax cost function is C(Q) + tQ
The necessary condition for maximizing after-tax profit:
In the example below, the increase in price ΔP is larger than the tax t. That is, tax
incidence on consumers (the change in the consumers’ price divided by the change
in the tax) can exceed 100% in a monopoly market but not a competitive market.
4. Causes of Monopolies
Why are some markets monopolized?
10
Two key reasons:
Natural monopoly: A market has a natural monopoly if one firm can produce
the market's total output at a lower cost than several firms could.
A firm is a natural monopoly because it has economies of scale. For example, natural
monopolies may have high fixed costs, but low and constant marginal costs. It has a
strictly declining average cost.
11
Barriers to entry: new firms need to obtain a license to operate
Example: U.S. cities require new hospitals to secure a certificate of need to
demonstrate the need for a new facility
By granting a firm the right to be a monopoly
Example: public utilities operated by a private company, e.g., Calgary`s Enmax
is a monopoly of electricity in South Alberta
By auctioning the rights to be a monopoly
Example: selling government monopolies to private firms (privatization). For
example, the privatization of Air Canada
Patents, copyrights, and licenses. For example, patented drugs vs generic drugs
12