Eb201701 Focus02.en
Eb201701 Focus02.en
Economic theory points to a potential role for the financial system over the
business cycle. Financial factors have been regarded as a possible driving force
behind business cycle fluctuations since at least the time of the Great Depression. 7
More recent general equilibrium approaches also emphasise the role of financial
frictions in output fluctuations. 8 According to these approaches, the financial system
can both act as an amplifier of shocks and be the source of shocks that trigger
business cycle fluctuations in the first place. The balance sheets of households,
firms and banks can give rise to various pro-cyclical mechanisms (such as the
financial accelerator). For example, demand shocks can be amplified through
corresponding changes in the value of collateral (such as residential or commercial
property) and the real value of nominally fixed debt. These theoretical considerations
suggest that credit and asset price-driven cyclical fluctuations can be expected to
yield higher peaks and lower troughs than normal business cycles, possibly with
more prolonged periods of boom and bust.
6
Borio, C., Disyatat, P. and Juselius, M., “Rethinking potential output: Embedding information about the
financial cycle”, BIS Working Papers, No 404, Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2013; Borio, C.,
Disyatat, P. and Juselius, M., “A parsimonious approach to incorporating economic information in
measures of potential output”, BIS Working Papers, No 442, BIS, 2014.
7
Fisher, I., “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions”, Econometrica, Vol. 1(4), 1933, pp. 337-
57.
8
See, for example, Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J., “Credit cycles”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 105,
1997, pp. 211-248; Gertler, M. and Karadi, P., “A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 58(1), 2011, pp. 17-34; Bernanke, B.S., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S., “The
financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework”, in Taylor, J. and Woodford, M. (eds.),
Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, Part C, 1999, pp. 1341-1393; Iacoviello, M., “House Prices,
Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle”, The American Economic Review,
Vol. 95(3), 2005, pp. 739-764.
9
See, for example, Rogoff, K., “Debt supercycle, not secular stagnation”, VoxEU.org, Centre for
Economic Policy Research, 2015.
10
Jorda, O., Schularick, M. and Taylor, A.M., “Macrofinancial History and the New Business Cycle Facts”,
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 31, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2016.
11
Dées, S., “Credit, asset prices and business cycles at the global level”, Working Paper Series, No
1895, ECB, April, 2016.
12
However, capital misallocation is not necessarily confined to real estate type assets. For more detail,
see Cecchetti, S.G. and Kharroubi, E., “Why does financial sector growth crowd out real economic
growth?”, BIS Working Papers, No 490, BIS, 2015.
13
The overestimation of potential output can lead to overly optimistic assessments of the fiscal policy
stance and debt sustainability of countries experiencing financial cycle driven booms which may limit
fiscal space and thus add to the drag on output in the event of a financial crisis. See Borio, C.,
Lombardi, M. and Zampolli, F., “Fiscal sustainability and the financial cycle”, BIS Working Papers, No
552, BIS, 2016.
2.5
2.4
2.3
2.2
2.1
2.0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
14
For a similar approach, see Melolinna, M. and Tóth, M., “Output gaps, inflation and financial cycles in
the United Kingdom”, Staff Working Paper, No 585, Bank of England, 2016.
15
See Adalet Mcgowen, M., Andrews, D. and Millot, V., “The Walking Dead? Zombie Firms and
Productivity Performance in OECD Countries”, Economics Department Working Papers, No 1372,
OECD, 2016.