Janmaat - Income Inequality - Europe
Janmaat - Income Inequality - Europe
Janmaat - Income Inequality - Europe
Abstract
The ongoing rise of inequality and the outbreak of the economic crisis since 2008 have fueled the
debate about the effects of macro-economic processes on democracy in general, and on political
participation in particular. Whereas the effect of economic disparity is well documented in the
literature, the implications of the economic downturn have not been sufficiently evaluated so far.
The article addresses this gap by offering a comprehensive overview of the impact of these macro-
economic factors on individual political participation in Europe. Using data from the first six rounds
of the European Social Survey (ESS), it shows that income inequality reduces participation and
enlarges the participatory gap between better- and worse-off. In contrast, economic contraction has
no effect on the overall level of participation and makes the poor participate more and the rich less.
1. Introduction
Rising inequality and the recent economic downturn have renewed scholarly attention in the effects
of macro-economic conditions on democracy. Despite the fact that democracy is essentially a
political revolution, rather than an economic one (Przeworski 2008) and that it has no "intrinsic
association with (...) the private realm of the economic market" (Bermeo 2012, 16), scholars are
concerned about the vitality and stability of democracy under conditions of widening disparities and
economic crisis (e.g. Thomassen 1989; Inglehart and Welzel 2005). One way of looking at this is to
evaluate the effect of these conditions on citizen participation. Few doubts exist about the
importance of citizens' participation for democracy. According to Schlozman et al. (1999), this is
because political participation contributes to the development of an individual’s sense of political
efficacy, to the spread of democratic orientations that facilitate cooperation within communities,
and to making government more responsive to the interests of citizens. For these reasons, studies on
democratic qualities routinely include participation as a fundamental outcome of investigation (e.g.
Morlino 2011).
Several studies examine the link between economic inequality and political participation. In
particular, Solt's series of articles represents a fundamental contribution to start with: inequality is
1
found to reduce overall levels of engagement and, most importantly from the democratic point of
view, to enlarge the participatory gap between the rich and the poor, no matter if studied from a
global comparative perspective (2008), with a special focus on the US (2010), or focusing on
Europe alone (2015). The contribution of Solt's analyses is fundamental, but there is still room for
further research. Firstly, his findings are not unanimously confirmed by other authors. For instance,
Anderson and Beramendi (2008) demonstrate that income inequality significantly lower civic
participation in 18 OECD democracies, but it does so to a similar degree for both the rich and the
poor. Secondly, and most importantly, all previous studies do not cover, to our knowledge, a period
of time that includes the recent economic crisis. This is an important limitation that needs to be
addressed and this article seeks to do so. On the one hand, we test Solt's findings on the effect of
economic inequality on an unprecedented dataset created with the first six rounds of the European
Social Survey (ESS). This allows us to look at a ten-year period of time from 2002 to 2012, thus
including three rounds before the economic crisis, and three rounds after its outbreak. To our
knowledge existing research has not yet examined the effect of inequality in periods that include a
major recession. On the other hand, we also pay attention to the effect of the so-called Great
Recession itself, both in how it influences participation directly and in how it magnifies or
diminishes the participation gap between rich and poor. Analyzing the impact of both macro factors
is particularly important, since predictions about their effects are made with reference to competing
theoretical perspectives, as we will explain in greater detail below.
The evidence from our analyses is mixed. On the one hand, Solt's findings about the
detrimental effect of income inequality are partially confirmed, although our results also show a
different pattern on one form of political participation which needs further attention. On the other
hand, the economic downturn apparently counteracts this tendency by fostering the participation of
the poor and reducing the participation of the rich.
The article is structured as follows: in the next section, we present in more details the
relevant literature and the working hypotheses. We do so by distinguishing between two main foci,
i.e. inequality and crisis, even though we will later show that the same theoretical models are useful
to interpret empirical patterns related to both. Data and variables are introduced in the third section;
the empirical analysis will be reported on in the fourth one. The main findings are summarized and
discussed in the final paragraph.
2
2.1 Inequality and participation
Traditionally, studies on economic inequality and political participation pay attention to individual-
level predictors and to their impact on citizens' likelihood to participate. Political participation is
taken as a costly behavior, associated with undetermined gains and certain costs, in terms of "time
to take part, money to contribute to campaigns and other political causes, and skills to use time and
money effectively" (Verba, Schlozman, and Brady 1995, 16). Individuals thus make decisions about
participating to the political process just as they make decisions to consume any other good. Since
intellectual and material resources are necessary for engaging in the political process, larger
amounts of resources are expected to increase the likelihood of engagement (Ansolabehere et al.
2003, 117-18). Verba and associates cover a broad range of such factors, e.g. social, economic and
educational resources (Verba, Nie, and Kim 1978) and family background (Verba, Burns, and
Schlozman 2003). In similar terms, Marsh and Kaase (1979) show that advantaged citizens are
more likely to engage in conventional and unconventional forms of participation. Levinson (2012)
underlines the importance of ethnic and educational backgrounds, while Loose and Jae (2013)
demonstrate that higher income reduces the opportunity costs of political participation in the US.
Besides its undisputed merits, this theoretical perspective remains silent about the impact of
macro-level conditions such as economic inequality on individual participation. The relative power
theory, as developed by Solt on the basis of Schattschneider's original hypothesis (1960), provides
the rationale for examining the effect of economic inequality. The point of departure is the
assumption that money and personal affluence can be used to influence others and to steer political
decisions. The more concentrated wealth and income are, the more power is in the hands of the rich.
On this basis, the well-off are expected to prevail more easily in occasionally open conflicts on
issues regarding their interests in more unequal countries (Goodin and Dryzek 1980). Furthermore,
they manage to prevent some issues to become part of the public debate by excluding them from the
agenda (Bachrach and Baratz 1970; Schattschneider 1960). How does it matter for political
engagement? If poor people perceive the political system to be incapable to defend their interests,
they can rationally decide to abandon their engagement in politics (Gaventa 1980; Pateman 1971;
Schattschneider 1960; Offe 2013). At the same time, also the rich have reduced incentives to
mobilize politically in defense of their interests, given the withdrawal of the main contenders (and
their possibility to steer politics by other means). All in all: following Solt's perspective, economic
inequality is expected to decrease political engagement, albeit with a stronger impact for the poor
than for the rich (Schattschneider 1960; Uslaner and Brown 2005). Put differently, as inequality
3
increases, the disparity in participation between the rich and the poor will widen. The first goal of
this article is to test this hypothesis, which includes two distinct statements:
H1) Inequality depresses overall participation and increases the participatory gap between the rich
and the poor.
Further empirical evidences of such patterns are reported, among others, by Lancee and Werfhortst
(2012; see also Toth et al. 2014) and Karakoç (2013). However, even though inequality is always
found to depress participation, its differential effect on the rich and the poor (i.e. its asymmetrical
impact) is challenged by further studies. On the one hand, Anderson and Beramendi (2008) show
that inequality significantly lower participation at both ends of the income distribution, thus leaving
the participatory gap unaltered (equal impact). On the other, Ansolabehere et al. (2003) find that
inequality encourages engagement for rich individuals (their focus is on campaign contribution) and
has an opposite effect at the other extreme of the income distribution (symmetrical impact).
This means we have good reasons to replicate the analyses on a range of outcomes, all the
more so in order to test the predictive capability of Solt's model in times of economic turmoil. As a
matter of fact, no studies among those mentioned above include data collected during the ongoing
crisis, and it is thus important to check whether the relationship between inequality and
participation still holds under these circumstances.
Our second aim is to assess whether the crisis itself has an impact on citizens' participation. So far
this question attracted little attention. A notable exception is the study by Kern et al. (2015) who
test the effects of indicators associated with the economic downturn (first and foremost
unemployment rates) on changes to participation in Europe. Their main working hypothesis builds
on the so-called grievance theory, which expects to see higher levels of political animosity and
participation in response to rising poverty and unemployment. Since 2008, most of European
countries faced enormous economic problems, in terms of economic contraction and rising
unemployment rates. When citizens perceive their own situation as falling short of expectations and
think they don’t get what they deserve, feelings of relative deprivation arise and these, in turn, are
expected to create a strong incentive for collective action and protest behavior (Gurr 1970,
Klandermans et al. 2008). Their analysis provides support for this model and indeed it shows that
4
rising unemployment levels encourage specific forms of non-institutionalized participation. Hence,
our working hypothesis in this respect goes as follows:
Notwithstanding its merit, their analysis can be improved. First of all, the authors do not control the
effect of the crisis for other factors at the country-level. Their dataset includes both democratic and
non-democratic countries (the Russian Federation) and no control for this and for different
participation propensities in Eastern and Western Europe is included in their model. Furthermore,
and most importantly, they do not control for additional economic factors, such as inequality or
country-specific levels of wellbeingi. Our analysis does so, in order to isolate the actual impact of
the economic crisis from that of other factors and to gain a more robust assessment of its
consequences. Second, they principally focus on the main effect of the crisis and present no
evidence for its contingent effect, i.e. the differential effect of the crisis depending on individual
economic resources. As economic crises often have more dramatic effects on the poor (cf. Baldacci
et al 2012), for instance because of cuts to welfare programs on which they disproportionately
depend, they are likely to feel more deprived than other groups and may thus, following the logic of
the grievance theory, be more inclined to become politically active than more privileged groups (cf.
Foster and Matheson 1995). This would lead one to surmise that the greater the economic downturn
is, the smaller is the difference in political participation between the rich and the poor (or, even
more spectacularly, the greater is this difference to the benefit of the poor):
H3) The economic crisis reduces the participatory gap between the rich and the poor.
Thus, while relative power theory expects lower levels of and greater social gaps in participation in
the more unequal countries, grievance theory anticipates opposite outcomes with respect to the
economic crisis, i.e. higher levels of and greater equality in participation in the more crisis-afflicted
countries.
3.1 Data
As already mentioned, we focus on democratic European countries. All survey data are drawn from
the European Social Survey (ESS), which is a biennial, high-quality survey of values, attitudes and
5
behavior among European populations. More specifically, we create a pooled dataset using the first
six rounds: this allows us to cover a period of time included between 2002 and 2012, with three
rounds collected before the economic crisis (2002, 2004 and 2006) and three rounds completed after
the beginning of the Great Recession (2008, 2010 and 2012). This leaves us 248.741 individuals,
nested in 130 country-year, nested in 29 different countriesii.
The ESS offers a vast range of indicators on several forms of political participation and some
descriptive statistics are included in Appendix A. Unsurprisingly, there is a great deal of variation
across different types of mobilization. Our first dependent variable is electoral participation, which
is measured with the classic question on whether the respondent has voted or not in the most recent
elections for the national parliament. Electoral participation is by far the most widely diffused
across all European populations: with 77.3% of respondents declaring their participation in the last
national elections, Europe is by and large in line (albeit slightly above) with other countries in the
world, given the figure provided by Blais (2007, 622-623) of a mean of 75.5%. This data is per se
quite telling about the resilience of electoral participation as the main channel of political
engagement and can explain why this form of participation continues to attract most scholarly
attention (Solt 2008). Previous research has highlighted a plethora of factors influencing voting,
ranging between individual-level demographic determinants, such as education, income, occupation
and age, and contextual-level conditions, such as characteristics of the voting system and
compositional features (for a good review of this research, see Harder and Krosnick 2008). We
include as many of these influences as control variables in our analyses (see further below).
ESS respondents are also asked whether or not they have done a specific political action
(e.g. contacting politicians, signing petitions, working in political parties, and so on; an exhaustive
list can be found on the ESS official website) during the last 12 months. Although such alternative
forms of participation are much less common, it is commonly assumed that rising sophistication
levels change the nature of participation, from traditional and hierarchical to alternative and more
egalitarian forms (Dalton 2008, Zuckin et al. 2006). Increasing attention should also be placed on
alternative forms of participation as these may even be more influential than conventional ones in
terms of their impact on public policies (APSA Task Force on Inequality and American Democracy
2004). For the sake of brevity, we focus on the three most diffused forms of alternative
participation, i.e. working in organizations, signing petitions and boycotting products. The question
wording of these items was as follows: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in
6
[country] or help prevent things from going wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any
of the following?” (1) “worked in another organization or association” (i.e. not a political party or
action group); (2) “signed a petition”; (3) “boycotted certain products”.
Three main independent variables are put under scrutiny, i.e. income at the individual level, income
inequality and a measure of the economic crisis at the macro-level. Since we are firstly interested in
the role of economic resources at the individual level, we focus on the role of the household's total
net income. Some economists prefer consumption expenditures instead, since it is more smoothed
over time and less volatile than income. However, as Brandolini and Smeeding (2011) discuss in
more details, consumption is preferred in less developed countries, whereas income remains the
prevalent indicator within rich countries, as it represents the possibility to consume and, as
measured over a span of a year, a satisfactory measure of material standards of living. The first
difficulty we had to face was the harmonization of the two income scales provided by the first three
rounds and the last three rounds of the ESS, i.e. the 12-point fixed scale provided by ESS 1, 2 and 3,
and the 10-point country-specific scale provided from ESS 4 on. In order to create a comparable
measure for all rounds, we first identified the category with the median income earner for each
country; then, we recoded all respondents with income above the median with 1, and the rest with 0.
Though providing a rough measure of within-country distribution of income, the dummy variable
allows us to evaluate the impact of earning an income above the median on the propensity to
participate.
At the country-year level, we take the Gini index of income inequality as our measure of
economic inequality. Country- and year-specific values are obtained from the Standardized World
Income Inequality Database (SWIID) created by Solt (2016), which is the largest database available
in this respect.
Measuring the economic crisis is less straightforward, given its multidimensional nature and
the many components that one may associate to it. Whereas aforementioned studies address the
effects of each dimension separately, we developed a synthetic measure of the Recession following
Kriesi (2014). This measure, which we labeled "Economic Crisis Index" (ECI), is based on the GDP
growth rate in the year preceding the ESS fieldwork, the budget deficit/surplus in the year before
the survey, and the unemployment rate of the same year. Similar to the Gini index it has country-
and year-specific values. High values denote negative GDP growth, large budget deficits and high
unemployment and thus reflect a severe economic crisis.iii
7
Further control variables are included in the models. First of all, we control for levels of
economic prosperity (measured by GDP per capita), which is included as a county-year variable.
Several studies confirm that turnout tends to be higher in economically advanced societies (Blais
and Dobrzynska 1998; Norris 2002; Fornos, et al. 2004). However, this pattern is confirmed only in
studies including rich and poor countries, whereas it does not hold in analyses based on countries
with less variation in affluence, such as Western democracies (Blais 2007). Secondly, post-
communist legacy is also taken as a potentially influential factor. The literature shows that
participation is systematically lower in post-communist countries (Howard 2003; Bernhard and
Karakoc 2007; Pacek et al. 2009). We therefore create a dummy variable that distinguishes post-
communist countries from others.
Several covariates are controlled for also at the individual level. The role of education in
connection to political participation has been assessed since long by the literature (e.g. Almond and
Verba, 1963) and its relevance is confirmed over and over (Wolfinger and Rosenstone 1980; Verba
et al. 1995; Blais 2000). For reasons of parsimony, we regroup the existing categories provided by
ESS into three different groups, i.e. those with 10 years of education or lower recoded as 1, those
with 11 to 13 years of education recoded as 2, those with more than 14 years of education recoded
as 3. By doing so, we create three categories that include approximately 33% of the population
each. Classically, we expect education to have a positive influence on individual propensity to
participate.
Age is the second most significant factor according to some studies (Blais 2000; 2007),
although its impact may be multifaceted. Whereas younger generations are generally supposed to be
less interested in political engagement, recent studies suggest that they tend to vote less, but
participate more through alternative channels, e.g. protest actions (Melo and Stockemer 2014).
Similarly, gender is expected to matter as well, since existing studies find marked differences
between males and females in intended political participation (e.g. Hooghe and Stolle 2004). A
dummy variable on the place of birth is included, as being born in another country most likely
depresses interest and engagement in the political process (cf. Diehl and Blohm 2001).
4. Empirical analysis
8
expect political engagement to be shaped both by predictors at the individual level and at the
country-year level and by interactions between these variables. We therefore estimate a series of
Multilevel Models (MlM). MLM is appropriate when data are nested, whereas using OLS
regression on nested data - by means of disaggregating level-2 variables at level-1 - would
overestimate the effect of macro-level factors (Snijders and Bosker 1999, Hox 2002). We estimate a
three-level model (of countries, country-years and individuals) rather than a two level one (of
country-years and individuals) to correct for the bias produced by the non-independence of
observations concerning years within countries (the same strategy was adopted by Solt in his
articles and by a number of studies that rely on repeated observations over time; see also Koster and
Kaminska 2011). Since our dependent variables are binary coded, we estimate Binomial Multilevel
Models with random effects. The table below reports the coefficients for two models for each form
of participation: in the first (Model 1), we test the main effects; in the second (Model 2), we
introduce the interactions of Gini and ECI with individual income. As each of these models includes
both Gini and ECI, these factors effectively control for one another.iv
We start by reporting the main effects of the predictors on the participation outcomes. Model 1
partially confirms findings from previous studies showing the detrimental impact of income
inequality on the likelihood to participate. As a rule, inequality decreases the probability to
participate - of approximately 3-4 points percentagev - , even though its effect is significant only at
the lowest level of statistical significance.
What about the gap between the rich and poor in countries with different levels of
inequality? We address this question by including interaction terms between income inequality and
household's net income in the model (Model 2), which is the standard approach in studies interested
in the contingent effect of macro-level variables on individual level resources (e.g. Duch and
Sagarzuzu 2014; Anderson 2007; Aguinis and Culpepper 2015). On first impression, the interaction
terms are neither always statistically significant, nor do they all go in the same direction. However,
their interpretation on the sole basis of their table coefficients is misleading for a number of
methodological reasons. Among other things, Brambor and his colleagues explain that it is not
possible to infer whether a certain predictor X has a meaningful conditional effect on Y from the
magnitude and significance of the interaction term with Z. Furthermore, it is perfectly possible for
the marginal effect of X on Y to be significant for substantively relevant values of the modifying
variable Z, even if the coefficient on the interaction term is insignificant (Brambor et al. 2006).
9
Because of this we take a closer look at the interactions by plotting the interaction terms. In the
plots below we show how the effect of income on participation varies across different levels of
inequality. The greater this effect, the larger the gap between the rich and the poor. The plots thus
allow us to directly address the statement about the participation gap in Hypothesis 1. We follow
the same strategy for assessing the interaction between economic crisis and income (see Figures 5-8
further down), thus allowing us to engage with Hypothesis 3.
As the Figure 1 shows, the effect of income barely changes under different levels of economic
inequality in the case of voting. If anything, the Gini index contributes to enlarge the participatory
gap between rich and poor (i.e. the slope is slightly positive), but the effect is not significant and too
weak to be taken into account. Nevertheless, the other graphs tell a radically different story: on the
one hand, our expectations are not confirmed by the second interaction, as the divide between the
rich and the poor significantly decreases alongside rising inequality in the case of working in
organizations. On the other hand, the disparity-exacerbating effect of inequality is confirmed by the
other two forms of participation: income inequality widens the gap between the rich and the poor
for boycotting products and signing a petition. In case of the latter, income does not make a
difference in the most equal countries but becomes a positive predictor of signing a petition as
inequality increases. All in all, Solt's findings and our first working hypothesis (H1) are partially
confirmed: economic inequality tends to depress overall levels of participation and enhances the
gap between the rich and the poor on some alternative forms of political participation.
The two models address the second issue of the article as well, i.e. testing the main and conditional
effect of the economic crisis. Following Kern et al. (2015), we control this effect for a number of
factors, including the main and contingent effects of income inequality. As compared to the
previous section, one thing seems clear: the economic crisis does not appear to have much of an
effect on overall participation as its effect is not significant in three out of four cases (see Model 1).
Rather than fueling or depressing citizens' engagement, the economic crisis seems to have no
consequences at all at first sight, with the notable exception of voting which is significantly reduced
by economic downturn. This disconfirms Hypothesis 2 which expected the economic crisis to
enhance participation.
10
A more careful evaluation is needed concerning the interaction terms in Model 2 and in the
light of the aforementioned clarification by Brambor and colleagues (2006). Similar to the previous
section, we plot the interaction terms in order to evaluate whether the effect of income varies under
different economic performances.
(Figures 5 - 8)
Again, the act of voting seems to be the most immune to contextual influences: the participatory
gap determined by household income remains stable, no matter if measured in countries hit by the
crisis (on the right of the figure) or in countries with high-performing economies. On the contrary,
the same analysis on other forms of participation highlights more variation: once controlled for all
other economic factors, the effect of income on the propensity to be part of an organization drops as
the economic crisis becomes more severe. Even more interestingly, the effect of income on the
propensity of boycotting products is apparently not significant when the economy fares well - or
barely significant in the case of signing petitions. In both cases, the effect becomes more evidently
significant and negative under poor performances. This means that the worse-off are comparatively
more active than the rich when the crisis hits hard, which is coherent with expectations based on the
grievance theory discussed above.
In terms of the control variables, economic prosperity, the other variable measured at the year-
country level, has little influence on participation, which is consistent with Blais' argument (2007)
that no significant difference exists among countries with relatively little variation in affluence. If
anything, economic wellbeing reduces traditional voting but encourages membership in
organizations. A very different story is reported by the dummy on post-communist countries, as the
analysis confirms the previous findings on the persistent divide between Eastern and Western
European countries in individual propensity to engage politically (Howard 2003, Bernhard and
Karakoc 2007, Pacek et al, 2009). In general, Western Europeans are approximately 4 to 5
percentage points more likely to be active than Eastern Europeans in all forms of participation
under scrutiny.
Interesting findings emerge among control variables at the individual level too.
Unsurprisingly, being born in another country heavily decreases the likelihood to be politically
active. Besides the strong effect registered for educationvi, the most interesting insights pertain the
11
role of gender and age. More specifically, the analysis sheds light on the different propensities to
participate of males and females: whereas males significantly vote more and work more in
organizations, females are more active both in the case of boycotting products and signing petitions,
even though the difference in both cases is around 1 point percentage. Similarly, the role of age
needs some refinement, as suggested by recent studies (e.g. Melo and Stockemer 2014). Younger
generations work less in associations; however, they are significantly more active in signing
petitions (up to two points percentage, if we compare respondents in their 20s and respondents in
their 70s). Finally, the role of economic resources at the individual level is confirmed for all forms
of participation. The coefficients in Model 1 show that belonging to the part of the population that
earns an income above the median change the probability to be active, but it accounts for an average
difference estimated between 1 and 2 points percentage in the three forms of participation under
scrutiny. This confirms that other predictors at the individual level are more important in
determining the likelihood of political engagement, first and foremost education, given the gap of
approximately 5 percentage points between the most and the least educated for all forms of
participation.
To say it with Lijphart (1997), if democracy is at its core associated with the ideal of political
equality, how does it cope with a reality of unequal participation which, in turn, is likely to lead to
an unequal influence over the outcome of the democratic decision-making process? To be sure, the
concept of political equality is complicated and discussing it is well beyond the scope of this article.
Measuring political inequality entails different and complementary strategies, broadly distinguished
between those that focus on the input side and those focusing on the output side (Dubrow 2014). In
other words, inequality can be assessed either in terms of unequal political input of certain groups in
the decision-making process, or in terms of the differential effects of political decisions on different
social groups. Focusing on citizens' participation clearly belongs to the former strategy and it moves
from the idea that even if the choice of non-participation at the individual level is perfectly
compatible with the framework of liberal democracy, recurring statistical patterns raise an issue of
underrepresentation of certain groups' interests. As Offe puts it, the problem arises when patterns of
uneven under-utilization of political resources exist: "here non-participation is evidently not freely
chosen, or it is freely chosen as the conditions that are statistically correlated with this choice are
themselves not freely chosen, but conditional on circumstances that are beyond the control of those
12
affected by them" (2013, 203). In view of this observation, the current article examined whether
within-country distribution of participation varies under different macro-economic circumstances.
Our analysis offers a twofold contribution to the literature. On the one hand, it tests existing
findings on the impact of economic disparities. More specifically, Solt's comprehensive studies on
the role of income inequality (2008, 2010, 2015) are replicated on European data and his findings
are by and large confirmed, even if tested in times of economic turmoil. Income inequality
generally reduces overall participation - though its effect is not statistically significant on all forms
of participation - and, most importantly, increases the gap between better- and worse-off in three
forms of participation out of four (minimally for voting and significantly for signing petitions and
boycotting products). Interestingly enough, inequality mitigates the income gap in the case of
working in organizations. This is because inequality has depressed overall levels of this form of
participation to such an extent that there is relatively little variation in this outcome in the most
unequal countries, and apparently too little for income to have an effect.vii Why there is so little
variation in working in organizations in more unequal countries is a question for further research.
On the other hand, the analysis shows that the crisis has no major effect on the propensity to
engage, but it does influence the within-country distribution of active citizens. In the case of voting
and working in organizations, the income-based divide is mitigated by the crisis; in the case of
boycotting products and signing petitions the worse-off are relatively more active than the rich in
countries having suffered most from the crisis.
These findings have some theoretical implications as well. Whereas the relative power
theory confirms its predictive capability concerning the effects of economic disparities, the
grievance model has good explanatory power regarding the effect of economic crises on the
political participation of different income groups. This is particularly true for alternative forms of
participation. Findings by Kern et al. (2015) are thus confirmed, even if controlled for all factors
that were not included in the previous studies. Similar to their study, our results suggest that both
theoretical approaches presented in this article (i.e. the relative power theory and the grievance
theory) can help to assess participatory tendencies, especially if these are tested in times of
economic turmoil.
Why do income inequality and the economic crisis have such contrasting effects on the link
between income and political participation and thereby confirm such conflicting theories? We can
only speculate about the reasons here. Possibly the diverging effects have to do with the different
pace at which the two macro-economic processes operate. While inequality is changing slowly and
is taking decades to become notably larger or smaller, an economic crisis can occur suddenly and
upset seemingly healthy growth trajectories (as happened in Greece). Perhaps the relative inertia of
13
inequality gives rise to a sentiment that not much can be done about it, which in turn might fuel
political disengagement and alienation amongst the poor. In contrast, the immediacy of an
economic crisis and the acute sense of loss experienced by those most affected by it might incite
people to act in an effort to regain what was lost (as illustrated by the mass demonstrations in
Greece in the aftermath of the crisis). In other words, while inequality might undermine a sense of
external political efficacy, economic crises could well enhance it. This is a question for future
research to explore.
14
Table 1 – The determinants of political participation (coefficients from multilevel binomial
regressions)
Vote Working in org Boycott Sign petition
Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2
15
Figure 1 - Marginal effect of income on voting conditional on the level of income inequality
16
Figure 3 - Marginal effect of income on boycotting products conditional on the level of income
inequality
Figure 4 - Marginal effect of income on signing petitions conditional on the level of income
inequality
17
Figure 5 - Marginal effect of income on voting conditional on the economic crisis
18
Figure 7 - Marginal effect of income on boycotting products conditional on the economic crisis
Figure 8 - Marginal effect of income on signing petitions conditional on the economic crisis
19
i
Taking into consideration only the GDP per capita annual growth (%) without controlling it for the overall level of
wellbeing (e.g. GDP per capita itself) overestimates the economic conditions of some fast developing countries (e.g.
Estonia) as compared to rich ones (e.g. (e.g. Finland).
ii
Differently from Kern et al. (2015), we exclude those countries that are rated either as not free or partly free by
Freedom House, i.e. Albania, Russia, Turkey, Ukraine and Kosovo. The reason for this is that participating to political
affairs may acquire a totally different meaning in full democracies and in authoritarian or semi-authoritarian regimes.
Furthermore, we must exclude from the analysis all those countries where the ESS question on income is not included
(Bulgaria 2008, Estonia 2004 and 2006, Cyprus 2006 and 2008, Hungary 2002 and 2006, France 2002, Ireland 2002,
Portugal 2010 and Slovakia 2008).
iii
Economic Crisis Index = GDP Growth - Unemployment + Deficit-Surplus. For the sake of clarity, we then reverse the
scale, so that higher scores correspond to more severe economic hardship. We created the measure by first standardising
the three variables that it includes and then by subtracting gdp growth from the sum of budget deficit and
unemployment rate.
iv
Although we have not found any theoretical leads in the literature to suggest that austerity might influence whether
income inequality enhances or mitigates the participation gap between the rich and poor, we nonetheless checked for
this possibility by running a model with a three-way interaction between economic crisis, income inequality and
individual income and a two-way interaction between economic crisis and income inequality. The effects of these
interactions turned out to be insignificant (results can be obtained from the authors upon request). Hence we only report
the results of the more parsimonious models (i.e. Models 1 and 2).
v
We are referring here to the predicted probabilities computed on the basis of the regression coefficients. In Binomial
Multilevel Models, the coefficient β associated to each Xn is the effect of a unit increment of X on the logit scale (i.e.
log-odds, or the natural logarithm of the odds determining the probability of a certain outcome Y associated to X). The
probabilities are computed by assigning different scores for the variable under scrutiny, holding all other variables
constant at their mean value and dummy variables at 1 (for more on predicted probabilities, please see Afshartous and
de Leeuw 2005; Skrondal and Rabe-Hesketh 2009).
vi
Three meaningful categories are built on the basis of the years of full-time education completed in order to include
approximately 30% of the respondents in each.
vii
A table showing the variation in the four outcomes across different levels of inequality and economic crisis can be
obtained from the authors upon request.
20
References
Aguinis, H., Gottfredson, R.K. and Culpepper, S.A. (2013) Best-Practice Recommendations
for Estimating Cross-Level Interaction Effects. Journal of Management 39(6): 1490-1528.
Aguinis, H. and Culpepper, S.A. (2015) An Expanded Decision-Making Procedure for
Examining Cross-Level Interaction Effects with Multilevel Modeling. Organizational
Research Methods. Published online: DOI: 10.1177/1094428114563618.
Almond, G.A. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in
Five Nations. Boston: Little, Brown & Co.
Anderson, C.J. (2007) The Interaction of Structures and Voter Behavior. In: R.J. Dalton and
H.-D. Klingemann (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior. New York: Oxford
University Press, pp. 589-609.
Anderson, C.J. and Beramendi, P. (2008) Income, Inequality, and Electoral Participation. In
P. Beramendi and C.J. Anderson (eds.) Democracy, Inequality, and Representation in
Comparative Perspective. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 258-311.
Ansolabehere, S., Figueiredo, de J. and Snyder, J. M. (2003) Why Is There So Little Money
in U.S. Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1): 105-30.
APSA Task Force on Inequality and American Democracy (2004) American Democracy in
an Age of Rising Inequality. Perspectives on Politics 2(4): 651-670.
Afshartous, D. and de Leeuw, J. (2005) Prediction in multilevel models. Journal of
Educational and Behavioral Statistics 30(1): 109-139.
Bachrach, P. and Baratz, M.S. (1970) Power and Poverty: Theory and Practice. London:
Oxford University Press.
Baldacci, E., de Mello, L. and Inchauste, G. (2002) Financial Crises, Poverty and Income
Distribution. Finance and Development 39(2): 24-27.
Bermeo, N. (2012) Does Electoral Democracy Boost Economic Equality. In: F. Fukuyama,
L. Diamond and M.F. Plattner (eds.) Poverty, Inequality, and Democracy. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, pp. 14-28.
Bernhard, M. and Karakoç, E. (2007) Civil Society and the Legacies of Dictatorship. World
Politics 59(4): 539-567.
Blais, A. (2000) To Vote or not to Vote? The Merits and Limits of Rational Choice.
Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Blais A. (2007) Turnout in Elections. In: Dalton, R.J. and Klingemann, H.-D. (eds.) The
Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 621-635.
21
Blais, A. and Dobrzynska, A. (1998) Turnout in Electoral Democracies. European Journal
of Political Research 33: 239-261.
Brambor, T., Clar, W.R., and Golder, M. (2006) Understanding Interaction Models:
Improving Empirical Analyses. Political Analysis 14(1): 63-82.
Brandolini, A., and Smeeding, T. M. (2011) Income Inequality in Richer and OECD
Countries. In: B. Nolan, W. Salverda and T.M. Smeeding (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of
Economic Inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 71-100.
Dalton, R.J. (2008) Citizen Politics: Public Opinion and Political Parties in Advanced
Industrial Democracies, 5th Edition. Washington D.C.: CQ Press.
Diehl, C. and Blohm, M. (2001). Apathy, Adaptation or Ethnic Mobilization: On the
political attitudes of an excluded group, Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 27 (3),
401-20.
Dubrow, J.K. (2014) Political Inequality in an Age of Democracy: Cross-national
Perspectives. London: Routledge.
Dubrow, J.K., Slomczynski, K.M. and Tomescu-Dubrow, I. (2008) Effects of Democracy and
Inequality on Soft Political-Protest in Europe: Exploring the European Social Survey Data.
Duch, R.M. and Sagarzazu, I. (2014) Crisis Perceptions and Economic Voting Among the
Rich and the Poor. In: N. Bermeo and L.M. Bartels (eds.) Mass Politics in Tough Times.
New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 224-265.
Fornos, C.A., Power, T. J. and Garand, J. C. (2004) Explaining Voter Turnout in Latin
America: 1980-2000. Comparative Political Studies 37 (8): 909-940.
Foster, M., and Matheson, K. (1995) Double Relative Deprivation: Combining the Personal
and Political. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 21: 1167–1177.
Gaventa, J. (1980) Power and Powerlessness: Quiescence and Rebellion in an Appalachian
Valley. Urbana: University of Illinois Press .
Goodin, R. and Dryzek, J. (1980) Rational Participation: The Politics of Relative Power.
British Journal of Political Science 10(3): 273-92.
Gurr, T.R. (1970). Why Men Rebel. Princeton: Princeton Universtiy Press.
Harder, J. and Krosnick, J. A. (2008). Why Do People Vote? A Psychological Analysis of
the Causes of Voter Turnout. Journal of Social Issues, 64 (3), 525-49.
Hooghe, M. and Stolle, D. (2004). Good Girls go to the Polling Booth, Bad Boys go
Everywhere. Gender Differences in Anticipated Political Participation Among US 14 Year
Olds. Women and Politics 26(3-4): 1-23.
22
Howard, M.M. (2003) The weakness of civil society in post-Communist Europe. Cambridge,
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hox, J. (2002) Multilevel Analysis. Techniques and Application. Malwah, London:
Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Publishers.
Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2005). Modernization, Cultural Change, and Democracy: The
Human Development Sequence. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.
Karakoç, E. (2013) Economic inequality and its asymmetric effect on civic engagement:
evidence from post-communist countries. European Political Science Review 5(2): 197-223.
Kern, A., Marien, S. and Hooghe, M. (2015) Economic Crisis and Levels of Political
Participation in Europe (2002–2010): The Role of Resources and Grievances. West
European Politics 38(3): 465-490.
Klandermans, B., van der Toorn, J. and van Stekelenburg, J. (2008) Embeddedness and
Identity: How Immigrants Turn Grievances into Action. American Sociological Review
73(6): 992–1012.
Koster, F. and Kaminska, M.-E. (2012) Welfare state values in the European Union, 2002–
2008. A multilevel investigation of formal institutions and individual attitudes. Journal of
European Public Policy 19(6): 900-920.
Kriesi, H. (2014) The Political Consequences of the Economic Crisis in Europe: Electoral
Punishment and Popular Protest. In: N. Bermeo and L.M. Bartels (eds.) Mass Politics in
Tough Times. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 297-333.
Lancee, B. and Werfhorst, H.G. van de (2012). Income Inequality and Participation: A
Comparison of 24 European Countries. Social Science Research 41: 1166-1178.
Levinson, M. (2012) No Citizen Left Behind. Cambridge and London: Harvard University
Press.
Lijphart, A. (1997) Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma. The
American Political Science Review 91(1): 1-14.
Loose, K. and Jae, D. H. (2011) Explaining Unequal Participation: The Differential Effects
of Winter Weather on Voter Turnout. Working Paper 2011-13, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
Marsh, A. and Kaase, M. (1979) Background of political action. In Barnes and Kaase (eds.)
Political action. Mass participation in five western democracies. Beverly Hills: Sage, pp.
97–136.
23
Melo, D.F. and Stockemer, D. (2014) Age and political participation in Germany, France
and the UK: A comparative analysis. Comparative European Politics 12(1): 33-53.
Morlino, L. (2011) Changes for Democracy. Actors, Structures, Processes. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Norris, P. (2002) Democratic Phoenix: Reinventing Political Activism. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Offe, C. (2013) Participatory Inequality in the Austerity State: A Supply-Side Approach. In:
A. Schäfer and W. Streeck (eds.) Politics in the Age of Austerity. Cambridge: Polity Press,
pp. 196-218.
Pateman, C. (1971) Political Culture, Political Structure and Political Change. British
Journal of Political Science 1(3): 291-305.
Pacek, A.C., Pop-Eleches, G. and Tucker, J.A. (2009) Disenchanted or Discerning: Voter
Turnout in Post-Communist Countries. The Journal of Politics 71(2): 473-491.
Pierson, P. (2001) New Politics of the Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Przeworski, A. (2008) The Poor and the Viability of Democracy. In: A. Krishna (eds.)
Poverty, Participation, and Democracy: A Global Perspective. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 125-146.
Quinn, G.P. and Keough, M.J. (2002) Experimental Design and Data Analysis for
Biologists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Schäfer, A. and Schoen, H. (2013) Mehr Demokratie, aber nur für wenige? Der Zielkonflikt
zwischen mehr Beteiligung und politischer Gleichheit. Leviathan 41(1): 94-120.
Schattschneider, E. E. (1960) The Semisovereign People: A Realist's View of Democracy in
America. New York: Holt, Reinhart, and Winston.
Schlozman, K.L., Verba, S. and Brady, H.E. (1999) Civic Participation and the Equality
Problem. In: Skocpol, T. and Fiorina, M.P. (eds.) Civic Engagement in American
Democracy. Washington: Brookings Institution Press, pp. 427–60.
Schlozman, K.L., Page, B.I., Verba, S., and Fiorina, M. P. (2005) Inequalities of Political
Voice. In: Jacobs, L., and Skocpol, T. (eds.) Inequality and American Democracy. New
York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 19-87.
Skrondal, A. and Rabe.Hesketh, S. (2009) Prediction in multilevel generalized linear
models. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 172(3): 659-687.
Snijders, T.A.B., and Bosker, R.J. (1999) Multilevel Analysis: An Introduction to Basic and
Advanced Multilevel Modelling. London: Sage Publisher.
24
Solt, F. (2008) Economic Inequality and Democratic Political Engagement. American
Journal of Political Science, 52(1): 48-60.
Solt, F. (2010) Does Economic Inequality Depress Electoral Participation? Testing the
Schattscheider Hypothesis. Political Behavior 32: 285-301.
Solt, F. (2015) Economic Inequality and Nonviolent Protest. Social Science Quarterly 96(5):
1314-1327.
Solt, F. (2016) The Standardized World Income Inequality Database. Social Science
Quarterly, first published online DOI: 10.1111/ssqu.12295.
Streeck, W., and Mertens, D. (2013) Public Finance and the Decline of State Capacity in
Democratic Capitalism. In: A. Schäfer and W. Streeck (eds.) Politics in the Age of Austerity.
Cambridge: Polity Press, pp. 26-58.
Thomassen, J.J.A. (1989). Economic crisis, dissatisfaction, and protest. In: M.K. Jennings,
J.W. van Deth et al. (eds.) Continuities in Political Action. A Longitudinal Study of Political
Orientations in Three Western Democracies. Berlin, New York: de Gruyter.
Tóth, I.G., Horn, D. and Medgyesi, M. (2014) Rising Inequalities: Will Electorates Go for
Higher Redistribution? In: B. Nolan, W. Salverda, D. Checchi, I. Marx, A. Mcknight, I.G.
Tóth, H.G. van de Werfhorst (eds.) Changing Inequalities in Rich Countries. Analytical and
Comparative Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 11-47.
Uslaner, E.M. and Brown, M. (2005) Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American
Politics Research 33: 868-894.
Verba, S. Nie, N.H. and Kim, J. (1978) Participation and Political Equality: A Seven-Nation
Comparison. New York and London: Cambridge University Press.
Verba, S., Schlozman, K., and Brady, H. (1995) Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in
American Politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Verba, S., Burns, N., and Schlozman, K.L. (2003) Unequal at the Starting Line: Creating
Participatory Inequalities across Generations and among Groups. The American Sociologist
34(1-2): 45-69.
Zuckin, C., Keeter, S. Andlina, M., Jenkins, K. and Delli Carpini, M.X. (2006) A New
Engagement? Political Participation, Civic Life, and the Changing American Citizen. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Wolfinger, R. and Rosenstone, S. (1980) Who Votes? New Haven: Yale University Press.
25
Wuensch, K.L. (2011) Interaction Significant, Simple Main Effects Not Significant.
Available at:
http://core.ecu.edu/psyc/wuenschk/StatHelp/InteractionSignificant_SimpleMainsNot.docx
26