Daudin Morys O'Rourke Chapter
Daudin Morys O'Rourke Chapter
Daudin Morys O'Rourke Chapter
Guillaume Daudin
University of Edinburgh and OFCE
Matthias Morys
University of Oxford
Kevin H. ORourke
Trinity College Dublin
Preliminary draft, not for citation. Comments welcome, including suggestions as to where we can cut.
1.1. Introduction
The period from 1870 to 1914 represented the high water mark of 19th century globalization,
which as Chapter 4 in the previous volume showed had been developing since the end of the
Napoleonic Wars. This chapter will explore several dimensions of this globalization, as well as its
effects on the European economy. Since the topic is vast, our focus will be on the links between
Europe and the rest of the world, rather than on the growing integration of the European economy
itself, although that will be alluded to at several stages during the chapter.
Nineteenth century globalization involved increasing transfers of commodities, people, capital
and ideas between and within continents. There are several complementary ways to measure
increasing international economic integration. The most straightforward is simply to measure the
growing volume of these international flows, perhaps scaled by measures of economic activity more
generally: for example, the ratio of commodity trade to GDP, or the number of migrants per head of
population. A more direct measure of integration is provided by the cost of moving goods or factors
of production across borders, and this cost will show up in international price gaps. Because it is less
easy to measure integration in the international markets for ideas and technology, these flows are
often not discussed in economists accounts of globalization, but they are sufficiently important that
they will be briefly considered here, problems of measurement notwithstanding.
Having documented the increasing integration of international markets in the late 19th century,
we then discuss some of the effects of this unprecedented globalization. Finally, we turn to the
question of how sustainable the relatively liberal 19th century world economy was: could globalization
have continued unabated after 1914, had World War I not intervened, or were there forces that would
have undermined open markets even had that cataclysm not occurred?
Chicago to New York City cost, and the New York to Liverpool cost. Between 1866 and 1870 the
former was equivalent to 17.2% of the Chicago wheat price, and the latter to just 11.6% of the
Chicago price. By 1909-13, these freight factors had declined to 5.5% and 4.7% respectively
(Findlay and ORourke 2007, p. 382). Thus, the 18.6 percentage point decline in the ChicagoLiverpool freight factor during this period can be decomposed into an 11.7 percentage point decline in
the Chicago to New York component, and a 6.9 percentage point decline in the trans-oceanic
component.
In addition, peace between the main powers between 1871 and 1914 promoted trade (Jacks
2006). The development of European formal and informal empires increased extra-European trade
through the reduction of trade barriers, the inclusion of colonies in currency unions, and the better
protection of (European) property rights (Mitchener and Weidenmier 2007). Meanwhile, the gradual
spread of the gold standard dampened exchange rate fluctuations and reduced uncertainty in trade.
Recent econometric work clearly shows that the gold standard promoted trade between countries
participating in it: by up to 30%, according to Lpez-Crdova and Meissner (2003) (for different
estimates, see also Estevadeordal et al. 2003 and Flandreau and Maurel 2005). The gradual spread of
the gold standard during the late 19th century was thus one of the factors underlying that periods
trade boom. Whether international currency arrangements such as the Latin Monetary Union (LMU)
and Scandinavian Monetary Union (SMU) had an additional positive effect on trade is a matter of
controversy. Lpez-Crdova and Meissner (2003) find that such monetary unions did promote trade
between their members, but Estevadeordal et al. (2003) find no such effect. According to Flandreau
and Maurel (2005), the SMU boosted trade but the LMU one did not, and indeed Flandreau (2000)
argues that trade promotion was in any case not an aim of the LMU.
The major force operating in the opposite direction was trade policy, and in particular the
anti-globalization backlash that will be discussed later in this chapter, which applied particularly to
trade in agricultural products. Notwithstanding this trend, intra-European and extra-European trade
grew rapidly during the 19th century. In most sectors, it reached a high point in 1913. European trade
roughly quadrupled in real terms between 1870 and 1913, with the increase being slightly higher in
Eastern than in Western Europe, albeit from a substantially smaller base (Maddison 2001, p. 362).
The export to GDP ratio of France, Germany and the United Kingdom (in 1990 prices) increased by
approximately 50 %, while the Spanish ratio more than doubled (ibid, p. 363). As shown in Figure
1.1.1, the geographical structure of European trade was fairly stable. Intra-European trade declined
slightly, from 71 % to 68 % of European trade. The share of trade with North America declined as
well, whereas the share of Africa more than doubled, presumably reflecting the incorporation of most
of that continent into European empires. This increased diversification of European exports continued
a trend that had started in the early 19th century, although the United Kingdom was the only country
that exported more outside Europe than in Europe. (NB: If we knew total European nominal GDP, we
could compute an extra-European openness rate)
2
Europe was a net exporter of manufactures and a net importer of primary products (Table
1.1). As can be seen, however, this masks important differences between regions. At one extreme lay
the United Kingdom, very heavily specialised in manufacturing and largely reliant on imported food
and raw materials. The rest of Northwestern Europe was similarly specialised, but in a much less
extreme fashion. The rest of Europe, however, still exported primary products and imported
manufactures, net. On the other hand, Eastern and Southern Europe were far more similar to North
America, another agricultural region beginning to industrialise, than to Oceania, Latin America or
Africa, which exported virtually no manufactured goods. Note also that this specialization dampened
somewhat over time, as Europeans primary deficit and manufactured surplus rose more slowly than
total European trade. This was probably the result of the relative decline of European industrialization
rates compared with the rest of the world, especially the United States. European commodity trade
was in deficit throughout the period (Yates 1959). This must have been balanced by some net exports
of services, but these have not been estimated. To give an idea of their magnitude, the United
Kingdom surplus in business services trade averaged over $800 million during 1911-13, as compared
with a figure for total European exports of just under $11 billion in 1913 (Imlah 1952 and Maddison
2001).
Price convergence remains the best indicator of international commodity market integration.
It is well documented for this period, especially across the Atlantic. Liverpool wheat prices exceeded
Chicago prices by 57.6% in 1870 but by only 15.6% in 1913. London-Cincinnati price differentials
for bacon were 92.5% in 1870, over 100% in 1880, 92.3% in 1895, but 17.9% in 1913 (reflecting the
introduction of modern refrigeration technology relatively late in this period). Price gaps for
manufactured goods (which were initially dearer in the United States) were falling as well: from
13.7% in 1870 to -3.6% in 1913 for cotton textiles, from 75% to 20.6% for iron bars, from 85.2% to
19.3% for pig iron, and from 32.7% to -0.1% for copper (ORourke and Williamson 1994, p. 900).
Liverpool cotton prices exceeded Bombay prices by 57 % in 1870 and by only 20 % in 1913 (Collins
1996), and exceeded their Alexandria equivalents by 42.1% in 1824-1832, by 40.8% during 18631867, but by just 5.3% during the last decade of the 19th century (Issawi 1966, pp.447-8). Similar
price convergence can be observed between London, Calcutta and Rangoon (Collins 1996).
Recent research, focussed on the international wheat market (e.g. Federico and Persson 2007,
Jacks 2005), has added greatly to our understanding of this phenomenon. First, a great deal of the total
price convergence experienced during this period was due to domestic market integration, driven by
railroads. Metzer (1974) has documented an impressive decline in grain price dispersion within
Russia after 1870, while Hurd (1975) and Williamson (1974, p.259) do the same for India and the
United States respectively. The implication is that studies looking at increasing integration between
port cities understate the convergence of the period.
Second, studies focussing on the Anglo-American comparison can overstate the price
convergence of the period, since elsewhere in Europe agricultural protection raised barriers to trade in
3
grain and other commodities, beginning in the 1870s (Bairoch 1989, ORourke 1997). Thus, Federico
and Persson (2007) show that while prices converged among free trade countries during our period,
there was a substantial increase in price dispersion between free trade and protectionist countries, with
the result that overall price dispersion actually increased. Falling transport costs implied that potential
market integration was increasing during this period, but politicians always had the possibility of
muting or even reversing this via protectionist policies (ORourke 2002). Thus, it is not surprising that
authors such as Federico and Persson, and Jacks (2005), have recently started to point out that overall
commodity price convergence was if anything more impressive between 1830 or 1840 and 1870 than
in the more intensively studied 1870-1913 period (Volume 1, Chapter 4). Whether these findings can
be generalised to commodities other than grains is a matter for further research. In a rare example of a
study going beyond grains, Klovland (2005) confirms that protectionism seems to have disrupted
Anglo-German price convergence for cereals, but that convergence continued after the 1880s for a
range of other commodities, which is consistent with the anti-trade backlash of the late 19th century
being a disproportionately agricultural phenomenon, industrial protectionism notwithstanding.
were Europeans.
What form did the foreign investment take and what was it used for? Roughly three quarters
of European investment before World War I was portfolio investment, i.e. investment in bonds and
shares rather than foreign direct investment (FDI) (Edelstein 2004, p. 195). This is very different from
todays era of FDI-dominated global capital markets and requires an explanation. Informational
asymmetries were certainly greater a hundred years ago than today, and increased the agency
problems associated with many types of investment. This is the key factor for Bordo, Eichengreen and
Irwin (1999) in explaining the composition of overseas investment then as opposed to now. Debt is
less risky for investors than equity, and thus a more uncertain environment led to more bond
purchases and fewer direct investments. Informational problems also explain the sectoral composition
of investment. The lions share of portfolio investment was used for government bonds and railway
bonds (UK: 35% + 22% of total portfolio investment; Germany: 49% + 33% of total portfolio
investment)1, with most of the remainder going into extractive industries and social overhead projects
other than railways (such as public utilities, urban infrastructure and transport etc.). As Bordo et al.
point out, it was easier to monitor a railway company (since the key numbers involved, miles of track
laid and passengers and goods carried, were easily available) than manufacturing or commercial
firms. It was also presumably relatively easy to gather information about the trustworthiness and
expenditure and revenue patterns of a foreign government. Furthermore, given that the most pressing
need was for transportation and social infrastructure, it may have been inevitable that portfolio
investment dominated FDI by such a wide margin, since such investments have probably always lent
themselves better to portfolio investment. Finally, while as we will see later the first modern
multinationals began to make their appearance during this period, the intangible assets which
ultimately motivate such investments (e.g. proprietorial knowledge, brand-names, and so on) were
probably less important then than now (Caves 1996).
What kinds of evidence can we muster to compare the integration of global capital markets
over time? There are at least three that have been used in the literature, and all tell the same story:
capital market integration has traced out a U-shape over the past 150 years (Obstfeld and Taylor
2004). Capital markets became more integrated during the late 19th century; they disintegrated after
1914; and they recovered those losses during the last two or three decades of the 20th century.
The first measure simply looks at the sizes of the capital flows involved. According to
Obstfeld and Taylor (2004, p. 55), foreign assets accounted for 7% of world GDP in 1870, but for
nearly 20% during 1900-14, which represents impressive integration. There followed a period of
disintegration: the figure was only 8% in 1930, just 5% in 1945, and still only 6% in 1960. However,
it then shot up to 25% in 1980, 49% in 1990, and 92% in 2000. On this measure it was not until some
time in the 1970s that the pre-1914 level of integration was recouped. These figures represent stocks
of foreign assets, but Obstfeld and Taylor also present evidence on the flow of net foreign investment,
1
as measured by the absolute value of the current account, scaled by GDP. Again, the U-shaped pattern
emerges from the data, with the difference that on this measure pre-1914 levels of capital flows have
not yet been recouped. The stock and flow data may in part yield different results because while the
former is gross, the latter is net, and the extent of two-way flows of short-term investments between
markets is one feature of todays capital markets that is completely unprecedented.
The second approach looks at price convergence. As capital market integration progresses,
price gaps bonds spreads in the language of financial markets should decline to the point where
they reflect only differences in risk between the assets under consideration. Several studies2 have
shown that bond spreads between peripheral economies, be they in Europe or not, and the NorthWestern European core countries of England, France, and Germany fell, on average, from some 5%
on 1870 to only 1% on 1914 (Figure 1.2), less than today (Mauro, Sussman and Yafeh 2002). Even
more compelling evidence of integration emerges if price gaps between identical assets decline. For
example, Garbade and Silber (1979) show that trans-Atlantic price spreads on US 5-20 bonds fell
immediately after the introduction of the trans-Atlantic telegraph in 1866. Obstfeld and Taylor (2004,
pp. 89-91) find that US-UK interest rate differentials were small and steady before World War I,
widened during the two World Wars and the interwar period, and narrowed during the 1980s and
1990s, consistent with the U-shaped pattern mentioned earlier.
The third approach uses quantity data and was first suggested by Feldstein and Horioka
(1980). International capital mobility breaks the link between domestic savings and domestic
investment, as domestic savings can be invested abroad and foreign capital can go into domestic
investment. Consequently, the weaker the relationship between domestic savings and domestic
investment, the higher is international capital mobility. Figure 1.2 shows one of the many
implementations of Feldstein and Horiokas basic idea, and it confirms the existence of a U-shaped
pattern of integration, disintegration and reintegration.
All three indicators of global financial integration show that capital market integration
increased substantially between 1870 and 1914, but that this was not a continuous process. As is true
today, there were reversals which potentially subjected capital-receiving countries to sudden stops
(Calvo 1998). A first wave of financial integration came to an end with the Baring crisis of 1891.
Capital receded dramatically for roughly a decade before massive foreign lending resumed again
around the turn of the century. Financial integration was at its peak immediately before the outbreak
of World War I.
What explains late 19th century capital market integration and what accounts best for the size
and the direction of capital flows? Some of the reasons suggested by economic historians are more
controversial than others, while confusion among competing theories is increased by the fact that
some studies are concerned with accounting for bond spreads, while others attempt to explain the
sizes and direction of flows. Without doing too much injustice to a large body of literature, we can
2
E.g. Flandreau and Zumer (2004), Mauro, Sussman, and Yafeh (2002).
6
distinguish between political, institutional and more purely economic explanations for late 19th
century capital market integration.
To begin without the risk of controversy: everyone agrees that the absence of military conflict
among the main lending countries England, France, Germany, the US, Netherlands, Belgium and
Switzerland between the Franco-Prussian War and World War I helped to create and stabilise an
atmosphere conducive to foreign lending. The second political explanation, by contrast, has been
highly controversial. Marxists have long argued that late 19th century capital exports and imperialism
are only two sides of the same coin. The argument runs as follows: excessive saving at home,
generated by a highly unequal distribution of income, required outlets in underdeveloped countries, as
domestic investment would have been subject to Marxs law of the falling rate of profit. This idea
pioneered by J.A. Hobson, allowed Lenin to declare imperialism to be the highest stage of capitalism.
The contention of a connection between empire and capital exports was subsequently discredited3,
only to be resuscitated recently. In a twist to the historiography, the almost forgotten Marxist theory
of a connection between empire and capital exports has been revived, but this time by revisionist
historians arguing for a more benign interpretation of imperialism. For example, Ferguson and
Schularick (2006) argue that members of the British Empire benefited from their colonial status
through substantially reduced interest rates, presumably as a result of more secure property rights.
Table 1.3 shows the destinations of English, French and German capital exports. It certainly
raises doubts about whether colonial affiliation truly mattered for the size and the direction of capital
flows. All English colonies combined (excluding Canada, Australia and New Zealand) received a
paltry 16.9% of English capital exports, which is less than what the US alone received (20.5%). The
French and German experiences suggest the same, with colonies receiving only 8.9% and 2.6%,
respectively, of the overall capital exports of their respective mother countries.
Turning to economic institutions and policies, a great deal of attention has been devoted to the
gold standard (Bordo and Kydland 1995, Bordo and Rockoff 1996) and, more recently, to sound
fiscal policies (Flandreau and Zumer 2004). Adherence to gold is seen as having promoted global
financial integration in two ways. First, it eliminated exchange-rate risk. Second, it signalled that the
government concerned would pursue conservative fiscal and monetary policies, which assured
potential investors that returns were reasonably safe.
While there has been much debate about whether it was gold standard adherence per se or
sound fiscal policy that mattered more, proponents of both positions probably agree that economic
institutions and policies can only facilitate capital imports, but never attract them if there is no
genuine interest on the part of investors in what a specific country has to offer. This brings us to
economic fundamentals as the main determinant in explaining the size and direction of flows.
What explains the fact that more than 50% of British capital exports went to areas of recent
settlement? British foreign investment headed mainly for regions where natural resources could be
3
exploited, not necessarily where labour was cheap (as would have been the case in Africa and Asia).
Investment demand in the areas of recent settlement was high due to capital (and labour) requirements
associated with frontier expansion. If New World land was to produce food for European consumers,
and raw materials for factories, railways had to make it accessible, land had to be improved, and
housing and infrastructure had to be provided for the new frontier communities.
This explanation for the direction of capital flows between 1870 and 1914 certainly matches
nicely the data on British capital exports (Table 1.3). Clemens and Williamson (2004a) provide
econometric evidence in favour of this view, showing that British capital exports went to countries
with abundant supplies of natural resources, immigrants, and young, educated, urban populations.
They also find that gold standard adherence and membership of the British Empire helped attract
capital inflows, ceteris paribus, but these two variables mattered far less in explaining capital flows
than did endowments, despite all the ink that has been spilt on discussing them. Supply and demand
imbalances across countries, rather than the presence or absence of frictions leading to price gaps
between markets, were what was really crucial. Clemens and Williamson did not have the data to
provide a similar analysis for French and German capital exports, however, and this is unfortunate
since the French and the German cases were somewhat different. While foreign investment into
Africa and Asia was rather unpopular in all three countries, France and Germany sent 61.1% and
53.3%, respectively, of their capital exports to other European countries. Investment into areas of
recent settlement, by contrast, played a substantially reduced role for both countries. According to a
recent paper by Esteves (2007), however, economic fundamentals were as important for German
investors as they were for British ones during this period.
The causes of this mass migration are by now well understood, thanks in particular to the
work of Hatton and Williamson (1998, 2005). On one level, the causes are obvious: the New World
was endowed with a higher land-labour ratio than Europe, and hence American and Australian
workers earned higher wages than their European counterparts. For example, British real wages in
1870 were less than 60% of wages in the New World destinations relevant to British workers, whereas
the equivalent figure for Irish workers was just 44%, and for Norwegian workers was just 26%
(Hatton and Williamson 2005, p. 55). The gains from migration were thus potentially enormous, and
once the new steam technologies had lowered the cost of travel sufficiently, mass emigration became
inevitable. This was particularly so since 19th century immigration policy was relatively liberal,
notwithstanding the policy developments which we will note later on.
On another level, there is the issue of what determined the timing of emigration streams from
different European countries: why did emigration from relatively rich countries such as Britain take
off before emigration from poorer countries such as Italy, where the gains to migrants were
presumably higher? What explains the fact that so few Frenchmen and women emigrated, while so
many Irish and Italians left? What explains the initial rise, and subsequent decline, of emigration rates
in several countries, documented in Table 1.4? Hatton and Williamson provide a simple econometric
explanation for all these questions, which can be represented in Figure 1.4. EM is a downwardsloping function relating emigration rates from a given European economy to home wage rates: as
home wages rise, emigration rates should fall, ceteris paribus. The initial rise in emigration rates
experienced in the typical economy (say from e0 to e1) must then have been due to rightward shifts in
the emigration function, from EM to EM, since wages were rising (say from W0 to W1), not falling,
in late 19th century Europe. In turn, such rightward shifts were caused by a variety of factors. First,
would-be emigrants were initially constrained by the cost of trans-oceanic transport, but as transport
costs fell, more migrants were able to leave their homelands. Second, these poverty traps could also
be overcome by previous emigrants sending home remittances or pre-paid tickets, thus directly
financing the cost of travel. This meant that emigration rates tended to increase as countries built up
stocks of emigrants overseas, the so-called friend and relatives effect. Third, as Chapter 5 indicates,
fertility rates were on the rise throughout Europe during this period, leading to an increase in the
supply of young, mobile adults. And finally, it has often been argued that the industrialisation
documented in Chapter 3 led to workers being detached from the land, again increasing their mobility.
Rising fertility, structural transformation and falling transport costs thus increased emigration
rates, initially in the richer economies whose workers could best afford the cost of transport, and then
in poorer economies as living standards rose across the continent. This emigration was initially selfreinforcing, as a result of the friends and relatives effect: all these factors led to EM shifting
rightwards. But eventually, the emigration function stabilised, and when this happened, emigration
became self-limiting: by lowering labour supply at home, it pushed up real wages (say from W1 to
W2), and economies thus moved up their EM schedules, experiencing lower emigration rates (e2).
9
Hatton and Williamson show that low French and high Irish emigration rates can be explained without
appealing to weird cultural behaviour in either country, since this one-size-fits-all European model fits
most countries perfectly satisfactorily. Thus, high Irish emigration rates can be explained by the
Famine of the 1840s, which created a large Irish migrant stock in the New World, while low French
rates can be explained by such factors as a precocious fertility transition. Economic rationality turns
out to do a pretty good job of explaining European emigration during this period.
transfer intangible assets such as new technologies abroad at arms length, via the market: thus,
Singers attempts to profit from its invention of the sewing machine to a French merchant proved a
complete disaster, the latter refusing to pay what he owed, or even disclose how many sewing
machines he was producing (ibid., pp. 38-9).
The diffusion of technologies was also helped by the creation of international scientific and
technical organizations. The Institution of Naval Architects was founded in 1860 in the United
Kingdom, but organized meetings in different countries and through its membership created an
international network of professional and learned bodies (Ville 1991). The number of international
scientific conferences and organizations increased dramatically (Error! Reference source not found.
1.5). Paradoxically however, at the same time science was seen as one of the weapons in the struggle
between European nations. Besides straightforward military applications, academic activity was used
a diplomatic weapon. Inviting foreign scientists and participating in scientific congress was part and
parcel of the rivalry between France and Germany, as each hoped to tighten their links with allied and
neutral countries, especially the United States (Charle 1994, ch. 8).
Governments increased formal technical cooperation. The International Telegraph Union was
founded in 1865 and the Universal Postal Union in 1874. Humanitarian cooperation was expanded as
well: the Red Cross was founded in 1863 and the first Geneva Convention signed in 1864. Most
sovereign states, both European and non-European, joined these global institutions. Another form of
rising globalization was the diffusion of popular forms of international exchanges and competitions.
The World Fairs were official showcases for the technical prowess of each nation. The 1876 World
Fair in Philadelphia was the first not to take place in Europe, and included official exhibitions from
Japan and China. The first Venice Biennale took place in 1895. The first modern Olympics took place
in 1896. The first five Nobel prizes were awarded in 1901 (English 2005).
Labour movements were increasingly globalized as well. Socialist ideals rejected nationalism
and advocated the international defence of the interests of labour. The first international was founded
in 1864 and the second in 1889, the latter having Japanese and Turkish members. The significance of
these events is difficult to assess. International, especially pan-European, scientific and cultural
cooperation between individuals had existed for a long time. De facto agreements about the rules of
war and the management of public goods e.g. the high seas pre-dated the first globalization. To
some extent, the heyday of elite cultural globalization was before 1870. The issue of nationalist
cultural identity gained in importance in the second half of the 19th century, leading to the
fragmentation of cultural activities as they become more popular. The formalization of cultural and
scientific discourse can be seen both as a weak attempt to stem the rise of nationalism, and as a way to
accommodate the inclusion of more diverse actors into the high spheres of European society and
culture. In the end, of course, it was too fragile to stand against the forces of nationalism.
Section 2. The effects of late 19th century globalization
11
small effect on the overall labour market, given agricultures small share in overall employment there
(just 22.6% in 1871). Thus, ORourke and Williamson (1994) estimate that British real wages rose by
43% between 1870 and 1913, and that no fewer than twenty percentage points of this increase can be
directly attributed to declining transport costs. On the other hand, in more agricultural economies the
net impact of cheap grain on wages could have been negative, if it sufficiently depressed agricultural
employment and wages (ORourke 1997).
While trade had a profound impact on land rents and relative factor prices, migration was the
dimension of globalization that probably had the greatest impact on European workers living
standards during this period. Emigration due to poverty can be a source of great sadness for the
families and communities left behind. It can be difficult therefore for people to admit that emigration
may in fact have been hugely beneficial for peripheral and impoverished economies, and yet this is
precisely what basic economic theory would suggest: lower the supply of labour, and its price should
rise.
Figure 1.6 shows the (PPP-adjusted) wages of unskilled male urban workers in three countries
of mass emigration, Ireland, Italy and Norway. Between 1870 and 1910, emigration lowered the Irish
labour force by 45%, the Italian labour force by 39%, and the Norwegian labour force by 24%
(ORourke and Williamson 1999, Table 8.1). The wages are measured relative to wages in the leading
European economy of the day, Britain. The figure shows that living standards in these three
economies did not just rise during the late 19th century: they rose more rapidly than in Britain. In
Ireland, for example, real wages rose from 73% to 92% of British wages during this period, while
Norwegian wages rose from 48% to 95%. This represents impressive convergence. In Italy there was
no convergence until the turn of the century, which is exactly when Italian emigration rates exploded,
attaining levels of over 100 per thousand per decade; thereafter, real Italian wages rose from 40% of
British wages in 1900, to 56% in 1913. Figure 1.7 repeats the exercise, this time reporting the three
countries wages relative to wages in the US. The figure shows that Norwegian wages continually
converged on US wages, while Italian wages converged after 1900; Irish wages converged over the
period as a whole, although very rapid US growth in the final two decades of the period implied Irish
divergence after 1895 or so.
Clearly, living standards in these peripheral emigrant economies rose very rapidly in the late
19th century, more rapidly even than in core economies like Britain and the US. At a minimum,
emigration did not prevent convergence; more positively, econometric and simulation studies show
that emigration was an important source of living standard convergence for countries such as Ireland.
To what extent can these findings be generalised? Taylor and Williamson (1997) calculate the labour
market impact of migration in 17 Atlantic economy countries between 1870 and 1910, taking care to
take account of return migration rates, which varied from country to country. According to their
analysis, which makes use of econometrically estimated labour demand elasticities and information on
labours share of income, emigration raised Irish wages by 32%, Italian by 28% and Norwegian by
13
10%. International real wage dispersion fell by 28% between 1870 and 1910, reflecting a convergence
of poorer countries on the rich, but in the absence of the mass migrations international real wage
dispersion would have increased by 7%. Wage gaps between New World and Old in fact declined
from 108 to 85% during the period, but in the absence of the mass migrations they would have risen
to 128% in 1910. The results suggest that more than all (125%) of the real wage convergence between
1870 and 1910 was attributable to migration. Even when allowance is made for the possibility that
capital may have chased labour, lowering the impact of migration on capital-labour ratios, migration
emerges as a major determinant of living standards convergence, explaining about 70% of the
convergence. Mass migration accounted for all of Irelands and Italys convergence on the United
States, and for 65-87% of their convergence on Britain. The biggest lesson of 19th century migration
history is that emigration is of major benefit to poor economies (a point stressed by Williamson
2002b).
as the Lucas paradox: capital usually flows to rich rather than to poor countries today, despite the fact
that wages are lower in poor countries (Lucas 1990). Three explanations have been offered to explain
the Lucas paradox for late 19th century Europe. First, lower labour productivity in the periphery can
potentially explain why capital did not flow to the poorer European countries (Clark 1987). However,
such an answer only begs the question as to why labour productivity was lower in the European
periphery. Second, non-adherence to gold might have dissuaded foreign investors. In support of the
latter theory it is worth pointing out that the Scandinavian countries had the best record of adherence
to gold among the peripheral economies. And finally, as the earlier discussion of British capital
exports suggests, it may simply be that these countries were not as attractive to investors as the landabundant territories of the New World.
consumers. Since much of the investment went into the construction of railways and other social
overhead projects, it implied cheaper imports of food stuff and raw materials, which represented a
major contribution to European core welfare.
America might have sparked rapid growth there, even in the absence of protection. Perhaps Germany
and the United States would have grown even more rapidly than they actually did in the absence of
protection. Such considerations have not prevented such prominent economic historians as Paul
Bairoch from stating that protection = economic growth and expansion of trade; liberalism =
stagnation in both (Bairoch 1989, p. 69).
Multiple regression analysis can evaluate such claims more precisely, by examining the
correlation between protectionism and economic growth, controlling for other factors that might
influence growth. By using panel data, it is furthermore possible to control for unmeasured
differences across countries that are invariant over time (by adding country dummy variables to the
specification). ORourke (2000) provided such an analysis for ten rich countries between the 1870s
and the Great War, including seven European economies: Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Norway,
Sweden and the UK. His surprising finding was that there was a clear positive partial correlation
between average tariffs and growth for this sample of countries: in one specification, a one standard
deviation increase in the average tariff was associated with a 0.74% increase in annual growth rates, a
large effect (ORourke 2000, p. 465). Not surprisingly, such a finding has been challenged by other
scholars. For example, Irwin (2002) argues that this positive correlation is a coincidence, driven by
the fact that the frontier economies of the time, such as the US, Canada and Australia (the three nonEuropean countries in this sample) had both a high growth potential and a high reliance on import
tariffs as a source of government revenue. (On the other hand, if this argument is correct, then
introducing country dummy variables into the analysis should lower or eliminate the positive
correlation between tariffs and growth, whereas in fact it strengthens it.) Clemens and Williamson
(2004b) broaden the analysis by including 35 countries in their sample, including such poorer
European countries as Austria-Hungary, Greece, Portugal, Russia, Serbia and Spain, as well as a
variety of Asian, Middle Eastern and Latin American counties. They find that while the overall
correlation between tariffs and growth was indeed positive, the correlation was negative for the poorer
European countries. Protectionism may have helped a country such as Germany during this period,
perhaps by fostering industrialisation there, but it did little good in countries such as Greece or Serbia,
if these results are to be believed. Quite why the same policy should have had different effects in
different countries is a question which these statistical exercises do not answer, but it should be noted
that Friedrich List himself, the great German protectionist thinker, maintained that
Measures of protection are justifiable only for the purpose of furthering and protecting the internal
manufacturing power, and only in the case of nations which through an extensive and compact
territory, large population, possession of natural resources, far advanced agriculture, a high degree of
civilisation and political development, are qualified to maintain an equal rank with the principal
agricultural manufacturing commercial nations, with the greatest naval and military powers (Part
Two, Ch, 26).
If free trade was not a universal panacea, then neither was protectionism, it appears.
18
3.1. Backlash
3.1.1. Trade
As we saw in Chapter 4 of Volume 1, 19th century European trade policy trends initially
reinforced the impact of falling transport costs. Things were different after the 1870s, however, as a
result of the growing impact of intercontinental trade on factor prices highlighted above. As we have
seen, this hurt European landed interests, and wherever these were powerful enough, the legislative
reaction was predictable. In Germany, Bismarck protected both agriculture and industry in 1879; in
France, tariffs were raised in the 1880s, and again in 1892; in Sweden, agricultural protection was reimposed in 1888 and industrial protection was increased in 1892; in Italy, moderate tariffs were
imposed in 1878, followed by more severe tariffs in 1887 (although this was not enough to prevent
mass emigration from the countryside: see Kindleberger 1951). Figure 1.8 gives ad valorem
equivalent tariffs for the four major European grains (wheat, barley, oats and rye) in three countries,
France, Germany and Sweden. In all three countries, tariffs on individual grains at times exceeded
50%, which represents heavy protection by any standard.
There were exceptions to this pattern of liberalisation followed by a reversion to protection.
Liberalization was both shorter and less dramatic in Iberia. Some small countries remained relatively
liberal: the Netherlands, Belgium, Switzerland, and Denmark, which transformed itself from a grainexporter to a grain-importing exporter of animal products (ibid.). The United Kingdom also
maintained free trade, despite the efforts of Joseph Chamberlain. As a grain-exporter, Russia hardly
feared free trade in agricultural products, but it was the first to backtrack from what had in any event
being a rather half-hearted liberalization, increasing tariffs substantially in 1877, 1885 and again in
1891. The purpose was to stimulate industrialization, and tariffs were combined with export subsidies
for cotton textile producers. Austria-Hungary also shifted sharply towards protectionism in the 1880s.
The Balkan countries had inherited liberal tariff policies from their Ottoman masters, but they too
gradually moved towards higher protection, albeit at a slower pace than the Germans or Russians
(Bairoch 1989).
Exactly why not all food-importing countries reverted to agricultural protection has sparked a
large political science literature (e.g. Gourevitch 1986, Rogowski 1989). Economic considerations
were surely important: it seems as though countries such as Denmark and the United Kingdom which
retained agricultural free trade were less vulnerable to the price and rent reductions which
globalization implied. In the Danish case grain prices had been low to begin with, while the country
was exceptionally well suited to meet the growing British demand for butter, eggs and bacon, in part
due to the success of its cooperative societies. In the British case, agriculture had already shrunk
19
significantly (Chapter 3), and further decline had little impact on the overall economy (ORourke
1997). Elsewhere, it seems that globalization undermined itself. Moreover, this switch towards
protectionism would turn out to be permanent. Countries such as Germany, and in particular France,
have remained strongly in favour of agricultural protection up to the present day (Tracy 1989).
3.1.2. Immigration
Meanwhile, something similar was happening in the land-abundant countries of the New
World. While emigration was good for European workers, as we have seen, the immigration of
millions of predominantly unskilled workers was bad news for their counterparts overseas. Hatton and
Williamson (1998) show that immigration lowered unskilled wages in the United States, although this
is clearly a ceteris paribus finding, since economic growth was raising living standards generally
during this period. Nonetheless, the effects could be large. According to the Taylor and Williamson
(1997) estimates cited earlier, immigration lowered US unskilled real wages by 8%, relative to what
they would have been in its absence; they lowered Canadian real wages by 15%; and they lowered
Argentinian real wages by 21%. Counterfactual or not, such impacts did not go unnoticed at the time,
and the result was a political backlash, resulting in gradually tightening restrictions on immigration in
the main destination countries (Timmer and Williamson 1998). For example, in 1888 the United
States banned all Chinese immigration for twenty years, while in 1891 it banned the immigration of
persons likely to become public charges as well as those assisted in passage (ibid., p. 765). The
screw continued to be tightened on immigration until 1917, when a literacy test was imposed on
would-be migrants, a provision which effectively blocked much of the low-skilled immigration of the
day. Very similar trends can be discerned in Canada and Argentina as well. This shift away from a
relatively laisser faire immigration policy was to prove extremely long-lasting, with the result that
European economies no longer had available to them the safety valve of overseas emigration that had
helped sustain living standards during the population boom and slow transition to modern growth of
the late 19th century.
i.e. raising the discount rate when needed would be adhered to if this conflicted with domestic
policy objectives. However, Eichengreen also notes that the franchise was already being extended
before the war in many countries, and that unemployment was becoming a growing social issue. One
can therefore speculate that even in the absence of war, this political factor would have ultimately
succeeded in undermining the gold standard, and with it the foundations of the pre-war international
financial system. Furthermore, according to Karl Polanyi (1957, p. 234) such a political development
might well have been inevitable, since Socialism is, essentially, the tendency inherent in an industrial
civilization to transcend the self-regulating market by consciously subordinating it to a democratic
society. To this extent, one might yet again see globalization as having undermined itself.
Several objections could be raised against such reasoning, however. First, the single largest
push for universal suffrage and democratisation came, as Eichengreen says, in the wake of World War
I, not as a result of globalisation. Second, even if the gold standard had proved unsustainable, this
would not necessarily have implied the end of global financial integration. In todays world, most
capital circulates among rich countries which are (with the notable exception of the euro zone) no
longer connected by fixed exchange rates. Indeed, as Obstfeld and Taylor (2004) point out,
abandoning fixed exchange rates makes it possible for countries to pursue both independent monetary
policies and a commitment to open capital markets. It was the attempt to combine fixed exchange
rates with Keynesian macroeconomic policies which, in their view, condemned mid-20th century
capital markets.
Yet another question is whether the magnitude of capital flows experienced before World
War I was sustainable. We have pointed out that frontier expansion was one of the main reasons for
the massive capital exports, and frontier expansion, by definition, has to come to a halt at some point.
Still, the areas of recent settlement were destined to remain the land-abundant countries for some time
to come, and hence could have continued to attract European capital (and labour). Even today,
population density in the US remains at 10% the level of the UK and Germany.
just as in the American West, with hitherto uncultivated land being cleared to produce rice (as in
Burma), cocoa (as in Ghana), or other primary products. Eventually, these frontiers would inevitably
be exhausted, as they were being exhausted by the end of this period in New World economies such
as the United States (where the frontier was officially declared closed in 1890). Once this had
happened, continuing population growth would lead to the onset of diminishing returns, forcing up
the price of the Souths primary exports. Meanwhile, declining transport costs meant that modern
industry would no longer be tied to coalfields and sources of iron ore, implying that it could spread to
low wage regions. Notably, several Southern countries, notably Japan, but also India, Mexico,
Brazil and others, were beginning to industrialize by the end of the period. All this suggests that the
North-South division of labour which underlay the late 19th century world economy would ultimately
have become blurred.
In addition, as we have seen there were powerful political forces which were undermining
that international economy as well. However, it would be wrong to portray European governments of
this period as being faced with a binary choice between open and closed international markets. Their
options were not restricted to resisting or giving into protectionist anti-globalization backlashes.
Rather, there was a range of complementary domestic policies which governments could and did
put in place during this period in order to shore up support for liberal international policies. Thus,
Huberman and Lewchuk (2003) show that there was extensive government intervention in European
labour markets in the late 19th century, a period that also saw a sustained rise in social transfers and
the beginnings of what eventually evolved into the modern welfare state (Lindert 2004). A range of
labour market regulations was introduced across the continent, for example prohibiting night work for
women and children, prohibiting child labour below certain ages, and introducing factory inspections.
The period also saw the widespread introduction of old-age, sickness and unemployment insurance
schemes. Moreover, this labour compact was more widespread in the more open European
economies. Huberman and Lewchuk interpret this finding as providing support for the argument that
unions were persuaded to back free trade, or openness more generally, in return for pro-labour
domestic policies. In related work, Huberman (2004) finds that working hours in Europe and her
offshoots declined between 1870 and 1913 as a result of labour legislation and union pressure, and
that the decline was greatest in small open economies such as Belgium, where the Labour Party
supported free trade after 1885 (Huberman 2007). Not only did governments not indulge in a race to
the bottom during the late 19th century globalization boom: in some cases governments cooperated so
as to ensure a general raising of standards. Such was the case, for example, with the Franco-Italian
labour accord of 1904, which raised labour standards in Italy as a quid pro quo for granting Italian
workers in France benefits which their French colleagues already enjoyed.
To some extent, therefore, late 19th century governments successfully managed the political
challenges posed by globalization, sometimes defusing protectionist demands by means of domestic
legislation, and sometimes giving into them. World trade might have grown more slowly after 1914
22
than it did before, even had war not intervened, and the political challenges facing governments might
have been exacerbated; but the 1920s and 1930s would have been utterly different had it not been for
the Great War, to which we now turn.
perceived that Germany might also be vulnerable, and began to view naval blockades as a potentially
useful offensive weapon in time of war; German planners reached similar conclusions and the two
nations embarked on a naval arms race. This vulnerability also meant that German worries that the
Reich could only lose a drawn-out, defensive war, and especially a two-front war. This encouraged it
to gamble on a quick victory against France. According to Rowe, the fact that states now found it
more difficult to maintain large armies also heightened the sense of insecurity which military planners
felt, and made it more difficult for them to credibly deter aggression. Paradoxically, Rowe concludes
(p. 446) that Europe did not go to war despite globalizations constraints on military force in prewar
Europe; Europe went to war because these constraints undermined the very foundations on which
European peace rested.
24
References
Angell, N. 1910. The Great Illusion: A Study of the Relation of Military Power in Nations to their
Economic and Social Advantage. London: William Heinemann.
Bairoch, P. 1974. General Structure and Trade Balance of European Foreign Trade. Journal of
European Economic History 3: 557-608.
Bairoch, P. 1989. European Trade Policy, 1815-1914. In The Cambridge Economic History of
Europe, Volume VIII, The Industrial Economies: The Development of Economic and Social Policies,
ed. P. Mathias and S. Pollard. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bairoch, P. 1993. Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. Hemel Hempstead:
Harvester-Wheatsheaf.
Bordo, M.D., B. Eichengreen and D.A. Irwin. 1999. Is Globalization Today Really Different from
Globalization a Hundred Years Ago? in Brookings Trade Forum 1999, ed. R.Z. Lawrence and S.M.
Collins. Washington DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Bordo, M.D., and F.E. Kydland. 1995. The Gold Standard as a Rule: An Essay in Exploration.
Explorations in Economic History 32: 423-64.
Bordo, M.D., and H. Rockoff. 1996. The Gold Standard as a 'Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval'.
Journal of Economic History 56: 389-428.
Cain, P.J. and A.G. Hopkins. 2002. British Imperialism 1688-2000, Second Edition. Harlow:
Longman.
Calvo, G. 1998. Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops.
Journal of Applied Economics 1: 35-54.
Caves, R.E. 1996. Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Charle, C. 1994. La Rpublique des Universitaires. Paris: Seuil.
Chiswick, B.R. and T.J. Hatton. 2003. International Migration and the Integration of Labor Markets.
In Globalization in Historical Perspective, ed. M.D. Bordo, A.M. Taylor and J.G. Williamson.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Clark, G. 1987. Why Isn't the Whole World Developed? Lessons from the Cotton Mills. Journal of
Economic History 47: 141-173.
Clark, G. and R.C. Feenstra. 2003. Technology in the Great Divergence. In Globalization in
Historical Perspective, ed. M.D. Bordo, A.M. Taylor and J.G. Williamson. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Clemens, M.A. and J.G. Williamson. 2004a. Wealth Bias in the First Global Capital Market Boom,
1870-1913. Economic Journal 114: 304-337.
Clemens, M.A. and J.G. Williamson. 2004b. Why did the Tariff-Growth Correlation Change after
1950? Journal of Economic Growth 9: 5-46.
Collins, W.J. 1996. Regional Labor Markets in British India. Mimeo, Harvard University.
Davis, L.E. and R.A. Huttenback. 1986. Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Political Economy
25
Fletcher, M.E. 1958. The Suez Canal and World Shipping, 1869-1914. Journal of Economic History
18:556-573.
Foreman-Peck, J. 1991. International Technology Transfer in Telephony, 1876-1914. In International
Technology Transfer : Europe, Japan and the USA, 1700-1914, ed. D.J. Jeremy. Aldershot: Eldward
Elgar.
Garbade, K.D. and W.L. Silber. 1978. Technology, Communication and the Performance of Financial
Markets: 1840-1975. Journal of Finance 33:819-832.
Gourevitch, P. 1986. Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic
Crises. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Harley, C.K. 1980. Transportation, the World Wheat Trade, and the Kuznets Cycle, 1850-1913.
Explorations in Economic History 17: 218-250.
Harley, C.K. 1990. North Atlantic Shipping in the Late Nineteenth Century: Freight Rates and the
Interrelationship of Cargoes. In Shipping and Trade, 1750-1950: Essays in International Maritime
History, ed. L.R. Fischer and H.W. Nordvik. Pontefract: Lofthouse.
Hatton, T.J. and J.G. Williamson. 1994. What Drove the Mass Migrations from Europe in the Late
Nineteenth Century? Population and Development Review 20: 1-27.
Hatton, T.J. and J.G. Williamson. 1998. The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and Economic Impact.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hatton, T.J. and J.G. Williamson. 2005. Global Migration and the World Economy: Two Centuries of
Policy and Performance. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Huberman, M. 2004. Working Hours of the World Unite? New International Evidence of Worktime,
1870-1913. Journal of Economic History 64: 964-1001.
Huberman, M. 2007. A Ticket to Trade: Belgian Workers and Globalization Before 1914. Economic
History Review, forthcoming.
Huberman, M. and W. Lewchuk. 2003. European Economic Integration and the Labour Compact,
1850-1913. European Review of Economic History 7: 3-41.
Hurd, J. 1975. Railways and the Expansion of Markets in India, 1861-1921. Explorations in
Economic History 12: 263-288.
Imlah, A.H. 1952. British Balance of Payments and Export of Capital, 1816-1913. Economic History
Review 5:208-239.
Irwin, D.A. 2002. Interpreting the Tariff-Growth Correlation of the Late 19th Century. American
Economic Review 92: 165-169.
Issawi, C. 1966. The Economy of the Middle East 1800-1914. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Jacks, D.S. 2005. Intra- and International Commodity Market Integration in the Atlantic Economy,
18001913. Explorations in Economic History 42:381-413.
Jacks, D.S. 2006. What Drove 19th Century Commodity Market Integration? Explorations in
Economic History 43: 383-412.
27
Jeremy, D.J., ed. 1991. International Technology Transfer, Europe, Japan and the USA, 1700-1914.
Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
Jones, M.T. and M. Obstfeld. 2001. Saving, Investment, and Gold: A Reassessment of Historical
Current Account Data. In Money, Capital Mobility, and Trade: Essays in Honor of Robert A.
Mundell, ed. G.A. Calvo, M. Obstfeld and R. Dornbusch. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Kindleberger, C.P. 1951. Group Behavior and International Trade. Journal of Political Economy
59:30-46.
Kirk, D. 1946. Europes Population in the Interwar Years. New York, London and Paris: Gordon and
Breach Science Publishers.
Klovland, J.T. 2005. Commodity Market Integration 1850-1913: Evidence from Britain and Germany.
European Review of Economic History 9: 163-197.
Lvy-Leboyer, M., and F. Bourguignon. 1990. The French Economy in the Nineteenth Century.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lindert, P.H. 2004. Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth since the Eighteenth
Century, Volume I, The Story. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lpez-Crdova, J.E. and C.M. Meissner. 2003. Exchange-Rate Regimes and International Trade:
Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard Era. American Economic Review 93:344-353.
Lucas, R.E. 1990. Why Doesn't Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries? American Economic
Review 80: 92-96.
Maddison, A. 1995. Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992. Paris: OECD.
Maddison, A. 2001. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.
Maddison, A. 2003. The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD.
Mauro, P., N. Sussman, and Y. Yafeh. 2002. Emerging Market Spreads: Then Versus Now. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117: 695-733.
Metzer, J. 1974. Railroad Development and Market Integration: The Case of Tsarist Russia. Journal
of Economic History 34: 529-550.
Mitchener, K.J. and M. Weidenmier. 2007. Trade and Empire. Mimeo, Santa Clara University and
Claremont McKenna College.
Morys, M. 2006. The Classical Gold Standard in the European Periphery: A Case Study of AustriaHungary and Italy, 1870-1913. PhD thesis, London School of Economics and Political Science.
O'Brien, P.K. and L. Prados de la Escosura, eds. 1998. The Costs and Benefits of European
Imperialism from the Conquest of Ceuta, 1415, to the Treaty of Lusaka, 1974. Revista de Historia
Econmica Special Issue, XVI, 1, Invierno.
Obstfeld, M., and A.M. Taylor. 2003. Sovereign Risk, Credibility and the Gold Standard: 1870-1913
vs. 1925-1931. Economic Journal 113: 241-75.
Obstfeld, M. and A.M. Taylor. 2004. Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis, and Growth.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
28
Offer, A. 1989. The First World War: An Agrarian Interpretation. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Offer, A. 1993. The British Empire, 1870-1914: A Waste of Money? Economic History Review 46:
215-238.
ORourke, K.H. 1997. The European Grain Invasion, 1870-1913. Journal of Economic History 57:
775-801.
ORourke, K.H. 2000. Tariffs and Growth in the Late 19th Century. Economic Journal 110: 456-483.
ORourke, K.H. 2002. Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790-2000. In From Europeanization
of the Globe to the Globalization of Europe, ed. H. Kierzkowski. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
ORourke, K.H., A.M. Taylor, and J.G. Williamson. 1996. Factor Price Convergence in the Late
Nineteenth Century. International Economic Review 37: 499-530.
ORourke, K.H. and J.G. Williamson. 1994. Late 19th Century Anglo-American Factor Price
Convergence: Were Heckscher and Ohlin Right? Journal of Economic History 54: 892-916.
ORourke, K.H. and J.G. Williamson. 1997. Around the European Periphery 1870-1913:
Globalization, Schooling and Growth. European Review of Economic History 1: 153-191.
ORourke, K.H. and J.G. Williamson. 1999. Globalization and History: The Evolution of a
Nineteenth Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Polanyi, K. 1957. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of our Time.
Boston: Beacon Press.
Robertson, D.H. 1938. The Future of International Trade. Economic Journal 48: 1-14.
Rodrguez, F. and D. Rodrik. 2001. Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptics Guide to the
Cross-National Evidence. In Macroeconomics Annual 2000, ed. B. Bernanke and K.S. Rogoff.
Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Rogowski, R. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rowe, D.M. 2005. The Tragedy of Liberalism: How Globalization Caused the First World War.
Security Studies 14: 407-447.
Sachs, J. D. and A.M. Warner. 1995. Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1-118.
Stone, I. 1999. The Global Export of Capital from Great Britain, 1865-1914: A Statistical Survey.
London: Macmillan Press.
Taylor, A.M. 1992. External Dependence, Demographic Burdens, and Argentine Economic Decline
after the Belle Epoque. Journal of Economic History 52: 907-36.
Taylor, A.M. 1996. International Capital Mobility in History: The Saving-Investment Relationship.
NBER Working Paper No. 5743.
Taylor, A.M. and J.G. Williamson. 1997. Convergence in the Age of Mass Migration. European
Review of Economic History 1: 27-63.
Temin, P. 1987. Capital Exports, 1870-1914: An Alternative Model. Economic History Review 40:
29
453-458.
Timmer, A. and J.G. Williamson. 1998. Immigration Policy Prior to the Thirties: Labor Markets,
Policy Interactions and Globalization Backlash. Population and Development Review 24: 739-771.
Tracy, M. 1989. Government and Agriculture in Western Europe 1880-1988, Third Edition. New
York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Ville, S. 1991. Shipping Industry Technologies. In International Technology Transfer : Europe,
Japan and the USA, 1700-1914, ed. D.J. Jeremy. Aldershot: Eldward Elgar.
Wilkins, M. 1970. The Emergence of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from the
Colonial Era to 1914. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Williamson, J.G. 1974. Late Nineteenth Century American Development: A General Equilibrium
History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Williamson, J.G. 1995. The Evolution of Global Labor Markets Since 1830: Background Evidence
and Hypotheses. Explorations in Economic History 32: 141-96.
Williamson, J.G. 2002a. Land, Labor and Globalization in the Third World, 1870-1940. Journal of
Economic History 62: 55-85.
Williamson, J.G. 2002b. Winners and Losers Over Two Centuries of Globalization. NBER Working
Paper No. 9161.
Yates, P.L. 1959. Forty Years of Foreign Trade. London: George Allen and Unwin.
30
1913
Region
Exports
Imports
Balance
Exports
Imports
Balance
UK
117
1362
-1245
760
2596
-1836
Northwestern Europe
840
1800
-960
3064
5894
-2830
Other Europe
750
515
235
1793
1689
104
1707
600
3677
330
-1970
270
5617
2101
10179
1542
-4562
559
Oceania
455
129
326
Latin America
1531
595
936
Africa
680
307
373
1792
949
843
12176
13701
-1525
Europe
USA and Canada
Asia
Total
1413
3720
575
4582
838
-862
Manufactures
1876-80
1913
Region
Exports
Imports
Balance
Exports
Imports
Balance
UK
865
225
640
1751
601
1150
Northwestern Europe
1080
450
630
3318
1795
1523
Other Europe
210
330
-120
578
1133
-555
2155
100
1005
190
1150
-90
5647
734
3529
891
2118
-157
Oceania
370
-361
Latin America
51
879
-828
Africa
26
451
-425
461
1247
-786
6928
7367
-439
Europe
USA and Canada
Asia
Total
35
2290
1285
2480
-1250
-190
Source: Yates (1959), pp.226-32.Note that world trade does not balance due to unrecorded trade.
31
Table 1.2. Foreign Investment of England, France and Germany, 1870 - 1913
23.9%
5.1%
16.5%
19.1%
17.3%
Foreign Investment as
% of Saving
Foreign Investment /
GDP
Saving / GDP
32.5%
38.5%
30.9%
29.4%
49.6%
Germany
Foreign Investment as
% of Saving
4.0%
4.7%
3.4%
3.7%
6.5%
Foreign Investment /
GDP
Foreign Investment as
% of Saving
12.3%
12.2%
11.0%
12.6%
13.1%
Saving / GDP
Foreign Investment /
GDP
1870 79
1880 89
1890 99
1900 09
1905 14
France
Saving / GDP
England
10.2%
18.8%
12.1%
8.3%
7.5%
32.1%
41.8%
19.8%
12.8%
Sources: Edelstein (1982, 2004), Feis (1930), Jones & Obstfeld (2001), Lvy-Leboyer& Bourguignon (1990),
Maddison (1995, 2003).
32
Table 1.3. Destination of English, French and German Foreign Investment 1870 - 1913
England
France
Germany
3.4%
1.0%
1.0%
0.8%
1.0%
2.5%
9.7%
25.1%
7.3%
4.9%
8.7%
2.9%
12.2%
61.1%
7.7%
7.7%
12.8%
7.2%
Europe
Russia
Ottoman Empire
Austria-Hungary
Spain and Portugal
Italy
Other Countries
Total (Europe)
Areas of recent settlement (outside Latin
USA
Canada
Australia
New Zealand
Total
Latin America
Areas of recent settlement
Argentina
Brazil
Total (areas of recent settlement)
Other countries
Mexico
Chile
Uruguay
Cuba
Total (Latin America)
Africa
Asia
India
Japan
China
Total (Asia)
Rest
Total
Colonies
20.5%
10.1%
8.3%
2.1%
41.0%
4.4%
17.9%
53.3%
15.7%
4.4%
15.7%
13.3%
16.2%
13.3%
7.3%
16.2%
8.5%
4.9%
4.3%
4.9%
9%
100.0%
8.9%
4.3%
2%
100.0%
2.6%
8.6%
4.2%
53.8%
2.0%
1.5%
0.8%
0.6%
17.7%
9.1%
7.8%
1.9%
1.8%
11.5%
11.0%
100.0%
16.9%
Notes: Numbers for Russia and the Ottoman Empire include investment into non-European parts.
Sources: Esteves (2007), Feis (1930), Stone (1999).
33
1851-60
1861-70
1871-80
1881-90
1891-00 1901-10
2.9
58.0
51.8
50.4
20.6
1.1
1.2
5.0
24.2
5.9
57.6
19.0
1.5
14.7
66.1
10.5
4.6
47.3
28.9
4.6
30.5
23.5
13.0
34
10.6
8.6
70.2
39.4
13.2
3.1
28.7
141.7
33.6
12.3
95.2
38.0
36.2
70.1
32.0
16.1
3.5
43.8
22.3
23.2
1.3
10.1
88.5
50.2
5.0
44.9
50.8
43.8
41.2
14.1
47.6
6.1
65.3
28.2
54.5
1.4
4.5
69.8
107.7
5.1
83.3
56.9
56.6
42.0
13.9
35%
30%
25%
Oceania
Africa
Asia
South America
North America
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
35
1.00
5.00
4.50
4.00
3.50
0.60
3.00
2.50
0.40
2.00
1.50
0.20
Correlation coefficient
0.80
1.00
0.50
1985
1980
1975
1970
1965
1960
1955
1950
1945
1940
1935
1930
1925
1920
1915
1910
1905
1900
1895
1890
1885
1880
1875
0.00
1870
0.00
Figure 1.2. Levels of international capital mobility and bond spreads of peripheral economies over
England, 1870-1985 (quinquennia).
Source: Cross-section correlation coefficient between saving and investment ratios based on Taylor (1996).
Bond spreads of peripheral economies: Spreads of Argentina, Austria-Hungary, Brazil, Greece, Italy, Portugal,
Spain and Russia over England (unweighted average), own calculations based on Flandreau & Zumer (2004).
36
1600
1400
Thousands
1200
1000
Old
800
New
600
Total
400
200
0
1840
1860
1880
1900
1920
Year
Source: Kirk (1946), p. 279. Note: Old consists of Britain and Ireland, Germany, Scandinavia, France,
Switzerland and the Low Countries. New consists of Italy, Austro-Hungarian Empire, Russian Empire, Iberia
and the Balkans.
37
38
400
160
350
140
300
120
250
100
200
80
150
60
100
40
50
20
0
18501854
18551859
18601865
18651869
18701874
18751879
18801884
18851889
18901894
18951899
19001904
19051909
19101914
19151920
Sources: Union des Associations Internationales, Les Congrs Internationaux de 1681 1899
/ International Congresses 1681 to 1899, Bruxelles, 1960; Union des Associations
Internationales, Les 1.978 Organisations Internationales fondes depuis le Congrs de
Vienne, Bruxelles, 1957.
39
40
41
70
60
60
50
50
40
40
percent
percent
70
30
30
20
20
10
10
0
1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910
France
Germany
0
1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910
Sweden
France
70
70
60
60
50
50
40
40
30
30
20
20
10
10
0
1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910
France
Sweden
Rye
percent
percent
Wheat
Germany
Germany
0
1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910
Sweden
France
Oats
Germany
Barley
42
Sweden