Deficit Mankew
Deficit Mankew
Deficit Mankew
Laurence Ball
N. Gregory Mankiw
This paper was prepared for the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium on Budget
Deficits and Debt, in Jackson Hole, Wyoming. on August 31 - September 2, 1995. We arc
Foundation for
grateful to Michael Rashes for research assisthnce and to the National Science
financial support. This paper is part of NBERs research programs in Economic Fluctuations and
not those of the
Monetary Economics. Any opinions expressed am those of the authors and
National Bureau of Economic Research.
© 1995 by Laurence Bali and N. Gregory Mankiw. All rights reserved. Short sections of text.
full
not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that
credit. including © notice, is given to the source.
NBER Working Paper 5263
September 1995
ABSTRACT
This paper discusses the effects of budget deficits on the economy in four steps. First,
it reviews standard theory about how budget deficits influence saving, investment, the trade
balance. interest rates, exchange rates, and long-term growth. Second, it offers a rough estimate
of the magnitude of some of the effects. Third, it discusses how budget deficits affect economic
welfare. Finally, it considers the possibility that continuing budget deficits in a country could
lead to a hard landing" in which the demand for the country's assets suddenly collapses.
the issue, many economists share the view that deficits are
haruful, and perhaps even disastrous.
When economists and policymakers decry deficits, they cite
as well as losers? If so, who are they? How large are the effects
right track.
deficits, we take
After describing the qualitative effects of
1
a stab in Section II at quantifying the effects of recent deficits
in the United States. As usual in economics, theory is too
stylized to give precise estimates of the sizes of the effects.
But some simple calculations shed light on the orders of magnitude
involved.
Both the likelihood of such an event and its effects are highly
uncertain. But the risx of a hard landing may be the most
compelling reason for reducing budget deficits.
2
variables, such as GDP, investment, net exports, wages, interest
revenue that the government saves rather than spends). When the
government runs a budget deficit, public saving is negative, which
reduces national saving below private saving.
The effect of a budget deficit on national saving is most
likely less than one—for—one, for a decrease in public saving
produces a partially.-offsetting increase in private saving. For
example, consider a one—dollar tax cut. This tax cut reduces
The total fall in investment and net exports must exactly match the
from the equality of the current account and the capital account.
When a country imports more than it exports, it does not receive
domestic products?
The answer is that these changes are brought about by interest
5
The appreciation of the currency, in turn, affects trade in
goods and services. With a stronger currency, domestic goods are
more expensive for foreigners, and foreign goods are cheaper for
domestic residents. Exports fall, imports rise, and the trade
balance moves toward deficit.2
To sum up: government budget deficits reduce national saving,
6
Budget Deficits in the United States
So far, our discussion of budget deficits has been
theoretical. Do the effects we have discussed occur in actual
experience? There is a large empirical literature that looks for
these effects, unfortunately, this work has neither refuted the
7
and persistent deficit, a fall of about 2.0 percent of GOP. These
8
Table 1
9
Long-Run Effects of Deficits: Output and Wealth
10
crowd out capital, national income falls because less is produced;
if budget deficits lead to trade deficits, just as much is
produced, but less of the income from production accrues to
domestic residents.
In addition to affecting total income, deficits also alter
factor prices: wages (the return to labor) and profits (the return
product of labor falls, for each worker has less capital to work
with. At the same time, the marginal product of capital rises, for
the scarcity of capital makes the marginal unit of capital more
profit.
budget deficits have a more direct implication for the future: the
11
funds to pay the debt.
By how much must taxes rise or spending fall to pay off a
country's debt? This question is more tricky than it seems, for
the answer depends on both policy choices and luck. One surprising
fact is that the government may never need to raise taxes or cut
spending at all. Instead, it can simply roll over its debt: it can
pay off interest and maturing debt by issuing new debt. At first
this policy might appear unsustainable, because the level of debt
increases forever at the rate of interest. Yet as long as the rate
of GDP growth is higher than the interest rate, the ratio of debt
to G' falls over time. With the debt shrinking relative to the
size of the economy, the government can roll over the debt forever
even as its absolute size grows. That is, the economy can grow its
way out of the debt.
percent, and the average interest rate on debt was 4.0 percent. If
these trends continue, a policy of rolling over the debt (and using
taxes to pay for current government services) will cause the debt
to grow more slowly than GDP. The debt will eventually become
negligible relative to the size of the economy, even with no tax
increases -
Does this scenario sound too good to be true? It may be. The
12
catch is that the future paths of interest rates and GD? are
uncertain. Although interest rates on government debt have usually
and they come when the economy is already suffering from a problem
that has caused the debt—income ratio to rise.'
upper bound on the future tax burden arising from past budget
deficits, assuming the government chooses to play it safe.
A Parable
States.
14
The debt fairy's actions would affect four key variables: the
burden of debt service, the level of GD?, the real wage, and the
GDP.
The replacement of debt by physical capital would also raise
output.
Since the capital stock rises by the level of debt D,
percent as well. -
16
government debt for capital, and the debt fairy reverses this
process.
That if we relax the obviously false assumption of a closed
lB
States and most other industrialized nations have experienced slow
growth for the last 20 years, relative to the previous three
decades. This slowdown in growth is behind the widely publicized
stagnation in living standards for many workers and the resulting
public concern that something is wrong with the economy. The
19
do not raise GNP, they do raise consumption in the short run by
lowering households' tax burden.
If one focuses on consumption as the proper measure of well-
being, budget deficits come to look like a particular policy of
income redistribution. Redistributions occur because of the change
New York, leaving total taxes unchanged. This law does not benefit
for surfboards and reduce the demand for opera, leading to higher
profits for surfboard manufacturers and lower wages for singers.
20
tax refonu: it shifts taxes between groups. Here the shift is not
the income from their wages, while a small part of society holds
most of the economy's wealth. When crowding—out raises the returns
on capital and reduces wages, the wealthy gain at the expense of
than we are.
Another possible answer is that levels of taxation should be
based on the benefits principle, which holds that people should pay
for the government benefits that they receive. For example, the
use of a gasoline tax to pay for road repair is not based on the
abilities to pay of drivers and non—drivers; instead, it is
justified on the ground that drivers should pay for roads because
they benefit from them, Similarly, one might argue that each
generation should pay for the government it provides itself,
regardless of its level of income.
These issues are not easily resolved. Yet one point is clear:
saying whether and why deficits are undesirable requires judgeaents
that are more philosophical than economic.
23
politicians to avoid the future suffering caused by budget
deficits, suppose you are worried about the effects of deficits on
your children, and aren't confident that Bill Clinton and Newt
Gingrich will take care of the problem by balancing the budget.
You can eliminate your worries simply by saving and leaving a
larger bequest to your children, so that they can bear the burden
And, since you are accumulating more capital than the typical
family, you and your children are among the winners from deficit—
induced changes in factor prices. That is, you benefit from the
higher rates of return that deficits cause.
for the rich. A large poor population might raise crime rates and
otherwise threaten the living standards of the wealthy. The fact
that most people——both rich and poor—-prefer to live in rich
communities suggests that people care about their neighbors' living
25
average American standard of living may fall behind that in Japan.
26
if the debt—income ratio does keep rising?
Part of the answer is clear: the effects we have already
landing" night come about and the possible effects on the economy.
in peacetime——until recently.'
28
countries would never default. But Orange County, California is
even richer than the United States, and it is about to default on
its debt. Orange County voters, turning down a tax increase needed
to honor the debt, appear to reject the idea that they should pay
default, but it would also tax the holders of other assets. The
tax could extend to foreign owners of domestic assets to reduce the
29
burden on domestic citizens.
30
hence, the likelihood of repayment. similarly, a crisis in the
United States might be triggered by bad news about income growth,
which would imply higher debt—income ratios for given fiscal
policies.
since a hard landing involves the psychology of markets, it is
hard to judge when it might occur. The debt crisis hit Latin
jnerican countries with debt—income ratios below the current U.S.
level of one halt, but these countries had external debts and hence
the economy? Theory and the experiences of LDCs gives some guide
as to the effects. The decline in the demand for domestic assets
leads to a sharp fall in the prices of these assets, including a
fall in the stock market. Interest rates and other asset yields
rise. The value of the domestic currency falls as investors sell
31
surplus, and capital flows out of the country.
Such a hard landing potentially hans an economy in many ways.
Most obviously, wealth falls because of the decline in asset
prices. The lack of investor confidence and higher interest rates
1993)
Third, the hard landing could lead to inflation through two
distinct channels. The drop in the domestic currency would
directly push up the prices of iriports, which could trigger
32
continuing inflation if monetary policy is accommodative. And, in
response to the fiscal crisis, the monetary authority may feel
increased pressure to raise revenue through money creation. Both
these effects were important in producing high inflation in Latin
America after the debt crisis. We can hope that the central banks
vagueness of fears about hard landings, these fears may be the most
33
generations and groups of people, perhaps they should not be a
central concern of policyrnakers. But as countries increase their
debt, they wander into unfamiliar territory in which hard landings
may lurk. If policyrnakers are prudent, they will not take the
chance of learning what hard landings in G7 countries are really
like.
34
References
Bali, Laurence. N. Gregory Mankiw, and Douglas W. Elmendorf, "The
Deficit Gamble," NBER Working Paper No. 5015, February 1995.
Bernheim, B. Douglas, "Ricardian Equivalence: An Evaluation of
Theory and Evidence." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2 (1981),
263—304.
council of Economic Advisers, Economic Renort of the President,
1994.
(1991), 445—502.
Feldstein, Martin, "The Budget and Trade Deficits Aren't Really
Twins," NBER Working Paper Mc. 3966, January 1992.
Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, "Domestic Saving and
International Capital Flows," Econonic Journal 90 (1980), 314—
29.
1988.
35
Martin FeldstCifl, ed., The Risk of Economic Crisis, The
University of Chicago Press, 1981.
36