Topic One - Consumer Theory
Topic One - Consumer Theory
TOPIC ONE.
LECTURE OBJECTIVES
Page 1 of 35
In your elementary microeconomics, the basic principles of consumer behaviour were introduced
by laying a strong foundation on the theory of demand on which premise the consumer behaviour
is build upon. The consumer behaviour is introduced as a utility maximising behaviour but subject
to consumer’s ability to purchase. A consumer is portrayed as an agent who goes for the best that
he/she can afford.
In level 200 series we describe more precisely what we mean by ‘best’ and ‘I can afford’. In the
first section, we will examine how to describe what a consumer can afford; the next section will
focus on the concept of how the consumer determines what is best. We will then be able to
undertake a detailed study of the implications of this simple mode of consumer behaviour.
Suppose that there is some set of goods from which the consumer can choose. In real life there
are many goods to consume but we will consider two.
Let the consumer’s consumption bundle be X 1 X 2 where X 1 , represents the number of units the
consumer chooses of good 1 and X 2 is the number of units of good to be chosen by the consumer.
Let p1 and p 2 represent the unit prices for the two goods respectively; and M to represent the
amount of money the consumer has to spend.
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M
The budget constraint of the consumer requires that the amount of money spent on the two goods
is no more than the total amount the consumer has to spend. The consumer’s affordable
consumption bundles are those that do not cost any more than M. The set of affordable
consumption bundles at prices P1 P2 and income M is called the budget set of the consumer.
Page 2 of 35
The set of bundles that cost exactly M is called the budget line.
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M
These are the bundles of goods that just exhaust the consumer’s income. The budget is set is
shown below:
X2
M
P2 Budget line
P1
Slope
P2
Budget set
M X1
P1
The budget set consists of all bundles that are affordable at the given prices and income.
M P1
X2 X 2 .............................................3
P2 P2
M P
This is an equation for a straight line with a vertical intercept of and a slope of 1
P2 P2
Page 3 of 35
The example tells how many units of good 2 the consumer needs to consume in order to just satisfy
the budget constraint, if she is consuming X 1 units of good 1.
The slope of the budget line measures the rate at which the market is willing to substitute good 1
for good 2.
X 2 P
1
X 1 P2
The slope of the budget line is also said to be an opportunity cost of consuming good 1. In order
to consume more of good 1, one has to give up some consumption of good 2. Giving up the
opportunity to consume good 2 is the true economic cost of more of good 1 consumption, and that
cost is measured by the slope of the budget line.
Consumer Preferences
This section is devoted to clarifying the economic concept of “best things” now that the meaning
of “can afford” is clear.
The objects of consumer choice are consumption bundles. This is a complete list of the goods and
services that are involved in the choice problem faced by a consumer.
Suppose there are two consumption bundles X 1 X 2 and Y1Y2 . The consumer can rank them as
to their desirability. That is, the consumer can determine that one of the bundles is strictly better
than the other, or decide that she is indifferent between the two bundles.
Page 4 of 35
Assumptions about Preferences
1. Completeness: It is assumed that any two bundles can be compared. That is, given any X
bundle and any Y bundle, then X 1 X 2 Y1Y2 or Y1Y2 X 1 X 2 or both, in which case
the consumer is indifferent between the two bundles. This is to say that the consumer can
make a choice.
2. Reflexive: We assume that any bundle is at least as good as itself
X 1 X 2 X 1 X 2
3. Transitive: If X 1 X 2 Y1Y2 and Y1Y2 Z1 Z 2 then we assume that consumer thinks
that X is at least as good as Y and that Y is at least as good as Z, then the consumer thinks
that X is at least as Z.
Indifference Curves
The whole theory of consumer choice can be formulated in terms of preferences that satisfy the
three axioms above. However, it is convenient to describe preferences graphically using
indifference curves. Consider a consumer’s consumption of goods 1 and 2:
X2
X 2*
0 X 1* X1
Page 5 of 35
If X 1 X 2 is a certain consumption bundle, the consumption bundle in the shaded region are
weakly preferred to X 1 X 2 . It is called the weakly preferred set. The bundles on the boundary
of this set for which the consumer is just indifferent to X 1 X 2 from the indifference curve. It
consists of all bundles of goods that leave the consumer indifferent to the given bundle.
If no further assumptions about preferences are made, ICs can take very peculiar shapes.
1. Perfect Substitutes
Two goods are perfect substitutes if the consumer is willing to substitute one good for the
other at a constant rate. The simplest case of perfect substitutes occurs when the consumer
is willing to substitute the goods on a one to one basis. ICs for such a consumer are all
parallel straight lines.
X2
ICS
Linear ICs, perfect substitution
0 X1
Page 6 of 35
2. Perfect Complements
Perfect complements are goods that are always consumed together in fixed proportions,
e.g. shoes (left and right). The ICs are L shaped, with the vertex of the L occurring where
the number of one good equals the number of the other good.
X2
0
X1
3. Bad Goods
A bad is a commodity that the consumer doesn’t like. Suppose that the two commodities
are meat and pepper, the consumer loves meat but dislikes pepper. But suppose there is
some trade off possible between meat and pepper i.e. there would be some amount of meat
in samosa that could compensate the consumer for having to consume a given amount of
pepper, if more pepper is given in the samosa, more meat has to be given to compensate
for having to put up with the pepper. Thus this consumer will have indifference curves
that slope up and to the right.
Page 7 of 35
X2
Bad
ICs
0 X1
Good
4. Neutral Goods
A good is a neutral good if the consumer doesn’t care about it one way or the other.
Suppose in the above case the consumer is just neutral about pepper X 2 . The IC would
be vertical lines as depicted below. The consumer only cares about the amount of X 1 and
doesn’t care at all about how much of X 2 he/she has. The more of X 1 the better but
X2
IC
Adding X 1
0 X1
Page 8 of 35
5. Imperfect Substitutes
If the rate at which one good is substituted for another is not constant, but diminishing,
then the two goods are imperfect substitutes. As more and more of one good is given up
successively larger units of the other good are consumed to compensate the consumer for
the loss. Such goods will have indifference curves that are rounded, i.e. the ICs are strictly
convex.
X2
X1
The slope of the IC is known as the MRS. It measures the rate at which the consumer is just willing
to substitute one good for another.
Suppose that we take a little of good 1, X 1 away from the consumer. Then we give him X 2 ,
an amount i.e. just sufficient to put him back on his/her IC, so that he is just as well off after this
substitution of X 2 for X 1 as he was before.
Page 9 of 35
X 2
The ratio is thought as being the rate at which the consumer is willing to substitute good 1
X 1
for good 2 and is called the MRS.
The MRS is an interesting measure of consumer behaviour. Suppose that the consumer has well
behaved preferences, i.e., preferences which are monotonic and convex, and currently consuming
some bundle X 1 X 2 . The consumer is now offered a trade: to exchange good 1 for 2 or good 2
for 1 in any amount at a “rate of exchange” of E.
i.e. if the consumer gives up X 1 units of good 1, he can get EX 1 units of good 2 in exchange or
X 2
conversely, if he gives up X 2 , units of good 2, he can get units of good 1.
E
X 2
MRS E
X 1
X 2 EX 1
X 2
X 1
E
Geometrically, we are offering the consumer an opportunity to move to any point along a line with
a slop E that passes through X 1 X 2 as depicted.
Page 10 of 35
IC
X2
X2
X 2
E
X 1
X1 X1
Moving up and to the left from X 1 to X 2 involves exchange of good 1 for good 2, and moving
down to the right involves exchanging good 2 for good 1. In either movement the exchange rate
is E. Since exchange always involves giving up one good in exchange for another, the exchange
rate E corresponds to slope at E.
The point of tangency between the budget line and the indifference curve is referred to as the
consumer equilibrium.
Perfect substitute’s indifference curves are characterized by the fact that the MRS is constant at
-1. The neutral case is characterized by the fact that the MRS is everywhere infinite. The
preference for perfect complements are characterised by the fact that the MRS is either 0 or infinite
and nothing in between.
The assumption of monotonicity implies that ICs must have a negative slope, so the MRS always
involves reducing the consumption of one good in order to get more of another for monotonic
preferences.
The case of convex ICs exhibits yet another kind of behaviour for the MRS. For convex ICs, the
MRS decreases as more of X1 is consumed. Thus the IC exhibits a diminishing MRS. Convexity
Page 11 of 35
of ICs implies that the more of a good consumed, the more willing is a consumer is to give some
of it up in exchange for the other goods. This seems very natural for a consumer and hence
convexity if ICs becomes both necessary and sufficient conditions for consumer equilibrium
besides just having a point of tangency between the consumer’s budget line and the IC.
UTILITY
The theory of consumer behaviour has been formulated with an objective of utility maximization.
Utility refers to the ability of/in a good to satisfy the consumer.
There are several approaches to the study of utility with one theory attaching significance to the
magnitude utility and is known as the cardinal utility theory. In this theory the size of the utility
difference between the bundles of goods is supposed to have some sort of significance.
Another theory formulates the consumer behaviour entirely in terms of consumer preferences and
utility is seen only as a way to describe preferences by ranking bundles according to utility derived
from each bundle. The proponents of this theory recognized that all that mattered about utility as
far as choice behaviour was concerned was whether one bundle had a higher utility than another
but how much higher didn’t matter (ranking was the only matter). Because of this emphasis on
ordering bundles of goods, this kind of utility is referred to as ordinal utility.
A utility function is a way of assigning a number to every possible consumption bundle such that
more preferred bundles get assigned larger numbers than less preferred bundles.
A utility function is a way to label indifference curves. Since every bundle of an IC must have the
same utility, a utility function is a way to assign number to the different indifference curves in a
way that higher ICs get assigned larger numbers. As long as ICs containing more preferred bundles
get a larger label than indifference curves containing less preferred bundles, the labelling will
represent the different preferences.
However, not all kinds of preferences can be represented by a utility function for example, suppose
a consumer had intransitive preferences so that A>B>C>A. Then a utility function for these
Page 12 of 35
preferences would have to consist of numbers U(A), U(B) and U(C) such that
U(A)>U(B)>U(C)U(A), which is impossible.
U X 1 X 2 X 1 X 2
Where , 0 , numbers that measure the value of goods 1 and 2 to the consumer. By
plotting all the points X 1 X 2 such that U X 1 X 2 equals a constant, yields a linear
indifference curve with a slope . For every different value of a constant, there is a
different IC, but having a similar slope of . Each represents utility functions which are
monotonic transformations to each other.
X2
a
ICs with a slope
b
X1
Page 13 of 35
2. Complementary Goods
These goods used together. The preferences for complementary goods take utility
functions of the form.
U X 1 X 2 Min X 1 X 2 MinX 1 , X 2
Where and are positive numbers that indicate the proportion in which the goods are
Any monotonic transformation of this utility function will describe the same preferences
which are presented by L-shaped ICs.
X2
0
X1
3. Imperfect Substitutes
Perfect substitutes have an additive utility function which implies that a consumer will
yield some level of utility even by consuming only one of the goods.
However, many cases are such that some level of utility is only possible when a
combination of the goods is consumed, i.e. no amount of utility is achievable from
consuming zero amount of one good. Such goods are said to be imperfect substitutes and
their preferences take multiplicative form of utility functions.
U X 1 X 2 X 1 X 2
Page 14 of 35
This kind of a function is referred to as a Cobb-douglas utility function. It yields a convex
monotonic indifference curve and are said to be well behaved.
It is the most useful preference in presenting algebraic examples of the economic ideas. A
monotonic transformation of the Cobb-Douglas utility function above will represent
exactly the same preferences as:
X2
Convex ICs
U4
U3
U2
U1
X1
Consider a consumer consuming bundle X 1 X 2 . The amount by which the total utility changes
U X 1 X 2 when an extra unit of a good is consumed is the marginal utility with respect to the
good.
Suppose an extra unit of good 1 is consumed such that total utility changes from U X 1 X 2 to
U U X 1 X 1 , X 2 U X 1 X 2
MU 1
X 1 X 1
Page 15 of 35
It measures the rate of change in utility (∆U) associated with a small change in the amount of good
1 X 1 . Therefore to calculate the change in utility associated with a small change in consumption
of good 1, we can multiply the change in consumption by the MU of the good.
U MU1X 1
Similarly,
U U X 1 , X 2 X 2 U X 1 X 2
MU 2
X 2 X 2
U MU 2 X 2
Recall that the MRS measures the slope of the IC at a given bundle of goods.
Consider now a change in the consumption of each good X 1 X 2 that keeps utility constant,
i.e., a change in consumption that moves us along the IC, then
MU1X 1 MUX 2 U 0
X 2 MU 1
MRS
X 1 MU 2
But U 0 since utility does not change along the indifference curve.
MU x1 .X 1 MU x 2 .X 2
X 2 MU x1
X 1 MU x 2
The slope is negative since to get more of one good, lesser units of the other good must be
X 2 MU 1
consumed in order to keep the same level of utility. For example if 2
X 1 MU 2
Page 16 of 35
Consumer Equilibrium
This section concentrates with putting together the budget line and the theory of preference in
order to examine the optimal choice of consumers. We have noted that the economic model of
consumer choice is that consumers choose the best bundle they can afford, i.e. the consumers
choose the most preferred bundle from their budget set.
Suppose the budget set and the well behaved consumer preferences are drawn on the same diagram
as:
X2
The consumer
equilibrium
X 2*
X 1* X1
The bundle of goods that is associated with the highest indifference curve and is affordable is
X *
1
X 2* . Any bundle above this one is unaffordable, such a bundle that appears on a point of
tangency between the consumers optimal choice and also referred to as the consumer’s equilibrium
choice. The point of tangency is called the consumer equilibrium point. Since a solution as is
represented above is an interior solution, where the consumers optimal choice involves both goods.
A situation where optimal consumption involves consuming 0 units of one good and some units
of another is called a boundary solution/optimum. For example:
Page 17 of 35
X2
IC
Budget line
0 X 1* X1
Boundary optimum: The optimum consumption involves consuming 0 units of good 2 and the
indifference curve is not tangent to the budget line.
The tangency condition is only a necessary condition to have as optimal choice but not a sufficient
condition. However, there is one important case where it is sufficient, the case of convex
preferences. In the case of convex preferences, any point that satisfies the tangency condition must
be an optimal point.
Generally there may be more than one optimal bundle that satisfies the MRS condition as show
below:
Page 18 of 35
X2
Optimal bundle
0 X1
In such a case, there are three tangencies but only two optimal points, so the tangency condition is
necessary but not sufficient. However, again convexity implies a restriction. If the indifference
curves are strictly convex, then there will be only one optimal choice in each budget line.
Recall that the marginal rate of substitution is the rate of exchange at which the consumer is just
willing to stay put. On the other hand, the market is offering a rate of exchange to the consumer
P1
of (the slope of the budget line).
P2
If the consumer is at a consumption bundle where he/she is willing to stay put, it must be one
where the MRS is equal to this rate of exchange.
P1
MRS
P2
MU 1 MU 2
P1 P2
Hence
Page 19 of 35
MU 1 P
MRS 1
MU 2 P2
Or simply
MU1 P1
consumer equilibrium condition
MU 2 P2
The equilibrium point (optimal choice) has this characteristic that the slope of the IC (MRS) is
equal to the slope of the budget line. The consumer’s choice model can be used to find the optimal
choices for other preferences. Some examples include:
1. Perfect Substitutes
Recall that perfect substitutes have linear indifference curves, just similar to a budget line. If
P2 P1 , then the slope of the budget line is flatter than the slope of the indifference curves. In
such a case, the optimal bundle is where the consumer spends all income on good 1.
The graph below illustrates an optimal choice with perfect substitutes which provide a
boundary solution.
Page 20 of 35
X2
Indifference curve
Budget line
Optimal choise
M X1
X 1*
P1
In summary
M
P if P1 P2
1
M
X 1 any number between 0 and if P1 P2
P1
0 if P1 P2
2. Perfect Complements
In this case, the optimal choice must always lie on the diagonal, where the consumer is
purchasing equal amounts of both goods, no matter what prices are. The optimal choice
can be illustrated as:
Page 21 of 35
X2
Indiffrence curves
Optimal choice
X 2*
Budget line
0 X 1* X1
3. Concave preferences
X2
Indifference curve
Budget line
X
Optimal choice
Z X1
Page 22 of 35
The optimal choice is the boundary point z, not the interior tangency point X because Z
lies on a higher indifference curve.
The consumer’s demand functions give the optimal amounts of each of the goods as a function of
the prices and income faced by the consumer. The demand function are written as:
X 1 X 1 P1 P2 M
X 2 X 2 P1 P2 M
In elementary microeconomics, a clear distinction is made between the normal, inferior and giffen
goods.
When the consumer income changes, the optimal choice for the goods changes yielding an income
expansion path. The income consumption path is used to derive an Engel curve. On the other
hand, a change in price also changes the optimal choice of the consumer yielding a price offer
curve which is used to derive the demand curve.
In this level we give it a mathematical approach where we seek to determine the demand functions
for the optimal choice bundle of the consumer.
MaxU X 1 X 2 ...........................................i
st
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M ......................................ii
Introducing a langrangian multiplier and converting (1) and (2) into a composite function we have:
L U X 1 X 2 P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M 0
Page 23 of 35
L U
P1 0.............................................iii
X 1 X 1
L U
P2 0.............................................iv
X 2 X 2
L
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M 0..................................v
Re- writing equations (4) and (5) and dividing them yields:
U
X 1 P
1
U P2
X 2
MU X 1 P1
MU X 2 P2
This is a similar concept to what was earlier called the consumer equilibrium condition. It
corresponds to a point of tangency between an indifference curve and the budget line from the
graphical approach discussed in the previous sections.
Solving equations (iii), (iv) and (v) above simultaneously, we obtain the demand functions for the
optimal choice bundle. This is best demonstrated using a specific consumer preference and in this
case the Cobb-Douglas preference.
U X 1 X 2 X 1 X 2
MaxU X 1 X 2
st
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M
Page 24 of 35
L X 1 X 2 P1 X 2 P2 X 2 M
L
X 1 1 X 2 P1 0.......................i
X 1
L
X 1 X 2 1 P2 0.........................ii
X 2
L
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M 0.........................iii
X 1 1 X 2 P1
X 1 X 2 1 P2
P1
X 1 1 X 2 1
P2
X 2 P1
X 1 P2
Such that
P1
X2 X 1 ...................................iv
P2
P2 X 2
X1 ....................................v
P1
Equation (4) and (5) represent the income expansion paths or the income offer curve.
Substituting equation (4) and (5) into equation (3) one at a time we obtain.
Page 25 of 35
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 M
P1 X 1
P1 X 1 P2 M
P 2
P1 X 1 P1 X 1 M
1 P1 X 1 M
P1 X 1 M
M
X1
1 P1
M
X 1*
P1
M
X 1* demand function for X 1
P1
M
X 2* demand funtion for X 2
P2
X 1* and X 2* are referred to as the Marshallian demand function that represents the optimal choice
bundle X 1* X 2* . They provide the solution to the consumer utility maximising problem.
Given the market prices and the income level for a consumer then the functions describe the exact
amount of both goods that the consumer would have to consume so as to maximise utility.
Revealed Preference
We have seen how we can use information about the consumer’s preferences and the budget
constraints to determine his/her demand. However, in real life, preferences are not directly
observable. We discover people’s preferences from observing their behaviour. The revealed
preference theory shows how we can use information about the consumers demand to discover
information about his/her preferences.
Page 26 of 35
The theory adopts a maintained hypothesis that the consumers preferences are stable over the time
period for which his/her behaviour is observed-whether they may be or are known to be strictly
convex. Thus there will be a unique demanded bundle at each budget.
Consider the figure below, where we have depicted a consumer’s demanded bundle X 1 X 2 and
another arbitrary bundle Y1Y2 i.e. beneath the consumer’s budget line.
good 2
X1 X 2
Y1Y2
good 1
Bundle Y1Y2 is certainly an affordable purchase at the given budget. The consumer could have
bought it if he/she wanted to and even had money left over. Since X 1 X 2 is the optimal bundle
it must be better than anything else that the consumer could afford. Hence it must be better than
Y1Y2 or any other bundle on or beneath the budget line.
Let X 1 X 2 be the bundle purchased at prices P1 P1 when the consumer has income M. Since
Y1Y2 is affordable at these prices and income, then:
P1Y1 P2Y2 M
Page 27 of 35
P1Y1 P2Y2 M
If the above inequality is satisfied and Y1Y2 is actually a different bundle from X 1 X 2 , then
Let X 1 X 2 be the chosen bundle when prices are P1 P2 and let Y1Y2 be some other bundle such
that:
P1Y1 P2Y2 P1Y1 P2Y2 . Then if the consumer is choosing the most preferred bundle, he can
Suppose further that Y1Y2 is a demanded bundle at prices q1 q 2 and that Y1Y2 is itself revealed
q1 y1 q 2 y 2 q1 z1 q1 z 2 .
Then X 1 X 2 Y1Y2 and Y1Y1 Z1 Z 2 . From the transitivity assumption, we can conclude that
X 1 X 2 Z1 Z 2 .
This is illustrated:
Page 28 of 35
good 2
X1 X 2
Y1Y2 budget lines
Z1 Z 2
good 1
Revealed preference and transitivity assumption tell us that X 1 X 2 must be better than Z1 Z 2
for the consumer who made the illustrated choices. In this case X 1 X 2 is said to be indirectly
revealed proffered to Z1 Z 2 . The chain of direct comparisons can be of any length such that if
bundle A is directly revealed to B, and B to C, C to D… all the way to Z, then bundle A is still
indirectly revealed to Z.
If a bundle is either directly or indirectly revealed preferred to another bundle, we will say that the
first bundle is revealed preferred to the second.
From the figure below, since X 1 X 2 is revealed preferred, either directly, to all of the bundles
below (shaded area) either budget lines, X 1 X 2 is in fact preferred to those bundles by the
consumer. That is, the true indifference curve through X 1 X 2 , whatever it is, must lie above the
shaded region. It therefore also follows that, the true indifference curve through Y1Y2 must lie
above the flatter budget line.
We have so far supposed that the consumer has preferences and that he/she is always choosing the
best bundle of goods affordable. If the consumer is not behaving this way, the estimates of the
indifference curves that we have constructed are meaningless.
Consider:
Page 29 of 35
good 2
X1 X 2 budget lines
Y1Y2
good 1
According to the logic of revealed preference, the diagram allows us to conclude two things.
indicating that X 1 X 2 was preferred to Y1Y2 indicating that X 1 X 2 was preferred to Y1Y2 but
then he/she indicating the opposite. This situation is absurd and violates the weak Axiom of
Revealed Preference
Clearly this consumer cannot be a maximizing consumer. Either the consumer is not choosing the
best bundle he/she can afford or there is some other aspect of the choice problem that has changed
that we have not observed. Perhaps the consumer’s tastes or some other aspect of his/her economic
environment have changed. If consumers are choosing the best bundles that are affordable, but
not chosen must be worse than what is chosen. Economists have therefore formulated this simple
point in a basic axiom of consumer theory referred to as the weak axiom of revealed preference
(WARP) it states that ‘if X 1 X 2 is directly revealed preferred to Y1Y2 and the two bundles are
not the same, then it cannot happen that Y1Y2 is directly revealed preferred to X 1 X 2 .
Page 30 of 35
In other words, if a bundle X 1 X 2 is purchased at prices P1 P2 and a different bundle Y1Y2 is
P1 X 1 P2 X 2 P1Y1 P2Y2
q1Y1 q 2Y2 q1 X 1 q2 X 2
That is, if the Y bundle is affordable when the x-bundle is purchased, then when the Y-bundle is
purchased, the X bundle must not be affordable.
The consumer in (immediate diagram) has violated the WARP and therefore this consumer’s
behaviour could not have been maximising behaviour. There is no set of indifference curves that
could make both bundles maximizing bundles.
On the other hand, a consumer who satisfies WARP is said to have a maximizing or optimal
behaviour and for such, it is possible to find indifference curves for which his/her behaviour is
optimal. One possible choice of indifference curves is illustrated below.
Good 2
X1 X 2
Budget lines
X1 X 2
Good 1
Page 31 of 35
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
The weak axiom of revealed preference requires that if X is directly revealed preferred to Y, then
we should never observe Y being directly revealed to X. The strong axiom of revealed preference
requires that the same sort of condition hold for indirect revealed preference. The strong Axiom
of Revealed Preference. The strong Axiom of Revealed Preference (SARP) states that:
If X 1 X 2 is revealed preferred to Y1Y2 either directly or indirectly and Y1Y2 is different from
It is therefore clear that if the observed behaviour is optimizing behaviour, then it must satisfy the
strong axiom. For if the consumer is optimising and X 1 X 2 is revealed preferred to, either
directly or indirectly, then it must be the case that X 1 X 2 > Y1Y2 . Therefore, having X 1 X 2
revealed preferred to Y1Y2 and Y1Y2 revealed preferred to X 1 X 2 would imply that X 1 X 2 >
Y1Y2 and Y1Y2 > X 1 X 2 , which is a contradiction. We can conclude that either the consumer
must not be optimizing or some other aspect of the consumer’s environment such as tastes, other
prices etc. must have changed.
While WARP is a necessary condition for optimizing behaviour, SARP is both necessary and
sufficient in the sense that, if the observed choices satisfy SARP, we can always find well behaved
preferences that could have generated the observed choices. It ensures both consistency and
transitivity of consumer preferences.
Page 32 of 35
Summary
NOTE
The weak axiom of revealed preference requires that if X is directly revealed preferred to Y,
then we should never observe Y being directly revealed to X. The strong axiom of revealed
preference requires that the same sort of condition hold for indirect revealed preference. The
strong Axiom of Revealed Preference. The strong Axiom of Revealed Preference(SARP)
states that If X 1 X 2 is revealed preferred to Y1Y2 either directly or indirectly and Y1Y2 is
Page 33 of 35
FURTHER READINGS
1. Nicholson, Walter, and Christopher M. Snyder. Microeconomic theory: Basic principles and
extensions. Cengage Learning, 2012.
2. Varian, H. R. (2014). Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach: Ninth International
Student Edition. WW Norton & Company.
3. Greenlaw, S. A., & Shapiro, D. (2017). Principles of Microeconomics 2e. Rice University.
Page 34 of 35
SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
- Using the following utility function, U ( x1 x2 ) x10.5 x20.5 , prove that the parameters
indicated are the elasticities with respect to the two goods consumed by an individual.
- Show the various states of consumer equilibrium with perfect substitutes goods
giving an account of different prices, that is P1<P2, P1>P2, P1=P2, where P1 and P2 are
prices of good X1 and X2 respectively. Explain your answer as clearly as possible
Page 35 of 35