Sovereign Debt
Sovereign Debt
Sovereign Debt
No 1099
Who holds sovereign
debt and why it matters
by Xiang Fang, Bryan Hardy and Karen K Lewis
May 2023
© Bank for International Settlements 2023. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be
reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.
Karen K. Lewis
University of Pennsylvania, NBER, and CEPR
Abstract
This paper studies the impact of investor composition on the sovereign debt market. We construct
a data set of sovereign debt holdings by foreign and domestic bank, non-bank private, and official
investors for 95 countries over twenty years. Private non-bank investors absorb disproportionately
more sovereign debt supply than other investors. Moreover, non-bank investor demand is most
responsive to the yield. Counterfactual analysis of emerging market sovereigns shows a 10% increase
in debt leads to a 6.7% increase in costs, but an out-sized 9% increase if non-bank investors are absent.
We conclude that these sovereigns are vulnerable to losing non-bank investors.
* We thank Maria Gelrud, Sophia Hua, and Max Yang for excellent research assistance. We also benefited from comments by
Karlye Dilts Stedman, Ester Faia, Gregor Matvos and participants at the Bank of International Settlements, Banque de France,
China International Finance Conference, Econometric Society North American Winter Meeting, Federal Reserve Board, Fed-
eral Reserve Bank of Dallas, Hong Kong University, INSEAD, London Business School, London School of Economics, the
Macro Finance Society, DebtCon5, EEA-ESSM Congress, the Midwest Finance Association, the National Bureau of Economic
Research, Society of Economic Dynamics, and the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. Any errors or omis-
sions are our own. The views expressed here are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Bank for International
Settlements. Contact: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
1 Introduction
The ability to issue debt is an important instrument at the government’s disposal. Sovereign
borrowing can help buffer the economy from the impact of adverse macroeconomic shocks.
Conversely, indebtedness can also make a country vulnerable to financial distress, as cri-
sis episodes have illustrated. Indeed, the sharp increase in fiscal expenditures and debt
issuance during the recent pandemic period, as well as concerns from the fallout of war,
has brought more urgency to understanding how a government can borrow. Answering
this question requires knowledge of who invests in sovereign debt and how these investors
impact borrowing costs. Therefore, this paper provides an analysis of who holds sovereign
debt and what this investor composition implies for governments’ borrowing costs.
We begin by documenting who holds government debt around the world and establish-
ing some new empirical regularities. For this purpose, we first assemble a dataset that dis-
tinguishes the holders of each country’s sovereign debt into investor groups that have been
highlighted in the literature. That is, we disaggregate debt held by foreign and domestic
investors and into three subgroups within those categories: private banks, other private in-
vestors that we term ”non-banks”, and official creditors consisting largely of central banks
and international organizations like the World Bank.1 Assembling these data series provides
1744 country-year observations for which we can decompose the holders of debt, spanning
Figure 1 shows both the growing importance of government debt as well as how the in-
vestor base varies in our data set. Specifically, Panel (a) shows that aggregate government
debt as a proportion of GDP has increased to the highest levels in recent history, spurred on
by the Covid-19 pandemic for both for advanced and emerging economies. Furthermore,
the composition of investor shares has changed over time. For example, as Panel (b) shows,
the share of domestic versus foreign investors has evolved with marked differences between
advanced economies (AEs) and emerging markets (EMs). The share of aggregate debt hold-
1 This decomposition follows that of Arslanalp and Tsuda (2012) and Arslanalp and Tsuda (2014).
2A partial decomposition is available for 151 countries.
1
ings by domestic investors has decreased for AEs while that same share has increased for
EMs. The share of debt held by non-bank private investors, shown in Panel (c), shows more
short-term fluctuations.
Figure 1: Trends in General Government Debt
75 0.6 0.6
50 0.4 0.4
25 0.2 0.2
0 0.0 0.0
03 06 09 12 15 18 21 00 03 06 09 12 15 18 00 03 06 09 12 15 18
AE EMDC AE (excl US) US EM (excl CN) CN
(a) Debt/GDP (b) Share Held Domestically (c) Share Held by Non-banks
Note: Panel (a) of this figure plots the time-series of general government debt-to-GDP ratio for the advanced economies,
emerging market and developing countries from IMF WEO. Panel (b) plots the share of general government debt held by
domestic investors by country group. Panel (c) plots the share of general government debt held by non-banks. Panels (b)
and (c) consist of balanced samples of 15 AEs including the US and 15 EMs including China (CN).
In this paper, we use these data to document how increases in sovereign debt are ab-
sorbed by the six different investor groups (foreign vs domestic and bank vs non-bank
vs official). Strikingly, we find that non-bank private investors increase their holdings of
sovereign debt at significantly higher rates than any other group, including private banks.
Furthermore, this absorption rate is greater than proportional to their average holdings.
Across all countries for instance, when there is an increase in debt, 69% of the increase is
allocated to non-bank investors, even though they make up only 46% of holdings on aver-
age. Moreover, for increases in foreign-held debt, 75% of the increase is due to non-bank
investors, even though they comprise only 42% of all foreign holdings. By contrast, banks
absorb less than their average holdings of sovereign debt: they hold 28% of the debt on av-
erage, but only take up 20% of new debt on the margin. This pattern holds for increases in
foreign and domestically held debt as well as in subsamples of AEs and EMs. Furthermore,
the general results are robust to accounting for currency valuation effects on foreign-held
2
debt. Thus, when the supply of government debt increases, private non-bank investors play
These aggregate results highlight the importance of non-bank private investors, a large
and heterogeneous group. To disentangle the behavior of different investors within this
group, we turn to more granular data sets. We begin by using data on Euro Area investors
to disaggregate the foreign non-bank investor group into non-financial corporations, pen-
sions and insurance companies, households, and a category of other financial institutions,
largely representing investment funds. Our analysis indicates that within this group, finan-
cial institutions such as investment funds drive the large response of non-banks. We then
repeat this analysis for domestic investors who hold US Treasuries and UK Gilts, finding
again that non-banks are the most responsive set of investors, and within domestic non-
Given these findings for who holds sovereign debt, we next consider why this composi-
tion matters to borrowers. To answer this question, we estimate a system of funding equa-
tions representing the willingness to extend credit. Since this willingness to fund depends
endogenously on the interest paid by the government, we require an instrument for these
borrowing costs. For this purpose, we exploit the fact that our data set provides the full
breakdown of sovereign debt by investor type for each country. As shown by Koijen and
Yogo (2020), such a market clearing condition can be used to provide an instrument that
is uncorrelated with unobserved latent factors that drive investors’ willingness to extend
credit. Accordingly, we use this concept to construct an instrument for the sovereign yield.
Our estimates provide striking results that again point to the importance of non-bank
investors. Specifically, for both Emerging Markets and Advanced Economies, non-bank
investors are the creditor group most responsive to changes in yields. Moreover, investors
of emerging market sovereign debt generally dislike inflation and prefer income growth
While these results provide measures of the sovereign’s view of each creditor group’s
willingness to fund, investors will perceive the returns on these investments differently for
3
two main reasons. First, while governments issue debt and pay interest over time, investors
focus upon holding returns per period as measured in the secondary market. Second, since
governments primarily issue debt in local currency, foreign investors who hold this debt
Although the aggregate data do not contain the identity nor portfolio of holdings by
these investor groups, we show that under some additional conditions we can provide in-
vestor demand estimates similar to those in Koijen and Yogo (2020) and Jiang, Richmond,
and Zhang (2022). First, we focus only on Emerging Markets because the identity of domes-
tic versus foreign investor groups is likely to be more comingled for Advanced Economies.
as shown by Koijen and Yogo (2020), the demand system under these assumptions allow
for substitution across debt issued by different countries. This estimation shows that the
elasticity of non-bank investors is again higher than that of banks, and that the elasticity of
To assess what these estimates imply for the sovereign borrower, we ask how much the
financing cost would increase for a hypothetical debt increase. Our estimates show that a
10% increase in debt corresponds to a 6.7% increase in yield for the average EM borrower.
However, if non-bank investors are not present and borrowers must borrow from banks,
the same 10% increase in debt corresponds to a substantially higher 9.1% increase in yield.
Thus, EM sovereigns appear highly exposed to the availability of non-bank investor fund-
ing. We also study the trade-off between borrowing costs and characteristics. For instance,
if inflation increases by 1%, the required yield for the average EM would increase by 2.5%.
The structure of the paper is as follows. We next provide a brief review of the litera-
ture. Section 2 describes the data and some basic stylized facts, including a decomposition
that highlights how much government debt each investor group absorbs on the margin. It
also reports the same decomposition using disaggregated non-bank investor holdings in
the Euro Area, the US Treasuries, and the UK Gilts. Section 3 sets up a framework to ex-
plore funding and investor demand in the sovereign debt market and reports estimates of
4
this demand by investor groups. Section 4 combines the country-level investor demand
Related Literature Since our paper studies investor behavior of sovereign debt holdings,
to a growing literature that uses the demand system approach to asset pricing introduced
by Koijen and Yogo (2019) and applied in domestic and international financial markets as
in Koijen and Yogo (2020), Koijen, Richmond, and Yogo (2020), Jiang et al. (2022), Bretscher,
Schmid, Sen, and Sharma (2020), and Koijen, Koulischer, Nguyen, and Yogo (2021). While
our estimation of different investor groups’ demand and the construction of instruments
follows the basic approach of this literature, we exploit the market clearing condition from
the issuer side. This identity arises naturally in our data because the supply of debt for
each country is matched to the full breakdown of holdings by investor groups. As such,
this feature contrasts with the common data structure in the literature that focuses upon
portfolio allocation of specific investors as in, for example, Maggiori, Neiman, and Schreger
the investors of a given country government debt to understand the exposure of issuers.
Our paper is also related to the literature on investor demand for Advanced Economy
sovereign debt. This strand of research includes, for example, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-
Jorgensen (2012), Jiang, Krishnamurthy, and Lustig (2018), Jiang, Lustig, Van Nieuwer-
burgh, and Xiaolan (2019), Liu, Schmid, and Yaron (2020), and Liu (2022). Consistent with
the view in this literature that banks and the official sector hold government debt for liq-
uidity and other purposes, we show that holdings by these groups are relatively insensitive
to yields. We also analyze the role of the global financial intermediaries and financial con-
ditions, as highlighted by Bruno and Shin (2015), Gabaix and Maggiori (2015), Fang and
Liu (2020), and Miranda-Agrippino and Rey (2021). By contrast to these papers, we also
find that non-bank private investors increase holdings of AE sovereign debt in response to
5
By studying investor types jointly, we also further the defaultable sovereign debt litera-
ture that has instead highlighted the importance of individual investor types. For instance,
an important part of the EM literature focuses only on the role of foreign investors, partic-
ularly foreign banks. See, for example, Eaton and Gersovitz (1981), Arellano (2008), Arel-
lano and Ramanarayanan (2012), Mendoza and Yue (2012), Cruces and Trebesch (2013), and
Arellano, Bai, and Mihalache (2020). On the other hand, the sovereign-bank nexus (“doom-
loop”) literature focuses on domestic bank investors as in, for example, Gennaioli, Martin,
and Rossi (2014), Perez (2014), Bocola (2016), Brunnermeier et al. (2016), Fahri and Tirole
(2018), and Chari, Dovis, and Kehoe (2020). A further area focuses on explaining the reserve
Dominguez, Hashimoto, and Ito (2012), Ghosh, Ostry, and Tsangarides (2017), Bianchi,
Hatchondo, and Martinez (2018), and Bianchi and Sosa-Padilla (2020), to name a few. We
instead evaluate the set of creditors together and thereby contribute to these literatures by
groups’ holdings to analyze the impact of investor composition on sovereign financing cost.
As noted above, this data decomposition is close to Arslanalp and Tsuda (2012, 2014), and
the extension in Arslanalp and Sunder-Plassmann (2022).3 In order to examine the impact
of marginal investors and their demand, however, we construct a dataset that begins earlier
spanning all investor types and encompasses a broader set of countries. This more expan-
sive base allows us to better estimate the impact of investor composition on sovereigns’ fi-
nancing costs. It also complements other studies based upon securities level issuances such
as Maggiori, Neiman, and Schreger (2020) and Faia, Salomao, and Veghazy (2022). Relative
to these granular data sets, our analysis provides a complete accounting of the investors of
We emphasize the role of non-bank investors, particularly noting the composition of the marginal investors (as opposed to
average holdings) as important for understanding debt financing exposure of sovereigns.
6
2 Evolving Composition of Sovereign Debt Investor Groups
We begin by analyzing the holders of sovereign debt and examining who are the marginal
investors that purchase new debt. We first describe the structure of the data and the in-
vestor group definitions, and highlight the broad trends in sovereign debt holdings. We
then analyze the marginal investment in sovereign debt for each group. We finish the sec-
We consider three basic types of investors: (1) private banks; (2) non-banks; and (3) official
creditors. We describe briefly these three categories below before detailing their construction
in the data. We also split these investor groups by their location: foreign vs domestic. This
gives us six groups: domestic banks, foreign banks, domestic non-banks, foreign non-banks,
The first group is private banks. These institutions are often considered primary inter-
mediaries for debt markets including their function as primary dealers (Arnone & Ugolini,
2005). They have therefore been the focus of both the emerging market (EM) and advanced
economy (AE) branches of sovereign debt studies. In the literature on emerging market
borrowing, foreign global banks are often modeled as the primary creditor. More broadly,
liquidity and capital regulation incentivize domestic banks to hold domestic government
The second group of private investors is a combination of all private investors who are
not banks. These investors are not subject to bank regulatory restrictions but may face other
constraints depending on the nature of their business. Overall, this investor group encom-
passes financial institutions such as pensions and insurance firms, endowments, mutual
funds, and hedge funds, as well as non-financial entities like corporations and households.
4 Bank regulation typically assigns risk-weights to different assets that banks hold for computing the required capital ratios.
So, acquiring sovereign debt, which typically carries a zero risk weight, does not reduce the bank’s regulatory capital ratios,
though it can affect other bank constraints like the leverage ratio. On the bank-sovereign doom loop, see Fahri and Tirole
(2018) and the Related Literature section above.
7
Finally, we consider official creditors. “Domestic Official” creditors are simply the “Do-
mestic Central Bank”, while the “Foreign Official” group includes foreign central banks,
foreign governments, and international organizations such as the World Bank and Interna-
This data set is organized around the sovereign issuers of debt, rather than tracking the
securities held by investors. Specifically, we are interested in how the holdings of each
investor group responds to changes in the sovereign’s total debt. To see this decomposition,
it will therefore be useful to define the book value of sovereign debt of a given country
indexed by n, as D (n) and the amount held by each investor group i, as Hi (n). Then, the
investor groups for country n debt can be aggregated across the investor groups to provide
where I is the number of investor groups. For example, in our aggregate data set above,
I = 6 since we have three types of investors with domestic and foreign counterparts for
each. We will use the decompositions in Equation (1) to uncover the marginal ownership
responses to supply changes over time below. Before doing so, we describe the data.
2.2 Data
The annual data series for the debt and holding groups come from various sources. Here
we describe briefly the overall approach in constructing these data series, relegating a more
complete discussion to Appendix A. The general approach follows the work of Arslanalp
and Tsuda (2012, 2014), and the recent expansion of their dataset (Arslanalp & Sunder-
Plassmann, 2022). We modify their methodology in order to broaden further the time period
and sample of countries for which we have data for all investor groups. We point interested
researchers to their papers and associated database for a full description of the approach.
We first derive each sovereign’s total debt from the IMF Historical Public Debt Database
(HPDD), which provides debt-to-GDP for a large number of countries over a long time
8
horizon. We multiply this series by GDP from the World Bank to recover the value of debt in
current US dollars.5 The total foreign holdings for each sovereign are constructed following
the methodology in Avdjiev, Hardy, Şebnem Kalemli-Özcan, and Servén (2022) (hereafter,
AHKS), which combines International Investment Position (IIP) data, the Quarterly External
Debt Statistics (QEDS), and the BIS international banking and international debt securities
statistics. The domestic total holdings are computed as the difference between total debt
The domestic and foreign holdings are further decomposed into the three groups de-
scribed above. Data for foreign bank holdings are estimated using the approach in AHKS.
Foreign official holdings for advanced economies and China are taken directly from Ar-
slanalp and Tsuda (2012, 2014), capturing the use of such debt as foreign reserves. For all
other countries for which their debt is less commonly held as reserves, we capture foreign
official lending as the sum of bilateral and multilateral lending from the World Bank Debtor
Reporting System (DRS). Foreign non-bank holdings are the difference between these mea-
sures for banks and foreign official with the total foreign holdings.
Sovereign debt holdings by domestic banks and domestic central banks are taken from
the IMF’s International Financial Statistics (IFS) dataset, supplemented with data from the
official websites of central banks when the data was incomplete. Domestic non-bank hold-
ings are measured as the difference between the domestic total and the sum of domestic
banks and domestic central banks. All holdings in the baseline data series are measured in
current US dollars.
by investor, with time series spanning 1991 to 2018.6 For some of the analysis, we split
the sovereigns into 3 groups: advanced economies (AEs), emerging markets (EMs), and
developing countries (DCs). Details of the country groups can be found in Appendix A.
5 For some countries, the HPDD data series stop in 2015. For these countries, we obtain post-2015 values by applying the
growth rate in total debt from the Quarterly Public Debt Statistics (QPSD), which has excellent coverage of the recent period,
to the last available level computed from the HPDD.
6 For a larger sample of 151 countries starting in 1991, partial data are available (i.e. data for some investor groups are
missing).
9
Advantages and limitations of the data. The main advantages of our dataset are that it allo-
cates all of a sovereign’s debt to individual investors, and that it spans a large number of
countries over a long time period. However, such coverage comes with drawbacks on detail.
For instance, our dataset does not include detailed information on the currency or maturity
of the debt or the specific location of the foreign investor. It does not have details on the non-
sovereign portfolios of these investors. Moreover, the data is annual, and so misses higher
frequency dynamics. In the conclusion, we discuss avenues for future research to build on
our analysis.
We next examine some general trends in holdings and the relative behavior of each investor
group’s holdings as government debt changes. Panels (a), (b), and (c) of Figure 2 shows
the average investor holdings-to-GDP shares of advanced economy (AE), emerging market
(EM) and developing economies (DC) debt, respectively. These figures show distinctive dif-
ferences within the groups. For all groups, the foreign bank and non-bank shares have been
stable over time.7 However, the proportion of foreign official holdings has become larger
for AEs, as central banks have increased their holdings of safe haven government debt for
reserve purposes, while the proportion of foreign official creditors has declined for emerg-
ing markets. Strikingly, the share of domestic non-banks has increased over time for EMs
relative to AEs, perhaps reflecting growing financial development within these economies.
By contrast, the AE holdings of domestic central banks has expanded over time, tied to the
These trends raise an important question. When the size of debt increases, which in-
vestors absorb the additional amount? In other words, who are the marginal investors for
the sovereign? To explore this question, we regress the change in debt held by each investor
7 Foreign
official data for AEs are not available until 2000, so foreign holdings are not fully reported before that point.
Coverage for EMs and DCs is broader after 1995.
10
Figure 2: Trends in Sovereign Debt
50
80 80
40
60 60
30
40 40
20
20 20
10
0 0 0
2002 2006 2010 2014 2018 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
DomBK DomNB DomCB ForBK ForNB ForOff
Note: Aggregate debt by country group detailed in Appendix A divided by the aggregate GDP of the country group. Each
panel shows a balanced sample over the given time frame.
where the subscript t indicates time, and where a(n) and at represent country fixed effects
and time fixed effects, respectively. Using the identity in Equation (1), the sum of the in-
Since all of the debt is absorbed by some investor, the coefficients estimated from this re-
I
gression will sum to 1: ∑ ai = 1. Each coefficient ai reflects the marginal holding response
i =1
of investor group i to variations in the supply of debt.
Table 1 shows the results of this regression. Panel A provides a baseline estimate labeled
”All” based upon a balanced sample of all countries. The first two columns provide these
results for an aggregated group of domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (1)
and (2) show that for every additional unit of debt supplied, 60% is absorbed by domestic
investors while the other 40% is picked up by foreign investors. In AEs and DCs, this split
is roughly equal, whereas for EM sovereign debt, domestic investors take over two-thirds
of additional debt.
11
Breaking down foreign and domestic investors by type in columns (3) through (8) reveals
additional insights. For the ”All” country estimates, non-bank investors tend to be the most
important, taking on 39% and 30% of additional debt holdings for domestic and foreign en-
tities, respectively. As reported in the following rows, decomposing estimates into country
groups shows the relative importance of investor groups across these countries. In partic-
ular, foreign non-banks are more important for AEs and DCs, while domestic non-banks
Note: Panel A of the table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (2) for each investor group. The first two columns
represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six investor groups.
Standard errors clustered at the country level are reported in the parentheses. Panel B of the table reports the average share
of holding by each investor group.
More important, however, is the role of investor groups relative to each other. Here, non-
bank investors again demonstrate the most striking results. For example, foreign non-banks
play a much stronger role in expanding holdings in response to new debt than do foreign
12
banks. In particular, the take-up of new EM debt by foreign non-bank investors is 24% of
the total in contrast to only 5% by foreign banks. These findings are in stark contrast to a
view that foreign banks play the biggest role in the EM debt market. And lastly, foreign
official investors are more important as marginal investors for DCs, where they serve as an
important source of financing (9% of the increased supply). Appendix B illustrates these
expansion in country debt and therefore one might wonder whether these holdings simply
represent proportional expansions to average holdings. Panel B of Table 1 reports the av-
erage holdings by investor group over the period and shows this is not the case. The large
marginal contribution of non-bank investor holdings are greater than the average holdings.
For example, in the baseline ”All” results, the average holdings of domestic non-banks and
foreign non-banks sum to only 46% (that is, 0.28 + 0.18). At the same time, the marginal
share reported in Panel A are jointly 69% (0.39 + 0.30) of the change. This pattern is clearly
robust across all the remaining decompositions including AE, EM, and DC.8
Appendix B.1 reports an extensive set of results of the same analysis under different
scenarios of recessions vs. non-recessions, crisis vs. non-crisis periods, as well as in different
groups measured in a common currency. However, such changes in holdings may arise
from currency valuation effects for debt that is originally issued in local currency. Indeed,
the importance of valuation effects in the balance sheet adjustment of countries has been
shown in a number of papers (e.g. Gourinchas and Rey (2007)).9 To consider this possi-
bility, Appendix B.2 repeats the analysis taking into consideration the currency valuation
effect. The results are largely unchanged: non-banks have a larger response to increased
8 The most recent shares in the sample are essentially the same as the averages, which rules out the possibility that non-
disaggregated data on holdings of specific investors. See, for example, Curcuru, Thomas, Warnock, and Wongswan (2011) for
an analysis of US portfolio investment in foreign equity markets.
13
debt supply than other investor groups.
As we showed above, private investors who are not banks play an important role in the
sovereign debt market. This finding raises the obvious questions: who are these investors
and how do they respond to changes in sovereign debt? To shed light on this question,
we turn to other more disaggregated data sets: (i) the Euro area securities holding statistics
(SHS) produced by the European Central Bank; (ii) US TIC data; and (iii) UK Gilt Holders
data.10 We utilise the Euro area data to shed light on the foreign non-bank segment, and the
We first examine the Euro Area SHS data. The SHS provides data on the holdings of
securities for all investors located in the Euro Area, split by sector of the holder/investor,
the type (e.g., equity vs debt) of security, the sector of the issuer, and the residence of the
issuer. Thus, we can observe the holdings of government debt issued by specific countries
for all Euro area investors, disaggregated by investor type. Specifically, the non-bank sector
in this data has the more granular breakdown: (a) households and non-profits, (b) insurance
and pensions, (c) non-financial corporations; and (d) ”other financial institutions” which in-
cludes entities like hedge funds and mutual funds. As above, we also study the holdings by
banks and the official sector. However, in this data source, the official sector is the govern-
ment, excluding the central bank. These data are quarterly, with sample taken over 2013 Q4
to 2020 Q3.
This setup allows us to examine how Euro Area non-bank investors behave relative to
each other and relative to other Euro area investors in regards to their holdings of foreign
sovereign debt (i.e. outside the Euro Area). Since Euro Area investors do not account for
the full set of foreign investors for a given government, we cannot replicate our previous
analysis. Nevertheless, we can adapt that approach to establish which types of non-bank
10 Faia, Salomao, and Veghazy (2022) analyze the underlying data for the Euro Area SHS, focusing on corporate bonds in
the euro-area, and find significantly different behavior for mutual funds relative to insurance and pension funds, similar to
our results below for sovereign bonds.
14
investors in the Euro Area drive the overall behavior of Euro Area non-bank investors in for-
eign sovereign debt markets. We therefore modify our regression in Equation (2) so that the
denominator is the total holdings of foreign sovereign debt by Euro Area investors, rather
than total debt. When we examine within the non-bank group, we replace the denominator
with the total holdings of sovereign n’s debt by Euro Area non-bank investors.
The coefficient results are summarized in Figure 3 while the regression results are rel-
egated to Table B8 in Appendix B. Similar to the aggregate data, the non-bank private in-
vestors are the most marginal group within the set of Euro Area investors (excluding central
banks). For the base case of all non-Euro Area countries, 77% of every additional unit of
sovereign debt picked up by these investors is held by Non-Banks, while only 23% is held
by Banks. These general patterns hold for all cases except for Advanced Economies in the
baseline estimates shown in Figure 3 panel (a), where banks seem to absorb the largest share
of the increase.11
Figure 3: Foreign Non-bank Marginal Holders: Euro Area Investors
0.5
0.8 0.8 0.8
0.4
0.6 0.6 0.6
0.3
0.4 0.4 0.4
0.2
(a) Advanced Economies (b) Advanced Economies (c) Emerging Markets (d) Emerging Markets
Note: This figure plots the regression coefficients in Equation (2) for euro area investors’ holdings of non-euro area
government debt. Panels (a) and (c) report the coefficients for regressions of EA investor holdings of non-EU government
debt for AE governments and EM governments, respectively, reported in columns (1), (2), and (3) in Table B8. These groups
are private Banks, Non-Banks, and other governments ”Gov”. Panels (b) and (d) report the coefficients for regressions of
disaggregated Non-bank EA investor groups based upon columns (4), (5), (6), and (7) of Table B8) for Households, Insurance
and Pensions (IP), Nonfinancial Corporations (NFC), and Other Financial Institutions (OthFin). The results use the total EA
investor holdings of non-EA debt by AE and by EM separately as the total denominator in Equation (2).
11 Debt from large AE countries such as the US are important for this group of investors, but are weighted equally with
other countries. If we weight this regression by the size of the total holdings of that sovereign’s debt by European investors,
then non-banks are again the most marginal investor in foreign AE sovereign debt.
15
More importantly, panels (b) and (d) in Figure 3 provide a decomposition within the
Non-bank investor group. Insurance and pension (IP) account for 12 to 14% of the addi-
tional sovereign debt picked up by foreign non-banks in both (non-Euro Area) advanced
and emerging markets. This is dwarfed by ”other financial institutions” (OthFin) such as
hedge funds and mutual funds, which picked up 85%. By contrast, the other two categories
of households (HH) and non-financial companies (NFC) essentially take on little to none of
We next turn to the US and UK data to examine the domestic non-bank group. These
data breakout the total debt issuance by the central government by who is holding the debt.
Thus, we apply our standard approach in Equation (2), dropping the time and country fixed
effects, as we are considering a single country. These datasets provide a detailed breakdown
of domestic holders of these securities, but provide little or no sector breakdown of the
foreign holders. We utilize data over 1995 Q1 to 2020 Q4 for comparability with the other
data. While we note that the US and UK are not typical countries, so results may not be
fully generalizable, they nevertheless provide a useful window into domestic non-banks’
The coefficients from these regressions are plotted in Figure 4 while the details are re-
ported in Tables B9 and B10 in Appendix B. For US Treasuries and UK Gilts, respectively,
Panels (a) and (c) depict the regression coefficients for the aggregated groups of total foreign
investors, domestic central banks, and domestic non-banks. As shown there, domestic non-
banks are the most marginal investors in these markets, accounting for nearly half of the
variation. Panels (b) and (d) break out the non-bank marginal share by underlying sector
for holdings of US Treasuries and UK Gilts, respectively. In the US, we see that investment
funds, including hedge funds and Money Market Funds (MMFs), are the most important
group, accounting for over half of the non-bank marginal variation (despite making up only
26% of non-bank holdings on average).12 The Insurance and Pension (I&P) sector accounts
for about 15%. In the UK, the I&P sector plays a much larger role for non-bank holdings,
12 The “household” sector includes hedge funds, private funds, and private trusts.
16
accounting for nearly half of the marginal absorption. Funds and other non-bank financial
institutions account for the other half. The large presence of I&P is notable especially in light
of the Sept 2022 turmoil in the Gilt market regarding pension funds.13
0.5
0.3 0.4 0.4
0.4
0.2 0.3 0.3
0.3
0.1 0.2 0.2
0.2
Note: This figure plots the regression coefficients in Equation (2) for the holders of US Treasuries and the holders of UK Gilts
over 1995q1-2020q4. The regression results are reported in Tables B9 and B10, for US Treasuries and UK Gilt, respectively.
Panels (a) and (c) give the aggregate breakdown for all foreign (Foreign), domestic central bank (DomCB), domestic bank
(DomBank), and domestic non-bank (DomNB). In panel (b), “HF/HH” includes Hedge funds, private equity, private trusts,
and direct household holdings. “Non Fin” is all non-financial holders excluding households. “Oth Fin” is all other financial
institutions apart from funds and Insurance and Pension (I&P). In panel (d), “Funds & Oth” comprises all funds and
financial institutions except for I&P. “Non Fin” includes all non-financial holders.
Overall, these disaggregated data suggest that the foreign non-bank investor group is
largely driven by the behavior of investment funds, with modest participation from the
I&P sector. For the domestic non-bank investor group, the I&P sector likely plays a larger
role alongside funds. Other domestic players may be context specific (e.g., the large role of
MMFs in the US may be unique), but the results suggest that investment and other funds
active traders. In the US, this sector makes up 43% of domestic non-bank holdings, while in the UK it accounts for 81%. This
fits with the perception that this sector is more stable in their holdings.
17
3 Sovereign Debt, Investor Holdings, and Yields
We showed above who holds sovereign debt and how the composition of investor holdings
varies when that debt expands on the margin. In this section, we describe a framework to
study the behavior of creditors, allowing us to consider why that composition matters. Sec-
tion 3.1 begins by considering how a sovereign may view the propensity for its investors to
provide credit as it varies debt and the yield on that debt. Although this framework could
in principle be used for any country, we study debt issued by AE and EM countries sepa-
rately because investors view these two types of assets differently. Investors hold AE debt
(for example, US Treasuries) mainly for its safety and liquidity, but investors primarily hold
EM debt for its yield. Therefore, in Sections 3.2 and 3.4 we estimate the funding propensi-
ties from the point of view of EM and AE sovereigns, respectively. Section 3.3 then shows
that under some additional assumptions, this framework may be used to identify and esti-
mate the investor demand similarly to the approach in Koijen and Yogo (2020). In Section
4, we combine these estimates with the marginal investor results above to determine the
We now describe a framework to relate the debt funding of a sovereign to its creditor hold-
ings and to study how those creditors respond to the yield. Clearly, the sovereign debt
The supply of debt depends upon factors that impact the desire to borrow along with the
cost of doing so. Specifically, a long literature has related government financing needs with
economic downturns and macroeconomic variables such as inflation (e.g. Aguiar, Chatter-
jee, Cole, and Stangebye (2020); Reinhart and Rogoff (2011)). Moreover, a government’s
ability to borrow depends upon its perceived riskiness. For example, in the defaultable
sovereign debt literature, debt levels depend upon the country’s income level and its de-
fault probability (e.g., Arellano (2008)). We summarize this relationship by treating the debt
18
supply-to-GDP as dependent on a vector of country-specific variables that impact the bor-
rowing decision, defined as xt (n) for a given country n, as well as its own lag. Thus, defining
the book value of country n’s debt as a share of GDP to be d(n) ≡ D (n)/Y (n), where Y (n)
is country n’s GDP level, we can write the debt supply function as: dt (n) = d (xt (n), dt−1 ).
Our analysis below uses the functional form for this process given by:
where γ0 is the legacy debt that has not matured and gt (n) = Yt (n)/Yt−1 (n) is country
n’s GDP growth rate. Governments mostly borrow long-term so that (1 − γ0 )−1 is ap-
proximately the maturity of country n’s debt. The newly issued debt depends on the set
characteristics xt (n). Below, we will assume that investors and governments view the same
Given a desired supply of book value for this debt, a government then raises the debt
according to the willingness to fund by a set of creditors. To examine the funding provided
by these investors, we define Pt (n) as the price of debt of government n at time t and the
holdings of country n’s debt are assumed to depend on the price of debt Pt (n) and other
m (n) =
country characteristics xt (n). We capture this relation as a funding function: hi,t
hi ( Pt (n), xt (n)). The market clearing condition in Equation (1) can then be rewritten as:
I
Pt (n)dt (n) = ∑ hi ( Pt (n), xt (n)). (6)
i =1
This condition implies an equilibrium price level of country n’s debt, Pt (n), as a function of
the book value of debt-to-GDP, dt (n), and the propensity for investors to fund debt depend-
19
The ability for the government to sustain debt will depend upon its borrowing costs,
captured by the price of debt. In general, the price of debt depends upon the interest rate,
debt maturity and coupon repayment schedule. While this information may be available for
some individual bond issuances, the debt maturity and payment schedules for total debt are
not available. Therefore, we assume that the annualized interest cost per period is proxied
by the yield-to-maturity on pure discount government bonds. In this case, the price of debt
is: Pt (n) = (1 + yt (n))−T , where y(n) is the yield of T-year debt issued by government n.
We now use this framework to estimate the investor willingness to fund debt viewed
m ( n ) as
from the point of view of the borrowing government. We specify this function hi,t
a log-linear function of yield yt (n) and exogenous characteristics xt (n).14 The empirical
regression model of investor i’s holding shares of country n’s debt-to-income is then:
m 0
ln hi,t (n) = θ0,i yt (n) + θ1,i xt (n) + θi (n) + θi,t + ε i,t (n) (7)
As Equation (7) shows, the willingness to fund by investor group i depends not only on
the yield and country-specific characteristics x(n), but also on country and year fixed ef-
fects. Country fixed effects θi (n) are included to capture the time-invariant characteristics
of countries that affect the overall ability to fund from a given investor group.15 Year fixed
effects θi,t are included to capture worldwide economic shocks that are common to all coun-
tries. Finally, ε i,t (n) captures investor i’s latent demand for country n’s debt.
Estimating holdings shares as in Equation (7) presents two identification issues. First,
likely to be correlated with latent demand ε i,t (n). To address this problem, we construct
an instrument for yield yt (n) based on the insight of Koijen and Yogo (2020) that utilizes
14 Since Pt (n) is a monotonic transformation of yt (n), we replace Pt (n) in the Hi function with yt (n).
15 The inclusion of fixed effects is a departure from Koijen and Yogo (2019, 2020). It is motivated by the different structure
of our data: allocating all of a borrower’s debt by the investors, rather than allocating all of the investors’ assets to the
borrowers or equity issuers. Foreign investors in our data are composed of different entities for each country. The identifying
assumption of our approach is that all countries face a common willingness to fund debt by a given foreign investor group
based on their exogenous characteristics, x(n), and yield. Including a sovereign country fixed effect within the vector of
characteristics better captures constant funding differences across sovereigns for a given investor type that are not captured
by the other characteristics. Moreover, domestic investors operate in very different contexts within their own countries. Thus,
including fixed effects also help to make domestic investor behavior more comparable across borrowers by controlling for
time-invariant differences of each country within each domestic investor group.
20
the market clearing condition to construct an implied yield that is orthogonal to the latent
demand and correlated with the observed yield. Our dataset includes a full set of creditors
for a particular sovereign, which enables us to construct the instrument using this insight.
Specifically, we begin by estimating the market value of holdings per investor group as
m
ln hi,t (n) = αi0 xt (n) + αi (n) + αi,t + ui,t (n). (8)
m ( n ) = exp( α̂0 x ( n ) +
The fitted values of this regression for each investor defined as ĥi,t i t
α̂i (n) + α̂i,t ) provides an exogenous measure of the right-hand side of the market clearing
The second identification issue concerns the endogeneity of the supply of debt. There-
fore, according to Equation (4), we project current debt-to-GDP on the characteristics and
Substituting the fitted values of Equation (9), defined as dˆt (n), for the realized debt along
m ( n ), into the market clear-
with the fitted values from the market value of holding shares, ĥi,t
where the fitted value is: dˆt (n) = γ̂0 dt−1 (n) gt (n)−1 + γ̂1 xt (n) + γ̂(n) + γ̂t . Based upon
this condition, we then solve for the hypothetical yield ỹ j,t that clears the market given the
exogenous variables. The hypothetical yield ỹ j,t is then used as an instrument for the actual
We now use this framework above to estimate the investor funding shares for EM sovereigns.
Note that estimating Equation (7) requires specifying a set of country-specific characteristics,
xt (n). For this purpose, we draw on a large literature on emerging market sovereign debt
21
that has provided a rich set of variables that may impact investor demand. In general, credi-
tors prefer a higher yield, but are concerned about potential default risk. Thus, creditors are
more likely to invest in countries with characteristics that they view as correlated with lower
default. For example, they are likely to be attracted to countries with higher growth, but dis-
like inflation.16 In light of the literature on sovereign debt and following Koijen and Yogo
(2020) that estimates asset demand across countries, we include real GDP growth (“GDP
growth”), inflation, the logarithm of the export-to-GDP ratio (“Exp-to-GDP”), the logarithm
of the nominal GDP (”GDP”) and sovereign credit ratings (”Ratings”).17 We use the five-
year local currency government bond yield (”Bond Yield”) as the relevant price variable.18
Table 2 reports the IV estimation results, relegating the reduced form holding estimates of
Equation (8) and the debt-to-GDP estimates of Equation (9) to the Appendix Section C.1 and
C.2, respectively. As would be expected on economic grounds, all investor groups increase
holdings in response to a higher yield. Moreover, most investor groups increase demand for
a country’s sovereign debt when GDP grows and inflation declines, although insignificantly
so for some groups. Exports-to-GDP and Ratings are relatively insignificant across groups.
The responsiveness of the holdings to yield provide an important first look at the rele-
vance of different investor groups for the sovereign, as reported in the first row of Table 2.
Within domestic investors, both banks and non-banks have a significant response to yield,
but the non-bank group is almost twice as responsive. That is, in response to a 1 percent
increase in yield, domestic non-banks increase their debt holding by 23% while domestic
banks do so by 12%. Similarly, among the foreign investors, foreign non-banks are the most
responsive as they increase holdings by 38% for a 1 percent increase of yield. Thus, non-
banks appear to vary their sovereign debt holdings by more than other investor groups in
16 See for example Arellano (2008) and Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) on output growth; Arellano et al. (2020) and Reinhart
and Rogoff (2011) on inflation. Aguiar et al. (2020) provides a survey.
17 Using a data base of bilateral holdings across countries with a larger number of observations, Koijen and Yogo (2020) also
include some other variables such as imports-to-GDP, real GDP per capita, and equity volatility. Using our much smaller data
base of holdings by country, we found that these variables were generally insignificant
18 We use five-year yields because the coverage of countries is greater than that of other maturities. Similarly, we use the
yields in local currency since EM governments primarily borrow in their local currency, and have been increasingly borrowing
from abroad in local currency, thereby making the liquidity in these markets greater. For discussion, see for example Du and
Schreger (2016) and Onen, Shin, and von Peter (2023), as well as Table C4 in the BIS Debt Securities Statistics.
22
response to yield changes.
Note: This table reports the IV estimates of the funding shares in Equation (7), with country and year
fixed effects for the EM sovereign debt. The sample spans 1996-2018 at annual frequency. The
dependent variable is holding of the group indicated in the column title to GDP. The standard errors
clustered at country and year levels are reported in the parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
These results provide insights from the sovereign’s perspective about how funding varies
across investor groups in response to changes in borrowing costs, captured by the local
currency yield. However, given that the data do not include information about the identity
of the investor, this analysis presumes governments do not have separate information about
the investor demand in the funding market. Nevertheless, in the next subsection, we show
that under some additional assumptions, our framework can be viewed as consistent with
the literature of demand system asset pricing as described in Koijen and Yogo (2019, 2020)
and our estimated demand elasticities are similar to those reported in the literature.
23
3.3 Investor Demand Estimation for Emerging Market Debt
As noted above, our data set does not provide the identity of the investor other than whether
it is domestic or foreign and its sectoral classification. Therefore, it does not provide infor-
mation about what the other holdings of these investors are. This omission is important be-
cause, in reality, investors substitute between debt issued by different countries. Moreover,
foreign investors care about returns denominated in their own currency, while domestic in-
vestors care about returns denominated in local currency. In principle, these issues could be
addressed with a more granular data set that included the identity of these investors and
Despite these issues, under two additional assumptions, our data can be used to esti-
mate a demand system model of EM debt by different investor groups following Koijen and
Yogo (2019, 2020). We summarize these assumption below, although Appendix D provides
more details. First, we assume that all foreign investors within a specific investment group
can be treated as a single investor. This assumption requires, for instance, that a foreign
bank does not become a domestic bank within the sample. This assumption appears more
reasonable for EM sovereign debt since many of their foreign investors are from advanced
economies. Second, since we do not know the identity of the foreign investors, we assume
that these investors are all US dollar-based investors. As such, they face foreign exchange
risk in holdings of non-US dollar denominated debt and base their risk-free rate on US Trea-
suries. Although this assumption is inaccurate for some foreign investors, the continued
importance of the US dollar in the global market suggests that it provides a useful bench-
Under these assumptions, we then treat the six creditor groups as distinct investor types
with desired portfolio shares of an unobserved wealth. As in Koijen and Yogo (2020), we
model investor i’s portfolio share of country n’s debt as a logistic function of expected re-
turns and the set of country characteristics xt (n).19 That is, we denote the portfolio holdings
19 UnlikeKoijen and Yogo (2020), we do not have a breakdown of total debt holdings to wealth by investor group and
therefore we collapse the two-step decision process within and across asset classes in that paper into one single step.
24
m ( n ) = ω ( n ) A where A is
of investor i of sovereign debt holdings of country n as: Hi,t i,t i,t i,t
the wealth of investor i in US dollars and ωi,t (n) is the share of country n’s sovereign debt in
investor i’s portfolio. Similarly, Hi,t (0) = Ai,t ωi,t (0) is the amount of investor i outside asset
holdings in US dollars and ωi,t (0) is the portfolio share of that asset. The regression model
where λi,t and λi (n) are year and country fixed effects and µi,t (n) is the expected excess
return of country n’s sovereign debt faced by investor i. Similar to our analysis in Section
3.2, country fixed effects are included to capture time-invariant country characteristics while
time fixed effects are included to capture global-wide shocks that are common to all coun-
tries.
Estimating Equation (11) poses two challenges. First, we do not observe the net worth or
the outside asset held by investor i. Second, the expected excess return faced by domestic
and foreign investors differ according to their base currency. Therefore, we next discuss how
Outside Assets We first describe our approach to the outside asset for the foreign investors
and the domestic investors, in turn. As noted above, we treat foreign investors as repre-
sentative investors in the global economy who make debt allocation decisions across all the
EM countries. Given that we do not observe the wealth or outside asset holding of such in-
vestors, we assume that their outside asset holding can be absorbed by the time fixed effect
and thus not affect our parameter estimation. Clearly, this treatment requires the foreign
Domestic investors are different from foreign investors, however, as they differ by coun-
try. For example, for a particular investor group such as ”banks”, we have N distinct domes-
tic banks in this investor group, one for each country. As such, we do not have a sufficient
number of observations for a given domestic investor to identify a separate response per
25
country. Therefore, we instead treat the responses of the domestic investors jointly across
countries but condition on a proxy for the outside asset, defined for a particular domestic
investor group as Hi,t (o, n). Thus, Equation (11) can be rewritten for domestic investors as:
m (n)
!
Hi,t 0
ln = λ0,i µi,t (n) + λ1,i xt (n) + λi,t + λi (n) + ε i,t (n) (12)
Hi,t (o, n)
In our baseline results below, we consider the level of GDP as a proxy of the outside asset
held by investor i of country n, allowing comparability to the foreign investor results. Our
results are qualitatively similar based on measures such as bank credit and the equity market
cap.
Expected Excess Returns We next discuss our treatment of excess returns for foreign and
domestic investor groups. All foreign investors are assumed to be US dollar-based, as noted
earlier. Thus, for foreign investors, we follow Koijen and Yogo (2020) in treating the expected
excess return for a US dollar-based investor as the fitted value of a predictive regression of
holding period return of debt plus the exchange rate change given by:
rt+1 (n) + st+1 (n) − st (n) − yt (US) = φ f pt (n) + ψ f (st (n) − zt (n)) + χ f (n) + ν f ,t+1 (n) (13)
where rt+1 (n) is the holding return of sovereign debt of country n in local currency, st (n)
is the log of exchange rate St (n), and yt (US) is the short-term yield of US Treasuries. The
predictive variables are the log of the bond price, pt (n), and the log of the real exchange rate
given by the difference between the log nominal exchange rate, st (n), and the difference of
price levels between country n and the US, zt (n). A country fixed effect χ f (n) is included to
then:
By contrast, domestic investors are local-currency based and view the realized returns in
excess of their own short term rate given by predictive regressions for each currency n:
26
where yt (n) is the short term rate in local currency of country n. The constructed expected
Appendix D.2 provides the estimation results of the return system as well as a description
Estimation Results Based upon these modifications for outside assets and expected returns,
we can now turn to estimating the investor demand equations. To address the endogeneity
of the expected excess return µi,t (n) for each investor group i, we first construct an instru-
ment following the same steps as in Section 3.2. These instruments are then used to estimate
the foreign and domestic investor demand in Equation (11) and Equation (12).
Table 3 provides the results of this baseline estimation in Panel A. The first two rows
again show the importance of non-bank investors, with the first row showing the depen-
dence on domestic excess returns and the second on foreign excess returns. Among the for-
eign investors, foreign non-banks are the most sensitive as a 1% change in expected excess
returns corresponds to a 10% change in debt holdings of a particular country. Among the
domestic private investors, domestic non-banks are more responsive than domestic banks
at 7.7% and 4.2%, respectively. Domestic central banks are more responsive, although this
response is likely motivated by policy decisions and not by the desire for a return. Across
investor groups, higher inflation leads to a decline in holdings while higher GDP growth
The estimates of expected return responses can further be used to obtain implied in-
vestor demand elasticities. Investors who increase their holdings of a particular country’s
sovereign debt in response to an increased yield would necessarily have to reduce portfo-
lio shares in another asset. This feature of the asset demand system allows for substitution
across debt issued by different countries and different assets more generally. As shown in
Koijen and Yogo (2019) and detailed in Appendix D.2, investor group i’s elasticity of de-
27
Table 3: Investor Demand: Emerging Markets
Panel A: IV Estimates
Note: This table reports the EM sovereign debt IV estimates of the demand function in Equation (12) for the first three columns and in
Equation (11) for the last three columns, including country and year fixed effects. The sample spans 1996-2018 at annual frequency. The
dependent variable is holding of the group indicated in the column title to GDP. The standard errors clustered at country and year level are
reported in the parentheses. Panel A reports the instrumental variable estimates. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Panel B gives the shares
and implied demand elasticities.
mand with respect to expected excess return equals λ0,i (1 − ωi,t (n)). Therefore, calculating
the elasticities requires adjusting the investors’ yield coefficients by their portfolio share of
country n debt holdings, ωi,t (n). Although we do not have measures of portfolio shares
of each investor groups, we can get estimates of domestic and foreign shares. For domes-
tic banks and domestic non-banks, we proxy for this share using the average ratio across
emerging markets of investor group holdings of own government bonds to assets. Taken
28
from the IMF Financial Soundness Indicators, these ratios are 0.14 for banks and 0.34 for
non-banks. For foreign investors, we take the data from the Euro area SHS data and BIS
area non-bank investors is about 1.5% of their portfolio. From the BIS banking statistics,
foreign banks have roughly 1% of claims on foreign sovereigns (Hardy and Zhu (2023)).
Panel B of Table 3 reports these shares and their implied elasticities with respect to yield.
These elasticities vary from 10 for domestic banks to around 35 for foreign non-banks. Al-
though much of the comparable elasticities in the literature relate to private assets instead of
sovereign debt, the estimates are consistent with other debt instruments. For example, for
ten year bonds, Jiang et al. (2022) find a range of 13 to 44, while the estimates in Koijen et al.
(2021) vary between 12 to 30 but reach 72 for foreigners. The similarity between these elas-
ticity estimates suggests that there may be a high degree of substitutability between private
and sovereign debt, an interesting question that we leave on the agenda for future research.
We now return to consider the funding of Advanced Economy debt based upon the frame-
work described in Section 3.2. The approach to estimating AE sovereign debt funding is
similar to that of EM sovereigns with two modifications. First, since variations in yields are
much lower for these countries, we regress the holdings on the logarithm of the yield.20 Sec-
ond, we omit some countries. In particular, given the special status of the US Treasury Mar-
ket, we exclude the U.S. sovereign debt from the AE sample. Indeed, as is well recognized
in the literature, US Treasuries are often treated as special safe assets in the international
exclude Greece for the period of 2009 to 2015 when Greece was experiencing a debt crisis
Table 4 reports the IV estimation results for AEs. The results for the first-step regressions
20 For some countries, the yields are very low during the Zero Lower Bound period implying implausibly out-sized re-
sponses.
21 On the safe asset status, see for example, Jiang, Krishnamurthy, and Lustig (2018)and the discussion in Gourinchas, Rey,
29
Table 4: Advanced Economy Funding: Instrumental Variable Estimates
Note: This table reports the IV estimates of the funding function in Equation (7), with country and
year fixed effects. The sample spans 2000-2018 at annual frequency. The dependent variable is holding
of the group indicated in the column title to GDP. The standard errors clustered at country and year
level are reported in the parentheses.* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
for the instrument and results for the projected debt are reported in Appendices C.3 and C.4,
respectively. As the first row shows, the responses of each investor group’s holdings to yield
changes are all positive. Moreover, as with the holdings of EM debt, the non-banks are the
most responsive to changes in yields within the domestic and foreign investor groups. In
particular, a one percent change in the local currency yield leads to a 2.2% change in holding
foreign non-banks respond to the same change with a 3.1% change in holdings compared to
a 0.98% change by foreign banks. Overall, the pattern that non-banks are more responsive
It would be useful to estimate these holdings as a demand system based upon the in-
30
noted earlier, in our data set foreigners are only identified as living outside the given coun-
try. Thus, we cannot cleanly identify which investors are foreign for a given sovereign.
For example, German banks will be in the ”Domestic bank” group for German debt but in
the ”Foreign bank” group for French debt. Thus, we cannot estimate realistic investor de-
mand systems for AE governments with this data set. A more granular data set of portfolio
holdings of sovereign debt and other securities would be required for the estimation of the
demand system for AE sovereign debt, an important study that we leave for future research.
Section 3 reported estimates of the demand response of different investors to, alternatively,
changes in the yield or the expected excess return of debt and to other country characteris-
tics. This section illustrates why the investor composition of sovereign debt holdings mat-
ters. For this purpose, we develop a measure of financing costs and show how it depends
upon the investor elasticity to yield. We then consider how this financing cost differs ac-
cording to the characteristics preferred by the various investor groups. All of the analysis in
this section is based upon the Emerging Market sample using estimates from the demand
system approach in Section 3.3. Using the estimates in Section 3.2 leads to similar results.
In this section, we conduct counterfactual analyses for private investors only. Despite
that official lenders’ holdings respond to the price of debt and other characteristics changes,
we treat official lenders’ holding as policy choices instead of market behaviors. The marginal
or average shares of official lenders are redistributed proportionally to private bank and
non-bank sectors.
We begin by asking the question: how much will the cost of financing increase if the gov-
ernment wants to increase the debt by one percent? This question is clearly an important
one given the projected rise of debt-to-GDP in the next few years. To calculate this measure,
we first note that the present value of the cost of borrowing to the country is equal to the
31
present value of debt to the creditors according to the market-clearing condition in Equa-
tion (6). For expositional parsimony, we also define the market-value of debt as: Dtm ≡ Dt Pt
and subsume the dependence upon country n. Then, Appendix E.1 shows that the overall
dy ∑iI=1 ai /( T + ηi )
ξ≡ = (17)
d ln D m ∑iI=1 ai ηi /( T + ηi )
where ηi is the yield elasticity of demand by investor group i and ai is the change in book
2. We call this measure ξ the ”financing cost sensitivity.” This calculation is a partial equi-
librium calculation as it does not account for substitution effects that arise from investors
adjusting their portfolios towards or away from non-EM sovereign debt assets in response
to prices.
cost of financing in response to a one percent change in the book value of debt. This sensi-
tivity equals the marginal absorption-weighted average of the inverse demand elasticities.
Intuitively, if the sovereign issues one percent more debt, ai percent is absorbed by investor
group i. To induce investor group i to absorb this amount of debt, the yield must rise by
ai /(ηi + T ). By contrast, the denominator shows how much debt should be issued at book
value in order to collect one more percent in market value. Since demand is downward-
sloping, the price of debt will in general decrease when the debt level increases. Thus, the
increase in market value of debt will be lower than the increase in book value of debt. If
the aggregate elasticity is relatively high, the price change is mild so that the increase in
debt revenue will be close to the increase in book value. We use our estimates to study the
Panel A of Table 5 reports these financing cost sensitivities calculated from Equation (17)
using the marginal responses a from Table 1 and elasticities η from Table 3. For convenience,
Panel D repeats the estimates used in this calculation. The first row of Panel A shows the fi-
nancing sensitivity using the total composition of investors in our sample estimates. Specif-
32
ically, if a government increases debt by 10 percent, the cost of financing given by the debt
yield, will increase by 59 basis points. The average 5-year yield of EM debt in our sample is
8.8%, so that an increase of 59 basis points represents a 6.7% increase in cost of financing.
Next, we consider how a change in the investor base would impact this financing sensi-
tivity. These counterfactuals evaluate how the financing costs are affected if the absorption
shares of a given investor group is set to zero while the remaining shares are distributed
proportionately across the remaining investors according to their marginal absorption lev-
els. As Table 5 Panel A shows in the row labeled ”No Bank”, excluding the bank investor
groups as a whole would move the cost of financing sensitivity from 59 basis points to 52
basis points in response to a 10% increase in debt revenue. By contrast, the next row la-
beled ”No Non-bank” illustrates how excluding the non-bank investor groups (domestic
and foreign) would impact financing. As reported, eliminating non-banks would signifi-
cantly increase the overall financing cost sensitivity to 80 basis points, representing a 9%
increase for the average emerging market. This greater sensitivity is due to the higher elas-
ticities of non-bank investors as reported in Panel D. Thus, when the investor base has more
We next consider how a change in the characteristics of the borrower would impact the gov-
ernment’s financing costs. Specifically, in this second set of illustrations, we ask the question:
how much would the yield have to change in response to changes in characteristics in or-
der to keep the market value of debt unchanged? This counterfactual provides information
about the investor substitutability between the borrowing costs and characteristics.
For this purpose, we define ζ as the change of yield in response to a unit change in one
of the characteristics, Xt (n), given the market value debt. Then, Appendix E.2 shows that ζ
33
where
m ( n )) m (n)
! !
I ∂ ln Hi,t I ∂ ln Hi,t
1
ζ̃ = −
T ∑ ∂Xt (n)
ψi ÷ 1− ∑
∂Pt (n)
ψi
i =1 i =1
and where ψi is the average share of emerging market debt held by investor group i, as given
in Table 1. The numerator ζ̃ is the response of yield to a unit change of characteristic Xt (n)
for a given book value of debt Dt (n). However, if the yield of debt changes in response to
changes in X, the market value of debt will move accordingly. Therefore, the book value of
To analyze this relationships, we focus on two characteristics: real GDP growth and the
inflation rate. Panel B of Table 5 reports the response of yield to a one percent decrease
in real GDP growth. As shown in Table 3 (repeated in Table 5 Panel D), a decrease of real
GDP growth induces investors to reduce their demand of debt, so that the yield increases.
In response to a one percentage point decrease of real GDP growth, the yield increases by
36 basis points, which is equal to a 4.1% rise in the average yield to EM debt. Similarly, if
inflation increases by one percent, the yield would have to increase by 22 basis points, which
is equal to 2.5% of the average yield to EM debt. The reason is that, other things equal, all
investors dislike investing in the debt of countries with low GDP growth and high inflation.
To evaluate how investors differ according to their view of these attributes and their im-
pact on funding, we next consider how the the cost of financing sensitivity changes with
different investor bases. Table 5 Panel B shows the results of this analysis under the rows
labeled ”No Bank” and ”No Non-bank.”22 Excluding the bank investor groups as a whole,
yield will increase by 41 basis points in response to a one-percent real GDP growth decrease
and 19 basis points in response to a one-percent inflation increase. By contrast, excluding the
non-bank investor groups implies that the yield would have to increase by 29 basis points
to a one percent decrease in real GDP growth but a significantly higher 28 basis points to an
increase in inflation. As Panel D shows, the reason is that foreign non-banks’ holdings of
debt have the strongest response to GDP growth and foreign banks’ holdings of debt have
22 As before, the absorption shares of different investor groups are set to zero with the remaining shares distributed propor-
tionately across the remaining investors according to their marginal absorption.
34
the strongest response to inflation among all investors. Thus, excluding investor groups
with strongest responses reduces the yield pressure from these changes. Overall, these re-
sults highlight the importance of non-banks not only for their sensitivity to yield, but to
characteristics as well.
Finally, we analyze the impact of changes in investor group latent demand on the borrow-
ing costs. In particular, we ask: how much would yield change in response to a one percent
increase in a given investor group’s latent demand given the market value of debt? Intu-
itively, if investors in a particular group, k, increase their latent demand, the price of debt
will increase. Thus, the government can issue less book value of debt to maintain the same
market value. The reduced debt issuance will further lower debt yield. Appendix E.3 shows
that this sensitivity of financing costs to latent demand can be expressed as:
dyt (n) ϕ̃
ϕ≡ = (19)
dek,t (n) 1 − Tξ
where ϕ̃ = ψk /T ÷ 1 + 1
T ∑iI=1 ψi ηi . Table 5 Panel C reports the results of this analysis.
Since domestic investors are in general less elastic than foreign investors and also hold more
debt, a demand increase leads to the larger yield reduction for domestic investors than for-
5 Concluding Remarks
The rising levels of government debt worldwide in the wake of the Covid-crisis have made
urgent the answers to questions about their repayment. At the front of those questions is:
who holds this debt and does it matter to borrowers in this market? In this paper, we address
these questions by analyzing a unique data set that decomposes sovereign debt into investor
holding groups for a large number of countries over almost three decades.
Based upon our analysis, the answers to these questions are striking. First, private fi-
35
Table 5: Borrowing Cost Sensitivity and Counterfactuals
Investor Group Domestic Bank Domestic Non-bank Foreign Bank Foreign Non-bank
Panel A reports calculations of the borrowing cost sensitivity in Equation (17). Panel B gives the effects on borrowing costs
due to the characteristics as in Equation (18). Panel C provides the effects of latent demand by investor group given in
Equation (18). Panel D provides the measures used in the counterfactual calculations. The marginal shares a and average
shares ψ are from Table 1 while the semi-elasticities η, and coefficients for GDP growth and inflation are from Table 3.
Footnotes: a scaled by 10% ; b based upon average EM five-year yield in our sample of 8.8%
36
nancial institutions that are not banks absorb substantially more of the variation in out-
standing government debt than other investor groups. Further decomposing this non-bank
investment group using country/region specific data, we find that investment funds are
the primary drivers of this larger group. Next, we identify the propensity to provide fund-
ing across investor groups by exploiting the market clearing condition provided by the full
set of creditors in our data. Using these estimates, we find that the elasticity of demand
by non-bank investors is higher than other groups. Finally, we use both the marginal in-
crease of holdings together with EM investor demand estimates to calculate the financing
cost sensitivities. An average EM country faces significant financing cost sensitivity since a
10% increase would lead to a nearly 7% increase in borrowing costs. These countries face
the greatest sensitivity of financing cost against losing non-bank investors compared to any
other investment groups, as removing them from the investor pool increases the borrowing
cost response from 7% to 9%. We conclude that EM sovereign investors are highly vul-
nerable to the presence or absence of non-bank investors. Thus, the behavior of non-bank
Our analysis opens up several avenues for future research, particularly given the limita-
tions of our data. For example, our data is annual and lacks detailed data on the currency
and maturity structure of sovereign debt. It also does not report the location of foreign
built from the investor side, such as fund level data or granular data underlying the euro
area SHS data, would allow researchers to dig further into the aspects of the data missing
from our study and provide greater analysis from the investors’ perspectives. They would
allow a deeper understanding of how investors trade off their holdings of sovereign debt
with other assets, how they respond differently to local currency versus foreign currency
debt of emerging market sovereigns, how the yield elasticity varies by maturity, or how in-
terventions by AE central banks affect their presence in the market. They would also allow
for greater analysis of the heterogeneity of this very diverse group of investors. We leave
37
References
Aguiar, M., Chatterjee, S., Cole, H., & Stangebye, Z. (2020). Self-fulfilling debt crises, revisited. Federal
Aguiar, M., & Gopinath, G. (2007). Emerging market business cycles: The cycle is the trend. Journal of
Arellano, C. (2008). Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies. American Economic
Review.
Arellano, C., Bai, Y., & Mihalache, G. P. (2020). Monetary policy and sovereign risk in emerging economies
Arellano, C., & Ramanarayanan, A. (2012). Default and the maturity structure in sovereign bonds.
Arnone, M., & Ugolini, P. (2005). Primary dealers in government securities. International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C..
Arslanalp, S., & Sunder-Plassmann, L. (2022). Sovereign debt repatriation during crises. IMF Working
Arslanalp, S., & Tsuda, T. (2012). Tracking global demand for advanced economy sovereign debt. IMF
Arslanalp, S., & Tsuda, T. (2014). Tracking global demand for emerging market sovereign debt. IMF
Avdjiev, S., Hardy, B., Şebnem Kalemli-Özcan, & Servén, L. (2022). Gross capital flows by banks,
Bianchi, J., Hatchondo, J. C., & Martinez, L. (2018). International reserves and rollover risk. American
Bianchi, J., & Sosa-Padilla, C. (2020). Reserve accumulation, macroeconomic stabilization, and sovereign risk
Bocola, L. (2016). The pass-through of sovereign risk. Journal of Political Economy, 124(4), 879–926.
Bretscher, L., Schmid, L., Sen, I., & Sharma, V. (2020). Institutional corporate bond pricing. Swiss Finance
Brunnermeier, M., Garicano, L., Lane, P., Pagano, M., Reis, R., Santos, T., . . . Vayanos, D. (2016). The
sovereign-bank diabolic loop and esbies. American Economic Review, 106(5), 508-512.
Bruno, V., & Shin, H. S. (2015). Cross-border banking and global liquidity. Review of Economic Studies,
38
82(2), 535-564.
Chari, V. V., Dovis, A., & Kehoe, P. J. (2020). On the optimality of financial repression. Journal of Political
Cruces, J., & Trebesch, C. (2013). Sovereign defaults: the price of haircuts. American Economic Journal:
Curcuru, S. E., Thomas, C. P., Warnock, F. E., & Wongswan, J. (2011). Us international equity investment
Dominguez, K., Hashimoto, Y., & Ito, T. (2012). International reserves and the global financial crisis.
Du, W., & Schreger, J. (2016). Local currency sovereign risk. Journal of Finance, 71(3), 1027-1069.
Eaton, J., & Gersovitz, M. (1981). Debt with potential repudiation: Theoretical and empirical analysis.
Fahri, E., & Tirole, J. (2018). Deadly embrace: Sovereign and financial balance sheets doom loops.
Faia, E., Salomao, J., & Veghazy, A. V. (2022). Granular investors and international bond prices: Scarcity-
Fang, X., & Liu, Y. (2020). Volatility, intermediaries, and exchange rates. Journal of Financial Economics.
Gabaix, X., & Maggiori, M. (2015). International liquidity and exchange rate dynamics. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 1369-1420.
Garcia Luna, P., & Hardy, B. (2019). Non-bank counterparties in international banking. BIS Quarterly
Gennaioli, N., Martin, A., & Rossi, S. (2014). Sovereign default, domestic banks, and financial institu-
Ghosh, A., Ostry, J., & Tsangarides, C. (2017). Shifting motives: Explaining the buildup in official
reserves in emerging markets since the 1980s. IMF Economic Review, 65, 308–364.
Gourinchas, P.-O., & Rey, H. (2007). International financial adjustment. Journal of Political Economy,
115(4), 665-703.
Gourinchas, P.-O., Rey, H., & Govillot, N. (2017). Exorbitant privilege and exorbitant duty. Working
Paper.
Hardy, B., & Zhu, S. (2023). Covid, central banks and the bank-sovereign nexus. BIS Quarterly Review,
March, 15-31.
39
Jiang, Z., Krishnamurthy, A., & Lustig, H. (2018). Foreign safe asset demand for us treasurys and the
Jiang, Z., Lustig, H., Van Nieuwerburgh, S., & Xiaolan, M. Z. (2019). The u.s. public debt valuation
Jiang, Z., Richmond, R., & Zhang, T. (2022). A portfolio approach to global imbalances. Journal of
Finance, Forthcoming.
Koijen, R. S., Koulischer, F., Nguyen, B., & Yogo, M. (2021). Inspecting the mechanism of quantitative
Koijen, R. S., Richmond, R. J., & Yogo, M. (2020). Which investors matter for equity valuations and
Koijen, R. S., & Yogo, M. (2019). A demand system approach to asset pricing. Journal of Political Economy,
127(4), 1475–1515.
Koijen, R. S., & Yogo, M. (2020). Exchange rates and asset prices in a global demand system (Tech. Rep.).
Krishnamurthy, A., & Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2012). The aggregate demand for treasury debt. Journal of
Laeven, L., & Valencia, F. (2020). Systemic banking crises database ii. IMF Economic Review, 68(2),
307–361.
Liu, Y. (2022). Government debt and risk premia. Journal of Monetary Economics, Forthcoming.
Liu, Y., Schmid, L., & Yaron, A. (2020). The risks of safe assets. Available at SSRN 3699618.
Maggiori, M., Neiman, B., & Schreger, J. (2020). International currencies and capital allocation. Journal
Mendoza, E., & Yue, V. (2012). A general equilibrium model of sovereign default and business cycles.
Miranda-Agrippino, S., & Rey, H. (2021). Us monetary policy and the global financial cycle. Review of
Economic Studies.
Onen, M., Shin, H., & von Peter, G. (2023). Overcoming original sin: insights from a new dataset. BIS
Perez, D. J. (2014). Sovereign debt, domestic banks and the provision of public liquidity.
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2011). This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly. In This
40
Wooldridge, P. (2006). The changing composition of official reserves. BIS Quarterly Review, September
2006, 25-38.
41
Online Appendix
A Data construction
The series in the aggregate dataset are sampled at an annual frequency, covering the years between
1990 and 2018. The series are denominated in US dollars.1 Debt for each category refers to general
government debt, which consists of state, local, and central government debt.
Total Total debt holdings are measured by combining the data from the IMF Historical Public Debt
Database (debt-to-GDP) and GDP series from The World Bank. While a full data series over time are
available for some, there are 96 countries for which the debt-to-GDP series ends in 2015.2 For these
countries, we forecast the total debt level using the forward-looking growth rates from QPSD total debt
Foreign Total The methodology for calculating foreign total holdings is based on that in Avdjiev et
al. (2022). We start by obtaining outstanding external liabilities of the general government sector from
the International Investment Position (IIP) data. This consists of adding together liability positions
from both portfolio debt securities (bonds) and other investment debt (loans). However, coverage of
IIP data by sector can be sparse, especially for recent years (Avdjiev et al., 2022). So, we fill in missing
values from a number of sources. First, if only data for the government sector is missing, but other
sectors are reported, we fill the missing government sector internally from the IIP by subtracting the
reporting sectors from the total. Then, the Quarterly External Debt Statistics (QEDS), when available
(for a limited set of countries starting from 2005). To fill in remaining values, we utilize data from the
Bahrain, Belize, Benin, Bermuda, Bhutan, Bolivia, Botswana, Brunei Darussalam, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cabo Verde,
Cameroon, Cayman Islands, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Republic of Congo, Cote d’Ivoire, Curacao, Djibouti,
Dominica, Ecuador, Republic of Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Eswatini, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Grenada, Guinea, Guinea-
Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Hong Kong SAR, Iran, Iraq, Jamaica, Jordan, Kenya, Kuwait, Lao People’s Democratic Republic,
Lesotho, Liberia, Libya, Liechtenstein, Macao SAR, Madagascar, Malawi, Maldives, Mali, Mauritania, Morocco, Mozambique,
Myanmar, Namibia, Nepal, New Zealand, Niger, Oman, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Qatar, Rwanda, Samoa, San Marino,
São Tomé and Prı́ncipe, Saudi Arabia, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Singapore, Solomon Islands, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Sudan,
Suriname, Syrian Arab Rep., Togo, Tonga, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Uganda, Uruguay, Vanuatu, Venezuela, Zambia,
Zimbabwe.
i
To fill in missing values for outstanding amounts of externally held government bonds, we use the
BIS International Debt Securities (IDS) data. The IDS consists of all debt securities issued in interna-
tional markets, which target foreign investors.3 These data are available for a wide range of countries
and time periods, and include granular splits by issuer country and sector, as well as other details not
utilized in this paper. Internationally issued bonds serve as a good proxy for bonds held by foreign
To fill in missing values for outstanding amounts of non-bond external sovereign liabilities, we use
the BIS International Banking Statistics, to capture lending from foreign banks, as well as IMF credit
from the IIP, which captures official lending. The foreign bank estimation is described below.
Foreign Official Foreign official holdings for advanced economies and China are taken from Ar-
slanalp and Tsuda (2012) and Arslanalp and Tsuda (2014), consisting mostly of foreign official reserves
held abroad. The remaining countries are populated with the data from the World Bank debtor re-
porting system (DRS) data on bilateral and multilateral official lending to emerging and developing
economy governments.
Foreign Bank The methodology for estimating foreign bank holdings is based on Avdjiev et al. (2022).
The Locational Banking Statistics (LBS) capture outstanding claims and liabilities of internationally
active banks located in 44 reporting countries against counterparties residing in more than 200 coun-
tries. Banks record their positions on an unconsolidated basis, including intragroup positions between
offices of the same banking group. The data are compiled based on the residency principle (as done for
IIP or QEDS). The LBS capture the overwhelming majority of cross-border banking activity. The his-
torical LBS data break down counterparties in each country into banks (bank and central bank sectors)
The second set of banking data is the Consolidated Banking Statistics (CBS). This differs from the
LBS in that the positions of banks reporting to the BIS are aggregated by the nationality (rather than by
3 A bond is flagged as international if the registration of the bond, the governing law of the bond, or the listing location
of the bond are not the same as the bond issuer’s country of residence. This classifies in essence any bond whose issuance
targets investors outside of its local market.
4 For US government bonds, when missing from IIP or QEDS, we utilize TIC data to fill in missing values, since US gov-
going back to 1978. More recent enhancements to the BIS LBS data (since 2013) provide more granular counterparty sector
splits, dividing the non-bank sector into the non-bank private sector and the public sector (ie government) (Garcia Luna &
Hardy, 2019).
ii
the residence) of the reporting bank.6 We use the CBS on an immediate counterparty basis (CBS/IC).7
The CBS data historically provide a borrower breakdown of the Non-Bank Sector into Public and Pri-
vate.
While we maintain a residence perspective when identifying holders of government debt, consis-
tent with the LBS and IIP, the CBS have a longer time series of the breakdown between public and
private borrowers, which allow for a larger and longer sample of estimates for foreign banks’ lending
to governments. We use the share of international bank debt for each sector from the CBS to estimate
the split of the Non-Bank LBS data into Public and Private components.8 We calculate the public sector
I NTC pub,n,t
XBS pub,n,t = XBCnb,n,t
[ (A.1)
I NTCnbp,n,t + I NTC pub,n,t
where npb indicates Non-Bank Private, nb indicates Non-Bank, pub indicates Public, n denotes the
of debt, XBC denotes the cross border claims (from the LBS) of BIS reporting banks, and I NTC is
international claims (from the CBS on immediate counterparty basis). The CBS international claims are
defined as the sum of XBC and the local claims by foreign affiliates of these banks that are denominated
in foreign currencies (LCFC).The sector breakdown in the CBS is not available for cross-border claims,
This construction of the split of bank debt makes the following assumptions: First, the sectoral
shares for I NTC are the same as the sectoral shares for XBC. This is reasonable since for most countries,
LCFC tends to be small relative to XBC.9 Second, the sectoral shares for the set of banks that report LBS
data (44 countries) are the same as the sectoral shares for the set of banks that report CBS data (31
countries). The 31 CBS reporting countries account for about 90% of the XBC in the LBS, and the CBS
captures the activities of the subsidiaries of banks from these 31 countries worldwide. As a result, the
CBS data are sufficiently representative to make the above assumption a reasonable one. Third, data
6 For example, the positions of a French bank’s subsidiary located in New York - which in the LBS are included in the
positions of banks in the United States - are consolidated in the CBS with those of its parent and are included in the positions
of French banks.
7 The CBS are compiled in two different ways: by immediate counterparty and by ultimate risk. The immediate counter-
party is the entity with whom the bank contracts to lend or borrow. Ultimate risk takes account of credit risk mitigants, such
as collateral, guarantees and credit protection bought, which transfer the bank’s credit exposure from one counterparty to
another.
8 This general approach is also used in Arslanalp and Tsuda (2012) and Arslanalp and Tsuda (2014)
9 While for most countries, LCFC tends to be small relative to XBC, there are a small number of exceptions. For example,
this is not the case in dollarized economies (e.g. Ecuador) and some emerging European economies (e.g. Hungary and
Poland), where lending denominated in euro and in Swiss francs has been non-negligible.
iii
for the CBS that allow us to estimate the split of Non-Bank into Public and Private are not available for
advanced economies before 2000, and are only available on a semiannual basis for EM for the period
before 2000. We linearly extrapolate the semiannual shares to Public and Private into a quarterly series
for EM. For advanced economies, we assume constant shares from 2000 backwards.10
Recently, the BIS has released its enhanced banking data, starting in 2013. These data contain more
granular borrowing sector splits - Bank, Public, and Non-Bank Private (Garcia Luna & Hardy, 2019).
Avdjiev et al. (2022) use this short, recent series to establish that this methodology for estimating bor-
rowing sector splits generates estimates that are very close to the actual (reported) figures.11 In addition,
we make a correction for Switzerland where holdings by external banks are significantly overestimated
Foreign Non-bank The Foreign Non-bank series is computed by subtracting Foreign Official and
Domestic Total Domestic Total series is computed by subtracting Foreign Total from the Total.
Domestic Central Bank For the most part, domestic central bank holdings are taken from the IMF’s
International Financial Statistics (IFS) data set. This data base provides the debt holdings levels from
the Standardized Reporting Form (SRF) only from 2001 onwards. Therefore, debt holding levels prior
to 2001 are backcasted with annual growth rate taken from the non-standardized reporting form (non-
SRF) in the same dataset. For the countries where the IFS data were incomplete, additional data were
taken from the official websites of respective central banks.13 For these cases, the IFS data were supple-
mented using the backward-looking growth rates taken from central banks’ websites.
Domestic Bank These holdings were compiled using the same procedure as for the Domestic Central
Bank.14
10 The assumption of constant shares for advanced economies before 2000 is not too concerning, as we only extend back 4
years.
11 Since not all LBS reporting countries have started providing the enhanced borrowing sector splits, these comparisons are
based on the set of LBS reporting countries which had started reporting enhanced LBS data as of March 2016.
12 Specifically, the ratio from consolidated banking statistics (CBS) is close to 30% around 2014, while updated data from the
Locational Banking Statistics (LBS), which includes a sector breakdown for government lending in recent years, suggests the
true ratio is closer to 10%, but not more than 20%. We therefore use a ratio of 15% to compute foreign bank holdings of Swiss
government debt.
13 Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Korea, Latvia, Portugal, Spain, Sweden,
UK.
14 The list of countries for which additional data from the official Central Bank websites was used: Belgium, Finland, France,
iv
Domestic Non-bank The Domestic Non-bank series were computed by subtracting the Domestic
Central Bank and Domestic Bank series from the Domestic Total.
Inconsistencies and Cleaning When combining data across different sources, inconsistencies are in-
evitable. While most of the dataset fits together, there are some cases where the sum of some of the
components (e.g. domestic central bank and domestic bank) add to more than the total (e.g. domes-
tic total). In these cases, the procedure produces some negative observations for residually computed
groups (e.g. domestic non-banks). In general, we used the following procedures to maintain internal
consistency in the dataset (i.e. the sum of the parts add up to the whole) for these special cases.
If the Foreign Official plus Foreign Bank is greater than the Foreign Total, we replaced the Foreign
Total as the sum of the Foreign Bank plus the Foreign Official; that is, replace Foreign = max(Foreign
If the sum of the Foreign total and the Domestic bank and the Domestic Central Bank is greater than
the total debt, we replace total debt as this sum; that is, replace Total debt = max(Total debt, foreign
Given these updated variables, we compute any residual categories as needed; that is, we subtract
the other variables from the updated totals to measure the Foreign Non-bank, the Domestic Total, and
After following this process, all of the generated data series are greater than or equal to zero, and
the data are internally consistent. Further, we manually examine cases where the negative values were
large to make sure that this procedure made sense. In a few cases where it appears driven by low data
Advanced economies (23): Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Ger-
many, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Singapore,
Emerging markets (45): Argentina, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Belarus, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China,
Colombia, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Egypt, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jordan,
Latvia, Lithuania, Kuwait, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Oman, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines,
v
Poland, Qatar, Romania, Russia, Serbia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, South Africa, South Korea, Thai-
Developing economies (27): Jamaica, Paraguay, Sudan, Angola, St. Lucia, Lebanon, Bolivia, Tunisia,
Papua New Guinea, Panama, Kenya, Sri Lanka, El Salvador, Ecuador, Dominican Republic, Malta, Al-
bania, Montenegro, Costa Rica, Namibia, Gabon, Kazakhstan, Liberia, Mongolia, Guatemala, Bahamas,
We now describe the data sources for the financial data used in Section 3. The 5-year bond yields are
the corresponding zero coupon yields provided by the Global Financial Data. Countries with avail-
able yields are Korea, United Kingdom, Venezuela, Sri Lanka, Iceland, Norway, Sweden, Australia,
Germany, Singapore, Denmark, Japan, United States, France, Belgium, New Zealand, Canada, Spain,
Finland, Hong Kong, Hungary, Portugal, Malaysia, Switzerland, Italy, India, Morocco, Philippines,
Netherlands, Thailand, Ireland, Austria, Greece, South Africa, Mexico, Poland, Mauritius, Armenia,
Fiji, Pakistan, Tunisia, Zambia, Belarus, Bulgaria, Bangladesh, Malta, Brazil, China, Indonesia, Viet-
nam, Angola, Colombia, Croatia, Israel, Peru, Qatar, Romania, Russia, Slovenia, Turkey, Egypt, Lithua-
For relevant short term rates by currency, we try to obtain 3-month government bond yields where
possible and, if unavailable, we use instead short term deposit rates in local currency. In particular, we
implement the following procedure. First, we take the 3-month bond yields if available from Global
Financial Data. Next, if missing, we use instead the short-term (most of them are 3-month) deposit
rate from the Global Financial Data. Then, if short term rates are still missing, we use the deposit
rate available from the World Bank (World Development Indicators, FR.INR.DPST). Finally, for the few
countries where no short rates are available from these other sources, we fill in the missing data with
Exchange rates are obtained from the World Bank (Global Economic Monitor, DPANUSSPF). Prices
used for the real exchange rates are downloaded from World Bank. We use the 4th quarter Headline
The characteristics data used are described next. We obtained real GDP growth, inflation, exports,
and the GDP level from the IMF World Economic Outlook. In particular, GDP growth is from se-
ries NGDPR PCH, the inflation is series PCPIEPCH, and the GDP level is from series NGDPD. The
vi
Sovereign Ratings measure is a combination of SP Sovereign Rating and Fitch Sovereign Rating. In or-
der to convert the discrete series to numerical levels, we follow the procedure described in Koijen and
Yogo (2020).
This appendix provides more detailed results for the analysis in Section 2.
In this appendix subsection, we report robustness checks for the analysis in Section 2.3. For example,
the analysis in the text treats the investor composition as constant. However, in reality, the composition
of marginal investors may change depending on the time period or circumstance. Indeed, the literature
on marginal investors has highlighted their importance and differences during crises and recessions
(e.g., Bruno and Shin (2015) and Miranda-Agrippino and Rey (2021).) During these times, banks may
cut back lending and central banks may intervene to stabilize the economy. Moreover, these cut-backs
may impact the overall responses of investor holdings of government debt. Therefore, we examine the
To examine marginal investor responses during these time periods, we estimate Equation (2) sepa-
rately when the country-year is, alternatively, (i) in a recession and not; (ii) during a banking crisis and
not; and (iii) in different sub-periods.15 We consolidate the results of these regressions into Figures B1
(panels (b) and (c)) and Figures B2, relegating detailed reporting of the regression coefficients to Tables
The figures highlight important patterns across geographic groups. Both Advanced Economies and
Emerging Market sovereign debt show marked differences in their marginal investors across different
circumstances. For example, domestic non-banks absorb more emerging market debt during recessions
or banking crises, whereas domestic banks decrease their absorption. In advanced economies, the do-
mestic central bank becomes a key investor during a crisis. After the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), both
domestic banks and domestic non-banks increase the share of debt they absorb. A similar pattern holds
for foreign official lenders in the case of advanced economies. This latter trend may reflect increased
15 We define a country as in a recession if its real GDP growth rate is negative, and a country as in a banking crisis if there is
or was a banking crisis in the past 3 years. Banking crises indicators follow Laeven and Valencia (2020). For the sub-periods,
we break the sample up into periods around the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), in particular before 2000, from 2000-2008, and
after 2009.
vii
holdings of debt in the form of reserves by foreign central banks, particularly those in EM countries.16
For developing countries, the role of domestic investors expands considerably during recessions.
The pattern over time is also interesting. From 2000-2009, foreign investors play a larger role in picking
up debt issued by DC sovereigns, but after the GFC domestic investors’ share increases substantially as
foreign non-bank investors contract. The share of foreign official has been increasing over time.
(a) By country group (b) Crisis and recession (c) By time period
Note: This figure plots the regression coefficients in Equation (2) for all countries under different circumstances. Panel (a)
depicts the coefficients for each investor group by country group as reported in Table 1 in the text. Panel (b) shows the
coefficients for each investor group during recession and non-recession times, and during crisis and non-crisis times. A
recession is defined by a negative real GDP growth rate. A crisis is identified following Laeven and Valencia (2020), which
includes a banking crisis, a currency crisis, and a debt crisis. Panel (c) shows the coefficients for each investor group in three
subsamples: pre-2000, 2000-2009, and post-2009.
The basic finding that Non-bank investors are important marginal investors continues to hold across
these different periods. The next subsections examine these relationships in more detail across investor
groups.
Table B1 reports the regression results depicted in Figures 2 for recessions and non-recessions.
16 If
these data were extended through 2020, we might see a much higher marginal share for the domestic central bank, as
some in AEs purchased amounts roughly equal to the net issuance of debt during that year (see the IMF Fiscal Monitor).
viii
Figure B2: Marginal Holders
1.0 1.0
1.0
0.8 0.8
0.6 0.6
0.5
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.2
0.0
0.0 0.0
recession
Recession
crisis
Crisis
2000-2009
2009
All
recession
Recession
crisis
Crisis
2000
2000-2009
2009
All
recession
Recession
crisis
Crisis
2000
2000-2009
2009
No
No
After
No
No
Before
After
No
No
Before
After
Domestic Domestic Domestic Foreign Foreign Foreign
bank non-bank central bank bank non-bank Official
Note: This figure plots the regression coefficients in Equation (2) under different circumstances for advanced economies,
emerging market economies, and developing countries in Panels (a), (b) and (c), respectively. A recession is defined by a
negative real GDP growth rate. A crisis is identified following Laeven and Valencia (2020), which includes a banking crisis, a
currency crisis, and a debt crisis. The regression estimates are in Tables B1, Table B2, and Table B3.
ix
Table B1: Marginal Holders of Sovereign Debt: Recession and No Recession
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (2) for each investor group during recessions (Panel A) and non recessions
(Panel B). A recession is defined as a negative real GDP growth rate. Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are clustered at
the country level and reported in the parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3)
through (8) correspond to the six investor groups described in the text.
x
B.1.2 Banking Crisis and No Banking Crisis
Table B2 reports the regression results depicted in Figures 2 for banking crises.
Table B2: Marginal Holders of Sovereign Debt: Banking Crisis and No Banking Crisis
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (2) for each investor group during times with banking crises (Panel A) and
without banking crisis (Panel B). A country-year (n, t) observation is defined as if country n experienced a banking crisis in either of year
t, t − 1, t − 2, t − 3. Banking crisis definitions follow Laeven and Valencia (2020). For the developing countries, the definition of crisis
includes not only banking crisis, but also debt crisis and currency crisis. Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are
clustered at the country level and reported in the parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively.
Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six investor groups described in the text.
Table B3 reports the regression results depicted in Figures 2 for different subperiods.
xi
B.2 Marginal Investors Considering Currency Valuation Effects
This section provides an analysis of the marginal holders of sovereign debt taking the currency valua-
To see the potential impact of currency, we define the impact of currency valuation on holdings
of sovereign debt n by investor group i as CVi,t (n). Then we can rewrite the general relationship for
holdings as:
where ∆ H̃i,t (n) is the change in holdings excluding currency valuation effects.
To compute ∆ H̃i,t (n), we make two assumptions. First, all domestic investors holdings of their own
sovereign debt is denominated in local currency. Second, the local currency share of foreign investors
may be proxied by the share of local currency among bonds issued in international financial markets,
derived from the BIS international debt securities statistics. In the absence of data on the currency
breakdown by investor group, we treat this share as applying equally across all foreign investors.
Under these assumptions, we then calculate the currency valuation adjustment as:
S t ( n ) − S t −1 ( n )
CVi,t (n) = Hi,t−1 (n) × LCi,t−1 (n) ×
S t −1 ( n )
where LCi,t (n) is country n local currency share of debt investor group i’s holding of country n’s debt,
and St (n) is the price of currency n in terms of dollar, both at time t. We define the currency valuation
adjusted change in total debt as ∆ D̃t (n) = ∑iI=1 ∆ H̃i,t (n). The regression Equation (2) is in turn written
as
We first report the results using the Currency Valuation (CV) measure over all periods. These are
reported in Table B4 below. As the results show, Non-banks continue to absorb the largest proportion
of debt on the margin. Moreover, the following subsections show that these patterns continue to hold
when decomposed by recessions and non-recessions in Table B5, by banking crisis in Table B6, and by
xii
Table B3: Marginal Holders of Sovereign Debt: Different Subperiods
Panel B: 2000-2009
All 0.52*** 0.48*** 0.15** 0.32*** 0.05*** 0.03 0.40*** 0.05**
(0.07) (0.07) (0.06) (0.08) (0.02) (0.02) (0.08) (0.02)
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (2) for each investor group before 2000 (Panel A), 2000-2009 (Panel B), and
after 2009 (Panel C). Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are clustered at the country level and reported in the
parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six
investor groups described in the text.
xiii
Table B4: Marginal Holders of Sovereign Debt Conditioning on Currency
Note: Panel A of the table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (B.2) for each investor group. The first two columns represent
domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six investor groups. Standard errors clustered at the
country level are reported in the parentheses. Panel B of the table reports the average share of holding by each investor group.
xiv
B.2.2 Recessions and Non-Recessions with Currency Valuation
Table B5 report the results of estimating Equation (B.2) conditioned on recessions or no recessions.
Table B5: Marginal Holders Conditioning on Currency: Recession and Non Recession
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (B.2) for each investor group during recessions (Panel A) and non recessions
(Panel B). A recession is defined as a negative real GDP growth rate. Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are clustered at
the country level and reported in the parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3)
through (8) correspond to the six investor groups.
xv
B.2.3 Banking Crisis and No Banking Crisis with Currency Valuation
Table B6 reports the results of estimating Equation (B.2) conditioned on banking crisis or no banking
crisis.
Table B6: Marginal Holders Conditioning on Currency: Banking Crisis and No Banking Crisis
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (B.2) for each investor group with during times with banking crises (Panel
A) and without banking crisis (Panel B). A country-year n, t observation is defined as if country n experienced a banking crisis in either of
year t, t − 1, t − 2, t − 3. Banking crisis definitions follow Laeven and Valencia (2020). For the developing countries, the definition of crisis
includes not only banking crisis, but also debt crisis and currency crisis. Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are
clustered at the country level and reported in the parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively.
Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six investor groups in the text.
xvi
B.2.4 Different Subperiods with Currency Valuation
Table B7 reports the results of estimating Equation (B.2) over different subperiods.
Note: This table reports the regression coefficients for Equation (B.2) for each investor group before 2000 (Panel A), 2000-2009 (Panel B), and
after 2009 (Panel C). Country and year FEs are included, and standard errors are clustered at the country level and reported in the
parentheses. Columns (1) and (2) represent domestic and foreign investors, respectively. Columns (3) through (8) correspond to the six
investor groups.
xvii
B.3 Non-bank Regressions: Euro Area SHS, US Treasuries, and UK Gilts
In this subsection, we report the results of estimating the marginal investor decomposition Equation (2)
for a disaggregated data set of Euro Area investors, US Treasuries, and UK Gilts.
Table B8 reports the estimates of the share of marginal Euro Area investor holdings of non-Euro Area
Note: This table reports regression coefficients of Equation (2) on sovereign debt issued by non-European countries for
different investor groups within Europe. Columns (1) through (3) report coefficients for governments, banks and the
non-bank sector. Columns (4) through (7) disaggregates non-banks into households (HH), insurance and pension funds
(insurPens), non-financial corporations (NFC), and other financial institutions (OthFin). Standard errors clustered at country
and year level are reported in the parentheses.
In particular, in the row labeled ”All”, this table reports the estimates of Equation (2) treating the
denominator as the total holdings of Non-Euro Area sovereign debt by Euro Area investors. Similarly,
in the rows labeled ”AE” and ”EM”, this denominator and related holdings breakdowns are based on
B.3.2 US Treasuries
Table B9 gives the estimates of Equation (2) for the US Treasuries using TIC data. In this case, for the
”All” row, the denominator is given by total holdings of US Treasuries while the numerator corresponds
to holdings by the reported investor groups. In the row labeled ”Non-bank”, the denominator is the
total holdings of Nonbank investors while the numerator is the subgroup of Nonbank investors given
by Money Market Funds (MMFs), Hedge Funds and Households (HF/HH), Insurance and Pensions
(IP), Other Financials (OthFin) and Non Financials (NonFin).As the table shows, non-bank investors
xviii
are particularly important within the domestic investor group. Taken together, Money Market funds
xix
Table B9: Marginal Investors in US Treasuries
Constant 0.004∗∗∗ 0.001 -0.001∗∗ -0.004∗∗∗ 0.000 -0.002∗∗ 0.001∗∗ 0.001∗ -0.001
(0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Observations 104 104 104 104 104 104 104 104 104
Note: This table reports estimates from Equation (2) for the holders of US Treasuries over 1995q1-2020q4. “HF/HH” includes Hedge
funds, private equity, private trusts, and direct household holdings. “NonFin” is all non-financial holders excluding households. “Oth-
Fin” is all other financial institutions apart from funds and Insurance and Pension (I&P). * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
xx
B.3.3 UK Gilts
Table B10 reports estimates for Equation (2) where the holdings are the shares of UK Gilts.
Table B10 gives the estimates of Equation (2) for the UK Gilts. In the row labeled ”All”, the de-
nominator is given by total holdings of UK Gilts while the numerator corresponds to holdings by the
reported investor groups. In the row labeled ”Non-bank”, the denominator is the total holdings of Non-
bank investors while the numerator is the subgroup of Nonbank investors given by ”Funds and Other”,
Insurance and Pensions (IP), and Non Financials (NonFin). As the table shows, non-bank investors are
xxi
C Supplemental Results for Instrument Construction
This appendix provides supplementary information for the instruments used in Section 3 of the text.
This section reports the regression coefficients for the first-stage regression that constructs the instru-
ments. The following Table C11 gives the results for Equation (8) for Emerging Market countries.
Note: This table reports the reduced-form estimates of the first-stage regression of instrument construction for EMs, with country and year
fixed effects. The sample spans 1996-2018 at annual frequency. The dependent variable is the logarithm of the holdings to GDP by investor
group indicated in the column title to GDP. The standard errors are reported in the parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Table C12 reports the projections of debt-to-GDP, dt (n) for EM countries using Equation (9). As de-
scribed in the text, this variable is projected on exogenous characteristics and its lag modified by the
gross GDP growth. A coefficient of 0.72 indicates about a 28% of mean reversion in the level of debt-
to-GDP. As described in the text, this finding may be interpreted as an average maturity of 3.6 years,
which is close to the 5-year bond yield we choose in the main analysis.
xxii
Table C12: Projected Debt-to-GDP Supply: EMs
Debt-to-GDP
Lag Debt-to-GDP 0.72∗∗∗
(0.03)
Inflation 0.11∗∗∗
(0.04)
Exp-to-GDP -0.03∗
(0.02)
Observations 362
R2 0.96
Note: This table reports the estimates of Equation (9) for emerging market economies. The sample spans 1996-2018 at annual frequency. The
standard errors are reported in the parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
C.3 IV Construction: AE
This section reports the estimates used to construct the Advanced Economy instruments for Table 4 in
the text. The following table gives the results of Equation (8) for Advanced Economies.
Table C14 reports the projections of debt-to-GDP, dt (n) for AE countries using Equation (9). As de-
scribed in the text, this variable is projected on exogenous characteristics and its lag modified by the
xxiii
Table C13: Reduced-form holding regressions: AEs
Note: This table reports the reduced-form estimates of the first-stage regression of instrument construction for AEs, with country and year
fixed effects. The sample spans 1996-2018 at annual frequency. The dependent variable is the logarithm of holdings to GDP by the group
indicated in the column title to GDP. The standard errors are reported in the parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Inflation -0.98∗∗
(0.45)
Exp-to-GDP 0.15∗∗∗
(0.05)
Observations 323
R2 0.98
Note: This table reports the estimates of Equation (9) for advanced economies. The sample spans 1996-2018 at the annual frequency. The
standard errors are reported in the parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
xxiv
D Supplemental Results for Demand System Estimation
In this appendix, we provide more detailed results about the demand system approach of estimation in
Table D15 reports the return predictive regression results for Equation (15) and (13) in the main text.
(1) (2)
Domestic Excess Return Foreign Excess Return
qt (n) 0.23∗∗∗
(0.06)
As described there, pt (n) is the logarithm of the price of a 5 year zero coupon bond in local currency
for country n and qt (n) is the logarithm of its real exchange rate relative to the U.S. dollar. In particular,
qt (n) ≡ st (n) − zt (n) where st (n) is the logarithm of the US dollar price of currency n and zt (n) is the
logarithm of the ratio of the price index of country n to the US price index.
We next describe the derivation of the investor demand elasticity following the literature of Koijen and
As described above, foreign non-EM investors hold the sovereign debt of all EM countries plus an
outside asset that does not include this debt. To calculate the demand elasticity relative to expected
returns µ, differentiate with respect to expected returns the ratio of shares for a given country n given
xxv
in Equation (11) in the text. This implies:
dδi,t (n) d(ln ωi,t (n) − ln(1 − ∑kN=1 ωi,t (k ))) d ln wi,t (n) w (k ) d ln wi,t (k )
= = + ∑ i,t = λ0,i (D.1)
dµi,t (n) dµi,t (n) dµi,t (n) k
w i,t (0) dµi,t ( n )
Without loss of generality, consider n = 1 and denote κn,j ≡ (d ln wi,t (n)/dµi,t ( j)). Suppressing the
N
ω (1) ω (k)
κ11 + κ11 + ∑ κ = λ0 (D.2)
ω (0) k =2
ω (0) k,1
N
(ω (0) + ω (1))κ1,1 + ∑ ω (k)κk,1 = λ0 ω (0) (D.3)
k =2
N
ω (1) ω (k)
κ j,1 + κ1,1 + ∑ κ =0 (D.4)
ω (0) k =2
ω (0) k,1
N
ω (0)κ j,1 + ω (1)κ1,1 + ∑ ω (k)κk,1 = 0 (D.5)
k =2
From the equation above, we see that κ j,1 for j 6= 1 does not depend on j. Therefore,
ω (1)
κ j,1 = − κ1,1 for j 6= 1 (D.6)
1 − ω (1)
Substituting this variable into the above Equation (D.3) and solving for κ11 implies:
Since this relationship holds for any arbitrary country n and individual investor i, then clearly the
demand elasticity for foreign investors can be written more generally as:
xxvi
D.2.2 Domestic Investors
We derive the elasticity of demand with respect to expected excess returns for domestic investors by
differentiating Equation (12) in the text. In particular, we differentiate this share as in:
subject to the constraint that the shares of wealth sum to one. In the case of domestic investors, we
assume they hold no other sovereign debt so that the share for domestic investors plus the share of
outside assets sum to one; that is, ωi,t (n) = 1 − ωi,t (0, n). Thus, differentiating the ratio of portfolio
Therefore,
d ln ωi,t (n)
= λ0,i (1 − ωi,t (n)) (D.10)
dµi,t (n)
Comparing this equation with Equation (D.8) makes clear that the form of the demand elasticities are
the same between foreign and domestic investors. Moreover, these demand elasticity measures are the
Price elasticity. Bond price and expected excess return are linked through the predictive regression of
m (n)
d ln Hi,t
= λ0,i (1 − ωi,t (n))φ0i (D.11)
d ln Pt (n)
We lack the data to assess the response of exchange rate in response to bond price change, thus we
must indirectly assume that the change of bond price does not affect demand of debt through changing
exchange rate.
Yield elasticity.
m (n)
d ln Hi,t 1
= − λ0,i (1 − ωi,t (n))φ0i (D.12)
dyt (n) T
xxvii
E Counterfactual Derivation
This section provides the detailed algebra for the calculation of counterfactual measures.
We are interested in the following question: if the government wants to increase debt by one percent,
how much will yield increase? To derive this measure, we start from the following equation:
6
Pt (n) Dt (n) = ∑ Pi,t (n) Hi,t (n) (E.1)
i =1
where Pt (n) is the price of debt issued by country n and Pi,t (n) is the price faced by investor group
i. In equilibrium, Pi,t (n) = Pt (n). Thus, the question above can be restated as: what will happen
to the yield if the government issues one more percent of (market value) debt? This question can be
answered by calculating the change in yield for a percentage change in the market value of debt; that
dyt (n)
is, ξ ≡ d ln( Pt (n) Dt (n))
.
To calculate this measure, note that Pt (n) = exp(− Tyt (n)). Therefore, we can rewrite this measure
as:
dyt (n) dyt (n)
ξ≡ = (E.2)
d ln ( Pt (n) Dt (n)) − Tdyt (n) + d ln Dt (n)
From the market clearing condition, we can express the yield as:
!
6
1
yt (n) = ln Dt (n) − ln ∑ Pti (n) Hi (n) (E.3)
T i =1
I d( Pti (n) Hi,t (n)) dHi,t (n)
dyt (n) 1 ∑
1 i =1 dHi,t (n) dDt (n) t
D ( n )
= − (E.4)
I i
d ln Dt (n) T T ∑i=1 Pt (n) Hi,t (n)
dHi,t (n)
Recall that from Section 2, the investor group i’s marginal financing share dDt (n)
= ai . Moreover, define
∂yt (n) 1 dyt (n)
the inverse demand elasticity as m (n)
∂ ln Hi,t
= η̃i . Then with these definitions, we can re-express d ln Dt (n)
Empirically, our estimates in Table 3 in Panel B provide the semi-elasticity of market value of holding
xxviii
with respect to yield. That is, we can denote our empirical estimates as:
ai
dyt (n) dyt (n)/d ln Dt (n) ∑iI=1 ηi + T
ξ= = = I a i ηi (E.6)
d ln ( Pt (n) Dt (n)) − Tdyt (n)/d ln Dt (n) + 1 ∑ i =1 T + ηi
as given in equation (17) in the text. ξ is the inverse of the aggregate demand semi-elasticity with
In this section, we derive the impact on yield implied by a change in one of the characteristics that we
denote Xt . Again we start with the market clearing condition of Equation (E.1). The market clearing
We first calculate how much the price of debt would change in response to a unit change in Xt (n)
given the book value of debt. Taking the first-derivative with respect to Xt implies:
I ∂H m ( n ) m
d ln Pt (n) d ln Pt (n) ∂Hi,t (n)
Dt (n) Pt (n) =∑ i,t
+ (E.7)
dXt (n) i =1
∂ ln Pt (n) dXt (n) ∂Xt (n)
∂ ln H m (n)
d ln Pt (n) ∑iI=1 ∂Xt (i,tn) ψi
= ∂ ln H m (n)
(E.8)
dXt (n) 1 − ∑iI=1 ∂ ln Pi,tt (n) ψi
where ψi is the average share of debt held by investor i. We can then write the yield response to a
I ∂ ln H m (n)
1 ∑i=1 ∂Xt (n) ψi
i,t
dyt (n)
ζ̃ = =− (E.9)
dXt (n) T 1 − I ∂ ln Hi,tm (n) ψ
∑i=1 ∂ ln Pt (n) i
Clearly, ζ̃ is the yield response to a unit change in Xt (n) given the book value of debt. But the market
value will change with the price response. Therefore, as above, we calculate how much the book value
xxix
Recall that the price of debt can be written as a function of Dt (n) and Xt (n) as P( Dt (n), Xt (n)). We
can rewrite the change of market value in response to a unit change in Xt (n) as
We then solve for the percentage change in the book value of debt due to a change in the given charac-
teristic as:
d ln Dt (n) ∂ ln Pt (n)/∂Xt (n) T ζ̃
=− = (E.11)
dXt (n) 1 + ∂ ln Pt (n)/∂ ln Dt (n) 1 − T ξ̃
where ξ is the inverse of aggregate demand elasticity derived in section E.1. Then defining the yield
response to a unit change in characteristics Xt (n) while keeping the market value of debt unchanged as
dyt (n) T ζ̃ ζ̃
ζ = ζ̃ + = (E.12)
d ln Dt (n) 1 − T ξ̃ 1 − T ξ̃
In this section, we derive the impact on the yield if investor i’s latent demand increases by one percent.
We also consider how much each investor’s holdings will change. We start from the market clearing
condition of Equation (E.1). The market clearing condition implicitly defines a function of Pt (n) =
P( Xt (n), Dt (n), ε t (n)) where ε t (n) is the vector of each investor’s latent demand for debt issued by
country n.
Again, we first fix the book value of debt Dt (n) and take the first-derivative with respect to investor
I ∂H m ( n ) m (n)
d ln Pt (n) d ln Pt ∂Hk,t
Dt (n) Pt (n) =∑ i,t
+ (E.13)
dε k,t (n) i =1
∂ ln Pt dε k,t (n) ∂ε k,t (n)
m ( n ) /∂ε ( n )
d ln Pt (n) ∂Hk,t k,t ψk
= m (n) = ∂ ln H m (n)
(E.14)
dε k,t (n) I ∂Hi,t
Dt (n) Pt (n) − ∑i=1 ∂ ln Pt (n) I
1 − ∑i=1 ψi ∂ ln Pi,tt (n)
xxx
We can then write the yield response as
dyt (n) 1 ψk
ϕ̃ = =− (E.15)
dε k,t (n) T1+ 1
T ∑iI=1 ψi ηi
Next, we calculate how much the book value of debt would have to change in order to keep the market
Solving for the implied percentage change of book value of debt to keep the market value of debt
unchanged implies:
d ln Dt (n) T ϕ̃
= (E.17)
dε k,t (n) 1 − Tξ
Then, defining the object of interest as ϕ, this relationship can be expressed as:
ϕ̃
ϕ= (E.18)
1 − T ξ̃
xxxi
Previous volumes in this series
1098 Long term debt propagation and real Mathias Drehmann, Mikael Juselius
May 2023 reversals and Anton Korinek
1096 Money Market Funds and the Pricing of Sebastian Doerr, Egemen Eren and
May 2023 Near-Money Assets Semyon Malamud
1095 Sectoral shocks, reallocation, and labor Joaquín García-Cabo, Anna Lipińska
April 2023 market policies and Gastón Navarro
1094 The foreign exchange market Alain Chaboud, Dagfinn Rime and
April 2023 Vladyslav Sushko
1093 Sovereign risk and bank lending: evidence Yusuf Soner Baṣkaya, Bryan Hardy,
April 2023 from the 1999 Turkish earthquake Ṣebnem Kalemli-Özcan and Vivian
Yue
1090 Tackling the fiscal policy-financial stability Claudio Borio, Marc Farag and
April 2023 nexus Fabrizio Zampolli
1088 Big techs and the credit channel of Fiorella De Fiore, Leonardo
April 2023 monetary policy Gambacorta and Cristina Manea