Demand-And Supply-Side Agglomerations: Distinguishing Between Fundamentally Different Manifestations of Geographic Concentration
Demand-And Supply-Side Agglomerations: Distinguishing Between Fundamentally Different Manifestations of Geographic Concentration
doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2008.00815.x
abstract Agglomeration research investigates the benefits that firms receive from locating
in close geographic proximity. Despite a substantial surge in interest in this topic over the past
20 years, a lack of distinction among unique manifestations of spatial concentrations of similar
firms threatens continuing progress in this stream of research. We argue that agglomerations
of related firms that draw benefits from the supply-related externalities of increased access to
specialized labour, specialized inputs, and knowledge spillovers are fundamentally different
from those that draw benefits from heightened demand realized through reduction in
consumer search costs. Extending agglomeration theory, we explicate the differences between
these distinct phenomena, discuss how the nature of key theoretical relationships varies across
these agglomeration types, and demonstrate significant implications for research. We discuss
how the differences affect a host of theoretical relationships and empirical research decisions.
INTRODUCTION
The last 20 years have seen a dramatic increase in attention to the potential for firms
locating in close geographic proximity to benefit from positive feedback, or externalities.
Such externalities occur when the ‘net benefits to being in a location together with other
firms increase with the number of firms in the location’ (Arthur, 1990, p. 237). Geo-
graphic concentration of economic activity occurs broadly; well-known examples include
high-technology industries (e.g. California’s Silicon Valley), automotive manufacturing
(e.g. Detroit), and local retail services (e.g. automobile dealers and mall food courts). As
Brown (1989, p. 451) observes, ‘the clustering of similar firms is a truly universal trait,
ranging from the hamburger alleys and automobile rows of most American cities to the
pronounced clusters of goldsmiths and banana sellers in the periodic markets of the third
world’.
Consistent with an emerging stream of literature in this area (e.g. Martin and Sunley,
2003), we take issue with the identification of nearly every geographic assemblage of
Address for reprints: Brian T. McCann, Purdue University, Krannert School of Management, 403 W. State
Street, West Lafayette, IN 47907, USA ([email protected]).
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2009. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
Demand- and Supply-Side Agglomerations 363
firms as a ‘cluster’, befitting of the externalities that accompany agglomeration. Indeed,
among agglomerated firms there are stark differences in the likelihood, the extent, and
the nature of such externalities depending on the underlying mechanisms driving the
agglomeration. Our purpose is to highlight that increased precision in the understanding
of such differences yields insight into important questions that have thus far remained
uninvestigated. Different causal mechanisms manifest themselves in very different
agglomeration phenomena. These differences across types of agglomerations have sig-
nificant implications for how we interpret prior literature on agglomeration and how we
develop theory and empirical studies around agglomeration. We contribute to this
literature in three important ways.
First, we follow a research tradition that has identified that clusters come in different
forms. However, our intent is not to develop a new taxonomy of agglomerations. Instead,
we contribute to this literature by investigating the implications of agglomeration differ-
ences across agglomeration types. In particular, we argue that differences in the nature
of externalities bears upon fundamental issues such as the geographic area spatial
concentrations occupy, the complexity and variety of agglomeration membership, the
size and scope of the externalities available to firms, and the degree of competition, as a
few examples. Prior efforts have not thoroughly investigated the differences across types
of agglomerations.
Second, while a number of important perspectives have illuminated the important
link between geography and firm location and performance, including organizational
ecology (e.g. Baum and Haveman, 1997; Baum and Mezias, 1992), international busi-
ness (e.g. Cantwell and Iammarino, 2001; Head et al., 1995), strategic management (e.g.
Porter, 1998b; Sorenson and Baum, 2003), and entrepreneurship (e.g. Cooper and Folta,
2000; Stuart and Sorenson, 2003) among others, we draw from Marshall’s (1920) earlier
work that has emphasized the difference between supply-side versus demand-side
agglomeration. While Marshall crafted this simple typology, he failed to develop the
implications inherent in many of the issues identified above. Our emphasis on Marshall’s
work is appropriate given that much of the prior management literature (e.g. Porter,
1998a; Pouder and St. John, 1996; Saxenian, 1994) focuses on geographical concentra-
tions of related firms whose co-location generates positive externalities (‘Marshallian
externalities’), and this research stream has popularized the term ‘cluster’ to refer to this
phenomenon. This literature, however, fails to fully appreciate a key distinction that
appeared in Marshall’s work. Marshall was careful to elaborate on how different mecha-
nisms might explain different types of geographic agglomerations of firms, and his work
can be used to clarify why agglomeration exists for today’s biotechnology firms versus
automobile dealers. Yet, management research does not frequently distinguish between
these types of agglomerations and their underlying causes. Instead, it recognizes agglom-
erations in a wide range of industries under the ‘cluster’ label, including semiconductors
(Almeida and Kogut, 1999), biotechnology (Prevezer, 1997), hotels (Canina et al., 2005)
and restaurants, car dealers, and antique shops (Porter, 2000). Tying our arguments to
the distinct causal mechanisms first outlined by Marshall (1920) that drive spatial con-
centration, we question whether every agglomeration of related firms is the result of
similar agglomeration externalities such that they should be considered identical
phenomena. In particular, we argue that a fundamental distinction exists between
PRIOR LITERATURE
A pursuit towards explaining the spatial concentration of economic activity has a long
tradition of scholarly work (e.g. Hotelling, 1929; Marshall, 1920). Our argument to
distinguish between two specific types of agglomeration fits well within a stream of
research that has already established a number of important distinctions. We first review
the clear distinctions that already exist in the literature and then highlight the area in
which we think further work is necessary, namely the difference between supply- versus
demand-related agglomerations of related firms.
Primary sources of • Specialized labour, specialized inputs, • Heightened demand flowing from
agglomeration and knowledge spillovers reduced consumer search costs
benefits
Industries that form • Most likely found in industries that are • Most likely found in retail and
SSAs and DSAs knowledge-intensive and require high consumer services industries
innovation rates (e.g. biotechnology) • Industries should be characterized by
• May have a common technology core heterogeneous products that require
but span across a number of industries visual inspection by the consumer
Composition • Focal firms, suppliers, and supporting • Primarily horizontally related firms
institutions (universities, VCs, • Focal firms
consultants, etc) – both horizontally and • Perhaps firms offering complementary
vertically related firms goods
• Related industry firms, producers of
complementary products, and primary
customer groups
Relationship • High • Low
complexity • Large number of both vertical and • Realizing agglomeration benefits does
horizontal relationships between not require any intra-DSA relationships
members to exist
• Knowledge flows across these • Where evidence of inter-firm
relationships, a relatively complex relationships does exist, relationships
process tend to involve exchange of explicit
• Knowledge that flows is often tacit information
Geographic • No requirement of immediate physical • To deliver reduced search costs to
space adjacency to realize benefits consumers, firms must locate within a
• Can extend over a fairly wide reasonable distance of each other
geographic range • Thus, groupings should be tighter
Source of • Congestion costs and rising input prices • Congestion costs and rising input prices
diseconomies less likely to develop as quickly more likely to develop quickly
• Adverse selection concerns may be • Adverse selection concerns not balanced
balanced by ‘better’ firms benefiting by ‘better’ firms benefiting more
more • Increased localized competition is a
• Increased localized competition less of a major concern
concern
Life cycle • Should take longer to initially develop • Benefits are relatively simple and should
• Establishing complex relationships takes not take long to establish (although it is
time not clear how many firms do you need
• Likely to take longer to reach to make a DSA)
diseconomy stage • Likely to reach diseconomy stage more
• Overall, life cycle might thus be longer quickly
• Overall, life cycle might thus be shorter
Temporal changes • Growing • Waning
in value • As successful competition continues to • Falling transportation costs and
become more dependent on knowledge increased information availability make
and innovation, cluster value should it less costly to gather information about
continue to increase heterogeneous products
Industrial composition of agglomerated firms. The first dimension we consider is the composition
of firms in the agglomeration. Specifically, we consider whether supply- and demand-
side agglomerations might differ with regard to industrial diversity within the agglom-
eration, from both a horizontal and vertical perspective. We consider SSAs and DSAs,
respectively.
1. SSA composition. Given that one of the key agglomeration economies in clustering is
access to specialized inputs, it is unsurprising that clusters should require the presence of
suppliers to generate those benefits. Nearby suppliers can also contribute to knowledge
spillovers. Specialized labour will be further attracted to the area by the presence of
suppliers and companies in related industries who are likely to require skill sets at least
somewhat similar to those required by the focal firms. One key type of specialized labour
often present in technology-related clusters may be ‘star scientists’. Both Audretsch and
Stephan (1996) and Zucker et al. (1998) found evidence that the location of new biotech
firms was associated with the presence of prominent scientists in the area. Supporting
institutions provide specialized inputs as well, including technical, financial, and strategic
advice. For example, Feller (1997) described the role of the Advanced Research Program
in Texas, which helped develop a high-technology cluster around the city of Austin. Folta
et al. (2006) described a variety of institutions that support biotechnology clusters.
Overall, clusters consist of both firms in a focal industry and a variety of suppliers of
related products, services, and infrastructure.
To the extent that knowledge spillovers and specialized labour/inputs are not
industry-specific, we should expect clusters to include not just firms in the focal industry
but also those in vertically-related industries that might be involved in the industry’s
vertical scope of activities. This view is consistent with Maskell (2001), who argues that
clustered firms draw advantages from both the vertical and horizontal dimensions of the
cluster. To the extent that the supporting institutions are also engaged in horizontally-
related industries, it is possible that clusters might be quite industrially diverse.
2. DSA composition. In contrast to clusters, DSAs generate agglomeration economies by
reducing consumer search costs, and all that is required for a reduction in these search
costs is a grouping of similar firms from which customers can choose. Neither suppliers
of specialized inputs nor supporting institutions must be present, as they bear no rela-
tionship to the reduction of search costs. Canina et al. (2005, p. 567) describe demand-
side agglomerations purely as the ‘result of firm heterogeneity that attracts more
consumers to an area simply because the area has a wider variety of firms from which to
choose’. This fact is even clearer to see when we consider one example. Fischer and
Harrington (1996) observe that shoe stores tend to co-locate in the Baltimore area. They
speculated that women’s shoes, in particular, were characterized by a lack of standard-
ized products, making price comparisons meaningless without visual inspection, thereby
Connections among agglomerated firms. The second dimension we consider is the connections
among firms in the agglomeration. Specifically, we consider whether SSAs and DSAs
might differ with regards to the intensity of interaction and the nature of knowledge that may be
conveyed across agglomerated firms.
1. SSA relationships. We begin by acknowledging that not all scholars agree on the
necessity of knowledge spillovers as an explanation for supply-side agglomerations. For
example, Krugman (1991a, p. 497) offers a formal model to explain agglomeration and
notes that ‘What is particularly nice about this result is that it requires no appeal to
elusive concepts such as pure technological externalities’. Krugman (1991b) further
argues that many highly localized industries (carpets in Dalton, Georgia or jewellery
producers in Providence, Rhode Island) are not characterized by high levels of knowl-
edge or technology. Yet, even in non-knowledge-based explanations for SSAs, intercon-
nections between firms play a key role. Focal firms access specialized inputs from their
relationships with supporting institutions and suppliers. As Krugman (1991b, p. 51)
notes, ‘there will be both backward and forward linkages that provide an incentive to
concentrate production’.
We cannot deny, however, the omnipresence of the role of knowledge spillovers in
research on supply-side agglomerations. Empirical evidence indicates that geographic
proximity does enhance knowledge spillovers. Jaffe et al. (1993) provide evidence con-
sistent with localization of knowledge spillovers by examining patent citation data. They
found that citations were five to ten times as likely to come from the same metropolitan
area as control patents. Audretsch and Feldman (1996) showed that knowledge-
dependent industries tend to be more spatially concentrated. Rosenthal and Strange
(2001) noted evidence suggesting that knowledge spillovers contribute to agglomeration
at the local level using a broad sample of 459 manufacturing industries. Rosenkopf and
Almeida (2003) also found evidence supporting geographic localization of knowledge
using patent citation data from the semiconductor industry. Finally, Sammarra and
Biggiero (2008) found that firms within Rome’s aerospace industrial cluster shared
technological, market, and managerial knowledge through innovation networks.
Geographic proximity facilitates the transfer of tacit knowledge across firms. In con-
trast, spatial concentration provides little advantage for the sharing of explicit knowledge,
Supporting
Institution
Supplier Supplier
Related Related
Industry Industry
Firm Firm
Firm Firm
(Industry A) (Industry A)
Supporting Supporting
Institution Institution
Firm Firm
Pool of Specialized Labour (Industry A) (Industry A)
Related Related
Industry Industry
Firm Firm
Supporting
Supplier Institution Supplier
Complement Complement
Firm Firm
Firm Firm
(Industry A) (Industry A)
Complement Complement
Firm Firm
Diseconomies of agglomeration. Some recent work (Pouder and St. John, 1996; Prevezer,
1997; Shaver and Flyer, 2000) has begun to note the potential for diseconomies of
agglomeration, particularly in later stages of a cluster’s evolution as the cluster grows
larger. While economies of agglomeration suggest increased benefits to members with
each additional firm, diseconomies of agglomeration suggest decreased benefits to
members with each additional firm. Folta et al. (2006) provide some support for the
presence of diseconomies in biotechnology clusters, finding that beyond a certain size
inflection point, the rate of patenting actually declined with each additional firm in a
cluster. We focus on four potential sources of diseconomy – congestion costs, input
prices, adverse selection, and local competition – and for each we provide a brief
explanation and analyse the relevance of the factor in each type of agglomeration.
1. Congestion costs. As areas draw more organizations, density increases, leading to what
some authors have labelled congestion costs (Prevezer, 1997). Congestion costs are a
function of the number of firms agglomerating within a region and the carrying capacity
of the area. The specific congestion costs with which we are concerned are those related
to increased traffic and transportation costs, making it difficult for employees and
customers to navigate within a region.
Such costs are consequential in SSAs because they may affect quality of life of
employees and potential employees by raising commute times, potentially lowering the
region’s ability to attract labour. They may also discourage the personal interaction
necessary to actualize knowledge spillovers. Congestion costs are relevant in demand-
side agglomerations because they have a direct effect on one of the key externalities
associated with agglomeration – it negatively influences customers trying to reduce
search costs. As search times and costs increase, shopping within the DSA becomes less
attractive to consumers, reducing the demand-heightening benefits of agglomeration.
Of course, some, if not most, of these costs may be due to urbanization and would
have occurred regardless of whether the agglomeration developed and prospered.
Accordingly, it is important to distinguish between the absolute level of congestion costs
and the marginal level of congestion costs attributable to agglomeration. The former will
be tied to the density of people and all economic activity in the region. The latter will
be tied to the marginal increase in density and economic activity in the region attrib-
utable to the agglomeration. In practice, it is difficult to calculate marginal congestion
costs. Nevertheless, we conceptually focus on marginal congestion costs and believe
they are likely to more rapidly develop in demand-side agglomerations than in supply-
side agglomerations.
The life cycles of SSAs and DSAs. The life cycle of an agglomeration is related to at least two
factors: how quickly the benefits are realized initially and how fast diseconomies start to
affect the agglomerating firms. We believe that SSAs should take longer (i.e. require
more firms) to initially develop, primarily due to the more complex nature of clusters.
Benefits flow from a complex web of inter-relationships among focal firms, related firms,
suppliers, customers, and supporting institutions. Such a web will take time to develop.
We have also argued above that clusters are generally less prone to rapid development
of diseconomies.
In contrast to clusters, we expect that DSA benefits will materialize rather quickly. No
complex web of relationships must form – all that is needed is a grouping of firms that
consumers recognize and patronize. Diseconomy forces, however, likely affect DSAs
more quickly than they do SSAs.
The above discussion addresses how the value of SSAs and DSAs differs as they grow
larger and as they age. This discussion treats time in a relative sense in that age is
measured relative to the start of the agglomeration. But, we also believe that agglom-
eration benefits will change over time when time is viewed in more of an absolute sense.
We next ask the question of how the value of SSAs and DSAs has changed over the past
say 30 years and how it might continue to change in the future.
Temporal changes in the value of SSAs and DSAs. We finally consider how the value of locating
within a supply- or demand-side agglomeration relative to locating in isolation may
change over time. We offer several factors related to technological advancement that
imply increasing value for SSAs (relative to isolation) over time and decreasing value for
DSAs.
With the increasing influence of technology on the ability to conduct business over
distances, a natural first inclination might be to believe that SSAs have become less
important over time. Falling physical and information transport costs related to techno-
logical advance may have diminished locational influences on competition; however, a
host of new influences increase the importance of cluster-based benefits in the increas-
ingly global and knowledge-based competitive environment.
In regard to the issue of specialized labour, Krugman (1996, p. 195) notes that ‘it
seems undeniable that over the past 20 years the advanced nations have experienced
technological change that is strongly biased in favor of skilled workers’. This bias is driven
not by a change in what goods and services are being produced but rather a change in
SSAs DSAs
What type of firms might benefit • Firms least able to attract • Firms least able to attract
most from agglomeration? specialized labour and input demand on their own
• Firms least able to internally
generate knowledge
What types of firms might • Large firms because they • Large firms because they attract
generate larger externalities? provide greater attraction for greater numbers of customers
labour and input providers? • Upscale firms because they
• Small firms because they are signal positive aspects of
more open and innovative agglomeration (e.g. safety of a
generating larger knowledge hotel location)
spillovers? • Other attributes that contribute
to higher demand spillovers
What is the form of the • Non-linear relationships likely • Non-linear relationships likely
agglomeration–performance • Positive externalities may • Positive externalities may
relationship? require greater time to develop develop fairly quickly
• Diseconomies may not develop • Diseconomies may develop
until SSAs become particularly earlier
large or dense
What complementary theories • Network theory • Transaction costs
might help further understand • Knowledge-based view • Industrial organization
agglomeration? • Others focused on social • Others focused on efficiency
interaction
SSAs DSAs
Heterogeneity may also exist in how much individual firms contribute to agglomera-
tion externalities, and again we believe that the distinct causal mechanisms play a role.
In DSAs, it appears that large firms and upscale firms contribute more (Canina et al.,
2005; Chung and Kalnins, 2001), perhaps due to their greater demand-generating
abilities. In SSAs, it is less clear who the differential contributors are. Shaver and Flyer
(2000) suggest that large firms may contribute more due to their higher ability to attract
Measuring the benefits of agglomeration. With the diverse sources of agglomeration externali-
ties, what constitutes an appropriate dependent variable is directly impacted by the type
of agglomeration being studied. With benefits flowing from access to specialized labour,
Conclusion
A large body of research has developed in an attempt to explain the role geographic
location plays in economic performance. We have argued that our quest to more fully
understand this relationship will continue to be retarded without a clear distinction
between fundamentally different types of agglomerations. Although they share a
common heritage, the phenomena of demand-based and supply-based agglomeration
are quite different.
Answers to fundamental questions in the agglomeration research stream differ across
SSAs and DSAs. Different types and densities of firms compose SSAs and DSAs, and
they are found in different industries. Moreover, they have dissimilar geographic bound-
aries and disparate levels of relationship complexity. In addition to trait-based distinc-
tions, we have also argued that how benefits are realized fundamentally differs between
supply- and demand-side agglomerations. Sources of diseconomies vary, and we have
speculated that the gains from SSAs are likely to have grown over time while the gains
of DSAs have likely fallen. Finally, we expect that the life cycles of the two types of
agglomeration are different.
Engaging in a rigorous comparison also allows us to offer insights into open research
questions regarding clusters. In particular, this paper responds to the call of authors like
Audretsch (2003, p. 44), who notes that ‘another important but relatively unchartered
area for future research involves the life cycle of spatial units’, and Folta et al. (2006, p.
240), who argue that ‘more work is needed to examine older industries and the possibility
that diseconomies of agglomeration dominate at a certain point’. Our comparisons also
help bring greater clarity to the definition of clusters, a topic of continuing debate
(Martin and Sunley, 2003).
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
We are grateful for the extensive comments received from General Editor Mike Wright and three anony-
mous reviewers. We also thank Stephen Tallman for his comments and suggestions on an earlier draft.
NOTES
[1] For review of this literature, see Fujita et al. (1999) and Fujita and Thisse (2002).
[2] Agglomeration researchers typically view relatedness in one of two ways. Relatedness may be defined
to encompass situations in which co-locating firms share an underlying technology or product focus not
constrained to a particular industry. For example, Porter (1998b) cites the example of over 400
Massachusetts’ companies focused on medical device products whose industries vary from electronic
equipment to plastic products as an example of a product-focused agglomeration. Relatedness is often
more narrowly viewed as firms within a particular industry (firms which produce goods that are at least
close substitutes) who co-locate. Much of the literature in this area involves studies of spatial concen-
trations within individual industries.
[3] For a detailed review of this literature, see McCann and Folta (2008).
[4] We also note that a colleague who has published extensively on supply-related agglomerations shared
with us that he often receives reviewer comments asking him to inform his work with studies of
demand-related agglomerations.
[5] Typologies are based on conceptual constructions while taxonomies consist of empirical entities that may
be classified into exhaustive and mutually exclusive categories based on observable and measurable
characteristics (Bailey, 1994).
[6] We thank an anonymous reviewer for encouraging us to more carefully consider the potential for
demand-related externalities in business service clusters.
[7] The four types of agglomerations are: (i) ‘Marshallian new industrial district’ made up of a number of
small but similarly-sized firms who exhibit levels of regional cooperation; (ii) ‘hub-and-spoke district’,
in which the regional structure revolves around one or several major corporations in one or a few
industries; (iii) ‘satellite industrial platform’, which is an area composed chiefly of branch plants of
absent multinational corporations; and (iv) ‘state-centred district’ in which a major government tenant
anchors the regional economy (like a state capital, key military or research facility, etc). We would argue
that the first and third are examples of agglomerations that include supply-side externalities; in the
hub-and-spoke district, the hub firms may generate supply-side externalities while the location deci-
sions of the firms along the spokes involve a source of benefits (a major customer) that is not increasing
with the number of spoke firms; the state-centred district also appears to be driven by an exogenous
benefit source of a major customer.
[8] We do note, however, that some scholars do not believe connections among firms within a cluster are
necessary for those firms to benefit from the enhanced knowledge generated within a cluster. Maskell
(2001) argues that firms can accrue knowledge benefits even in the absence of interactions among
related firms. The benefits flow from increased variation of product solutions created by clustered firms,
which competitors capitalize on through simple monitoring of those firms.
[9] Ingram and Roberts (2000) also found evidence of friendships among managers of high-end hotels in
Sydney, Australia. They further speculate that the association between friendships and performance
that they discover may be related to these referral practices.
[10] Kalnins (2006) notes that the relatively fixed capacity of hotels (at least in the short to medium term)
helps facilitate networks and ties between owner/managers of hotels. This industry-specific condition
may help explain why we might not see these relationships in other DSA industries.
REFERENCES
Almeida, P. and Kogut, B. (1997). ‘The exploration of technological diversity and the geographic localiza-
tion of innovation’. Small Business Economics, 9, 21–31.
Almeida, P. and Kogut, B. (1999). ‘Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in regional
networks’. Management Science, 45, 905–17.
Arthur, W. (1990). ‘Silicon Valley locational clusters: when do increasing returns imply monopoly?’. Math-
ematical Social Sciences, 19, 235–73.
Audretsch, D. B. (2003). ‘Managing knowledge spillovers: the role of geographic proximity’. In Baum,
J. A. C. and Sorenson, O. (Eds), Geography and Strategy: Advances in Strategic Management. Oxford: JAI Press,
20, 23–48.
Audretsch, D. B. and Feldman, M. P. (1996). ‘R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and
production’. American Economic Review, 86, 630–40.
Audretsch, D. B. and Keilbach, M. (2007). ‘The theory of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship’. Journal of
Management Studies, 44, 1242–54.
Audretsch, D. B. and Stephan, P. E. (1996). ‘Company-scientist locational links: the case of biotechnology’.
American Economic Review, 86, 641–52.
Bailey, K. D. (1994). Typologies and Taxonomies: An Introduction to Classification Techniques. Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage.
Baum, J. A. C. and Haveman, H. A. (1997). ‘Love thy neighbor? Differentiation and agglomeration in the
Manhattan hotel industry, 1898–1990’. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 304–38.
Baum, J. A. C. and Mezias, S. J. (1992). ‘Localized competition and organizational failure in the Manhattan
hotel industry, 1898–1990’. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 580–604.
Baum, J. A. C. and Singh, J. V. (1994). ‘Organizational niches and the dynamics of organizational mortality’.
American Journal of Sociology, 100, 346–80.
Brown, S. (1989). ‘Retail location theory – the legacy of Hotelling, Harold’. Journal of Retailing, 65, 450–70.
Canina, L., Enz, C. A. and Harrison, J. S. (2005). ‘Agglomeration effects and strategic orientations: evidence
from the US lodging industry’. Academy of Management Journal, 48, 565–81.
Cantwell, J. A. and Iammarino, S. (2001). ‘EU regions and multinational corporations: change, stability and
strengthening of technological comparative advantage’. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10, 1007–37.
Chen, T. J. (2003). ‘Network resources for internationalization: the case of Taiwan’s electronics firms’.
Journal of Management Studies, 40, 1107–30.
Chung, W. and Kalnins, A. (2001). ‘Agglomeration effects and performance: a test of the Texas lodging
industry’. Strategic Management Journal, 22, 969–88.