Block-3 Imperfect Part 2
Block-3 Imperfect Part 2
Competition
Block 3
Imperfect Competition-II
Oligopoly
UNIT 5 OLIGOPOLY
Structure
5.0 Objectives
5.1 Introduction
5.2 Oligopoly
5.2.1 Equilibrium in an Oligopolistic Market
5.3 The Cournot Model
5.3.1 Equilibrium using Residual Demand Curve
5.3.2 Equilibrium using Reaction Curves
5.3.3 Cournot Equilibrium with Different Costs
5.4 Collusion and Cartels
5.5 The Bertrand Model
5.5.1 Bertrand Paradox
5.5.1.1 Condition to be satisfied for the Bertrand Paradox
5.5.2 Bertrand Equilibrium using Reaction Curves
5.5.3 Comparison between the Cournot and the Bertrand Model
5.6 The Stackelberg Model
5.7 The Dominant Firm Model
5.8 Let Us Sum Up
5.9 Some Useful References
5.10 Hints or Answers to Check Your Progress Exercises
5.0 OBJECTIVES
After reading and studying the unit, you should be able to:
Imperfect
Competition-II 5.1 INTRODUCTION
We have so far considered three different market structures, viz. Perfect
competition, Monopoly and Monopolistic competition. Perfect competition
and monopoly are the two extreme forms of market structures. In a perfect
competitive market, there is free entry and exit, many buyers and sellers,
perfect information, etc. Such an idealised market does not exist in reality.
Moreover, except for some natural monopolies, one hardly finds any
example of a monopolistic market structure. A step closer to the reality is
the monopolistic competition market structure which assumes no barriers
to entry and non-price competition (in the form of product differentiation)
between firms. But firms under monopolistic competition are naïve and
therefore do not involve in strategic interactions. This makes the market
structure under monopolistic competition rarely experienced in reality. The
present unit is a move towards a relatively more realistic market structure.
Most markets are better described as oligopolies. These are markets where
there exist more than one market player, yet where each firm is large
enough to enjoy some monopoly power. There are barriers to entry which
result in a market with a small number of dominant players dependent
strategically on each other’s decisions about output or price. The prominent
example of an oligopolistic market structure is that of soft drink suppliers,
Pepsi and Coca-cola. For instance, if price of Pepsi is lowered to attract more
sales, it will necessarily attract a reaction from Coca-cola suppliers whose
customers will get lured away by the lower Pepsi price. Unless Coca-cola is
willing to bear the revenue loss (which is unlikely to happen), it will find
itself obligated to respond to Pepsi’s price cut, which in turn would affect
Pepsi sales. Considering rival’s reaction thus becomes significantly important
in such a market condition. How do firms behave in an oligopolistic market
is what will be covered in this unit.
5.2 OLIGOPOLY
In oligopoly market structure a few firms account for most or all of the total
production. Barriers to entry and exit result in prevalence of a small number
of dominant players that remain strategically dependent on each other. By
strategically dependence it is meant, a firm while taking its optimising
decisions must consider the expected reaction of its rival. This is because,
output and/or price decision by one impacts output sales and hence the
revenue earnings of the other players in the market. Like in perfect
competition firms in oligopoly cannot take market price as it comes, neither
do they have the price-setting power like that with a monopolist who can
set the price and worry about no prospective retaliation. In oligopoly, firms
possess certain degree of price-setting power (or the monopoly power, i.e.,
the rate at which it can set the price above its marginal cost) depending on
their market structure, as they have to worry about retaliation from
competitors. Any action by a firm in oligopolistic market is followed by a
counter reaction from other firms in that market. This compels each firm to Oligopoly
consider its rivals’ expected reactions as it decides about output and pricing.
It follows that accurately portraying the interactions between firms across a
wide range of possibilities is the critical task of any model of oligopoly.
There are two different ways in which firms might interact with each other
in an oligopolistic market structure. They may cooperate or choose not to
cooperate. If they collude, that is, choose to cooperate with each other so as
to maximise their joint profits, they form a cartel. For example, the
Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) is a cartel of oil
producing countries that cooperate in how much oil to produce in an
attempt to move the price of oil up or down in the market. On the other
hand, if they behave non-cooperatively, acting in their own self-interest,
they take into account the actions of other firms. Examples of a non-
collusive oligopoly model include— the Cournot model, the Bertrand model,
the Stackelberg model and the Dominant firm model. We will be covering
these models in the present Unit.
Imperfect Where C(Qi) is the cost function faced by firm i. First-order condition for
Competition-II
profit maximisation for any of the firm ݅ሺ݅ ൌ ͳǡ ʹሻ involves differentiating
the profit function with respect to ܳ and put it equal to 0.
߲ߨ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ߲ܦ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ߲ܳ
ฺ ൌ Ͳ ֜ ܳ ܦ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ െ ܥൌ Ͳ
߲ܳ ߲ܳ ߲ܳ
డ ሺொభ ǡொమ ሻ డொ
ฺ ܳ ܲ െ ܥൌ Ͳ
డொ డொ
Multiplying and dividing the first term on the LHS with Q×P, we get
డ ሺொభ ǡொమ ሻ ொ ொ
ฺ ቂ ቀ ቁ ܲ െ ܥቃ ൌ Ͳ
డொ ொ
డொ
ሾ డொ ൌ ͳሿ
Taking first term of the LHS on the RHS and dividing both the sides by P
ܲെܥ ߲ܦ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ܳ ܲܳ ͳ
ฺ ൌ ቆെ ቇ൬ ൰
ܲ ߲ܳ ܲ ܳ ܲ
ି ଵ
ฺ ൌെ ݏ
ఌ
are first obtained separately for each firm, and then solved simultaneously
to obtain Nash equilibrium. The market price is then determined using the
total output of both firms.
P = A – BQ
P = A – B(Q1 + Q2)
P =[A – BQ2] – BQ1
where [A – BQ2] represent the price intercept of the residual demand curve
facing the first firm. The MR curve will be given by first finding the total
revenue (TR) function of the first firm, which equals quantity × price, that is,
A – BQ2– 2BQ1 = 0
Now, we solve for profit maximising level of Q1 (let it be denoted by Q1*)
from the above equation, which we get as a function of given quantity of Q2
(also known as the reaction curve for firm 1):
ଵ
Q1*= െ ܳଶ
ଶ ଶ
Imperfect
Competition-II
D Q1 = 0
Price
A
A – bQ2
DZ1 E D’
0 Quantity
Y1* =
െ ࡽ
Y2 Y1
Fig. 5.1 : Equilibrium under Cournot Model using Residual Demand Curves
where, R1 (Q2) represents the reaction function of firm 1 which gives the
optimal amount of output supplied by firm 1 as a function of given quantity
supplied by firm 2 (Q2). Similarly, the reaction curve equation for firm 2 will
be given by,
ଵ
R2 (Q1): MR2 = MC ֜Q2 = ଶ െ ଶ ܳଵ (3)
To note here is that if both demand and cost functions are linear, reaction
function will be linear as well. In Fig. 5.2, we plot these reaction functions by
marking output supplied by firm 1 and firm 2 on the vertical and the
horizontal axis, respectively. Reaction curve of firm 1, given by Equation (2)
has the vertical intercept given by Q1 = ଶ when Q2 = 0, and horizontal
intercept given by Q2 =
when Q1 = 0. Similarly, we plot reaction curve of
firm 2.
Q1 Oligopoly
Y1* =
O Q2
Y2* =
Now, equilibrium output for firm 1 and firm 2 will be given by the
intersection point of the two reaction curves. This is also called “Cournot-
Nash Equilibrium”, as each firm is doing the best it can given the behaviour
of rival firms. This can be ascertained by substituting reaction curve for Firm
2 into the reaction curve for firm 1:
ଵ ଵ
Q1 = ଶ െ ଶ ቂଶ െ ଶ ଵ ቃ
ଵ
Q1 = ଶ െ ସ ସ ܳଵ ֜ Q1*= ଷ
If firm act as a monopoly, then the optimising output will be given by setting
MR = MC:
Hence, we find that Cournot duopoly model has a higher total quantity and
a lower price as compared to Monopoly quantity and price, respectively.
Moreover firms under the Cournot competition earns less profit (even at the
మ మ మ ଶమ
industry level) as compared to the monopolyฺ ସ ଽ and ସ ଽ
.
Example
Where Q is total production of both firms (i.e., Q = QІ н QЇͿ͘ ůƐŽ ůĞƚ ƚŚĞ
marginal cost of production faced by both firms be Rs. 40, i.e.͕DІсDЇс
40. Calculate the residual demand function for both the firms. Using them
ascertain their reaction curves and the Cournot-Nash equilibrium quantity
produced by each firm?
Solution
We will first be finding the inverse demand function from the given demand
ଵ
function. Given, Q = ଶ (100 – P), the inverse demand function would be
డ்ோభ
TR1: P × Q1= 100Q1–2Q2Q1 – 2Q12 ; MR1: డொభ
= 100–2Q2– 4Q1
P =[100–2Q1] – 2Q2
ଵ
And the corresponding reaction curve for firm 2 will be: Q2 = 15 – ଶ Q1
equilibrium price, P* = 60
Profit by firm 1 = Profit by firm 2 = Total Revenue – Total Cost
Let us compare this result with the monopoly outcome. For the monopolist,
the aggregate inverse demand curve will be P = 100 – 2Q.
Hence, we find that Cournot duopoly model has a higher total quantity (=
20) and a lower price (= 60) as compared to Monopoly quantity (= 15) and
price (= 70), respectively. Also the total industry profit in case of Cournot
model (= 400) is less than that of a monopolistic industry profit (= 450).
Considering the demand function PсϱϬоϮQ. Let the marginal cost faced by
firm 1 be Rs. 2, and that faced by firm 2 be Rs. 8. Find the Cournot-Nash
equilibrium in such a case.
We make use of the optimising condition to find the reaction curves for
each of the firms.
డ்ோభ
TR1: P × Q1= 50Q1–2Q2Q1 – 2Q12 ; MR1: డொభ
= 50–2Q2– 4Q1
1) Consider a Cournot duopoly of firm 1 and 2 producing output Q1 and Q2,
respectively. Let market demand curve be P = 60 – Q, where Q = Q1 +
Q2. Assume marginal cost of production is null for both the firms.
Calculate Cournot-Nash equilibrium output of both the firms.
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
2) Let market demand curve be P = a – bQ, where Q = Q1 + Q2. Let there be
two firms 1 and 2 producing output Q1 and Q2, respectively at a
constant marginal cost of ‘c’. Calculate output of both the firms under
the Cournot model.
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
(we know from our earlier section) the equilibrium outputs of each firm:
QІсQЇсଷ
If the two firms collude and form a cartel, then total Revenue of the cartel
will be given by:
డ்ோ
TR = (A – BQ) Q = AQ – BQ² ; Marginal Revenue (MR): డொ
= A – 2BQ
For cartel equilibrium, the two firms jointly behave like a monopolist and
jointly control the entire market share. So from the equilibrium condition:
MR = MC ֜A –2BQ = 0 ֜ Q* = ଶ
(same as the monopoly solution).
Therefore total equilibrium quantity is Q = ଶ
. Using the demand function,
we get the equilibrium price as P = ଶ .
The goal of the cartel is to set the industry output at a level that maximises
industry profits. A rule governing the cartel behaviour specifies how the
industry output and profits must be shared among the cartel members. In
our example, we assume the two firms are producing homogeneous goods
and are sharing similar cost structure which enabled the firms to equally
share the industry output and thus profits, which means QІсQЇсସ. This is
less than the Cournot equilibrium output of ଷ units produced by each firm.
By independently maximising their own profits, firms produce more total
output than they would if they collusively maximised industry profits. This
pursuit of self interest does not typically maximise the well being of the
industry as well as their individual profits. In terms of our numerical
example, we saw that the total industry output of the duopoly was higher
than that of the monopolistic industry, but total industry profit of
monopolistic industry (Cartel) was higher as compared to the duopoly.
Let us assume a Bertrand model of duopoly where there are two firms, 1
and 2, producing homogenous product at a constant marginal cost “C”. The
ĨŝƌŵƐ ĐŚŽŽƐĞƉƌŝĐĞƐ WІ ĂŶĚ WЇ͕ ƐŝŵƵůƚĂŶĞŽƵƐůLJ͘ ůů ƐĂůĞƐ ŐŽ ƚŽƚŚĞĨŝƌŵ ǁŝƚŚ
the lowest price. Sales are split equally if PІ = PЇ͘/ŶĐŽŶƚƌĂƐƚƚŽƚŚĞŽƵƌŶŽƚ
or Stackelberg models, the only Nash Equilibrium is the perfectly
competitive outcome i.e., PІ = PЇ = C. This results from the fact that each
firm in the Bertrand model has an incentive to undercut price as long as
production remains profitable. If one firm cut its price than the rival’s price,
then even for a slightest undercutting, it can appropriate the entire market
share, thereby, inducing the rival out of the market. Similarly, the same firm
may face zero market share if its rival outcompetes it by a slightest
undercutting of their price. Given that each firm has an incentive to
undercut its price in order to grab the market share, the firms would engage
in reciprocal price undercutting until the price gets pushed down to the level
of marginal cost “C”. At this price, economic profits would be zero. Hence
firms would have no incentive to undercut its price further. This would be
Nash equilibrium as there would be no incentive for either firm to change its
price once ଵ ൌ ଶ ൌ . If either firm lowers their price below marginal cost,
they would incur losses. If either raised their price, then it would be no
better off, because it would lose the entire market share to the rival. Thus,
quantity sold by each firm depends on both prices. If P1< P2, then firm 1
serves the entire market demand D(P1); the opposite happens, that is, firm 2
serving the entire market demand D(P2) when P1> P2; and when P1 = P2¸ each
ሺሻ
firm supplies half of the total market demand, that is, . If ܲଵ ൌ ܲଶ
ଶ
ܥǡeven though the firms share the market equally, it is not an equilibrium
strategy. In this case either of the firm has an incentive to undercut the price
and grab the entire market and still enjoy positive profit.
Oligopoly
5.5.1 Bertrand Paradox
The unique pair of prices satisfying condition 5.1 is given by P1 = P2 = C (the
given constant marginal cost) at which ȫଵ = ȫଶ = 0. This situation is referred
to as the condition of Bertrand Paradox. The paradox results from the fact
that just two firms are sufficient to dissipate the market power and yield an
outcome similar to the perfectly competitive market (which usually assumes
many sellers). In other words, with the number of firms rising from one to
two, the price decreases from the monopoly price to the competitive price
and stays at the same level even when the number of firms increases
further. This is contrary to our perception, where we think that markets with
a small number of firms possessing market power typically charge a price
above the marginal cost.
PM R1(P2)
A
C
O PM P2
C
Fig. 5.3: Bertrand Equilibrium using Reaction Curves
In the above figure, firm 1’s reaction function R1(P2) shows when firm 2’s
price is below the marginal cost, i.e., when P2< C, it is optimal for firm 1 to
set its price at the marginal cost, i.e., P1 = C as shown by the horizontal
segment CA of the firm 1’s reaction curve R1(P2). The 45ιline represents
prices where P1 = P2. PM represent the monopoly prices charged for the
good when both the firms collude and act as a monopolist. Now, again look
at the reaction curve of firm 1. When firm 2’s price is above the marginal
cost (C) but below the monopoly price (PM), then it is optimal for firm 1 to
set price just below firm 2, i.e. P1< P2. Whereas, when firm 2’s price is above
the monopoly price, it is optimal for firm 1 to charge the monopoly price, i.e.
P1 = PM. With both facing the same marginal cost (C), reaction function of
firm 2, R2 (P1) will be symmetrical with respect to the 45ι line. Symbolically,
we can represent a reaction function as follows:
ଶ
R1 (P2) = ൝ ଶ െ ɂ ൏ ଶ and
ଶ
ଵ
R2 (P1) = ൝ ଵ െ ɂ ൏ ଵ
ଵ
where, Ԫ represents a small positive number. Bertrand equilibrium is given
by the intersection of both the reaction curves at Point A, where P1 = P2 = C,
which is mutually best response for both the firms. At any other price above
the marginal cost, either firm would always find it is in their best interest to
undercut its rival’s price a little (say by Ԫ> 0) and serve the entire market
itself. It is only at the price equals to the marginal cost that firms have no
incentives to deviate from the equilibrium prices.
Oligopoly
5.5.3 Comparison between the Cournot and the Bertrand
Model
In the Cournot model, firms engage in quantity competition, so quantity is
the strategic variable of the firm whereas in the Bertrand model firms
engage in price competition, so price is the strategic variable. In the Cournot
model the equilibrium price is generally above the marginal cost and the
quantity approaches the perfectly competitive market situation only when
the number of firms becomes large. In contrast to this, in the Bertrand
model even with two firms, price competition dissipates the monopoly
power and ensures competitive price which is equal to the marginal cost.
Another difference is that in the Cournot model, the firms take their rival’s
output as given and cannot “steal” any consumers away from their rivals by
lowering their prices. Whereas, a Bertrand rival believes that it can lure
customers from its rivals by small cuts in price.
P = A – BQ [where, Q = QІнQЇ
'ŝǀĞŶŵĂƌŐŝŶĂůĐŽƐƚŝƐDІсDЇсϬ͘
Backward Induction: Consider period 2 first. Here, firm 2 will choose its
optimal output according to its own Reaction function i.e.
ଵ
ܴଶ ሺܳଵ ሻǣQ2 = ଶ െ ଶ ܳଵ (4)
So the first order condition for the optimisation of firm 1’s profit is obtained
by setting the first - order partial derivative with respect to QІĞƋƵĂůƚŽnjĞƌŽ͘
డஈభ ሺொభ ǡொమ ሻ ଶொభ
డொభ
= 0 ֜A – 2BQ1 – ଶ
ଶ
=0
Solving for optimal Q1, gives QІсଶ.
Now, substituting QІ ďĂĐŬ ŝŶ Ƌ͘ ;ϰͿ͕ ǁĞ ŐĞƚ ƚŚĞ ŽƉƚŝŵĂů ŽƵƚƉƵƚ ŽĨ Ĩŝƌŵ Ϯ͗ Oligopoly
Q2 = ସ. So the equilibrium output choice of firm 1 and 2 are:
[QІсଶ , Q2 = ସሿ.
ଷ
Equilibrium price under Stackelberg model : P = [A – B(Q1 + Q2Ϳсоସሿ= ସ
Profit of the follower (firm 2): ȫଶ (ܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ) = [A – B(Q1 + Q2)]ܳଶ ൌ о
ଷ మ
Bସሿ ସ ֜ ȫଶ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ൌ ସ ସ
ൌ ଵ ֜ ȫଵ(ܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ȫଶ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ֜ Thus
the leader enjoys higher market share and higher profit than the follower in
equilibrium.
Unlike the Cournot outcome which was symmetric, that is both the firms
produced the same level of output, in the Stackelberg model, leader firm
i.e., firm 1 enjoys greater market share (produces more output) as
compared to the follower i.e., ܳଵ ܳଶ in the equilibrium. One may
compare the Stackelberg equilibrium outcome with that of the Cournot
outcome and may check that the leader (firm 1) produces more than
produced by a firm in Cournot equilibrium whereas the follower produces
less than Cournot equilibrium quantity. Thus, there is an advantage of being
the first mover.
ଷ
Now, the total industry output will be Q1 + Q2 = ସ, which is more than the
ଶ
total industry output under Cournot equilibrium of ଷ
for a given value of A
and B. Profit of the Stackelberg leader is higher than the firm under Cournot
మ మ
competition ฺ ȫଵ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻௌ >ȫଵ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ฺ ଼ ଽ. Moreover profit of
the Stackelberg follower is lower than the firm under Cournot competition
మ మ
ฺ ȫଶ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻௌ ൏ ȫଶ ሺܳଵ ǡ ܳଶ ሻ ฺ ଵ ൏ ଽ. Industry profit under
Stackelberg model is greater than that of the Cournot competition
Price
SF
MC D
P1
P*
D
C
B
P2 A
DZD D’
O YD` YF YT Quantity
Fig. 5.4: Dominant Firm Model
In Fig. 5.4 DD’ curve represents the market demand which is served by the
dominant firm and the fringe firms collectively. Fringe firms are assumed to
behave as competitive firms supplying where their marginal cost equals the
price set by the dominant firm. This way fringe firms collectively behave as a
competitive industry whose output can be determined by the supply curve
SF. The dominant firm’s problem is to find a price which maximises its own
profits. To solve this problem we need demand curve of the dominant firm.
The extent of demand that the dominant firm gets to serve is equal to the
total quantity demanded at that price (given by DD’) minus the quantity the
fringe firms supply at that price (given by SF).This is represented by the
residual demand curve P1AD’. In other words, P1AD’ represents the
horizontal difference between the fringe firm’s supply curve SF and the
market demand curve DD’. At price P1, dominant firm produces nothing with
fringe firms serving the entire market demand at that price. On the other
hand, at a price as low as P2 dominant firm gets to serve the entire market
demand with supply by fringe firms falling to zero. The dominant firm’s
residual demand curve between these two extreme prices is given by P1A.
Corresponding to the residual demand curve of the dominant firm, we have
a marginal revenue curve represented by MRD. MCD likewise represents the
marginal cost curve of the dominant firm.
The dominant firm optimise at point B where marginal revenue equals
marginal cost resulting in profit maximising output QD sold at the market
price P*. At this price fringe firms will supply QF amount of output as will be
given by their supply curve. Total output at P* equals QT which is the sum of
QD and QF. Total output generated in this model will be less than
competitive output. This is clear by the figure above. Dominant firm
optimise at a point where its price is above the marginal cost it faces. An
efficient optimum in this case will be given by the point C where MCD
intersects the residual demand curve resulting in higher total output as is
given by the point D. In this case, not only fringe firms but also the dominant Oligopoly
firm is producing where MC equals price.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Explain the difference between the Bertrand model and the Stackelberg
model of Oligopoly.
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
2) For the following demand curve P = a – 2b and constant marginal cost
curve ‘c’, find equilibrium price, quantity and profit according to:
i) Stackelberg Model
……………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………
Structure
6.0 Objectives
6.1 Introduction
6.2 The Game Theory
6.3 A Game
6.4 Types of Games
6.4.1 Non-cooperative versus Cooperative Games
6.4.2 Games of Complete and Incomplete Information
6.4.3 Zero-sum Game versus Non-zero Sum Games
6.4.4 Simultaneous-move versus Sequential-move Games
6.5 Alternative Forms of Representing a Game
6.5.1 Normal-form Representation of a Game
6.5.2 Extensive-form Representation of a Game
6.6 Solving a Game theory Problem
6.6.1 Dominated Strategies
6.6.2 Dominant Strategies
6.6.3 Dominant Strategy Equilibrium
6.6.4 Iterated Elimination of Strictly Dominated Strategies
6.6.5 Nash Equilibrium
6.6.6 Multiple Equilibria
6.7 Mixed Strategies
6.8 Sequential Games
6.8.1 Sub-game Perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE)
6.8.2 Backward Induction
6.9 Application of the Game Theory
6.10 Let Us Sum Up
6.11 Some Useful References
6.12 Answers or Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
6.0 OBJECTIVES
After reading the unit, you should be able to:
x define the concept of a Game in the Economic theory;
x describe basic elements of a Game, viz. (1) players, (2) strategies and (3)
payoffs;
x discuss different types of Games;
x appreciate two different forms of representing a Game;
Imperfect x appreciate various basic concepts required to solve a Game theoretic
Competition-II
problem;
x elucidate different equilibrium concepts related to the Game theory;
x explain the notion of a sequential game; and
x discuss the application of the Game theory.
6.1 INTRODUCTION
In Unit 5 we discussed the market structure of oligopoly where firms’
decision problem exhibit strategic interdependence. In such a market,
output or price decision by one firm impacts output (sales) or price decision
and hence the profit of the other firms in the market. As a result,
optimisation by firms in this market involves taking care of their strategic
interdependence. Game theory is nothing but the study of interactive
decision-making. A group of people (or players, teams, firms, countries) are
in a game if their decision-making problem is interdependent. Thus in a
multi-agent framework the behaviour of individual agents are contingent to
the fact that action of one agent affects the payoff of the other agent(s). In
the previous unit we discussed game theory in the context of firm
competition. One can come across many real life situations involving
strategic interdependence where more than one agent is involved in
decision-making (like football, soccer, baseball are games). Economists apply
various general tools to arrive at the solution of the problems involving
strategic situations. In fact game theory has been used in many fields in
recent decades (apart from Economics) like Political Science, Sociology,
Computer Science, Biology. The present unit will be elaborating upon that.
6.3 A GAME
A ‘Game’ is an abstract of a strategic situation involving interdependence. A
simplest form of game is defined by: players, actions or strategies and
payoffs. In game theory, players are the agents who are involved in the
decision-making. Each player has a number of strategies or action to choose
from. The strategies chosen by each player determine the outcome of the
game, with each possible outcome resulting in a payoff to each player.
i) Players: Players are the agents playing the game. They may be firms,
individuals, countries, or just about anything else that is capable of
executing a strategy. In the duopoly game, for instance, the players are
the two firms. Generally, in an n-player game, players are numbered
from 1 to n, with any arbitrary player to be called player i.
ii) Strategies: Strategies are the actions or the set of actions available to
the players. For instance, in case of Cournot game, each firm’s strategy
is to choose its quantity, taking as given the quantity of its rivals. In case
of an n-player game we assume any player i has a strategy set Si
consisting of different strategies, with si referring to any arbitrary
element of the set Si, i.e. si^i.
iii) Payoffs: Payoffs are the returns to the players at the conclusion of the
game. For instance, payoffs are the profits in case of profit maximising
firms. In an n-player game, payoff function for any arbitrary player i will
be given by Ui (s1,s2, s3....sn), where (s1, s2, s3....sn) represents the
combination of strategies (one for each player) chosen by the n-players.
Here Ui is the payoff to player i as a function of (s1, s2, s3....sn).
Besides the above set of three elements, a game is modelled by specifying
‘information’ that each player has when it decides its course of action. It is
usually assumed that there is common knowledge, that is, each player
knows not only about the ‘‘rules of the game’’ called common knowledge of
the game, but also what the other player knows, and so forth called the
common knowledge of rationality. Other aspects of information vary from
game to game, depending on timing of moves and other issues.
Prisoner’s Dilemma
A well known example of a non-cooperative and a game of complete
information is the Prisoners’ Dilemma game. Consider the following set-up
of the game: A crime is committed for which there is no eye witness.
Suspects 1 and 2 are caught and imprisoned in two separate cells. Thus
each prisoner is in a solitary confinement with no means of communicating
with each other. The magistrate speaks to each prisoner separately, and
asks them to act as an informer. If one of them confesses the crime, he will
be freed but the other one will spend 4 years in prison. If both confess, each
will spend 3 years in prison. If both stay quiet and do not confess, the crime
cannot be probed, so they will get nominal punishment by spending only
one year in prison. Thus each player then has two possible strategies: Not
confess (N) or Confess (C) and they decide simultaneously.
Entry in each cell of the above figure represents (Player 1’s, Player 2’s)
payoff in terms of number of years in jail (a negative payoff with a negative
sign) from each of the two strategies. In other words, the first numerical
figure in each cell of the matrix corresponds to payoff of player 1 and the
second figure corresponds to payoff of player 2. For example, if we look at
ƚŚĞ ĂĐƚŝŽŶ EŽƚ ŽŶĨĞƐƐ͕ EŽƚ ĐŽŶĨĞƐƐ ƚŚĞ ƉĂLJŽĨĨƐ ĂƐƐŽĐŝĂƚĞĚ ĂƌĞ ;оϭ͕ оϭͿ͘
This means when both the players simultaneously decide not to confess,
both will be spending one year in jail. The next entry in first row, second
column is (Not confess, Confess), this means player 1 will get 4 years of
imprisonment and player 2, freedom.
Game Theory and
6.5.2 Extensive-form Representation of a Game
its Applications
A simultaneous game can also be represented by the extensive form using a
game tree. In Fig. 6.2 each dark dot is called the decision node for the player
indicated there. The first move belongs to Player 1, who can choose to
confess or not confess. The next move belongs to Player 2, who can also
choose among the two options (confess or not confess). Payoffs are decided
at the end of the tree towards the extreme right. To reflect the fact that the
Prisoners’ Dilemma is a simultaneous move game, a dotted oval is drawn
around Player 2’s decision nodes to reflect the fact that Player 2 does not
know which of the two decision nodes he is at since he does not observe
which action Player 1 has chosen, that is, he does not know whether the
first decision by Player 1 was to confess or not confess. This dotted oval
around the two nodes of Player 2 indicates his lack of specific information.
An information set of a Player is a collection of nodes such that the same
player (here Player 2) moves at each of these nodes; and the same moves
(here Not Confess, Confess) are available at each of these nodes.
Not Confess
(оϭ͕оϭͿ
Player 2
Not Confess
(оϭ͕оϭͿ
Player 2
A
Not Confess Confess
(оϰ͕ϬͿ
Player 1 Not Confess
B (0, оϰͿ
Confess
Confess
Player 2
(оϯ͕оϯͿ
Fig. 6.3
The two nodes (say A and B) which signifies the move of Player 2 represent
the information set of Player 2. Clearly the information base of Player 2 at A
Imperfect and at B are not same in this case of sequential-move game. The Prisoner’s
Competition-II
Dilemma is widely studied throughout the Social Sciences. It is a compelling
scenario because the tensions it portrays between an individual player’s
self-interest and the group’s self-interest shows up in many different ways
around us. Understanding this shows us the reality of counter-productive
outcomes in a non-cooperative situation.
Generally, in an n-player game, among strategies s’i and s’’i each belonging
to strategy set Si of an arbitrary player i, strategy s’i is dominated by strategy
s’’i if player i’s payoff from playing s’i is lower than the payoff he attains
from playing s’’i for each feasible combination of other players’ strategies
(i.e., whatever be the strategy played by the other players).
Game Theory and
6.6.2 Dominant Strategies
its Applications
A dominant strategy for a player is the one that yields best payoff for that
player no matter what the other player does. That is, a dominant strategy is
a player’s best response to all the feasible strategies of the other player.
Generally, strategy si* will be referred to as the dominant strategy for
player i if he is strictly better off playing si* rather than any other strategy
regardless of what his opponent plays.
Please note: If a player has a dominant strategy then for this player all other
feasible strategies become dominated by this dominant strategy. But in
many situations, a player may not have a dominant strategy and yet may
have dominated strategies.
Player 2
A B C
Player 1 P (6,6) (1, 11) (4, 5)
Q (4,1) (3,3) (5, 6)
We can begin eliminating the dominated strategy of either of the player. For
instance, for Player 2, there are three strategies A, B and C. Irrespective of
Player 1’s strategy (either P or Q), strategy A for Player 2 is strictly
dominated by strategy B. This is because if Player 1 plays P, Player 2 gets 6
from playing A whereas 11 from playing B (6 < 11). Similarly if Player 1 plays
Q, Player 2 gets 1 from playing A whereas 3 from playing B (1 < 3). Hence,
strategy A can be eliminated for Player 2 so that the game reduces to:
Player 2
B C
Player 1 P (1, 11) (4, 5)
Q (3, 3) (5, 6)
Now irrespective of Player 2’s strategy (either B or C), strategy P for Player 1
is strictly dominated by Q. If Player 2 plays B, Player 1 gets 1 from playing P
and 3 from playing Q (1 < 3). Similarly, if Player 2 plays C, Player 1 gets 4
from playing P and 5 from playing Q (4 < 5). So player 1 being rational won’t
play the strictly dominated strategy P, so P can be eliminated so that the
game to reduce to:
Player 2
B C
Player 1 Q (3, 3) (5, 6)
Now Player 1 is left with one strategy Q. Player 2 will choose to play strategy
C for a payoff of 6 which is higher than the payoff of 3 from strategy B. Thus,
we arrive at the equilibrium solution strategy profile of (Q, C) yielding a
payoff of (5, 6) through iterated elimination of dominated strategy.
Player 2
Not Confess Confess
Player 1 EŽƚŽŶĨĞƐƐ ;оϭ͕оϭͿ ;оϰ͕ϬͿ
ŽŶĨĞƐƐ ;Ϭ͕оϰͿ ;оϯ͕оϯͿ
Player 2
Not Confess Confess
Player 1 EŽƚŽŶĨĞƐƐ ;оϭ͕оϭͿ ;оϰ͕0)
Confess (0͕оϰͿ ;оϯ͕оϯ)
From the above payoff matrix, mutually best response strategy of both the
players is the Nash equilibrium in pure strategy i.e., each move involved is
the best response to the other moves. In other words, a cell in the normal
Imperfect form is a Nash equilibrium in pure strategy if each entry is marked
Competition-II
(underlined) as being the best response to the other moves. This way,
;ŽŶĨĞƐƐ͕ŽŶĨĞƐƐͿLJŝĞůĚŝŶŐĂƉĂLJŽĨĨŽĨ;оϯ͕оϯͿǁŝůůďĞƚŚĞEĂƐŚĞƋƵŝůŝďƌŝƵŵŝŶ
the above game.
But one may also note that both the players would have been better off if
both played ‘not confess’. When both play ‘not confess’ the resulting payoff
is one year of imprisonment. This is certainly better than the three year of
imprisonment that they suffer when both choose to play ‘confess’. Thus,
(Not Confess, Not Confess) is the Pareto optimal outcome of this game.
However, both players playing ‘not confess’ is not an equilibrium, because
given (say) Player 1 plays Not Confess, Player 2 always has an incentive to
deviate towards the strategy ‘confess’ and vice versa in the absence of
binding agreement. If binding agreement is possible, then both would agree
on the (Not confess, Not confess) combination, reaching a higher payoff.
Thus, rules of the games that do not allow binding agreements may induce
the players towards the strategy that results in lower payoffs for both of
them. Game-theoretic conditions like Prisoners’ Dilemma arise in many real
world settings. For instance, in a cartel agreement among suppliers of steel
to restrict output would lead to higher prices and profits if it could be
sustained, but such an agreement may be unstable because it may be too
tempting for an individual steel supplier to sell more output at the high
price.
Remember:
2) With just two strategies for each player if one strategy is dominant, the
other must be dominated. However with more than two strategies
available, a player might have dominated strategies but no dominant
strategy. If neither player has a dominant strategy, we can deduce
equilibrium by iteratively eliminating the dominated strategies and
successively moving towards the reduced form of game.
Husband
Opera Boxing
When both wife and husband end up at Opera, woman receives a payoff of
3 while her husband 1, on the other hand, when they end up attending a
boxing match, woman receives a payoff of 1 while her husband receives a
payoff of 3. When they both go to different locations, their payoff reduces
to 0. There is no dominant (or dominated) strategy for any of the player in
this game. A player would rather go for Opera if the other player chooses to
go for Opera, while the former would go for a boxing match if the later
chooses to go for a boxing match. It illustrates the fact that every game
cannot be solved using the iterated elimination of dominated strategies. For
Nash equilibrium we mark the best responses of the husband and the wife.
Husband
Opera Boxing
Wife Opera (3, 1) (0, 0)
Boxing (0,0) (1, 3)
For both of them, best response is to play the same action as the other. This
results in multiple pure strategy Nash equilibria, (Opera, Opera) and (Boxing,
Boxing) yielding payoffs of (3, 1) and (1, 3), respectively. It is not possible to
say which is pareto superior as they are symmetric.
Imperfect Matching Pennies
Competition-II
This is a game where two players 1 and 2, each possessing a coin (penny)
decides to simultaneously display their coins with either heads or tails facing
up. If the face of the coins matches with either both head or both tail faced
up, Player 2 gives his penny to Player 1; if face of the coins do not matches,
Player 1 gives his penny to Player 2. The normal form of the game is as
follows:
Player 2
Head Tail
Player 1 ,ĞĂĚ ;ϭ͕оϭͿ ;оϭ͕ϭͿ
dĂŝů ;оϭ͕ϭͿ ;ϭ͕оϭͿ
Such a game is called a zero-sum game due to the fact that sum of the
payoffs of the players in each box add to zero. We will employ the same
method of underlining the best responses we applied in case of Prisoner’s
Dilemma to solve for the Nash equilibrium. We get the following result:
Player 2
Head Tail
Player 1 Head (1͕оϭͿ ;оϭ͕ϭ)
dĂŝů ;оϭ͕ϭ) (1͕оϭͿ
To solve the Mixed Strategy Nash equilibrium, suppose that Player 2 opts for
,ĞĂĚ ǁŝƚŚ ƉƌŽďĂďŝůŝƚLJ Ɖ͕ ĂŶĚ ĐŚŽŽƐĞƐ dĂŝůƐ ǁŝƚŚ ƉƌŽďĂďŝůŝƚLJ ϭоƉ͘ ^ŝŵŝůĂƌůLJ
ƐƵƉƉŽƐĞWůĂLJĞƌϭƉůĂLJƐƚŚĞŐĂŵĞǁŝƚŚĂƉƌŽďĂďŝůŝƚLJĚŝƐƚƌŝďƵƚŝŽŶƋĂŶĚ;ϭоƋͿ
for Head and Tail. Now, the expected payoff of Player 1 for playing a pure
strategy of Head when Player 2 plays a mixed strategy with a probability Game Theory and
its Applications
ĚŝƐƚƌŝďƵƚŝŽŶƉĂŶĚ;ϭоƉͿŝƐ͗
Imperfect Thus if the player has to play Mixed strategy, in equilibrium the expected
Competition-II
payoffs from the different strategies should be equal.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Following is the payoff matrix in strategic form in which two players
have two strategies each.
Player 2
Left Right
Player 1 Top (7,3) (5,3)
ŽƚƚŽŵ ;ϳ͕ϬͿ ;ϯ͕оϭͿ
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
C) Find dominant strategies of both players.
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
2) Following is a game in which the players have three strategies each.
Player 2
Left Centre Right
Player 1 Top (4,5) (1,6) (5, 6)
Middle (3,5) (2,5) (5, 4)
Bottom (2, 5) (2, 0) (7, 0)
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
b) Find Nash equilibrium in pure strategy of the game. Game Theory and
its Applications
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
3) Are dominant strategy always Nash equilibrium? Is the converse true?
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
…………………………………………………………………………………………………………….
4) From the following payoff matrix where the payoffs are the profits or
losses of the two firms, determine
Firm B
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
Imperfect 5) From the following payoff matrix, where the payoffs refer to the profits
Competition-II
firms earn by cheating and not cheating in a cartel
Firm B
Cheat Don’t Cheat
Firm A Cheat (3,2) (9,1)
Don’t Cheat (2,6) (7,4)
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
b) What if we change the payoff of the bottom left cell to (4, 4)?
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
……………………………………………………………………………………………………….
7) In the Battle of Sexes game (given in the Section 6.6), two pure strategy
Nash equilibria are derived. Derive the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium
of the game (if there is any).
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
……………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Opera (3, 1)
Husband
Boxing
Opera
A (0, 0)
Wife Opera
(0, 0)
Boxing
B Boxing
Husband
(1, 3)
Fig. 6.4
As one may notice, the oval around the decision nodes of Player 2 (that was
there in case of simultaneous-move game) has been removed. This is
because with sequential moves, husband (second mover) can observe his
wife’s (first mover) action and hence is aware of the decision node he is on
before he takes his action. The wife’s possible strategies remain unchanged
at Opera or Boxing. But the husband’s set of possible strategies has
expanded to four strategies; as for each of the wife’s two actions, he can
choose one of two actions. So the husband has the option to move either
from node A or node B, that is, he is not in the same information base. Note
that to define the husband’s strategies completely we must define an action
at each information set that he makes a choice at, even if that information is
not actually reached in the game. Thus all strategies in his strategy profile,
include an action for both the top and bottom information sets. To solve for
the Nash equilibria, we will consider the normal form of the game and use
the method of underlining payoffs for best responses:
Imperfect
Competition-II
Husband
Always Opera Follows Wife Opposite to Always Boxing
(Opera|Opera) (Opera|Opera) Wife (Boxing|Opera)
(Opera|Boxing) (Boxing|Boxing) (Boxing|Opera) (Boxing|Boxing)
(Opera|Boxing)
Husband
Always Opera Follows Wife Opposite to Always Boxing
(Opera|Opera) (Opera|Opera) Wife (Boxing|Opera)
(Opera|Boxing) (Boxing|Boxing) (Boxing|Opera) (Boxing|Boxing)
(Opera|Boxing)
Wife Opera (3, 1) (3, 1) (0, 0) (0, 0)
Boxing (0,0) (1, 3) (0, 0) (1, 3)
Opera (3, 1)
Husband (ii)
Boxing
Opera
(0, 0)
Wife Opera (i)
(0, 0)
Boxing
Boxing (iii)
Husband
(1, 3)
Fig. 6.5
Opera (3, 1)
Husband (ii) Opera (3, 1)
Boxing
Opera Opera
(0, 0)
Husband
Wife Opera (i) Wife
(0, 0)
Boxing Boxing
Boxing (iii) Boxing (1, 3)
Husband
(1, 3)
Fig. 6.6
In Fig. 6.6 the method of Backward Induction involves first solving the two
subgames (ii and iii) for Nash equilibrium. In subgame (ii), given that wife
opts for Opera, husband’s best response would be to choose Opera for a
payoff of 1 rather than going for Boxing match resulting in payoff of 0.
Similarly, in subgame (iii), given that wife opts for Boxing, husband’s best
response will be to go for a Boxing match. Now, we replace the two
subgames with their respective Nash equilibrium strategies to get a simple
game where wife is to decide. Wife gets a payoff of 3 if she goes for Opera,
while Boxing results in a payoff of 1. Nash equilibrium strategy yielding the
higher payoff will be for her to go for Opera. So the wife’s best response is
to go for Opera. Thus, we get the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium
outcome as (Opera|Opera).
Game Theory and
6.9 APPLICATIONS OF THE GAME THEORY its Applications
Each player has a dominant strategy of charging low price. The equilibrium
is therefore {low price, low price} yielding payoff (270, 270). It is a scenario
similar to Prisoner’s Dilemma game, where the equilibrium outcome is the
one which gives lowest joint-payoffs (= 270 + 270 = 540). The strategy {Low
Price, Low Price} is the Nash equilibrium as well as Dominant strategy
Equilibrium. However the outcome {high price, high price} with a highest
joint-payoffs (= 400 + 400 = 800) is a Pareto improvement over the Nash
equilibrium outcome.
In this game, neither of the two firms will have a dominant strategy, hence
no dominant strategy equilibrium. But the game will be having two Nash
equilibria, viz. {Do not advertise, Advertise} and {Advertise, Do not
advertise}.
Firm 2
Salty Sweet
Firm 1 ^ĂůƚLJ ;оϯ͕оϯͿ ;ϭϬ͕ϭϱͿ
^ǁĞĞƚ ;ϭϱ͕ϭϬͿ ;оϯ͕оϯͿ
Clearly in a static (or simultaneous move) game there are two Nash
equilibria in pure strategies (Sweet, Salty) and (Salty, Sweet). Let us consider
the sequential move (extensive form) of the game (see Fig. 6.7 and 6.8)
Fig. 6.7
Imperfect
Competition-II
Salty
(10, 15)
Firm 1
Sweet (15, 10)
Fig. 6.8: (Reduced form of the Game)
Firm B
Accommodate Price War
Small (2,10) (0,8)
Firm A
Large (4,5) (1, 12)
As per the above payoff matrix, for firm A ‘large’ is the dominant strategy,
given firm A choose this, firm B will respond by launching a ‘price war’. At this
the Nash Equilibrium will be (Large, Price War) where firm A will have a payoff
of 1 and firm B a payoff of 12. But firm A can do better if you turn this into a
sequential-move game. Here firm A can commit to a scale of operation in
advance. If firm A decide ‘large’, then firm B’s best response is to fight a ‘price
war’, resulting in firm A’s payoff to be 1. But if firm A choose ‘small’ then firm
B’s best response will be to accommodate yielding a payoff of 2 to firm A.
Hence Sub game Perfect Nash Equilibrium strategy in this sequential move
game is (Small, Accommodate, Large, Price War), where firm A enters ‘small’
and firm B ‘accommodates’ in the top information set, and engages in a price
war in the bottom information set. Hence, equilibrium payoffs is (2,10).The
Sub-game Perfect Nash Equilibrium outcome is (Small, Accommodate). This
shows moving first can have strategic value.
The extensive form can be depicted as follows: Game Theory and
its Applications
Accommodate (2, 10)
Firm B
Price War
Small
(0, 8)
Firm A Accommodate
(4, 5)
Large
Price War
Firm B
(1, 12)
Fig. 6.9
Firm A
Small Cars Big Cars
We have a sequential game, in which firm A is the first mover (leader), it can
do best by making small cars and so firm B should make small car seats.
ĂŶĨŝƌŵƚŚƌĞĂƚĞŶĨŝƌŵƚŽƉƌŽĚƵĐĞďŝŐĐĂƌƐĞĂƚƐخEŽ͕ďĞĐĂƵƐĞŝĨŝƚŵĂŬĞƐ
big car seats and firm A makes small cars, firm B would earn a payoff of ‘1’
and not ‘2’. Therefore this threat won’t work out and it is called an empty
threat. In other words, this threat is not a credible threat. However it can
make its threat credible by shutting down small car seats factory. The new
payoff matrix is now:
Firm A
Small Cars Big Cars
Small Car Seats (0,6) (0,0)
Firm B
Big Car seats (1,1) (10,3)
Now firm A would be forced to produce big cars and firm B would produce
big car seats and earn a payoff of ‘10’. But here one may question, what if
ĨŝƌŵĨŝŶĚƐĂŶŽƚŚĞƌƉƌŽĚƵĐĞƌƚŽƉƌŽĚƵĐĞƐŵĂůůĐĂƌƐĞĂƚƐخ,ĞƌĞ͕ƚŚĞƌŽůĞŽĨ
reputation becomes very important.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Two firms are planning to enter into a market. Firm 1 is contemplating
its capacity strategy, which can be “aggressive” or “accommodating”.
Firm 2 also has similar options. The payoff matrix is as follows:
Imperfect
Competition-II
Firm 2
Aggressive Accommodating
Aggressive (7,2) (10,3)
Firm 1
Accommodating (9,5) (11,4)
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
b) Write the game in Extensive form and find the optimal strategy of
firm 1, if it could move first. What would firm 2 doǫ
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
2) Two cereal manufacturers firm A and firm B are contemplating
manufacturing a cereal made from either wheat or rice.
The payoff matrix is as follows:
Firm 2
Wheat Rice
Firm 1 Wheat (10,12) (6,8)
Rice (1,6) (8,12)
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
b) If firm 1 chooses first, what is the optimal strategy of firm 2 ? Does
firm 1 have any advantage in moving first ?
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………………………………..
Game Theory and
6.10 LET US SUM UP its Applications
Game theory is a set of tools that economists use to analyse conflict and
cooperation between firms or any other rational players or decision-making
agents. Each firm adopts a strategy or plan of action to compete with other
firms. The unit discusses various elements employed in representing a game.
Every game theory model includes players, strategies and payoffs. The
players are the decision-makers and the strategies are the potential choices.
The payoff is the reward or profit or the outcome of each combination of
strategies. The unit also discussed the two forms of representing a game,
viz. the normal and the extensive form. It continued in explaining various
basic concepts needed to solve a game theoretic problem. The dominant
strategy is the optimal choice for a player, no matter what the strategy of
the other player is. When both the players are having a dominant strategy,
we reach a dominant strategy equilibrium. Nash Equilibrium occurs when
player choose mutually best response strategy, given the strategy chosen by
the other player. Examples of various games including, the Prisoners’
Dilemma, the Battle of the Sexes, Matching Pennies, etc. were discussed in
order to illustrate the concepts of equilibrium. The concept of the Mixed
strategy Nash equilibrium arises when there is no Nash equilibrium in Pure
strategies. From the simultaneous-move games, we moved next to a
Sequential-move games where the time pattern of choices is important. The
two additional concepts of that of a Sub-game Perfect Nash equilibrium and
the method to reach such equilibrium known as the Backward induction
method, were also covered with illustration. The unit concluded with a
discussion on some application of the Game theory.
Imperfect
Competition-II 6.12 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR PROGRESS
EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
1) a)
Left (7, 3)
Top Right
(5, 3)
Player 1 Left (7, 0)
Bottom
Right
(3, о1)
Player 2
Left (4, 5)
Center (1, 6)
Right (5, 4)
3) a) Yes, if all players are using their dominant strategies then it would
be the case that it is optimal given what the other players are doing
and therefore a Nash Equilibrium. No, the converse is not true.
4) a) Firm A does not have a dominant strategy.
b) Firm B has a dominant strategy of low price.
c) Nash Equilibrium is {Low price, Low price}
5) a) Nash Equilibrium is {Cheat, Cheat}
b) Nash Equilibrium would be {Don’t Cheat, Cheat}
Check Your Progress 2 Game Theory and
its Applications
1) a) Nash Equilibrium would be {Accommodating, Aggressive}
Aggressive (7, 2)
Aggressive
(10, 3)
Accommodating
Firm 1
Aggressive (9, 5)
Accommodating
Accommodating (11, 4)
Firm2
2) a) The two Nash Equilibrium are {wheat, wheat} and {Rice, Rice}.
b) Firm 1 should choose wheat and firm 2 would also choose wheat,
giving firm 1 a payoff of 10. Yes firm 1 has an advantage of moving
first. If firm 2 were to move first, it would choose Rice,then firm 1
would also choose Rice giving firm 1 a payoff of only 8.