DISSERTATION
DISSERTATION
1 Theoretical Framework
Both inflation and monetary policy are subjects of great importance and interest,
therefore evaluating them and their effect on various macroeconomic variables is of pivotal
concern to the society at large. According to Keynes (2018), monetary policy may impact the
level of aggregate demand, via modification of money supply. They assert that this may result
in full employment without the generation of inflation. Later, during the advent of the
eighties, the Keynesian theorists lost credibility while the monetarist theories, proposed by
economists such as Alton Melter, Karl Brunner, and Milton Friedman. These economists are
of the view that monetary regulation constitutes the capacity to stabilize the economy. This
way, Cerna (2012, p. 59) posits that the neoclassic school of economic thought introduces a
Gherman & Adam (2010) observed that the objective of monetary policy is to
guarantee a high rate of employment besides price stability. This double goal, which is
renowned and reviewed within literature as the monetary policy’s dual mandate, may resent
the declared aim of several central banks that primarily focus on price stability (Gherman,
2010, p.90). Moreover, Gherman & Adam (2010) opine that the current few businessmen and
opportunities, still have the conviction that central bank actions impose to impact on GDP’s
evolution besides other essential macro-economic variables that are of interest to the public.
The ideology that monetary policy fails to ascertain natural employment growth or to match
the correspondent GDP level is not considered a reason for the absence of effort towards the
transparent while striving to avoid excessive flexibility and fluctuation (Brash, 2000). The
disinflation, coupled with restrictive fiscal and monetary policies besides rather neutral
depreciation, mandatory reserves, and a high rate of interest (Pop, 2011). Based on economic
literature, in the current economies, reaching a steady and low inflation results in new
value of total output (Friedman, 1971). According to Friedman (1963), previous efforts to
implement a counter-cyclical monetary policy were so futile that the most appropriate
approach to adopt a stabilizing policy encompasses the overall prevention and simply
maintaining money stock at a constant level. Korhonen & Nuutilainen, (2016) assert that
Friedman also proposed that the money stock must be allowed to expand exclusively at a
constant rate (k ), which corresponds to the economy’s rate of growth. This measure was
offset the prevailing economic fluctuations. Overall, Roberts (2004) opines that inflation is
presumed to be founded on an increased level of demand for services and goods as outlined
in the fact that individuals strive to utilize cash balances. Conclusively, the authors assert that
assumed to beconstants; while the level of price (P), varies in proportion with the level of
Jhingan (2011) noted that both the monetarists and the Keynesian economists are
convinced that inflation is a result of increased aggregate demand attributed to several factors
including increased money supply, increased level of disposable income, increased public
expenditure, increased consumer spending, cheap currency, deficit financing, private sector
expansion, black money, public debt repayment, and increased exports. On the other hand,
the factors that affect supply include shortage of production factors, natural calamities,
(1988). For instance, it assesses the significance of the aspects of alternative rules of
monetary policy via utilizing various economic models. However, the distinction between
policy objectives and economic structure could be ineffective. To begin with, the quadratic
loss function of the central bank may be perceived as the representative agents’ welfare
model framework; for instance, an increase in price rigidity increases the inflation objective’s
relative weight in the function of optimal loss that a central bank which adopt inflation
targeting should employ (Walsh, 2009). Generally, researchers are in consult that inflation-
targeting has resulted in substantive progress in the context of monetary policy practice
restriction regime and highlight its benefit of providing the platform for ample discretion
based on a rule-based framework which is consistent with Kydland & Prescott (1977).
2.1.2 Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate
development of the rate of exchange framework. Fundamentally, each of the countries has
experienced a shift from the fixed rate of exchange to a managed floating system of exchange
rate. This scenario is attributed to several reasons. To begin with, the regime is a necessity for
a country in itself. As the most rapidly developing countries under the emerging economies
category, the BRICS states should have more market-compliant and flexible rates of
exchange to balance the scenario. The export and import businesses of the national foreign-
exchange project of reserve management or the enterprises need to adopt a more similar
model to the marketized system of exchange rate in the management of the country’s
exchange rate adjustments. Thus, the open rate of exchange framework may serve an
appropriate role in bridging one currency’s single system of exchange rate with the
advancement of a flexible floating system of the rate of exchange (Jiang et al., 2019). A shift
of either the LM or the IS curve may result in the fluctuation of a country’s business cycle.
Different economic factors result in the shifting of the IS-LM curves, hence they shift
independently. A variation in the level of aggregate demand shifts only the IS curve rather
For a flexible economy such as that of the BRICS, the condition of the equilibrium in
the goods market provides that production (Y) equals the demand level for goods. The latter
points to the sum of net exports, public spending, investment, and consumption. This
relationship is reflected in the IS curve. Suppose the definition of consumption is provided as:
C = C(Y-t), in which t is representative of the tax rate, the equilibrium level would be
defined as:
Y = G + NX+ C(Y-t) + I
This case holds that the level of investment is unstable, and Young, Warren & Darity,
William (2004) observe that it is mainly dependent on two aspects: the interest rates and sales
level. Suppose a firm’s sales increase, it must opt investing new plants to increase the
production level, hence a positive link. In line with rates of interest, the higher the latter; the
costlier the investments, such that the relationship between investments and rates of interest is
negative. Besides the provisions of the IS-LM framework, since net exports exist, the rates of
exchange must also be brought into consideration, hence a direct impact on the net exports.
Assuming that e represents a foreign currency’s domestic price, or alternatively, the number
of units of a home currency that have to be foregone to obtain a unit of a foreign currency.
i= Rate of Interest
determines the equilibrium in the market for goods, and observe the effect of interest rates,
we obtain the IS curve. This curve represents the value of equilibrium for any interest rate. A
rising rate of interest would result in reduced production via its impact on the level of
investment. Ultimately, the slope of the curve is negative (Meyer, 1983). The LM curve
reflects the relationship which defines money and liquidity (Boianovsky, 2004). In a floating
economy, the rate of interest is established in the money demand and money supply
Y-Real Income
i-Rate of interest
Also, the analysis of the rate of exchange is essential since it impacts money demand,
such that investors would opt to sell or buy bonds based on the rate of exchange.
The money market equilibrium implies that, based on the money quantity, the rate of
interest is positively related to the level of output. With an increase in output, money demand
increases, however, as pointed out, the supply of money is given. This way, the rate of
interest should increase such that the opposite impacts influencing the money demand are
offset (Friedman, 1966), hence individuals will raise their demand for money attributed to
increased income and reduce the demand due to increasing rates of interest.
Moreover, in the monetary policy and exchange rate of the BRICS countries, a
balance of payment curve indicates the specific points at which the BP curve achieves
equilibrium. Conversely, it reflects the combination of the rates of interest and production
rates that ascertain that the BP is appropriately financed, implying that the net export volume
which influences total output should exhibit consistency with the net-capital outflows’
volume. Often, the curve slopes upwards because increased production means more imports
that will cause disturbances to the BP equilibrium, unless the rates of interest rise (which may
result in a consistent equilibrium based on capital inflows). However, in line with the
greatness of capital mobility, it would have a smaller or greater slope (Mundell, 1963) such
that a higher mobility implies that the curve gets flatter. Upon the derivation of the BP curve,
it is essential for the monetary authorities to appropriately employ it. On the one hand, any
points situated above this curve implies a surplus in the balance of payments. On the other
hand, any points situated below the balance of payments curve will represent a deficit in the
balance of payments. This is significant since base on the country’s economic state of the
In a scenario where the capital is perfectly mobile for these countries, expansionary
monetary policies tend to shift the LM curve (LM’), hence the equilibrium moves from e0 to
e1.
On the contrary, Maradiaga (2014) postulates that since the BRICS countries operate
on a flexible rate of exchange, the scenario is different. Consequently, the IS curve shifts to
the upper right (IS’). The ultimate equilibrium is established at E2. Given the same rate of
interest, the level of production has substantively increased, hence revealing the effectiveness
The classical theory of monetary economics is the first most established monetary
policy theory based on Irving Fisher’s QTM, which sets the basis for the connection between
economic variables and monetary policy. This theory postulates that both output and money
velocity are held constant, therefore any increase in money quantity will ultimately result in a
proportional increase in prices based on the theory of money quantity. Moreover, growth over
the long term was only impacted by real factor aspects, and that money supply comprises
both long run and short run neutrality (Mankiw & Taylor, 2007; Galí, 2015).
Keynes critiqued this theory, both as an applied policy tool and theoretically,
suggesting that money velocity is not constant and is unstable. Also, QTM was built on the
assumption of the lack of a trade-off between output and inflation (Keynes, 2018). The
Keynesian economists insisted on price rigidity besides that money quantity rapidly adjusted.
The demand for money was rather more endogenous but exogenous and depends on interest
rates and income as outlined in the theory of liquidity preference. Also, the theory assumes
that the rate of interest and output are positively related, drawing from the LM curve
(Relationship between liquidity Preference and money supply). The basic IS-LM version
framework assumes that the price level is fixed; hence cannot be employed in the analysis of
inflation except for the short run output (Boianovsky, 2004). The theory of liquidity
preference combines the demand for money with the central bank’s money supply quantity to
establish the level of money equilibrium. This equilibrium is an indicator that interest rate is a
any rise in money supply results in reduced rate of interest at which the money demand
quantity is equal to the level of money supply. Lower rates of interest constitute a positive
result on the marginal efficiency of investment and capital. This results in the expansion of
output. The Hicksian IS/LM framework’s perspective of the Keynesian overall theory,
however, was empirically contested (Backhouse & Bateman, 2011). Keynes questioned the
monetary policy’s effectiveness when an economy plunges into a liquidity trap besides due to
financial market uncertainties. Rather, he advocated for a more effective fiscal policy role.
The assumption that the supply of money is considered exogenous in both the Keynesian and
classical theories had been similarly critiqued and abandoned in modern theories (Romer,
2006). The lengthened periods of low rates of interest in the Keynesian perspective are also
considered to constitute distortions in the context of asset price-bubbles that are unsustainable
(Schwartz, 2009). However, monetarism has been challenged based on the money demand
assumes exogenous supply of money which is both empirically and theoretically contested
(Romer, 2000). The constant money velocity assumption has also been subjected to criticism
(Mishkin, 2007). Tang (2016) observes that neutrality over the long term has also been
empirically challenged. More succinctly, the author finds that over the long run, money’s
neutrality over the long run is absent, suppose the same holds as true for the short run,
Considering that the five BRICS countries share similar aspects in the nature of their business
cycles, Kutu & Ngalawa (2017) sought to determine the probability of any of these states
shifting to expansionary regime from the contractionary regime. The study finds that the
region-wide monetary policy has substantively large impacts on the level of industrial
output in both the recession and boom periods of the economic business cycle.
Practically, monetary policy may constitute a sustained positive impact on the growth
of the economy via avoiding negative outcomes of an ineffective monetary policy. This needs
a stable and low rate of inflation. However, this does not reflect the perspectives of various
individuals when they seek to establish the relationship between growth and monetary policy.
Rather, individuals envisage monetary policy as enhancing growth via the stimulation of
aggregate demand based on low rates of interest. This evidence suggests that the influence of
monetary policy is substantively limited when in itself, it does not result in instability (Borio
& Disyatat, 2010). Unprecedented changes in monetary policy stance such as monetary
disturbances and shocks, may enhance the level of economic activity, however, this has a
temporary effect. Efforts to persistently and systematically stimulate growth in this manner
results in increased inflation, hence compelling the central bank to raise the rates of interest
and cause recession to maintain their operations during inflation. The events of the late
seventies and early eighties demonstrate the undesirability of such an ineffective strategy of
monetary policy.
However, the central bank may still employ another approach in impacting real
economic operations. For instance, central banks may employ their balance sheets in altering
credit allocation within the economy. Through buying or lending the securities owned by
entities in the private sector, allocation of central bank credit may result in the flow of more
resources to specific economic segments. This limits the flow of resources to other sectors,
however, and can interfere with distorting economic activity in an unproductive manner.
However, this section considers the allocation of central bank credit as fiscal policy rather
than monetary policy. Consequently, it is appropriate that such actions are exclusively
Monetary policy constitutes a unique capacity in influencing the long run price level.
The mechanism upon which monetary policy exerts its eventual impact on the level of price
is via the money creation process, implying the process by which the actions of the central
banks impact distinct money forms, including bank deposits, used by individuals in
transactions for services and goods. In the contemporary, it is more often to imagine the
scenario of monetary policy as a tool of interest rate targeting, rather than the supply of
money, partly due to the fact that the demand for money appears to fluctuate substantively
(Cornand & Heinemann, 2014). Nevertheless, before two thousand and eight, the Fed was
successful with the achievement of the federal funds rate target via the manipulation of the
bank reserves’ supply. Declines in the rate of interest target by the Fed compelled an increase
in bank reserves’ supply. The resultant money creation process and the private system of
References
Backhouse, R. E., & Bateman, B. W. (2011). Methodological issues in Keynesian
macroeconomics. In The Elgar Companion to Recent Economic Methodology.
Edward Elgar Publishing.
Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a
quantitative business cycle framework. Handbook of macroeconomics, 1, 1341-1393.
Boianovsky, M. (2004). The IS-LM model and the liquidity trap concept: From Hicks to
Krugman. History of political economy, 36(5), 92-126.
Borio, C., & Disyatat, P. (2010). Unconventional monetary policies: an appraisal. The
Manchester School, 78, 53-89.
Brash, D. (2000). How should monetary policymakers respond to the new challenges of
global economic integration?. Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, 85(4), 17-22.
Cerna, S. (2012). The monetary policy in post crisis period. Timisoara Journal of
Economics, 5(17), 58-78.
Cornand, C., & Heinemann, F. (2014). Experiments on monetary policy and central banking.
In Experiments in macroeconomics. Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Friedman, M. (1963). Price determination in the United States treasury bill market: A
comment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 318-320.
Friedman, M. (1971). The demand for money. In A Theoretical Framework for Monetary
Analysis (pp. 11-15). NBER.
Galí, J. (2015). Monetary policy, inflation, and the business cycle: an introduction to the new
Keynesian framework and its applications. Princeton University Press.
Gherman, A. M., & Adam, A. (2010). Monetary Policy Approaches Taking into
Consideration the Current Economic Context. Theoretical and Applied
Economics, 12(12), 89.
Jhingan, M. L. (2011). The economics of development and planning. Vrinda Publications.
Jiang, Y., Li, C., Zhang, J., & Zhou, X. (2019). Financial stability and sustainability under the
coordination of monetary policy and macroprudential policy: New evidence from
China. Sustainability, 11(6), 1616.
Keynes, J. M. (2018). The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Springer.
Korhonen, I., & Nuutilainen, R. (2016). A monetary policy rule for Russia, or is it rules? (No.
2/2016). BOFIT Discussion Papers.
Kutu, A. A., & Ngalawa, H. (2017). Monetary policy and industrial output in the BRICS
countries: A markov-switching model. Folia Oeconomica Stetinensia, 17(2), 35.
Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of
optimal plans. Journal of political economy, 85(3), 473-491.
Mankiw, G. N., & Taylor, M. P. (2007). Macroeconomics.(European Edition ed.).
Maradiaga, D. I. (2014). Exchange rate volatility effects on BRICS countries
exports (Doctoral dissertation, Louisiana State University).
McCallum, B. T. (1988). Real business cycle models.
Meyer, P. A. (1983). Money Multipliers and the Slopes of IS-LM. Southern Economic
Journal, 226-229.
Mishkin, F. S. (2007). Inflation dynamics. International Finance, 10(3), 317-334.
Mundell, R. A. (1963). Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible
exchange rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science/Revue
canadienne de economiques et science politique, 29(4), 475-485.
Pop, N. (2011). Monetary policy decision–the fascinating theory and the ineffable institution.
Roberts, J. M. (2004). Monetary policy and inflation dynamics. Available at SSRN 633222.
Romer, D. H. (2000). Keynesian macroeconomics without the LM curve. Journal of
economic perspectives, 14(2), 149-169.
Tang, M. M. J. (2016). A review of the literature on monetary neutrality.
Walsh, C. E. (2009). Inflation targeting: what have we learned?. International
Finance, 12(2), 195-233.
Woodford, M. (1999). Optimal monetary policy inertia. The Manchester School, 67, 1-35.
Young, Warren & Darity, William. (2004). IS-LM-BP: An inquest. History of Political
Economy. 36. 10.1215/00182702-36-Suppl_1-127.