7 - Central Banking and Monetary Policy
7 - Central Banking and Monetary Policy
7 - Central Banking and Monetary Policy
OVERVIEW
This chapter:
• shows that the central bank, like any bank, is both a money and a credit
provider, as it issues a means of final payment and provides credit to the
banking sector, which needs both to avoid financial crises;
These points are relevant to understanding the scope and limits of mone-
tary policy, and to critically discussing both contemporary monetary policies
and the regulatory reforms carried out at national and international levels
in the aftermath of the global financial crisis that erupted in 2007–08.
KEYWORDS
This chapter will offer a deep criticism of mainstream monetary policy, and
in doing so will discuss the so-called impotence of monetary policy, a topic
that has been revived of late by Lawrence Summers, the former United States
Treasury Secretary and Chief Economist of the World Bank, though the
notion goes as far back as Keynes, who once claimed, ‘[i]t is to the theory of
a generalised monetary economy, i.e. of an economy in which, through the
fault or the inaction or the impotence of the monetary authority . . . that this
book will attempt to make a contribution’ (Keynes, 1979, pp. 67–8). This
chapter is written in this spirit.
Further, this chapter provides a systemic view of money and banking, enabling
us to understand the monetary–structural origins of the global financial crisis
that erupted in 2007–08, particularly after the demise of Lehman Brothers
in the United States. It thereby offers an explanation of this crisis based on
s tructural rather than behavioural factors, which the regulatory reforms put into
practice at national as well as international levels do not and cannot address.
This chapter thus highlights the largely ignored fact that a monetary–structural
reform of domestic payments systems is required in order to eradicate the factors
of systemic crises, which are the hallmark of a monetary disorder affecting the
working of our national economies. As a result, the objectives of monetary
policy should go much beyond price stability, contributing to re-establishing
monetary order and guaranteeing financial stability at systemic level.
To summarize, this chapter will consider: (1) monetary policy and its trans-
mission mechanism from a mainstream and a post-Keynesian perspective;
and (2) the architecture of monetary policy.
BOX 7.1
BOX 7.2
BOX 7.3
Woods regime in the early 1970s (Box 7.3). Indeed, in the 1980s and 1990s,
the majority of central banks implemented their monetary policy with a view
to reaching some previously announced target for the rate of growth of a
given monetary aggregate; as M0, that is, central bank money, or as M3, that
is, the total sum of bank deposits across the banking system, including both
the central bank and the set of commercial banks (Box 7.4).
This assumed control over the money supply is at the heart of the original
mainstream monetary model, which was based on the so-called ‘quantity
theory of money’, which further assumed a direct influence of the money
supply on inflation (Box 7.5).
In other words, according to this view, central banks could effectively influence
inflation directly via a proportional relationship that this theory establishes
BOX 7.4
BOX 7.5
between (changes in) the money supply (M) and (changes in) the general
price level (P), according to the following so-called ‘equation of exchange’:
MV ; PQ(7.1)
economic system during a given period, say a calendar year) and Q is physi-
cal output (the bulk of goods and services produced during the same period
of time). This equation of exchange states that the value of money times its
velocity (left-hand side) is equal to the value of output (right-hand side). This
suggests therefore that the money supply and the price level are connected.
BOX 7.6
MONETARISM
Monetarism is a school of thought devel- of money was zero, so that changes in the
oped by Milton Friedman, as a direct money supply caused changes in the price
challenge to Keynesian economics, of output. Over the long run, it is possible
which rested on the use of fiscal policies. to find a so-called natural rate of economic
Friedman developed these views in par- growth. This being the case, if central
ticular in a monumental book, co-written banks wanted an inflation rate of, say,
with Anna Schwartz, entitled Monetary zero, the proper policy would be to allow
History of the United States 1867–1960. the money supply to grow at the same
In this book, Friedman and Schwartz rate as long-run economic growth (fixed
(1963) argued that, historically, excessive monetary rule), thereby eliminating ‘excess’
growth of the money supply contributed money growth. This is why the assump-
to periods of high inflation. An adversary tion of exogenous money or control over
of Keynesian economic policies, Friedman the growth of the money supply by the
rejected the importance of fiscal policy central bank is paramount: it was impera-
and instead favoured the use of mon- tive for Friedman to assume it in order to
etary policy. Monetarism emphasizes that undermine Keynesian economics. As the
changes in the money supply have a direct authors of this book explain, however,
and predictable impact on inflation. This money is endogenous, which undermines
approach is based on the quantity theory the essence of monetarism. This said, one
of money, which stipulates that MV ; PQ. does not need central bank control over the
Rewriting this equation in terms of growth monetary base to justify inflation targeting
# #
rates, we have M ; p 1 g 2 V. Monetarists policies inspired by monetarism.
assumed that the growth of the velocity
where a dot over a variable indicates its rate of change over time, π is the
measured rate of inflation on the goods market, and g represents the growth
rate of produced output. Box 7.6 gives a summary of this view.
Equation (7.2) has been used to set up and justify monetary-targeting strat-
egies, once the central bank was in a position to determine the three vari-
ables on the right-hand side of that equation (see Box 7.6). The German
Bundesbank, for instance, was implementing this strategy in the 25 years that
preceded its adoption of the euro on 1 January 1999 (Table 7.1).
The Bundesbank decided the targeted growth rate of the relevant monetary
aggregate (∆M*), applying equation (7.3):
where πnormative is the desired rate of inflation, gpotential is the rate of growth
of potential output, and ∆V is the rate of change in money’s ‘velocity of
circulation’.
Provided the central bank controls the monetary base and we assume a
constant relationship between that base and the money supply, monetar-
ism thus believed in the ability of central banks to target a specific rate of
inflation.
While monetarism has today been abandoned by central banks – that is,
the notion that central banks control the money supply – the spirit of this
approach remains very much entrenched in policy circles. While many or
most central banks have now recognized their inability to control the money
supply (Box 7.7), they have now favoured an approach that focuses on their
ability to control the rate of interest, something post-Keynesians have been
saying for several decades now.
Yet, the mainstream version of this interest rate procedure is much differ-
ent. First developed by American economist John Taylor in a 1993 paper,
it stipulates that central banks should now set the interest rate at a level that
generates an inflation rate consistent with their targeted inflation rate, or
BOX 7.7
some targeted monetary aggregate that in turn would deliver a desired rate of
inflation. In this sense, the money supply rule advocated by Milton Friedman
was replaced with an interest rate rule. Yet, the core idea of monetarism, that
inflation is influenced by central bank policies, remains in practice. With the
Taylor rule, inflation becomes ‘always and everywhere’ a monetary policy
phenomenon.
where i represents the policy rate of interest set and controlled by the central
bank during the relevant period represented by t, a is a positive parameter, mt
is the observed growth rate of the targeted monetary aggregate, and m* is the
targeted rate of growth for that monetary aggregate. We can also assume that
central banks target a specific rate of inflation; a strategy that has been called
inflation targeting. In this sense, the above equation simply becomes:
In equation (7.5), the central bank is now targeting a specific rate of infla-
tion, say 2 per cent. Accordingly, if the rate of inflation is above its target
level, or similarly if the monetary aggregate is above its targeted level (as in
equation 7.4), the rule dictates that the central bank should increase the rate
of interest.
ci 1 TC, TI 1 TTD
BOX 7.8
In the first instance, central banks will change their interest rate (i) as
described above, whenever observed or actual values of inflation are above
the targeted rate. Specifically, they will increase the rate of interest. Then, in
a first instance, this should translate into lower consumption (C) and invest-
ment (I).
Second, this drop in total demand (TD) should translate into an increase in
unemployment rates (U), which in turn lowers the inflation rate (P):
TTD 1 cU 1 TP
This second step is crucial for monetary policy, and is known as the Phillips
curve (Box 7.8): a theory that describes the short-run inverse relationship
between the unemployment rate and the rate of inflation. As unemployment
increases, inflation comes down, and vice versa.
The above discussion can also be extended in the context of an open economy,
that is, an economy that considers both imports and exports, but also the
exchange rate. If one considers such an economy, one should expand on this
interest rate view by including the effects on total demand and the price level
that stem from an exchange rate depreciation (appreciation) induced by a
reduction (increase) in the policy rates of interest administered by the central
bank. Indeed, it is assumed that if central banks increase the domestic rate
of interest above the world rate, this increases the demand for the domestic
currency as investors move their funds into the domestic economy to take
advantage of higher returns, thereby pushing up the demand for the domes-
tic currency and hence its value. The inverse applies when domestic rates of
interest are below the world rate.
Further, the interest rate channel as described above also affects an economic
system’s financial stability, as it could generate an asset bubble on either finan-
cial or real estate markets (in the absence of the proper macroprudential reg-
ulations), when the policy rates of interest are kept too low for too long. This
induces debtors as well as creditors to increase the volume of credit in order
for both to profit, in one way or another, from the inflating credit bubble (see
Chapter 6 for analytical elaboration). In this perspective, the mainstream
explanation of the subprime bubble and ensuing crisis observed across the
US housing market during the late 1990s and early 2000s is based basi-
cally on a too-generous monetary policy by the United States (US) Federal
Reserve in the aftermath of the so-called ‘dot.com’ bubble. The bursting of
this bubble led the US monetary authority to dramatically reduce policy
rates of interest in an attempt to kick-start the domestic economy, which was
also negatively affected by the terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001.
In this light, mainstream economists believe that the policy rates of interest
decided by central banks, when used in a countercyclical manner, are a pow-
erful instrument with which to fine-tune economic activity and affect total
demand and, hence, have an impact on the price level in order to guarantee
price stability across the economy. The spending behaviour of both con-
sumers and businesses would thus be determined by a variable – the rate of
interest – that central banks could influence, if not control, through a reduc-
tion or an increase in their own policy rates of interest. This is particularly
so with respect to their credit lines: if a central bank (say) reduces its policy
rates of interest, banks will reduce (although not one-to-one) their own rates
of interest, thereby inducing more consumers and businesses to borrow from
the banking sector in order to expand production when the economic system
is affected by a recession (such as in the aftermath of a financial crisis).
Once low or near-zero interest rates failed to stimulate economic activity, the
mainstream perspective induced a number of central banks, and in particular
the US Federal Reserve System in the aftermath of the global financial crisis
that erupted in 2007–08, to try to support economic growth with so-called
unconventional policies, in particular quantitative easing (QE); that is, an
expansionary monetary policy aimed at making sure that banks lend to cred-
itworthy non-financial businesses (private sector firms), in order for these
businesses to carry out their investment projects and thus expand economic
activity, thereby increasing the level of employment.
There are several problems with this reasoning. First, banks do not need
reserves to lend (see Chapter 5), and as such, more reserves do not lead to
more lending. Banks do not lend reserves to the private sector, as it is not
their function. So, in that sense, increasing reserves serves no purpose with
respect to bank lending. That is the meaning of endogenous money. Banks
were never constrained in their ability to lend. This was essentially the con-
clusion of a Bank of England report, which stated that: ‘As a by-product of
QE, new central bank reserves are created. But these are not an important
part of the transmission mechanism . . . these reserves cannot be multiplied
into more loans and deposits and . . . these reserves do not represent “free
money” for banks’ (McLeay et al., 2014, p. 1).
Further, reducing the policy rates of interest to zero (or even to the negative
domain) may not be enough to reduce banks’ own rates of interest, particu-
larly on the interbank market. Shortly after the collapse of Lehman Brothers
in the United States on 15 September 2008, the US monetary authority
reduced the federal funds rate of interest close to zero, but in fact the inter-
bank market rate of interest increased, since banks were reluctant to lend on
this market because of their higher uncertainty (notice again the importance
of uncertainty) about the actual financial situation of their counterparts on
that market. Indeed, the interest rate channel may not work as monetary
authorities expect, although a long period of very low policy rates of interest
can have various problematic effects in the financial sector and beyond it, in
the absence of a properly designed regulatory framework.
For instance, banks could be induced to borrow from the central bank in
order for them to inflate a financial bubble, through a sustained increase in
the purchase of financial assets, particularly those assets whose high risks may
lead many financial institutions to buy them with the expectation of earning
high yields. Also, banks and non-bank financial institutions could inflate a
real estate bubble, particularly as a number of middle-class individuals may
be attracted by favourable borrowing terms in order to become homeowners.
As shown by the subprime bubble that inflated during the 1995–2005 period
and burst in 2006, spurring a series of systemic effects in the United States
and beyond it, a number of non-performing loans can increase banks’ finan-
cial fragility to a point where several financial institutions become bankrupt.
In particular, those financial institutions that are ‘too big to fail’ – individually
or as a group – will require an intervention by the public sector, which must
bail them out to avoid a systemic financial crisis that will induce a deep reces-
sion, if not a depression (like the Great Depression of the 1930s).
This state of affairs has induced many regulatory reforms at national and
international levels, such as the so-called Basel Agreements signed within the
framework of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, at the Bank for
International Settlements. The large majority of these reforms aim to affect
the banks’ behaviour, to limit their risk-taking attitude and provide them
with a cushion of safety that should be solid enough to avert a systemic crisis
in the case of financial or real estate turmoil.
In fact, however, these regulatory reforms do not and cannot avoid a sys-
temic crisis, as this is the result of a structural disorder affecting the payments
system, rather than stemming merely from agents’ behaviour. The main-
stream perspective is not in a position to detect and explain such a systemic
crisis, because it considers that any economic system is merely the result of
a series of demand and supply forces that the set of economic agents exert
on any kinds of market. In this view, therefore, it all boils down to individual
behaviour, so that the working of the system as a whole is studied (and can
be studied appropriately) with a system of equations that allow to establish
the system’s ‘equilibrium’, provided that the public sector does not intervene
in the ‘market mechanism’, because this intervention would be a matter of
hindrance and not a macroeconomic stabilizing factor.
Yet, there is empirical evidence that shows this process is severally limited.
First, regarding the relationship between changes in the rate of interest and
their impact on consumption and investment, there is evidence that shows
the latter two magnitudes are not very interest-sensitive, as explained by the
following quotation:
authors have generalized the link to include business investments (see Fazzari,
Ferri, and Greenberg, 2010 and the references provided therein) but a robust
interest elasticity of investment has also been difficult to demonstrate empirically.
(Cynamon et al., 2013, p. 13)
Claudio Borio (2017, p. 2), Chief Economist at the Bank for International
Settlements, was quite candid: ‘the response of inflation to a measure of
labour market slack has tended to decline and become statistically indistin-
guishable from zero. In other words, inflation no longer appears to be suffi-
ciently responsive to tightness in labour markets.’ In other words, the inverse
relationship between unemployment and inflation has disappeared. This is
a devastating conclusion. Without these two relationships, monetary policy
has lost its essence, and it begs for a complete rethinking of what monetary
policy is and what it does. To better understand this, it is to post-Keynesian
economists that we must turn our attention.
So assume you purchase (consume) a good from a store; you are now in debt
vis-à-vis the store, which you extinguish by using cash (bank money), or your
bank account. In this sense, your payment is finally settled through the bank
(Figure 7.1).
Contrary to the conventional wisdom, however, the bank deposit does not
stem from pre-existing saving, the origin of which would remain mysterious
(as it cannot be explained logically). All bank deposits result, in fact, from a
bank loan, and this is why a central bank must exist, to avoid banks moving
‘forward in step’ (Keynes, 1930/1971, p. 23) without any endogenous limit
to money creation, because this would be a major factor of financial crises
(Box 7.9 and Figure 7.2; see Chapter 4 on the monetary circuit). Indeed,
the existence of a central bank closely depends on the book-entry nature of
money (see Rochon and Rossi, 2013). Its role is to make sure that all pay-
ments on the interbank market are final rather than just promised, as would
BOX 7.9
occur if banks would be allowed to pay simply by issuing their own acknowl-
edgement of debt.
its debt to a third party. This may occur against collateral (that is, a series of
financial assets that the paying bank provides to the central bank as a guaran-
tee of repayment), or it might also occur without collateral (in an emergency
situation, particularly when the paying bank is ‘too big to fail’ without pro-
voking a number of negative outcomes across the domestic or global finan-
cial system). When the central bank intervenes in this regard, it plays the role
of a lender of last resort, as nobody else is willing to lend to the bank in need
of funding its own payments. The central bank may charge a rate of interest
to the borrowing bank, which is usually higher than the interbank market
rate of interest, as a penalty for the bank not being able to raise funds on that
market. This suffices to induce banks to manage their own business in order
to limit the number of instances where they need to turn to the central bank
as a lender of last resort.
The intervention of the central bank as a lender of last resort confirms that
the amount of central bank money is not set by the monetary authority
(exogenously), but actually depends on the needs of the set of banks par-
ticipating in the domestic payments system (endogenously). The ‘helicop-
ter view’ of money, hence the money multiplier, therefore cannot account
for the working of a monetary economy, thus invalidating the orthodox
perspective on factual grounds. The rate of interest set by the central bank
is indeed an exogenous magnitude, and does not depend on the market
rates of interest; rather, it influences them (although not by a one-to-one
relationship and with variable time lags, also depending on the size, type,
and private or public ownership of each bank participating in the domestic
payments system).
stability through its own rates of interest, as explained above. The ortho-
dox argument that an interest rate hike reduces demand on the market for
produced goods and services, thereby lowering inflationary pressures, can
be questioned with regard to the likely impact of monetary policy tightening
on banks’ own rates of interest. If firms have to pay higher rates of interest
because the central bank has raised its own interest rates for banks borrowing
from it, then the firms’ output will be sold at a higher price (hence an increase
in the price level) owing to higher production costs due to bank lending.
There are two ways in which monetary policy can affect income distribution:
through (1) the income channel; and (2) the wealth channel, as depicted in
Figure 7.4.
The income channel can be divided further into a direct and an indirect
mechanism, the first of which concerns the impact of changes in the rate
of interest directly on the income of individuals: rentiers and workers. This
works through the bond market and on bond holders, or rentiers as we call
them: individuals whose income arises not from work, but from simply
owning a class of assets. When interest rates increase, say the rate of interest
on a ten-year bond, the higher rate translates into a higher return for bond
holders. In this sense, lower rates will tend to reduce the income flow to
rentiers. In this context, the rate of interest itself is an income distributive
variable; a central conclusion of post-Keynesian economics.
The second, albeit indirect, mechanism works through the labour market.
Changes in the rate of interest may have effects on labour markets, unem-
ployment, and thus the income of workers. For instance, as the rate of inter-
est falls in a recession, this may encourage the hiring of workers, a drop in
As for the wealth channel, consider, for instance, when policy rates of inter-
est diminish, as in the aftermath of the global financial crisis that erupted in
2007–08, with the aim of supporting economic activity and employment
levels. In fact, as already pointed out, neither firms nor households will be
induced to increase their borrowing from the banking sector if they fear being
unable to repay their debt (and the relevant interest) when it matures. Rather,
this reduction of interest rates will spur financial transactions, thus inflating
an asset price bubble that is further reinforced by the so-called ‘wealth effect’,
which consists in feeling richer when one’s assets are priced higher on the rel-
evant market. Clearly, wealthy individuals whose assets are priced higher as a
result of a reduction in policy rates of interest will not increase their spending
to buy a series of consumption goods, thereby supporting economic activity,
but rather increase their spending on real estate and financial markets, thus
increasing the relevant asset prices. Holders of these assets will thereby feel
richer, giving rise to an upward spiral that could inflate a bubble, threatening
the financial stability of the whole system.
The conclusion to be drawn from this short analysis is that monetary policy
may work first and foremost through income and wealth distribution.
Incremental changes in interest rates affect the distribution of both income
and wealth between rentiers and workers, and between households. Since
we know that poorer individuals spend a greater proportion of their income
than wealthier ones, a policy that redistributes income toward workers is
better. In this sense, a permanent policy of low interest rates is to be consid-
ered. Indeed, this is what Rochon and Setterfield (2007, 2008, 2012) have
advocated in their work on post-Keynesian interest rate rules. Of course, this
policy would then require governments to adopt a proper regulatory frame-
work to prevent financial bubbles.
Yet, the past three decades have shown the fragility of our economic system
when monetary policy is not accommodative to workers. Lavoie and
Seccareccia (1999) and Seccareccia and Lavoie (2016) showed that mone-
tary policy has consistently favoured rentiers, thereby exacerbating an already
unequal distribution of income and wealth. In other words, monetary policy
has acted as an incomes policy that protected rentiers.
stability and nothing else, because this provides the best macroeconomic
environment for other categories of agents to contribute to economic growth
and maximum employment levels. In other words, this approach argues that
stable prices and low inflation are the best economic outcome possible.
This argument has been further reinforced by referring to the so-called ‘sac-
rifice ratio’, that is, the ratio measuring output and employment losses as a
result of a reduction in the rate of inflation. Mainstream literature points out
that these losses are lower when the central bank is independent from the
government, arguing that a central bank’s independence enhances monetary
policy credibility, which is instrumental in making sure that an inflation-
Yt = Y* + b (pt – pe)(7.5)
Now, the problem with this reasoning is that agents are not ‘always and every-
where’ rational, as they do not have all the information and the knowledge
required to be rational. Rather, as Keynes pointed out, the future is unknown
and unknowable. Further, there are too many variables and reciprocal influ-
ences among their set to be able to appraise the actual working of the whole
economic system with a particular model or series of models. Hence, the
‘pretense-of-knowledge syndrome’ (Caballero, 2010) that affects main-
stream economics and the ensuing monetary policy-making is a dangerous
factor of financial instability and economic crisis, as it gives a false perception
of security in simply targeting price stability on the goods market by con-
temporary central banks. In fact, as heterodox economists have pointed out,
inflation-targeting central banks have been inflicting an anti-growth bias to
their economic systems, without preserving the latter from financial bubbles
that gave rise to system-wide crises once they burst. A clear example is the
monetary policy stance of the European Central Bank. Before the euro area
crisis erupted towards the end of 2009, the bank’s inflation-targeting strategy
inflated a credit bubble in a variety of so-called peripheral countries across
the euro area, while it hindered economic activities as the monetary policy
rates of interest were not reduced until measured inflation had fallen below
1 per cent, but increased as soon as expected inflation (a virtual magnitude)
was close to 2 per cent, even though measured inflation was much lower than
that (see Chapter 14 for analytical elaboration on this).
well-being of citizens above the need to contain inflation. In their view, this
leads to the policy conclusion that central banks should contribute to output
stabilization and employment maximization, as well as sustainable economic
growth, while also considering the impact of interest rate policy on income
and wealth distribution across the economic system, without neglecting the
fact that a central bank should contribute to financial stability for the system
as a whole. This puts the conventional policy tools used by central banks
(namely, interest rates, open-market operations, repurchase agreements and
reserve requirements) under stress, as they are not appropriate, individu-
ally and as a whole, to ensure that the above set of policy goals are fulfilled
adequately.
We can generalize this rule (many economists write it in different ways), and
end up with a specific rule called the ‘Taylor rule’ (see Taylor, 1999):
This policy rule has been criticized on several grounds. First, it integrates
neither exchange rate issues nor the problems stemming from financial insta-
bility, perhaps because it is difficult to determine exchange rate misalign-
ments and to define financial instability. Second, the notion of a ‘natural’
rate of interest is a figment of the imagination (Box 7.10), as it stems from a
dichotomous view of the working of an economic system that is conceived
as made up of a ‘real’ sector and a ‘monetary’ sector that would be separated
from each other.
In the ‘real’ sector, equilibrium would be attained when savings are equal to
the amount of firms’ desired investment, thereby determining the ‘natural’
interest rate. In the monetary sector, by contrast, money supply and money
BOX 7.10
demand (two separate and independent forces in the orthodox view) would
determine, at equilibrium, the market rate of interest; which may thus differ
from the natural rate, thereby generating an inflationary or deflationary pres-
sure across the whole economic system.
Third, the ‘Taylor rule’ ignores the fact that interest rate policies affect both
income and wealth distribution across this system, which is a major issue for
financial stability as well as for macroeconomic stabilization, as explained
above. In light of all these critiques, the heterodox approach to interest
rate policy offers two alternative views: one that has the merit of including
macroeconomic stabilization in a central bank’s objectives, and another that
focuses on the distributional impact of changing the rates of interest set
by the monetary authority, as discussed above. In the former view, central
banks are important actors in influencing the economic performance of the
relevant countries, as monetary policy is in a position to support or hinder
economic growth not just through its impact on price stability, but also
via output and employment stabilization. In the latter view, by way of con-
trast, monetary policy impacts upon income and wealth distribution via
the setting of interest rates, which tends to favour the owners of financial
capital (the rentiers) in that the targeted rate of inflation is lower (and the
policy rates of interest are higher) than what is needed in order to reduce the
income share of rentiers and to increase the income share of wage earners
with a view to inducing economic growth in a sustainable way for the whole
system.
Conclusion
This chapter aimed at exploring and contrasting various approaches to mon-
etary policy. We argued that the mainstream approach, based on the Taylor
rule and inflation targeting, finds very little empirical support for its theory,
especially given the collapse of the Phillips curve relationship. This suggests
that its fine-tuning approach of incremental changes in interest rates must be
discarded. In its place, post-Keynesians correctly argue that monetary policy
works mainly through income distribution, both directly and indirectly,
through labour markets.
Of course, mainstream economists have not accepted this reality, and instead
continue to rely on counter-cyclical changes in interest rates. Yet, for reasons
explained in this chapter, this approach does not work, and central banks are
forced to increase interest rates several times in an elusive quest to reach a
fictional natural rate of interest. In doing so, interest rates are pushed so high
that in the end they have a negative impact on economic activity, proving that
there is nothing neutral on the road to finding the natural rate of interest. In
the end, monetary policy collapses the economy, and reveals itself at best as
being a blunt tool that causes tremendous harm.
REFERENCES
Bofinger, P. (2001), Monetary Policy: Goals, Institutions, Strategies, and Instruments, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Borio, C. (2017), ‘Through the looking glass’, lecture delivered at OMFIF, 22 September, London.
Caballero, R.J. (2010), ‘Macroeconomics after the crisis: time to deal with the pretense-of-knowl-
edge syndrome’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24 (4), 85–102.
Cynamon, B., S. Fazzari and M. Setterfield (2013), ‘Understanding the Great Recession’, in
B. Cynamon, S. Fazzari and M. Setterfield (eds), After the Great Recession: The Struggle for
Economic Recovery and Growth, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–30.
Eichner, A. (1976), The Megacorp and Oligopoly, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Eichner, A. (ed.) (1979), A Guide to Post-Keynesian Economics, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Eichner, A. (1985), Toward a New Economics: Essays in Post-Keynesian and Institutionalist Theory,
Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Eichner, A. (1987), The Macrodynamics of Advanced Market Economies, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Friedman, M. (1969), The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, Chicago, IL: Aldine
Publishing.
Friedman, M. (1987), ‘Quantity theory of money’, in J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman (eds),
The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Vol. IV, London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, pp.
3–20.
Friedman, M. and A. Schwartz (1963), Monetary History of the United States 1867–1960, Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hawtrey, R.G. (1932), The Art of Central Banking, London: Longmans, Green & Company.
Holt, R. and S. Pressman (2011), A New Guide to Post Keynesian Economics, London: Routledge.
Keynes, J.M. (1930/1971), A Treatise on Money, Volume 1: The Pure Theory of Money, reprinted
in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Volume V, London and Basingstoke:
Macmillan.
Keynes, J.M. (1979), The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Volume XXIX: The General
Theory: A Supplement, London and Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Krugman, P. (2018), ‘Why was Trump’s tax cut a fizzle?’, New York Times blog, 18 November,
available at https://www.nytimes.com/2018/11/15/opinion/tax-cut-fail-trump.html.
Lavoie, M., L.-P. Rochon and M. Seccareccia (2010), Money and Macrodynamics: Alfred Eichner
and Post-Keynesian Economics, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Lavoie, M. and M. Seccareccia (1999), ‘Interest rate: fair’, in P. O’Hara (ed.), Encyclopedia of
Political Economy, London, UK and New York, USA: Routledge, pp. 543–5.
McLeay, M., A. Radia and R. Thomas (2014), ‘Money creation in the modern economy’, Bank of
England Quarterly Bulletin, 54 (1), 14–27.
Phillips, A.W. (1958), ‘The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money
wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957’, Economica, 25 (100), 283–99.
Rochon, L.-P. and S. Rossi (2013), ‘Endogenous money: the evolutionary versus revolutionary
views’, Review of Keynesian Economics, 1 (2), 210–29.
Rochon, L.-P. and M. Setterfield (2007), ‘Interest rates, income distribution and monetary policy
dominance: post Keynesians and the “fair rate” of interest’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics,
30 (1), 13–41.
Rochon, L.-P. and M. Setterfield (2008), ‘The political economy of interest rate setting, inflation,
and income distribution’, International Journal of Political Economy, 37 (2), 2–25.
Rochon, L.-P. and M. Setterfield (2012), ‘A Kaleckian model of growth and distribution with
conflict-inflation and Post-Keynesian nominal interest rate rules’, Journal of Post Keynesian
Economics, 34 (3), 497–520.
Seccareccia, M. and M. Lavoie (2016), ‘Income distribution, rentiers and their role in a capitalist
economy: a Keynes–Pasinetti perspective’, International Journal of Political Economy, 45 (3),
200–23.
Sharpe, S. and G. Suarez (2014), ‘Why isn’t investment more sensitive to interest rates: evidence
from surveys’, Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No. 2014-002.
Taylor, J.B. (1993), ‘Discretion versus policy rules in practice’, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.
Taylor, J.B. (1999), ‘Monetary policy guidelines for employment and inflation stability’, in R.M.
Solow and J.B. Taylor (eds), Inflation, Unemployment, and Monetary Policy, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, pp. 29–54.
? EXAM QUESTIONS