Effects of Foreign Aid in Africa
Effects of Foreign Aid in Africa
Effects of Foreign Aid in Africa
Africa
Robert Gillanders∗
[email protected]
August 4, 2010
Abstract
This paper revisits the aid effectiveness debate. A vector autoregression model is applied
to a panel of Sub-Saharan African countries. This method allows one to analyse the
impact of foreign aid on human development and economic development simultaneously.
The results on the full sample indicate a small increase in economic growth following a
fairly substantial aid shock. The size of the effect puts the result somewhere between the
arguments of aid optimists and those of aid pessimists. Human development, as proxied
by the growth rate of life expectancy, shows a small but positive response to aid shocks.
Economic growth is found to respond more to aid shocks in groups defined by better
economic policies, poor institutions and high aid dependence. Human development
responds more to aid shocks in democracies and good institutional environments.
∗ This work, which forms part of my Ph.D. thesis, was funded by the Irish Research Council for the
Humanities and Social Sciences. I also wish to thank my supervisor, Karl Whelan, and Inessa Love, who
kindly made her PVAR Stata program available to me.
1
1 Introduction
For better or for worse, Official Development Assistance (ODA) is the main tool employed
by the rich world in its attempts to promote prosperity in the developing world. Given
the importance of this tool, it should not be a surprise that many scholars of development
consider its impacts worthy of study. Taken as a whole, the literature on aid is vast. Many
studies look at aid’s effect on growth. Others look at the effect on human development, as
proxied by variables such as the Human Development Index (HDI) or the infant mortality
rate. The problem is that the aid literature largely focuses on one issue at a time.
Why is it important to look at both elements? We all know that while GDP per capita is
a good measure of the overall state of a society (due to its high correlations with things we
actually do care about), it is far from perfect. Amongst other factors, it ignores distributional
issues, non-market activities and environmental quality. Economic development is surely
a large part of the concept of “development” but there are other elements that matter.
Other social sciences are at pains to make this point to economists, but I would argue that
we already know this. Certainly, the small but growing empirical literature on aid and
human development (which is outlined below) shows that economists are aware of the multi-
dimensional nature of development.1 The task then, is to examine both (broadly defined)
elements of development simultaneously.
A panel vector autoregression model (PVAR) allows one to do just that. Another merit of
this notoriously atheoretical approach is that, as both Easterly [2003] and Easterly, Levine,
and Roodman [2004] point out, much of this literature suffers from a lack of a formal theory
linking aid and growth to guide applied researchers in settling on an econometric specifica-
tion. It also avoids the need for instrumentation strategies which have been criticised by
some.2
Interest lies specifically with the impulse response functions (IRFs) obtained from the model.
These will show the response path of economic growth and human development to a one time
shock in foreign aid holding all other shocks at zero. To deal with concerns about biasses
that could arise from estimating the model without allowing for unobserved heterogeneity
(i.e. fixed effects), the sample is restricted to countries in Sub-Saharan Africa. These IRFs
serve as the baseline results and it is shown that these results are in line with GMM estimates
which allow for country specific fixed effects. The sample is then split into groups defined
by economic policy, institutional quality, democracy and aid dependence. This allows us to
see if aid is more effective in certain environments.
2
Several important and policy relevant results emerge from the analysis. Firstly, aid shocks do
seem to induce economic growth within the first few years following the shock. However, they
are only in the region of 1% and are tempered by some later negative responses. Secondly,
aid appears to have a small positive impact on human development, though the error bands
do not allow us to rule out that the effect is negative or non-existant. In countries with
good economic policy, the early impact of aid on economic growth jumps to about 2%,
though this is once again tempered by some negative responses later on. In democracies,
aid has a much larger impact on human development and a lower, though smoother, effect
on economic growth than in either the full sample or in autocracies. Relative to countries
with good institutions, those with poor institutional environments make more use of aid in
the economic sphere and less use of aid in terms of human development. Finally, countries
which are more dependent on aid see a better response in terms of both economic and human
development.
One of the main implications of these findings is that while aid does lead to economic growth,
the impact is not transformative and to maintain even this extra 1% growth, it would require
frequent large injections of aid. Another is that while the response of GDP per capita growth
is higher in some environments, it is not so much higher that donors could justify focusing
all aid monies on countries with these characteristics. This is further supported by the fact
that often it is the case that when aid fails to have an impact on one of the dimensions of
development in one of the sub-samples, it impacts on the other.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 outlines the existing literature.
Section 3 outlines the data and discusses issues of measurement. Section 4 describes the
econometric approach in detail. Sections 5 and 6 present the baseline and grouped results
respectively and Section 7 concludes.
There is an extensive literature that seeks to examine the impact of foreign aid on growth
and a smaller one that looks at aid’s impact on human development. Some studies have
found positive effects, some conditional effects and others no effects. Given the wide range
of findings and the debates that they have prompted, it is worth examining some of the
relevant recent papers in brief.
3
2.1 Aid and Economic Development
There are many studies that have examined the effect of aid on growth. I limit myself here
to the more recent work, both for brevity and because it adequately highlights the issues
that will be examined in Section 6. Recent work has chiefly focused on conditional aid
effectiveness.3
Burnside and Dollar [2000] reignited the aid effectiveness debate when they found that
while aid has no effect on growth on average, aid works in a good policy environment. They
include an aid*policy interaction term and find that it is statistically significant and robust to
a number of specifications. This paper launched the debate on conditional aid effectiveness.
Easterly, Levine, and Roodman [2004] recreate the Burnside-Dollar dataset and expand on
it significantly. By following the approach of Burnside and Dollar to the letter, they find
that not only is the crucial aid*policy coefficient insignificant but it has the opposite sign.
Easterly [2003] re-examine the issue in a different way. By employing Official Development
Assistance (ODA) as the measure of aid as opposed to the measure used by Burnside and
Dollar, Effective Development Assistance (EDA), Easterly finds that the aid*policy interac-
tion term is no longer significant.4 He also varies the specification of good policy and again
finds that the aid*policy term is insignificant. The crucial interaction term is also found to
be insignificant by varying the definition of growth (Burnside and Dollar defined growth as
real GDP growth over four years) to consider eight, twelve and twenty four years.
One of the best examples of support for the Burnside-Dollar result comes from Collier and
Dollar [2002]. They expand the Burnside-Dollar dataset to include 349 aid-growth-policy
episodes as opposed to the original 275. The other modification they make is to employ the
World Bank’s Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA) as their policy variable.
Their findings agree with the Burnside-Dollar result.
However, Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp [2004] question the suitability of the CPIA for growth
regressions. They include a climate*aid interaction term and find that it is negative and
significant. The aid*policy term loses its significance once climate*aid enters the specifica-
tion. They suggest that the climate variable may be a proxy for deep determinants such as
institutions. This is a significantly different conditional effectiveness result and one which
will be examined in Section 6. Given the sketch of the literature above, it will come as no
surprise that the role good policy has to play will also be investigated.
Svensson [1999] examines whether civil and political liberties play any role in aid effective-
ness. He finds that an aid*democracy interaction term is highly significant and that an
3 Roodman [2007] provides an excellent overview of the entire literature.
4 As many authors note, the two measures are highly correlated. The two are fully defined in the data
section below.
4
aid*policy term à la Burnside and Dollar is insignificant. It is important to note that he
considers, and rejects, the possibility that democracy is simply a proxy for good policies.
This suggests we should add democracy to our list of conditional results to be examined.
This sample of the aid and economic growth literature is chiefly included to motivate the
division of the sample into groups defined by economic policy, institutions and democracy in
Section 6. However, it also shows that the traditional approach of running either standard
cross-sectional or panel growth regressions augmented with aid and aid interaction terms
leads to fragile results. Indeed, the title of Roodman [2007], “The Anarchy of Numbers:
Aid, Development, and Cross-Country Empirics”, sums up the literature well. Each of the
papers is a fine econometric work, and it may be that these factors do indeed matter, but
the fragility of the results is undeniable.5 This is another motivating factor in employing
the PVAR methodology – it offers a fresh perspective.
While nowhere near as extensive as that which concerns itself with economic development,
there is a small but growing literature that seeks to empirically assess the impact of foreign
aid on human development.
Kosack [2003] finds that aid has a positive effect on HDI growth but only in democratic
countries. His estimates also suggest that aid will have a negative effect on HDI growth
in autocracies. Interestingly, he finds that democracy alone has a negative effect on HDI
growth. He interprets these findings as implying that ‘more-democratic poor countries have,
on their own, lower growth in the quality of life, but that aid to these countries may reverse
this negative tendency’ (p6).
McGillivray and Noorbakhsh [2007] examine the impact of aid on the level of the HDI and
allow conflict to enter the analysis. They find that aid alone has a negative impact on HDI
scores but disagree with Kosack [2003] in that they do not find either a negative effect of
democracy on the HDI or a positive aid*democracy interaction term.6 These two studies
gives us a second reason to divide the sample along lines of democracy.
Using quantile regression, Gomanee, Girma, and Morrissey [2005a] examine aid’s effects on
human development as measured by both the HDI and the infant mortality rate. They argue
that while aid might not have a direct impact on welfare, it may have an indirect one via
pro-poor expenditures (PPE). By constructing a PPE index they find that aid has a positive
5 Roodman examines seven leading papers in the aid-growth literature, (including Burnside and Dollar
[2000], Collier and Dollar [2002] and Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp [2004]) and finds that each of them is
susceptible to changes in the sample and in specification.
6 Rather they find that aid and conflict have negative effects on human development and that aid is no
5
impact on welfare through public expenditure and that the effect is greater in countries with
lower welfare. They also argue that good economic policy is not required for aid to be
effective in promoting human development. A related paper, Gomanee, Morrissey, Mosley,
and Verschoor [2005b], finds to the contrary that there is a direct impact of aid on human
development and little evidence of an indirect effect via PPE. It is clear that there is nearly
as much disagreement and tendency for conflicting results in the aid-human development
literature as there is in the aid-growth literature.
There are of course more works that concern themselves with the effects of aid on economic
and human development. However, the papers above provide a sufficient overview of the
evidence and suggest that it may be illuminating to examine whether aid has different effects
in groups of countries defined by economic policy, institutional quality and democracy.
Another division of the sample is inspired by Hansen and Headey [2009]. They utilise a
PVAR model to examine the short-run macro effects of aid. They split the countries in their
sample into those that are highly dependent on ODA and those that are not. In the context
of the current work, it is plausible that there is some critical level of aid dependence under
which aid cannot be effective. It is equally plausible that being overly dependent on aid
results in macro distortions or poor governance.
3 Data
The data on yearly economic growth comes from the World Bank’s World Development
Indicators (WDI).7 While economic growth is a (relatively) concrete concept, the other two
variables that will be used in this analysis are somewhat nebulous. Thus, it is good practice
to devote a little time to defining exactly what the “aid” and “human development” variables
used in the analysis actually are.
This paper uses the notation aidit to represent total net ODA per capita. This includes
flows from all donors (as measured by the OECD) to recipient i at time t. aidit is measured
in constant 2007 US dollars.8 The data come from the OECD Development Assistance
Committee (DAC).9 In choosing how to measure aid, one must make two important decisions.
7 TheWDI can be accessed at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator
8 Giventhat ODA contains concessional loans, these net flows can be negative if the repayment of loans
are greater than new loans and grants.
9 The data can be accessed at www.oecd.org/dac/stats/data
6
Firstly, what counts as foreign aid? This effectively boils down to the choice between
ODA and EDA. ODA is defined on the OECD’s website as:
“Grants or loans to countries and territories on the DAC List of ODA Recipients
(developing countries) and to multilateral agencies which are: (a) undertaken by
the official sector; (b) with promotion of economic development and welfare as
the main objective; (c) at concessional financial terms (if a loan, having a grant
element of at least 25 per cent). In addition to financial flows, technical co-
operation is included in aid. Grants, loans and credits for military purposes are
excluded. Transfer payments to private individuals (e.g. pensions, reparations
or insurance payouts) are in general not counted.”10
EDA is an adjustment to ODA that replaces the official loans component with “the grant
equivalents of official loans” and disregards grants that are tied to technical assistance.11
Although this may seem like an important modification, the two are hugely correlated.12 I
choose to use ODA as the aim of the paper is to assess the impact of the West’s efforts and
ODA is the tool they employ.
The other issue one must decide on is how to normalise the aid variable. Many studies
express aid as a fraction of GDP. In my case this would lead to a mechanical relationship
between two of my main variables of interest - aid and economic growth. To avoid this, I
divide yearly aid data by yearly population data from the Penn World Tables. Thus, aidit
is fully defined as total net ODA per capita.
One also faces two issues when attempting to quantify human development (HDit ). The
first is finding an ideologically neutral measure. While some of us would consider low
levels of poverty or inequality to be good indicators of human development, others would
disagree. Claiming either of these variables as good proxies for human development requires
one to take an implicit ideological stance.13 Using democracy or measures of government
accountability is similarly unsatisfactory.
The second problem is the lack of sufficiently long time series data relating to
human development. The UN’s Human Development Index (HDI) is equal parts economic
10 See www.oecd.org/dac/glossary
11 Chang, Fernandez-Arias, and Serven [1999].
12 Dalgaard and Hansen [2001] show that the correlation between the two (as a fraction of GDP) in nominal
terms is 0.98 and between real EDA and nominal ODA it is 0.89. They also suggest that the difference
between the two measures “seems to be a simple transformation” (p26).
13 Of course, if one set out to examine the impact of ODA on inequality or poverty then this issue of an
7
prosperity, education and life expectancy and is largely free of ideology.14 However, the series
is not of sufficient length to be usable in an analysis such as this.
I consider life expectancy to be an ideologically clean proxy for human development. While
there are other aspects to human development, a long lifespan is essential to pursue many
of them. The data series, which again comes from the World Bank’s WDI, is of sufficient
length and covers a sufficient number of countries. The specific variable, denoted as HDit ,
is the growth rate of total life expectancy at birth (in years).15
The data allows for a balanced panel of 31 countries over the period 1973-2005. The main
reason for the omission of 17 countries is GDP growth series that start too late. Some of
these data poor countries have very small populations and others had particularly turbulent
starts to their independence. The list of countries that are used in the analysis, along with
summary statistics, can be seen in Appendix A.
4 Econometric Approach
This paper is concerned with the IRFs associated with the following PVAR model:
p
X
Zit = α0 + βq Zit−q + it (1)
q=1
where Zit is the vector (aidit , growthit , HDit )’, α0 is a vector containing the constant terms,
0
βq is the matrix of coefficients for lag q and it is distributed as (0, σi2 ) with E(it is ) = 0
for all t 6= s.
This model can be viewed as the most restrictive possible in that it imposes common slopes
and common intercepts and can be estimated by Pooled Ordinary Least Squares (POLS). It
is well known that POLS yields biased and inconsistent estimates if the true data generating
process contains a fixed effect. To reduce such concerns, only countries in Sub-Saharan
Africa are considered. All countries are of course different, but these countries should form a
sufficiently homogeneous group to allow POLS estimates of the relationships between ODA,
economic growth and human development to be meaningful. Such concerns should be further
reduced by the division of the sample into the subgroups outlined above.
Less restrictive models have been estimated. The next most restrictive model allows for
heterogeneity in the relationships by allowing for country specific intercepts. This modifica-
tion leads to a dynamic panel data model with country fixed effects. Such a model can be
14 Though it is somewhat arbitrary in that it gives equal weight to each component. For more detail see
8
estimated via GMM techniques as is done by Love and Zicchino [2006]. This approach will
be used as a check on the main results.
An even less restrictive variant of equation (1) allows for both country specific intercepts
and slopes. Pesaran and Smith [1995] show that these sort of models can be estimated by
applying the Mean Group Estimator (MGE). This is the method adopted by Hansen and
Headey [2009]. However, Rebucci [2003] shows, using Monte Carlo simulations, that standard
Fixed Effects estimation performs better than MGE in a PVAR with country specific slopes
and intercepts as long as slope heterogeneity is not “relatively high”. In addition, the
simulations indicate that for MGE to be a useful alternative, the time dimension of the
panel must be longer than that which is to be found in most macroeconomic datasets.
As it is not the reduced form disturbances of equation (1) that we are interested in, we
need a method to recover the pure structural shocks. The most common way to obtain
orthogonalised shocks is to employ a Choleski decomposition which orders the shocks in a
sensible way. The channel of influence I impose is the following:
Aid shocks can impact on growth and human development contemporaneously; growth can
impact on human development contemporaneously but only influences aid flows with a lag;
human development only operates on the other two variables with a lag. The choice of
ordering is a crucial factor in any VAR exercise.16 The rationale behind the chosen ordering
is as follows:
• Donor countries (especially their bureaucrats) need time to observe and react to
changes in the recipient country. Thus aid flows will only respond to changes in
economic and human development with a lag.
• It takes time for increasing human development to translate into economic develop-
ment. It is much more plausible that economic growth can have a contemporaneous
effect on human development.
While this is only one of six possible orderings, it seems the most plausible and the sensitivity
of the results to alternative Choleski decompositions is examined in Appendix B. To interpret
any econometric results correctly, one needs some idea of how accurate they are likely to be.
To this end, 95% confidence intervals are constructed using standard Monte Carlo methods.
Finally, to determine the apropriate number of lags to include, that is the p in equation (1),
I employ standard information criteria.
16 The importance of the ordering increases with the correlation between the reduced form innovations.
9
Figure 1: Full Sample IRFs: POLS
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws.
Both the Akaike information criterion and the Schwarz-Bayesian information criterion indi-
cate that the model should include 8 lags. I will maintain this lag structure in what follows
to make each set of results fully comparable.
5.1 POLS
The IRFs obtained from the full sample of 31 countries can be seen in Figure 1. For
completeness I present all the IRFs from the system though interest only really lies with the
responses of the growth rates of GDP per capita and life expectancy to a shock in aid. Each
IRF shows the response path of the variable in question to a one time positive one standard
error increase in the estimate of the shock variable holding all other shocks at zero. The
values of the shocks can be read off the Y-axis of the diagonal elements of Figure 1 at time
zero.
10
It is, however, reassuring that the none of the other IRFs display inexplicable behaviour.
Aid tends to decline following an economic growth shock and tends to increase following a
shock to the growth of human development. It is plausible that when donors see an increase
in economic growth they scale back aid but when they see some improvements in human
development they attempt to consolidate these gains. Economic growth is slightly lower
for a few periods following a shock to human development growth – perhaps due to people
switching from economic to leisure or other non-market activities – though the effect quickly
dies out. Finally, a shock to growth increases the growth rate of human development until
about seven periods after the shock, at which point the growth of human development is
lower than it would have been. This is perhaps due to increased pollution or other retarding
influences that can arise from increased economic activity.
Turning to our main concerns, we can see that an aid shock at time zero has an immediate,
but small, positive impact on GDP per capita growth. This positive impact increases to
about 1% extra growth one period after the shock and the positive impact still exists in
period two. These short run increases in growth can be explained as increases in government
investment and perhaps consumption. The next three periods see growth that is lower than
it would have been in the absence of the intial aid shock. A plausible explanation for this
is that recipient governments treat the aid shock at time zero as a permanent increase and
are taken by surprise when it proves to be transitory. They may not be entirely wrong in
this as Figure 1 shows that the response of aid to its own shocks persists beyond fifteen
periods, though it does drop rapidly to roughly a third of the value of the shock. After
this we see a return to a positive response. This would fit with government investments on
infrastructure (made with the initial aid shock) paying off. By the 10th step the initial shock
has no more influence. The error bands are generally tight enough for us to have confidence
in the estimated response path.
So is aid effective in terms of generating economic growth? Given the results of Figure 1,
one would have to say yes. The positive responses to aid seem to outweigh the middle period
where growth is lower than it would have been. However, there are two important issues
one should bear in mind:
1. The extra injection of $33 per person is not cheap. Even at this level, the results don’t
fit the description of transformative.
2. Given that the effects die out by the 10th period, can we say that the induced growth
is sustainable?
These results thus sit somewhere between the arguments of aid optimists and aid pessimists.
Yes aid seems to be effective in that it does induce some economic development, but to make
it a promising tool for eliminating global poverty it would need frequent large injections.
11
Figure 2: Full Sample IRFs: GMM
Notes: Each panel shows the response of the indicated response variable to a one standard deviation shock in the shock variable.
Results obtained using the PVAR program kindly made available to me by Inessa Love.
So are the results in terms of human development more supportive of aid advocates? Not
really. The estimated response path is uniformly positive but very small in magnitude. That
said, the human life span is measured on a (sadly) small scale so an increase in its yearly
growth rate of even a fraction of a percent may be quite good, especially given that the
response persists until the 10th period following the initial shock. However, the error bands
allow for the possibility that the impact may be negative. The results in this respect are
thus ambiguous.
12
The results are presented in Figure 2. The IRFs only trace out the responses to six periods
after the initial shock and use a slightly different value for the shocks, but we can immediately
see that the responses to an aid shock are very similar to those obtained using simple POLS,
both in the pattern and in magnitude. The only difference of note is that a smaller aid
shock generates a larger, though still rather small, response in the growth rate of human
development. Overall we can be confident that POLS is a satisfactory method and that the
results presented in Figure 1 are valid.
6 Conditional Results
Given how influential the Burnside-Dollar result has been in donor circles, it makes sense
to use the model to see if we can find evidence of aid working better in a good policy
environment. One lesson to be taken from the literature is that often the definition of
good policy is somewhat arbitrary in what is included and once it is changed the significant
results disappear. With this in mind, I have chosen the most objective measure of economic
policy that I have come across. The World Bank’s Doing Business (DB) project collects
information across a wide variety of aspects of the business environment and ranks countries
on the overall ease of doing business. The full methodology can be found on the project’s
website.17 Here, it is sufficient to note that the surveys are as objective as possible and
cover most aspects of a countries business environment. Thus, the ranking should provide a
good proxy for overall economic policy. This is quite a different measure of policy from the
weighted indices of macroeconomic indicators that are commonly used in this literature.
I use the most recent rankings as my measure. While this is open to criticism, the data only
goes back to 2004 and each year has seen additional important variables added. I believe
that the data can safely be regarded as a good measure of a countries stock of economic
policies. I consider a country with a ranking in the top 100 to have good economic policy.
Countries below this, admittedly arbitrary, cutoff form the bad policy sample. A benefit of
17 http://www.doingbusiness.org
13
dividing the sample this way is that even if we would see countries move around somewhat
in the rankings over time had we the data, such broad ranges make it more likely that they
remain within the bounds I have set for good and bad policy.
Figure 3 presents the IRFs obtained from running the model on each of the policy groups.
The top set are for the good policy sample and the bottom set for the bad policy sample. It
will come as no surprise that only six countries made the cut for good policy.18 As mentioned
above, I continue to include eight lags in the model over all samples.
The results are not as precise as those of Section 5 but are striking nonetheless. It is worth
noting that the magnitude of the aid shock in both cases are very similar. In the good policy
group, economic growth is actually lower than it would have been at t=0 absent the aid
shock. However, by t=1 growth is between roughly 1% to 2.5% higher than it would have
been. We see the same pattern of negative response that we saw in the full sample after
t=2 with some marginal postitive responses after t=5. While the error bands do not allow
one to discount the possibility that these long lasting effects are negative, they were not
present in the full sample results. The bad policy sample responses are markedly different
and (not surprisingly given that these countries form the vast majority of the full sample)
are very similar to the full sample results. There is one big difference – between t=7 and
t=15, growth is marginally but statistically significantly lower than it would have been in
the absence of the initial aid shock.
In terms of human development, the error bands are too broad to draw much inference.
Certainly in the bad policy group the estimated effect is indistinguishable from zero with
error bands evenly distributed on either side. In the good policy group the error bands are
also too wide for the most part but we can see an unambiguously negative response for the
first two periods following the aid shock. After that we cannot say what sign the effect takes
but the positive responses seem to outweigh the negative ones.
These results suggest that, in terms of increasing GDP per capita growth, aid does work
better in a good policy environment. However, I would argue that it still does not reach
the level of transformative power that aid advocates claim. A 2% boost to economic growth
is certainly impressive but once again it is not cheap and is tempered by some negative
responses. On the other hand, the results certainly do not conform to the arguments of the
most despairing of aid pesimists. Once again we see some beneficial impact of aid, even
in countries with bad policy. In good policy environments we see a large early increase in
economic growth alongside some long lasting, albeit quite modest, benefits.
18 Appendix A shows which countries are in this and each subsequent sub-sample.
14
Figure 3: Good Vs. Bad Policy IRFs
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws. The top set is for the sample
composed of those countries which rank in the top 100 in the World Bank’s ease of doing business ranking. The bottom set is for the
sample composed of those countries which rank below 100 in the World Bank’s ease of doing business ranking.
15
6.2 Democracy Vs. Autocracy
We saw in Section 2 that there is evidence that being a democracy matters for both di-
mensions of aid effectiveness. To examine this issue using my PVAR model, I utilise the
measure of democracy created by the Polity IV project. This variable combines information
on democratic and autocratic features of a country and places them on a scale from −10
(hardcore autocracy) to +10 (hardcore democracy). This suggests a simple division of the
sample. Countries with an average Polity score (over the sample period) less than 0 are
consigned to the autocratic group. Those with a score of 0 or higher form the democratic
group.
Figure 4 shows the IRFs for both sub-samples. As was the case with the bad policy group,
the autocracy group forms the vast majority of the full sample and it is therefore unsurprising
that the IRFs are mostly very similar to the baseline results. The big difference is that we
see no appreciable impact of aid on human development. Turning to the democratic sample,
we see a relatively large response of human development to an initial aid shock. Not only is
it relatively large, it is positive and persists to the 11th step. As the shocks are once again
of very similar magnitudes, this result partially supports the findings of Kosack [2003] – aid
seems to work in terms of promoting human development only in democratic countries but
we cannot see any clear evidence of it retarding human development in autocracies.
In terms of aid’s impact on economic growth, as noted above, the autocratic sample’s re-
sponses are very similar to the full sample’s. The democratic countries response path has
error bands that are too wide to draw any firm inference but the response does seem to
be positive until the 5th period following the aid shock as opposed to the 3rd period in the
autocratic sample. After that it is generally not possible to make any inference about the
sign of the response. These results clearly do not conform with Svensson [1999]. Aid does
not seem to be more effective in promoting economic growth in democratic environments.
The next division of the sample is inspired by Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp [2004], who, as we
noted in section 2, argue that deep determinants of a society may play a big role in making
aid effective. They point specifically to institutional quality. This has enormous intuitive
appeal – good institutions should lead to a well ordered society which in turn should lead
to an effective use of resources such as foreign aid.
To investigate, I divide the sample using a standard measure of institutional quality. The
Polity IV dataset contains a variable which quantifies the constraints on the power of the
executive along a seven point scale. I define countries with an average value over the sample
period of three or higher as possessing good institutions. This is inescapably and unavoidably
16
Figure 4: Democracy Vs. Autocracy IRFs
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws. The top set is for the sample
composed of those countries with an average score of 0 or higher in the Polity index. The bottom set is for the sample composed of
17
Figure 5: Good Vs. Bad Institutions IRFs
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws. The top set is for the sample
composed of those countries with an average score of 3 or higher in the constraint on executive power variable created by the Polity
18
arbitrary to some degree, but the definition of point three on the scale suggests it is a valid
cutoff point.19
Figure 5 presents the results which suggest that good institutions do not lead to more effective
aid in terms of economic growth.20 In fact, the IRF shows very little response of economic
growth to aid. Bad institutions on the other hand, do seem to yield better aid-growth results
in the early periods following the aid shock. Compared to the baseline results, the same aid
shock gives an economic growth response that is about twice as big. As in the baseline case,
this is tempered by some negative responses after period two: negative responses which are
likewise larger than in the baseline case. We can also see that there are some marginal
negative responses after t=10 that persist until t=15. Overall, the responses of economic
growth to aid, both positive and negative, are larger in the bad institution sub-sample. The
relative impact of aid is reversed when we turn to human development. The response in
the good institutions sample is in line with the baseline results while in the bad institutions
sample we see no appreciable effect.
Why might it be the case that bad institutional environments get more economic bang for
their aid buck and less in terms of human development? One possibility is that as they are
not as constrained by legislatures representing the popular will and thus can concentrate the
aid monies in a few large scale national projects rather than having many small scale local
ones. This is all speculation and highlights the biggest drawback of the PVAR approach –
while we can see outcomes quite well, the mechanisms are completely obscured.
The final division is along lines of aid dependency. There are no firm theoretical reasons to
do so, but there are some plausible mechanisms that could relate aid effectiveness to the level
of aid dependency. It could be that a certain level of aid relative to the size of the economy
is needed for its effects to be substantial. On the other hand, it could be that high aid
dependence fosters corruption, retards reform and induces other such harmful behaviours.
There are also issues of absorption that may induce macroeconomic problems which could
limit aid effectiveness. These positive and negative potential consequences of the level of aid
dependence are not necessarily mutually exclusive. One effect may temper the other or each
could operate on different time scales.
19 “Slightto Moderate Limitation on Executive Authority: There are some real but limited restraints on
the executive.” Marshall and Jaggers [2008].
20 This result is supported if one uses the World Bank’s Rule of Law (RL) variable as the measure of
institutional quality. The Polity variable is preferred as RL is only available for relatively recent years.
The results in terms of human development are quite different however, with neither group showing much
response. Results available on request.
19
Figure 6: High Vs. Low Aid Dependence IRFs
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws. The top set is for the sample
composed of those countries with an average nominal aid to nominal GDP ratio of 15% or higher. The bottom set is for the
remaining countries.
20
While a PVAR model cannot get at these mechanisms, it would be interesting if we could
observe outcomes consistent with these arguments. There is no firm definition of aid depen-
dence. I take any country with an average nominal aid to nominal GDP ratio of 15% or
greater to be aid dependent. Once again this is somewhat arbitrary but 15% is a large slice
of any economy and the mean across the full sample was approximately 12%.
Figure 6 shows the results. The top set are for the aid dependent countries and the bottom set
for the remainder. For the most part the results in terms of aid and economic growth are very
similar to what we saw in the full sample: an aid shock induces economic growth in the early
periods in both cases followed by lower growth in the next few periods with a final positive
spike before tapering off. There are some differences worthy of note. Compared to both the
full sample and the less dependent sample, the level of the early positive responses in the
highly dependent countries are somewhat higher and the subsequent negative responses are
not as severe. Perhaps most interestingly, the responses after t=10 in the highly dependent
sample are negative and statistically significant. In the baseline case, there was no further
response after this point. In the low dependence group, we can see some small positive
induced growth persisting until the 15th period. While the model offers no explanation for
these differences, it is interesting nonetheless to see them in the data. The higher responses
in the dependent sample suggests that the first “hypothesis” above may hold. Likewise the
negative effects that become apparent only in the dependent sample could be consistent with
behavioural changes (such as corruption or postponed reform).
With regards to human development, the results from the two groups are near polar oppo-
sites. In the highly dependent countries, an aid shock increases the growth rate of human
development in a similar way as in the full sample, though the error bands once again allow
for the possibility that the effect is negative or non-existent. In the other countries, aid
shocks tend to lower the growth of human development. It is difficult to think of a reason
why this is the case and I will refrain from speculation in this instance.
7 Conclusions
This paper has been an attempt to look at whether aid is effective using a different approach
to that found in the existing literature. Given the range of contradictory findings on this
question, no single work can claim to be definitive. However, the approach taken here is free
from many of the difficulties encountered by the usual panel approach. In particular, the
PVAR method does not rest on the oft maligned instrumentation strategies used in much of
the previous work.
The results lie somewhere between the findings and arguments of aid pessimists and aid
optimists. Aid does seem to work in terms of generating economic growth but not to an
21
extent that could be called transformative. The time path of the responses in most samples
showed that the early success of aid is mitigated by some later negative responses before
a recovery and eventual petering out. Evidence was also presented that suggests that this
impact is more pronounced in countries with good economic policy. Aid does not seem to
be more effective at promoting economic development in democracies but does appear to
work better, at least initially, in what would commonly be regarded as poor institutional
environments. Economies that are relatively dependent on aid show lower negative responses
for the most part but small negative responses in later periods that one does not observe in
the less dependent sample.
The results for human development were generally ambiguous but suggest that aid may
induce small increases in the variable used as a proxy for human development, the growth
rate of life expectancy at birth. This increase was larger and unambiguous in democracies
and we also saw a fairly unambiguous positive response in good institutional environments.
Aid dependent countries see positive responses while the rest show a negative impact.
The major failing of the PVAR method is that it offers no insight into what the underlying
mechanisms generating these results might be. That said, much of this literature is based
on ad-hoc speculation and econometric specifications. The benefit of the approach is that,
as other VAR advocates point out, it lets the data speak for itself. In this case the data
seem to be making two points:
2. Aid seems to work better in terms of economic growth in some environments, but not
to such an extent that it would be sensible to focus aid only on countries with those
characteristics. It is often the case that when we see aid failing to stimulate economic
growth in one of our groupings, we see it causing human development growth and vice
versa.
22
A Summary Statistics and Sub-Sample Allocation
Country Growth rate of Growth rate of ODA ODA as a Doing Business Constraints on Polity Democracy
Life Expectancy GDP per capita per capita percentage of GDP Rank Executive Power Score
Benin 0.777 0.466 64.527 9.782 172 3 -1
Botswana -0.273 6.017 172.829 5.911 45 6 7
Burkina Faso 0.635 1.849 66.388 12.909 147 2 -4
Burundi 0.330 -0.234 56.202 18.623 176 1 -4
Cameroon 0.236 1.141 57.082 4.013 171 2 -6
Central African Rep. 0.179 -1.220 78.300 12.041 183 2 -3
Chad 0.201 1.547 56.652 11.874 178 1 -4
Côte d’Ivoire 0.393 -1.497 57.644 4.103 168 2 -6
DR Congo 0.215 -3.783 26.721 8.449 182 1 -5
Gabon 0.631 0.784 167.456 1.790 158 1 -7
Gambia 0.849 0.567 119.769 20.230 140 4 3
Ghana 0.383 0.176 46.631 7.648 92 3 -2
Guinea-Bissau 0.663 -0.149 149.697 40.479 181 3 -3
Kenya -0.052 0.292 44.148 6.366 95 3 -4
Lesotho -0.317 3.016 102.086 17.163 130 3 -2
Liberia 0.696 -3.229 75.870 24.116 149 2 -3
Madagascar 0.837 -1.480 48.313 9.553 134 4 0
Malawi 0.630 -0.037 57.742 18.609 132 2 -4
Mali 0.671 1.478 79.681 16.654 156 3 -1
Mauritania 0.462 -0.226 223.875 22.284 166 3 -7
Niger 0.785 -1.421 67.676 13.665 174 3 -2
Nigeria 0.417 0.469 4.306 0.616 125 3 -2
Rep. Congo -0.129 1.383 122.089 6.590 179 2 -5
Rwanda 0.247 1.562 75.300 18.995 67 1 -6
Senegal 0.716 -0.034 110.040 10.127 157 4 0
Sierra Leone 0.686 -0.226 50.235 15.077 148 3 -4
Sudan 0.596 1.961 47.863 4.874 154 2 -5
Swaziland -0.268 2.596 94.583 4.823 115 1 -10
Togo 0.593 -0.414 69.909 9.487 165 1 -5
Zambia -0.463 -1.498 111.299 15.371 90 3 -3
Zimbabwe -0.882 -1.099 42.201 3.500 159 4 -2
Notes: Except in the case of the Doing Business rank, values are means over the period 1973-2005. The Doing Business data refers
to the 2010 issue. To be included in the good policy sample a country must place in the top 100 in the Doing Business rankings.
The democratic sample comprises countries with a Polity democracy score of 0 or higher. The good institutions sample is populated
by countries with a constraints on executive power score of 3 or more. Aid dependent countries are defined as those with aid as a
23
B Robustness: Alternative Choleski Decomposition
Notes: Each IRF depicts the response of the row variable to a one standard error shock in the estimate of the column variable. The
upper and lower lines are 95% error bands generated using Monte Carlo simulation with 2500 draws.
As mentioned in the main text, the Choleski decomposition chosen is only one of six possible
orderings. While I believe that the restrictions are valid, it is worth while to point out that
the results are nearly identical if one uses the next most sensible, and quite different, ordering.
In particular, let us endow donor agencies with quicker reflexes and restrict aid so that it
requires at least one period to have an effect. The ordering is thus:
Given that the recovery of the structural shocks hinges on the choice of ordering, this is
an important check on the robustness of the results. Figure 7 shows that, apart from the
imposed restrictions on contemporaneous impacts, the IRFs are for all intents and purposes
identical to those found using the preferred ordering.
24
References
The World Bank. Doing Business 2010. The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank, 2010a.
Craig Burnside and David Dollar. Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review,
90(4):847–868, September 2000.
Charles C. Chang, Eduardo Fernandez-Arias, and Luis Serven. Measuring aid flows : a new
approach. Policy Research Working Paper Series 2050, The World Bank, February 1999.
Paul Collier and David Dollar. Aid allocation and poverty reduction. European Economic
Review, 46(8):1475–1500, September 2002.
C-J. Dalgaard and H. Hansen. On aid, growth and good policies. The Journal of Development
Studies, 37(6):17–41, August 2001.
Carl-Johan Dalgaard, Henrik Hansen, and Finn Tarp. On the empirics of foreign aid and
growth. Economic Journal, 114(496):F191–F216, 06 2004.
William Easterly. Can Foreign Aid Buy Growth? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3):
23–48, Summer 2003.
William Easterly, Ross Levine, and David Roodman. Aid, policies, and growth: Comment.
The American Economic Review, 94(3):774–780, 2004.
Walter Enders. Applied Econometric Time Series. Wiley, 2nd edition, 2004.
Karuna Gomanee, Sourafel Girma, and Oliver Morrissey. Aid, public spending and human
welfare: evidence from quantile regressions. Journal of International Development, 17(3):
299–309, 2005a.
Karuna Gomanee, Oliver Morrissey, Paul Mosley, and Arjan Verschoor. Aid, government
expenditure, and aggregate welfare. World Development, 33(3):355–370, March 2005b.
Henrik Hansen and Derek Headey. The short-run macroeconomic impact of foreign aid to
small states: An agnostic time series analysis, 2009.
Stephen Kosack. Effective aid: How democracy allows development aid to improve the
quality of life. World Development, 31(1):1–22, January 2003.
25
Inessa Love and Lea Zicchino. Financial development and dynamic investment behavior:
Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 46(2):190–
210, May 2006.
Monty G. Marshall and Keith Jaggers. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics
and Transitions, 1800-2008, 2008.
Mark McGillivray and Farhad Noorbakhsh. Aid, conflict and human development. Working
Papers 2007-03, Department of Economics, University of Glasgow, 2007.
M. Hashem Pesaran and Ron Smith. Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic het-
erogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1):79–113, July 1995.
Alessandro Rebucci. On the heterogeneity bias of pooled estimators in stationary var spec-
ifications. IMF Working Papers 03/73, International Monetary Fund, April 2003.
David Roodman. The anarchy of numbers: Aid, development, and cross-country empirics.
World Bank Economic Review, 21(2):255–277, May 2007.
J. Svensson. Aid, growth and democracy. Economics and Politics, 11(3):275–297, November
1999.
26