Unit 3
Unit 3
In any given period, there is an exact equality between aggregate output (production) and
aggregate income. You should be reminded of this fact whenever you encounter the
combined term aggregate output (income) (Y).
aggregate output (income) (Y) A combined term used to remind you of the exact equality
between aggregate output and aggregate income.
From the outset, you must think in “real terms.” Output Y refers to the quantities of goods
and services produced, not the dollars circulating in the economy.
Also, we are taking as fixed for purposes of this unit and the next the interest rate (r) and
the overall price level (P).
While Keynes recognized that many factors, including wealth and interest
rates, play a role in determining consumption levels in the economy, in his
classic The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money,
current income played the key role.
C = a + bY
The aggregate consumption function shows
the level of aggregate consumption at each
level of aggregate income.
The upward slope indicates that higher levels
of income lead to higher levels of
consumption spending.
marginal propensity to consume (MPC)
That fraction of a change in income that is
consumed, or spent.
C
marginal propensity to consume slope of consumption function
Y
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 6
Aggregate Consumption Function
C = C0 + mpc.Y
▪ C0: autonomous consumption
▪ mpc: marginal propensity to consume
0 100 -100
80 160 -80
100 175 -75
200 250 -50
400 400 0
600 550 50
800 700 100
1,000 850 150
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 11
Other Determinants of Consumption
▪ The assumption that consumption depends only on income is
obviously a simplification.
▪ In practice, the decisions of households on how much to
consume in a given period are also affected by their wealth, by
the interest rate, and by their expectations of the future.
▪ Households with higher wealth are likely to spend more, other
things being equal, than households with less wealth.
▪ Lower interest rates are likely to stimulate spending.
▪ If households are optimistic and expect to do better in the
future, they may spend more at present than if they think the
future will be bleak.
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 12
Vietnam Consumer Confidence Index
THINKING PRACTICALLY
1. The Save More Tomorrow Plans encourage people to save more by committing themselves to
future action. Can you think of examples in your own life of similar commitment devices you
use?
Planned Investment (I) versus Actual Investment
▪ planned investment (I) Those additions to capital stock and
inventory that are planned by firms.
▪ A firm’s inventory is the stock of goods that it has awaiting
sale.
▪ actual investment The actual amount of investment that
takes place; it includes items such as unplanned changes in
inventories.
▪ If a firm overestimates how much it will sell in a period, it will
end up with more in inventory than it planned to have.
▪ We will use I to refer to planned investment, not necessarily
actual investment.
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 15
Planned Investment and the Interest Rate (r)
Increasing the interest rate, ceteris paribus, is likely to reduce the level of
planned investment spending. When the interest rate falls, it becomes less
costly to borrow and more investment projects are likely to be undertaken.
planned aggregate expenditure (AE) The total amount the economy plans to spend in
a given period. Equal to consumption plus planned investment:
AE ≡ C + I
Equilibrium: Y = C + I
Y>C+I
aggregate output > planned aggregate expenditure
C+I>Y
planned aggregate expenditure > aggregate output
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 19
Deriving the Planned Aggregate Expenditure Schedule and Finding Equilibrium. The
Figures in Column 2 Are Based on the Equation C = 100 + .75Y.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
There is only one value of Y for which this statement is true, and we can
find it by rearranging terms:
C+S=C+I
Because we can subtract C from both sides of this equation, we are left with:
S=I
Thus, only when planned investment equals saving will there be equilibrium.
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 23
The S = I Approach to Equilibrium
Aggregate output is equal to planned aggregate expenditure
only when saving equals planned investment (S = I).
The size of the multiplier depends on the slope of the planned aggregate
expenditure line. The steeper the slope of this line, the greater the change
in output for a given change in investment.
THINKING PRACTICALLY
1. Draw a consumption function corresponding to S0 and S1 and describe what is
happening.
The Size of the Multiplier in the Real World
In considering the size of the multiplier, it is important to realize that the multiplier
we derived in this unit is based on a very simplified picture of the economy.
The size of the multiplier is reduced when tax payments depend on income (as
they do in the real world); when we consider Central Bank behavior regarding the
interest rate; when we add the price level to the analysis; and when imports are
introduced.
In reality, the size of the multiplier is about 2. That is, a sustained increase in
exogenous spending of $10 billion into the U.S. economy can be expected to
raise real GDP over time by about $20 billion.
Practice
You are given the following data concerning Kadwan, a country located in
the mountains: (1) Consumption function: C = 150 + 0.7Y; (2) Investment
function: I = 75; (3) AE ≡ C + I; (4) AE = Y.
a. What is the marginal propensity to consume in Kadwan, and what is the
marginal propensity to save?
b. Graph equations (1) to (4) and solve for equilibrium income.
c. Suppose equation (2) is changed to (2’) I = 90. What is the new
equilibrium level of income? By how much does the 15-currency unit
increase in planned investment change equilibrium income? What is the
value of the multiplier?
d. Calculate the saving function for Kadwan. Plot this saving function on a
graph with equation (2). Explain why the equilibrium income in this graph
must be the same as in part b.
Aggregate Demand and Equilibrium Output 31