Thesis
Thesis
An Operator-Theoretic Approach
John Stachurski
Department of Economics
July 9, 2002
1
Abstract: For many years the trend in macroeconomics has been towards
models which are both explicitly stochastic and explicitly dynamic. With
these models, researchers seek to replicate and explain observable properties
of the major economic time series. One manifestation of this trend towards
stochastic dynamic modeling has been increasing use of the inherently dy-
namic models developed in the field of economic growth. The latter have
proved to be suitable not only for the study of growth and development, but
also for that of many other areas within macroeconomics, such as business
cycles, fiscal policy and public finance.
On one hand, the thesis has been motivated by the availability of new and un-
exploited techniques for studying the kinds of Markovian systems generated
by these models. The techniques in question are operator-theoretic, with
a particular focus on integral Markov semigroups in the function space L1 .
They are particularly well suited to analysis of Markov chains on unbounded
state space.
On the other hand, motivation also comes from the demand side: new con-
ditions for evaluating the stability of stochastic dynamic models are valuable
2
A highlight of the thesis is a set of new sufficient conditions for the stability of
perturbed dynamical systems on the nonnegative half-ray R+ . By introduc-
ing a Lyapunov criterion, a set of general conditions is found which includes
existing work from the mathematical literature as a special case.
3
• due acknowledgement has been made in the text to all other material
used,
• the thesis is less than 100,000 words in length, exclusive of tables, maps,
bibliographies and appendices.
4
The author thanks the Economic Theory Center, University of Melbourne for
generous financial support and other assistance. The author is grateful to the
following three institutions for their hospitality during research visits: Cen-
tre de Recherche en Mathématiques, Statistique et Economie Mathématique,
Université Paris 1, Panthéon-Sorbonne; CentER, Tilburg University; and the
Institute of Mathematics, Silesian University, Katowice.
Less direct but equally important contributors to this thesis were the author’s
family, in particular Mum, Dad, Marta, Terry, Nic and Gwen; as well as
friends Aaron Bilcock, Simon Hosking, Kirdan Lees and Murdoch MacPhee.
Thank you for your love and support. Finally, the author acknowledges his
great debt to Miss Cleo Fleming, a.k.a. the lemming, who, on top of ev-
erything else, managed to sit patiently through many long and excited late-
night diatribes about integral Markov semigroups and the axioms of Hausdorff
space.
Contents
1 Introduction 9
2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.2.1 Outline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
5
CONTENTS 6
3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
3.2.1 Assumptions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
3.2.2 Technology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
3.3.1 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.3.2 Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
CONTENTS 7
4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
4.2 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65
4.3 Applications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
4.5 Proofs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
5 Asymptotic Distributions 84
5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
5.3 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
5.4 Applications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
5.5 Proofs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
CONTENTS 8
6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
6.3 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
6.4 Application . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
Introduction
The stochastic growth model, which links production to savings, and savings
in turn to investment and production, has become a benchmark model in
economics, not just for theoretical and empirical growth problems, but also
for areas ranging from business cycle theory and finance to public sector eco-
nomics and development. This thesis presents four essays which examine the
dynamic properties of a collection of well-known growth models. The pri-
mary contribution is new sufficient conditions for existence, uniqueness and
stability of stochastic equilibria. A small amount of supplementary material
considers related dynamic properties, such as the law of large numbers and
the central limit theorem.
The theme which unites the essays is our focus on operator-theoretic meth-
ods. Growth models are viewed as Markov chains, which in turn are trans-
9
CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 10
Many of the arguments are based on a framework for proving global sta-
bility of Markov operators suggested by the Polish mathematician Andrzej
Lasota [38]. Lasota implements a straightforward but relatively unknown
fixed point technique, which combines an interesting contraction condition
with a compactness notion called Lagrange stability.
Following this introduction, the thesis is divided into five main chapters
(Chapters 2–6). The first of these (Chapter 2) is an exposition of the math-
ematical framework outlined in the previous paragraph. The objective is to
set out the key ideas and definitions, in order to avoid having to repeat them
in each of the remaining theory chapters. Some of the results in this prelim-
inary chapter are—to the best of the author’s knowledge—new, and the key
proofs of existing results are also new.
When the distributions of the state variables in a Markov chain converge over
time to a unique limiting distribution, one can perhaps anticipate that if, for
example, one takes a sufficiently long time series from that model and calcu-
lates the average value, then that value should be close to the mean of the
limiting distribution. The third essay (Chapter 5, based on the manuscript
“Stochastic Growth: Asymptotic Distributions,” forthcoming in the journal
Economic Theory) focuses on these kinds of econometric questions. More
precisely, we seek sufficient conditions for globally stable stochastic growth
CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 12
models to also have law of large numbers and central limit theorem proper-
ties. Again our treatment admits the standard econometric shocks. Instead
of restricting the support of shocks, we require a rather strong “average con-
traction” condition on technology.
These two criteria are in a sense conflicting. For example, a very general
sufficient condition for a given model to have property P is property P .
Obviously the condition is sufficient (P implies P ). Moreover, the condition
characterizes the class of models that have property P (not P implies not P ).
CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 13
Yet it is clear that this sufficient condition does not give the researcher who
seeks to verify property P in a specific model much additional information.
The objective of the author has been to balance the two criteria. On one
hand, the conditions contained here often extend existing work. On the other
hand, it is hoped that the conditions will prove easy for applied researchers
to verify, being stated in a mathematical language which is familiar to the
non-theorist.
Extensive literature reviews are included at the beginning of each essay. How-
ever, the thesis as a whole was particularly influenced by the following work.
On the economic side, the most important reference was without doubt the
classic stochastic optimal growth paper of Brock and Mirman [10]. In addi-
tion, Mirman published a number of papers around the same time which all
focused on the dynamic properties of stochastic neoclassical economies with
convex (i.e., decreasing returns) technology [44, 45].
On the mathematical side, the greatest influence on this thesis has been
the work of Andrzej Lasota, a functional analyst at the Polish Academy of
CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 14
Science. In particular, the author has made extensive use of Lasota’s invari-
ant principle for Markov semigroups [38], as well as various ideas from his
monograph on the L1 approach to dynamic systems with M. C. Mackey [40].
Chapter 2
2.1 Introduction
15
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 16
In this thesis we treat precisely the same problem, but use a different set of
techniques that have evolved recently in the applied mathematics, physics
and biology literature. In this preliminary chapter, a rather detailed intro-
duction to these mathematical techniques is given.
Much of the early L1 theory is due to Hopf [29]. The monograph of Foguel
[20] contains an extensive survey of asymptotic results. Lasota and Mackey
[40] use L1 techniques to study perturbed and chaotic systems. Operator-
theoretic treatment of Markov processes begins with Krylov and Bogolioubov
[35]. See also Kakutani and Yoshida [33]. Recently the most active work
within the L1 framework is that being conducted by a team of Polish math-
ematicians led by A. Lasota [38].2
This section gives a broad and heuristic overview of the mathematical tech-
niques used in the thesis. The discussion is intended to be intuitive rather
than rigorous. In particular, no definition of integral is given, and mathe-
matical objects are referred to without attempting to prove that they do in
fact exist. Formal arguments begin in Section 2.3.
2.2.1 Outline
identified with points on the unit sphere in the space of integrable functions.
(The set of densities coincides with the intersection of the positive cone and
the boundary of the unit sphere.) Thus any stable stochastic equilibrium
can be viewed as a point on this infinite dimensional sphere to which nearby
points are attracted as time evolves.
xt+1 = T xt , T : X → X. (2.3)
The map T encodes the structure of the economic system, which is in turn
determined by the primitives of the model, such as preferences, technology
and market conditions. A realization or trajectory for the system is a se-
quence (T n x) in X generated by iterating the map T on initial state x.3 An
equilibrium is a fixed point of T on X.
3
Here T n x is defined recursively by T n x = T (T n−1 x), T 1 x = T x.
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 21
ST (x∗ ) = {x ∈ X : T n x → x∗ (n → ∞)}.
xt+1 = T xt
xt+2
xt
Suppose now that the system (2.3) is perturbed at each transition from state
xt to state xt+1 by serially uncorrelated, X-valued shock εt with distribution
given by density ψ:
T xt
xt+1 = T xt + εt
T xt+1
xt xt+2
Z
ϕt+1 (xt+1 ) = p(xt , xt+1 )ϕt (xt )dxt (2.6)
In analyzing the behavior of the sequence (ϕt ), one possibility is to use stan-
dard techniques from the classical theory of Markov processes.6 However, it
is also possible to frame the same problem as a semidynamical system. The
idea is to re-interpret the state space to be the collection of all densities on
X. Call this set D. The other half of the pair is the operator (call it P ) that
6
See, for example, Shiryaev [52, Chapter 8].
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 24
ϕt+1 = P ϕt , P : D → D. (2.7)
But the recursion (2.7) is now in exactly the same formula as the determin-
istic system (2.3), which means that similar techniques can be applied to its
analysis. This translation of the perturbed system (2.4) into a deterministic
map on the space of density functions is called the L1 approach to Markov
processes. Evolution of the economy is characterized by a sequence of densi-
ties generated by iterating P on some initial density ϕ0 . An equilibrium is a
fixed point of the semidynamical system (D, P ). The economy has a unique,
globally stable equilibrium whenever (D, P ) is asymptotically stable in the
sense of Definition 2.1, 21.
These definitions are consistent with those used in previous studies.7 How-
ever, the space of possible states D and hence equilibria has been constructed
to include only those distributions that can be represented by density func-
tions. Thus probability mass cannot be concentrated at a point. In partic-
ular, this means that the model does not include the deterministic system
as a special case; the distribution of the disturbance term ε must be non-
degenerate.
7
The operator P is analogous to T ∗ in Brock and Majumdar [9, Eq. (4.3)], Futia [21,
p. 380], and Stokey et al. [58, Eq. (2), p. 213], and to T in Hopenhayn and Prescott [28,
p. 1392].
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 25
Further, let L1 (µ) be the space of µ-integrable real functions on the mea-
surable space (X, B). As usual, L1 (µ) is interpreted as a Banach lattice of
equivalence classes; functions equal off a µ-null set are identified. A density
R
function on X is an element ϕ ∈ L1 (µ) such that ϕ ≥ 0 and ϕ = kϕk = 1.
The set of all density functions is denoted D(µ).
The sets M and L1 (µ) are related in that L1 (µ) is isometrically and lattice
isomorphic to that subset of M (call it Mµ ) which is absolutely continuous
with respect to µ. The relevant isomorphism is Radon-Nikodým (RN) differ-
entiation. In what follows the two sets L1 (µ) and Mµ are identified; we do
8
In other words, M is the class of countably additive real functions on B. For a
definition of the total variation norm, see, for example, Stokey et al. [58, Section 11.3], or
Futia [21, p. 380].
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 26
xt+1 = T (xt , εt ).
Intuitively, the probability that the state variable is in B next period is the
sum of the probabilities that it travels to B from x across all x ∈ X, weighted
by the probability νt (dx) that x occurs as the current state.
Following Futia [21], Stokey et al. [58] and other authors, the relationship
(2.9) is redefined in terms of operators. Suppose we define an operator
P : M 3 ν 7→ P ν ∈ M by
Z
P ν(B) = N(x, B)ν(dx). (2.10)
It follows from (2.9) and (2.10) that if νt is the distribution for the current
state xt , then P νt is the distribution for the next period state xt+1 .
Evidently P is linear and also positive, in the sense that it maps the positive
cone of M (i.e., the finite measures on B) into itself. In addition, P P ⊂ P,
10
The distribution for the entire stochastic process (xt )t≥0 can be constructed uniquely
from the transition kernel and an initial value x0 [52, Theorem II.9.2]. The real number
νt (B) is the probability that this distribution assigns to the event xt ∈ B and xs ∈ X for
all other s 6= t.
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 28
This equilibrium concept is entirely standard.12 The real number ν ∗ (B) gives
the probability of being in Borel set B in this period, assuming that the
current distribution is ν ∗ . The value P ν ∗ (B) gives the probability of being
in B next period, given that the current distribution is ν ∗ . The equality of
ν ∗ (B) and P ν ∗ (B) for each B ∈ B therefore implies that the probability law
ν ∗ , once reached, is the law that governs the economy in the next and indeed
all subsequent periods.
Note, however, that stability is defined here in terms of the norm topology.
Existing techniques typically obtain only weak or weak-star stability.13
The framework introduced so far essentially follows Brock and Majumdar [9],
Futia [21], Stokey et al. [58] and other previous work in economics. However,
in this section we diverge slightly, approaching Markov chains generated by
(2.4) using the L1 method [29]; stochastic processes are studied by analyzing
evolution of density functions which represent the marginal distributions of
current and future state variables. The advantage is that we can exploit a
very useful technique for studying Markov chains in L1 due to Lasota [38].
Embedding the Markov problem in the function space L1 (µ) requires that
12
See, for example, Brock and Mirman [10, p. 492], Futia [21, p. 377] or Stokey, Lucas
and Prescott [58, pp. 317–8].
13
Using coarser topologies is not a free lunch. After all, in every infinite dimensional
normed space U , there exists a sequence of points all with norm one such that the sequence
converges to the zero element in the weak topology induced by the norm dual of U .
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 30
In the chapters that follow this assumption will be verified for different con-
ditions on T and Ψ.
Let Assumption 2.1 hold, implying the existence of p. Using p, the Markov
operator P corresponding to (T, Ψ) can now be reinterpreted as a linear
self-mapping on the function space L1 (µ). Specifically, if h ∈ L1 (µ), then
Z
P h(y) = p(x, y)h(x)dx. (2.11)
The two definitions (2.10) and (2.11) of P are equivalent for the absolutely
continuous measures Mµ ⊂ M when these measures and their RN derivatives
in L1 (µ) are identified. That is, if h ∈ L1 (µ) is the RN derivative of λ ∈ Mµ ,
then P h defined by (2.11) is the RN derivative of P λ defined by (2.10). To
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 31
= P λ(B).
Note that P D(µ) ⊂ D(µ), as can be shown directly using Fubini’s theorem.
Thus P is indeed a Markov operator (on L1 ) in the sense of Definition 2.2,
page 28. As before, if ϕ is the current marginal density for the state variable,
then P t ϕ is that of the state t periods hence. Evolution of such a sequence
of density functions is illustrated in Figure 2.3 for the case X = R.
P P
ϕt ϕt+1 ϕt+2
if there exists no other fixed point of P in the space D(µ), and globally stable
if P t ϕ → ϕ∗ in the L1 (µ) metric as t → ∞ for every ϕ ∈ D(µ).
This section considers some fixed point and stability results for arbitrary
semidynamical systems. The key notions we will use are Lagrange stability
and strong contractiveness.
While the ideas in this section draw heavily on Lasota [38], the approach and
the proofs are presented here for the first time.
Lagrange stability has been used extensively in the study of nonlinear differ-
ential equations and iterated function systems. Lagrange’s original stability
work was on the N -body problem of planetary motion. He showed that a
first-order approximation of the system does not grow without bounds. The
concept of Lagrange stability retains this meaning.
A fixed point result for Lagrange stable systems is now stated. An alter-
native proof based on spectral decomposition can be found in Lasota and
Mackey [40, Proposition 5.4.1], although the notation and formulation is
somewhat different. Here a new proof is offered based on an infinite dimen-
sional Brouwer (i.e., Schauder) fixed point theorem.14
Proof. Take any x ∈ U . Define γ(x) to be the set of all points T n x, n ∈ N; let
γ̂(x) be its convex hull; and let cl(γ̂(x)) be the closure of the latter. Since the
convex hull of a precompact set in V is again precompact [1, Theorem 5.20],
it follows that γ̂(x) is precompact. Since the closure of a precompact set is
compact, cl(γ̂(x)) must be compact. Using the linearity of T , if a ∈ γ̂(x),
then evidently T a is again in γ̂(x), or T γ̂(x) ⊂ γ̂(x). But then T cl(γ̂(x)) ⊂
cl(γ̂(x)). The reason is that if A is any set with T A ⊂ A and A0 is the
closure of A, then T A0 ⊂ A0 , because a0 ∈ A0 implies the existence of a
14
Schauder: Every self-mapping invariant on a nonempty compact convex subset of a
locally convex Hausdorff space has at least one fixed point in that set.
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 35
Remark 2.2. Note that Lagrange stability is quite a bit stronger than we
actually require in the proof. Lagrange stability has been used here because
of its relationship with subsequent results.
Proof. This result is already known [32, Theorem 4.1.6, Corollary 1], but we
include a proof for completeness. The stability part of the proof may be new.
Uniqueness has already been proved above. Consider the problem of exis-
tence. Define r : U → R by r(x) = %(T x, x). Evidently r is continuous. Since
U is compact, r has a minimizer x∗ . But then T x∗ = x∗ , because otherwise
T x∗ minimizes r on U .
= lim %(T T nk x, x∗ )
k
= lim αnk +1 = α,
k
Integration obtains
Z Z
kP f k = |P f |dµ ≤ P |f |dµ = kf k.
triangle inequality,
kP ϕ − P ϕ0 k = kP (ϕ − ϕ0 )k
Z Z
= p(x, y)[ϕ(x) − ϕ0 (x)]dx dy
Z Z
< p(x, y)[ϕ(x) − ϕ0 (x)] dx dy
Z Z
= p(x, y)|ϕ(x) − ϕ0 (x)|dx dy
Z Z
= p(x, y)dy|ϕ(x) − ϕ0 (x)|dx
= kϕ − ϕ0 k,
Lasota [38, Theorem 4.1] has made the important insight that in the case of
integral Markov operators such as (2.11), it is sufficient to prove that {P t ϕ :
t ≥ 0} is weakly precompact for every ϕ ∈ D(µ). The reason is that integral
Markov operators map weakly precompact subsets of L1 (µ) into strongly
precompact subsets.17 Therefore, if {P t ϕ : t ≥ 0} is weakly precompact,
then {P t ϕ : t ≥ 1} is strongly precompact. But then {P t ϕ : t ≥ 0} is also
strongly precompact.
17
This result appears to be due to A. Krasnosielski.
CHAPTER 2. EQUILIBRIA OF MARKOVIAN MODELS 41
In fact Lasota [38, Proposition 3.4] has used a Cantor diagonal argument to
show that weak precompactness of {P t ϕ : t ≥ 0} need only be established
for a collection of ϕ such that the norm closure of the collection contains
D(µ).
Therefore,
Proof. The proof is immediate from Theorem 2.2, Lemma 2.3 and Proposi-
tion 2.1.
σ-finite measure space (X, B, µ), a collection of functions {fα }α∈Λ in L1 (µ)
is a weakly precompact subset of that space if and only if it is norm bounded
and the following two conditions hold:
Evidently it is sufficient to verify that these conditions are satisfied for all
but a finite number of the collection {fα }.
Chapter 3
3.1 Introduction
This first essay studies equilibria in the stochastic optimal growth economy
of Brock and Mirman [10], but without the assumption that the shock which
perturbs production is realized within a bounded interval. It provides suffi-
cient conditions for existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibria in terms
of the primitives of the one-sector model, namely the utility function u, the
per capita production function f and the distribution ψ of the disturbance
term ε.
The original work of Brock and Mirman extends the deterministic optimal
growth problem of Ramsey [50], Cass [11], Koopmans [34] and others to a
stochastic setting. With regard to equilibria, they show that the existence,
43
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 44
uniqueness and stability results of the deterministic case are also realized
in a stochastic model under similar assumptions on preferences and produc-
tion technology. In their analysis, the productivity shock is restricted to a
bounded interval of the real line.1
rate is exogenously given, and the conditions are not stated in terms of the
primitives u, f and ψ. Further, the problems of uniqueness and stability
are not treated. In the present essay, conditions for existence, uniqueness
and stability are obtained in terms of the triple (u, f, ψ) and the restrictions
imposed by optimizing behavior.
The mathematical techniques used in the essay are based on recent innova-
tions in the theory of perturbed dynamical systems. The two key concepts
are Lagrange stability and strong contractiveness.
The structure of the essay is as follows. Section 3.2 formulates the stochastic
optimal growth problem. Section 3.3 states the main result. The proof is
then developed over Sections 3.4–3.5.
3.2.1 Assumptions
has finite mean E(ε). In addition, ε satisfies E(1/ε) < 1. The shock is less
R1
than one with positive probability, i.e. 0 ψ(x)dx 6= 0.
3.2.2 Technology
The conditional density for next-period output given income x and consump-
tion c is, by a change of variable argument,
y 1
y 7→ ψ . (3.1)
f (x − c) f (x − c)
Given that f (0) = 0, (3.1) is not defined when consumption is equal to in-
come. In this case (when c = x), next-period income is zero with probability
one. Such a probability cannot be represented by a density. Consequently,
the fully specified technology associating savings x − c to next-period income
will be defined by probability B 7→ Q(x, c; B), where
Z
y 1
Q(x, c; B) = ψ dy.
B f (x − c) f (x − c)
Future utility is discounted geometrically at rate β ∈ (0, 1). The agent selects
a sequence (ct ) to solve " ∞
#
X
max E β t u(ct ) (3.2)
t=0
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 48
Here Egx signals integration with respect to the (well-defined and unique)
Markovian distribution over infinite-dimensional sequence space RN+ gener-
ated by Markov transition kernel Q(x, g(x); dy).3
3
See, for example, Hernández-Lerma and Lasserre [26].
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 49
V 0 (x) = u0 (g(x)).
4. If g is an optimal policy, then 0 < g(x) < x, ∀x > 0, and both x 7→ g(x)
and x 7→ x − g(x) are nondecreasing (savings and consumption both
increase with income).
Proof. See, for example, Mirman and Zilcha [46, p. 331–2]. (For a formal dis-
cussion of Markov control programs with unbounded reward see Hernández-
Lerma and Lasserre [27, Chapter 8].) Here parts 1–3 of the theorem =⇒ part
4.
Substitution of the optimal control into the production relation yields the
closed-loop law of motion
It is now possible to state our main result, which gives sufficient conditions
for existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibria in the stochastic growth
model of the previous section. It shows that the original results of Brock
and Mirman also hold for many of the standard (unbounded) shocks used in
mathematical statistics.
The proof is developed in stages through the remaining sections. The ap-
proach is to represent the economy (u, f, ψ) as a semidynamical system and
then apply the concepts of Lagrange stability and strong contractiveness.
The proof of Lagrange stability (Proposition 3.1, p. 57) constitutes the main
technical contribution of the essay. As expected, the Inada conditions and
the concavity of the program are crucial to the proof.
4
See Definition 2.4, page 31.
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 51
3.3.1 Examples
Let f and u satisfy Assumptions 3.1 and 3.2 respectively, and let the density
ψ of ε be lognormal. In other words, ln ε is normally distributed with mean
m and variance σ 2 , σ > 0. Since E(1/ε) = exp(σ 2 /2 − m), E(1/ε) < 1 if
σ 2 /2 < m. In this case, all of the components of Assumption 3.3 are also
satisfied, and (u, f, ψ) has at least one equilibrium. In addition, the density
function is everywhere positive. It follows from part 2 of the theorem that
the equilibrium is unique and globally stable.
In fact the same result holds for any lognormal shock. To see this, let m and
σ be arbitrary, σ > 0, and let θ be a constant strictly larger than E(1/ε).
If ε∗ = θε, f ∗ = (1/θ)f and ψ ∗ is the distribution of ε∗ , then (u, f ∗ , ψ ∗ )
satisfies Assumptions 3.1–3.3 and all of the conditions of the theorem. Hence
(u, f ∗ , ψ ∗ ) has a unique, globally stable equilibrium. But
1
f ∗ (x − c)ε∗ = f (x − c)θε = f (x − c)ε,
θ
so (u, f, ψ) and (u, f ∗ , ψ ∗ ) are identical.5 It follows that (u, f, ψ) also has a
unique, globally stable equilibrium.
3.3.2 Remarks
The restriction
Z ∞
1
E(1/ε) = ψ(x)dx < 1 (3.4)
0 x
5
More formally, both economies have the same density kernel.
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 52
used in the theorem has a simple interpretation. Previous work has assumed
that ε is realized in a compact interval [a, b], 0 < a ≤ b < ∞. Here, in con-
trast, the shock may be arbitrarily large or arbitrarily close to zero. Equation
(3.4) implies that ε is “unlikely” to be very close to zero, or, in other words,
that the left-hand tail of the density ψ is relatively small. To see this, define
for nonnegative summable function V and for density h on R++ the (possibly
infinite) number
Z
E(V |h) = V (x)h(x)dx, (3.5)
R++
implying
E(V |h)
Z
h(x)dx ≤ . (3.6)
R++ \Ga a
This is in fact a version of Chebychev’s inequality. Substituting I −1 : x 7→ x−1
for V , ψ for h and 1/r for a gives
Z r
ψ(x)dx ≤ rE(1/ε).
0
It has also been assumed that E(ε) is finite. This is a restriction on the
right-hand tail. To see this, substitute I : x 7→ x for V and ψ for h to obtain
Z ∞
E(ε)
ψ(x)dx ≤ . (3.7)
a a
operator associated with (3.8) by (2.11). The semidynamical system for the
Brock-Mirman process is then (D(µ), Q). If initial income x0 is distributed
according to ϕ0 , then time t income is distributed according to Qt ϕ0 .
The proof of Theorem 3.2 proceeds as follows. After some preliminary results,
Lagrange stability of the semidynamical system associated with (u, f, ψ) is
established. Next, strong contractiveness of the economy is established using
the additional hypothesis of positivity of ψ. The proof is then completed in
Section 3.5.2.
This first lemma is required in the proof of Lagrange stability of the semidy-
namical system (D(µ), Q) associated with (u, f, ψ).
6
For a kernel estimated nonparametrically from actual growth data see Quah [48, Fig-
ures 5 and 6].
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 55
xt
xt+1
where the first inequality follows from the fact that V is nondecreasing and
the second from the fact that V is concave. Thus,
Z 1
0 0 0
V (x) ≥ V (f (x − g(x)))f (x − g(x))M, M = β zψ(z)dz.
0
We claim that D has the desired properties. To see that D is dense in the
densities, fix ϕ ∈ D(µ) and define h0k = 1(1/k,k) ϕ. Since kh0k k ↑ 1 by the
monotone convergence theorem, it follows that for some K ∈ N, kh0k k > 0
whenever k ≥ K. For all such k define
For notational simplicity define q(x) = f (x − g(x)). Use will be made of the
fact that
1 1
E(1/ε) ≤ γ + C (3.10)
q(x) x
for all positive x, where γ and C are nonnegative constants, γ < 1.
To verify (3.10), recall that ∃x0 > 0 such that q(x) ≥ x when x ≤ x0 by
Lemma 3.1. Choose any γ such that E(1/ε) < γ < 1. Then
1 1
E(1/ε) ≤ γ , ∀x ≤ x0 . (3.11)
q(x) x
C
E(I −1 |Qn h) ≤ γ n E(I −1 |h) + ,
1−γ
C
E(I −1 |Qn h) ≤ 1 +
1−γ
Now fix any ε > 0. According to the Dunford-Pettis condition part (i), we
require a δ > 0 and a K ∈ N such that n ≥ K implies
Z
Qn h(x)dx < ε
A
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 60
Evidently,
ε
G(x) < whenever x ≤ α.
2
Now consider the case where x > α. Select δ 0 > 0 such that
Z
0 ε
µ(B) < δ =⇒ ψ(z)dz < .
B 2
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 61
when µ(A) < δ and n ≥ K. Thus part (i) of the Dunford-Pettis condition
holds for the collection (Qn h)n≥K .
Next, part (ii) of the condition needs to be checked for the same h. Let I be
the identity map on R++ . We have
Z ∞
n
E(I|Q h) = yQn h(y)dy
Z0 ∞ Z ∞
y 1 n−1
= y ψ Q h(x)dx dy
0 0 q(x) q(x)
Z ∞ Z ∞
y 1
= ψ ydy Qn−1 h(x)dx
q(x) q(x)
Z0 ∞ 0
= E(ε)q(x)Qn−1 h(x)dx
Z0 ∞
≤ E(ε)f (x)Qn−1 h(x)dx.
0
Since E(ε) is finite, it follows from the concavity and Inada conditions in
Assumption 3.1 that x 7→ E(ε)f (x) can be majorized on R++ by an affine
CHAPTER 3. OPTIMAL GROWTH WITH UNBOUNDED SHOCK 62
function with slope less than one. In other words, there exist nonnegative
constants a and b, a < 1, such that E(ε)f (x) ≤ ax + b, ∀x > 0. Therefore
Z ∞ Z ∞
n−1
E(ε)f (x)Q h(x)dx ≤ [ax + b]Qn−1 h(x)dx
0 0
= aE(I|Qn−1 h) + b.
b
E(I|Qn h) ≤ an E(I|h) + ,
1−a
b
E(I|Qn h) ≤ 1 +
1−a
By (3.6),
∞
E(I|Qn h)
Z
Qn h(x)dx ≤
r r
for any n and any positive r. Hence
Z ∞
n 1 b
Q h(x)dx ≤ 1+ , n ≥ M,
r r 1−a
and condition (ii) of the Dunford-Pettis condition holds for {Qn h}n≥M .
Proof. The result follows immediately from implied positivity of the density
kernel (3.8) and Lemma 2.3, page 39.
4.1 Introduction
64
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 65
which in turn provides foundations for real business cycle and other macroe-
conomic literature.
While (4.1) excludes a larger model architecture than previous studies of the
equilibrium problem, it is demonstrated that the additional structure can be
exploited to obtain results that have considerable generality within this class.
Further, our approach leads naturally to sufficient conditions stated directly
in terms of the primitives g and ε; such conditions are easy to verify in
applications. Third, the temptation to compactify the state space is resisted,
permitting incorporation of standard econometric shocks. Fourth, equilibria
are realized as fixed points of a contractive linear operator, and are therefore
amenable to approximation by numerical methods.
The stability of (4.1) has previously been studied in the mathematical litera-
ture. In particular, there exists a well-known set of sufficient conditions due
to K. Horbacz [30, Theorem 1]. The results obtained here provide a general
principle which yields the conditions of Horbacz as a special case.
The essay proceeds as follows. Section 4.2 states our results. Section 4.3
gives applications. Section 4.4 formalizes the problem as a preliminary to
the proofs. The proofs are collected in Section 4.5.
4.2 Results
In this section we state new stability results for the economy on R+ defined
by (4.1). The results pertain to the existence, uniqueness and stability of
stochastic equilibria. Our definition of this property is the standard one:
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 66
Our basic assumptions on the structure of the model (4.1) are as follows.
First,
Assumption 4.1. The shocks (εt ) are uncorrelated and identically dis-
tributed by density function ψ on R+ .
Second,
1
Thus we accommodate the possibility that g may be zero at a finite number of points.
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 67
The function V in Condition 4.1 is large at 0 and +∞. The condition should
be interpreted as a restriction on the probability that the state variable moves
toward these limits without bound.
Condition 4.3 also holds for the lognormal, exponential, χ-squared, gamma
and Weibull distributions. The condition is used here to bound the proba-
bility that ψ assigns to closed intervals in R+ \ {0}.
The proofs of Theorems 4.1 and 4.2 are given in Section 4.5.
Proof. Evidently Condition 4.4 is also satisfied if Assumption 4.2 holds and
g is weakly monotone increasing on R+ . Theorem 4.2 then implies the stated
result.
4.3 Applications
We analyze the dynamics of two capital accumulation models using our meth-
ods. One is a standard overlapping generations model, while the other is of
optimal growth with externality-driven increasing returns.
The framework is as follows. Agents live for two periods, working in the
first and living off savings in the second. Savings in the first period forms
capital stock, which in the following period will be combined with the labor
of a new generation of young agents for production under the technology
yt+1 = F (kt , `t )εt , where y is income, k is capital and ` is labor input. For
convenience we assume that labor is constant (`t = `), and set f (k) = F (k, `).
Following Galor and Ryder [22, p. 362], we assume that f : R+ → R+ has
the usual properties f (0) = 0, f ∈ C 2 , f 0 > 0, f 00 < 0, and
As Galor and Ryder point out [22, Lemma 1, p. 365], restrictions on the
utility function are necessary to obtain unique self-fulfilling expectations.
Here it is assumed that agents maximize utility
subject to the budget constraint c0t+1 = (wt − ct )(1 + rt+1 ), where c (respec-
tively, c0 ) is consumption while young (respectively, old), wt is the wage and
rt is the interest rate. In this case optimization implies a savings rate from
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 70
wage income of β/(1 + β), whence kt+1 = (β/(1 + β))wt . Assuming that
labor is paid its marginal factor product yields the law of motion
β
kt+1 = [f (kt ) − kt f 0 (kt )]εt . (4.2)
1+β
Proposition 4.1. Assume that the Galor-Ryder condition (GR) holds. If,
in addition, E(ε) < ∞ and E(1/ε) < β/(1 + β), then the economy (4.2) has
a unique and globally stable stochastic equilibrium.
Remark 4.1. As in Chapter 3, Section 3.3.2, the bound E(1/ε) < β/(1 + β)
is used to restrict weight in the left-hand tail of ψ, preventing the economy
from collapsing to zero as a result of adverse shocks.
Proof. We verify that (4.2) satisfies the conditions of Corollary 4.1. To this
end, let D = β/(1 + β), let h(k) = f (k) − kf 0 (k) and let g(k) = Dh(k). It
follows from our assumptions on f that the function k 7→ h(k) is zero at zero,
continuously differentiable, strictly increasing and satisfies limk↓0 h0 (k) > 1.
This last fact—which is equivalent to (GR)—implies that
Evidently Assumptions 4.1 and 4.2 are satisfied. Regarding Condition 4.1,
consider the Lyapunov function defined by V (k) = 1/k + k. We have
Z
1
V [g(k)z]ψ(z)dz = E(1/ε) + E(ε)g(k). (4.4)
g(k)
Consider the first term in the right hand side of (4.4). By (4.3),
1 1
E(1/ε) ≤ α1 , ∀k ∈ [0, δ), (4.5)
g(k) k
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 71
1 1
E(1/ε) ≤ E(1/ε) , ∀k ∈ [δ, ∞). (4.6)
g(k) g(δ)
1 1
E(1/ε) ≤ α1 + C1 , ∀k ∈ R+ . (4.7)
g(k) k
Consider now the second term in the sum (4.4). By the assumptions on f
it is clear that the function k 7→ E(ε)Df (k) can be majorized on R+ by an
affine function k 7→ α2 k + C2 , where α2 and C2 are nonnegative constants,
α2 < 1. Therefore,
Here 0 < A1 < A2 represent the state of technology, and kb is a fixed “thresh-
old” level of capital per worker.
αβA(kt )ktα
k1∗ kb k2∗ kt
A plot of the map k 7→ αβA(k)k α is given in Figure 4.1 for the Azariadis-
Drazen threshold case, in which A is a step function. As drawn, the deter-
ministic version has two equilibria, k1∗ and k2∗ .
Proposition 4.2. For a class of shocks that include the lognormal distribu-
tions, the economy (4.11) has a unique, globally stable stochastic equilibrium.
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 74
1.4
ϕ0
ϕ25
1.2 ϕ2000
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4
Proof. We verify that (4.11) satisfies the conditions of Theorem 4.1. Evi-
dently Assumptions 4.1 and 4.2 hold. By the hypotheses of the proposition,
we may assume that ψ satisfies Conditions 4.2 and 4.3, and that E | ln ε| < ∞.
Regarding Condition 4.1, let V (k) = | ln k|. The function V so constructed
is a Lyapunov function on R+ . Moreover,
Z Z
α
V [DA(k)k z]ψ(z)dz = | ln D + ln A(k) + α ln k + ln z|ψ(z)dz
≤ α| ln k| + C
= αV (k) + C,
where the x-axis is the logarithm of capital per head.4 Here ϕ0 can be
thought of as an initial distribution of a “large” number of Azariadis-Drazen
economies.
Previously a set of conditions for obtaining stability of the model (4.1) was
identified by K. Horbacz [30, Theorem 1]. Her results can be obtained as a
special case of Theorem 4.2.
The statement and proof of the above problem are somewhat tangential to
the economics (as opposed to mathematics) discussed in this chapter. As a
4
The parameters are β = 1, α = 0.5, A1 = 0.5, A2 = 2, kb = 0.6875, ε lognormal, ln ε ∼
N (0, 0.5). The densities are generated using a Monte Carlo simulation and estimated
nonparametrically by the Parzen window method with Gaussian kernel and bandwidth
0.38. Such estimates are known to converge to the true density in L1 norm for large
sample size [12]. Here each generation is represented by 200 sample points.
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 76
Prior to the proofs, a more formal definition of the model (4.1) is given. To
begin, let R be the real numbers, let B be the Borel sets of R, let R+ =
[0, ∞), and let B+ = B ∩ R+ . The Lebesgue measure is again denoted by µ.
Integration where the measure is not made explicit is taken with respect to
R
µ; integration using the symbol without subscript is taken over R+ .
In what follows we use the notation of Chapter 2, Section 2.3, where the
underlying space X of Chapter 2 now corresponds to the half-ray R+ with
the usual topology.
Let the sequence of shocks (εt ) in (4.1) be uncorrelated and identically dis-
tributed by Ψ ∈ P. We assume that Ψ is absolutely continuous with re-
spect to µ. In this case there exists a unique density ψ ∈ D(µ) satisfying
ψ = Ψ(B) for all B ∈ B+ ; ψ is the Radon-Nikodým (RN) derivative of Ψ
R
B
with respect to µ.
We wish to embed the Markov chain generated by (g, ψ) in the function space
L1 (µ). To do so requires that the transition probabilities B 7→ N(x, B) of
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 77
the Markov chain (see (2.8), p. 26) can be represented by density functions
(recall Assumption 2.1, p. 30, and the subsequent discussion).
= 0.
It follows from this discussion that the density kernel p exists, as does the
Markov operator in L1 (µ) defined by (2.11) on page 30.
5
Density kernels need be defined only up to the complement of a null set—systems
with kernels equal µ × µ-a.e. have identical Markov operators and we do not distinguish
between them in what follows.
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 78
4.5 Proofs
The main proof is based on Theorem 2.2, page 38. We show that the semidy-
namical system (D(µ), P ) associated with the economy (g, ψ) is both strongly
contracting (Definition 2.6, p. 36) and Lagrange stable (Definition 2.5, p.
33). As usual, D(µ) is treated as a metric space with the L1 norm distance.
Proof. Since ψ is strictly positive, representation (4.12) implies that the den-
sity kernel p is µ × µ-a.e. strictly positive on X × X. As stated earlier, per-
turbed dynamical systems with kernels that are equal µ × µ-a.e. have iden-
tical Markov operators. If p is strictly positive, then (D(µ), P ) is strongly
contracting by Lemma 2.3, page 39. The result follows.
Proof. Let V be the Lyapunov function in Condition 4.1. Let D be the set
of all density functions ϕ in L1 (µ) such that
Z
V (x)ϕ(x)dx < ∞. (4.13)
Regarding (i), pick any ε > 0. We exhibit a δ > 0 and an N ∈ N such that
Z
µ(A) < δ =⇒ P t f (x)dx < ε, ∀ t ≥ N.
A
R
Define E(V |g) = V g. By Fubini’s theorem,
Z
t
E(V |P ϕ) = V (y)P t ϕ(y)dy
Z Z
t−1
= V (y) p(x, y)P ϕ(x)dx dy
Z Z
= V (y)p(x, y)dy P t−1 ϕ(x)dx.
But
Z Z
V (y)p(x, y)dy = V [g(x)z]ψ(z)dz ≤ αV (x) + C
C
E(V |P t ϕ) ≤ αn E(V |ϕ) + .
1−α
C
E(V |P t ϕ) ≤ 1 + , t ≥ N,
1−α
for some N ∈ N.
The next step is to bound the first term in the sum on the right hand side
of (4.16), taking the constant a as given, and assuming that at least one of
Condition 4.3 or Condition 4.4 holds.
Assume first that Condition 4.3 holds. Using the expression for the density
kernel given in (4.12), we have
Z
P ϕ(y) = p(x, y)P t−1 ϕ(x)dx
t
Z
y 1
= ψ P t−1 ϕ(x)dx
g(x) g(x)
Z
y y 1 t−1
= ψ P ϕ(x)dx
g(x) g(x) y
M
≤ .
y
Therefore,
Z Z Z
t M
P ϕ(y)dy ≤ dy ≤ J(a)dy = J(a)µ(A),
A∩Ga A∩Ga y A
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 82
where the finite number J(a) is the maximum of M/y over the closed and
bounded interval Ga ⊂ R+ \ {0}.
We now establish the same when Condition 4.4 holds, again by bounding
the first term in the sum (4.16). Suppose first that there exists a c with
g(x) ≥ c > 0 for all x in R+ . In this case, because
Z Z Z
t
P ϕ(y)dy = p(x, y)P t−1 ϕ(x)dxdy
A∩Ga A∩G
Z Za
= p(x, y)dy P t−1 ϕ(x)dx,
A∩Ga
and because
Z Z
y 1
p(x, y)dy = ψ dy
A∩Ga g(x) g(x)
ZA∩Ga
= ψ(z)dz
A∩Ga
g(x)
Z
≤ ψ(z)dz
A∩Ga
c
Z
≤ ψ(z)dz
A
c
µ), then
Z Z
ε
p(x, y)dy ≤ ψ(z)dz <
A∩Ga A
c
2
CHAPTER 4. SYSTEMS WITH MULTIPLICATIVE NOISE 83
Finally, suppose to the contrary that while Condition 4.4 is satisfied, there
exists no c with g(x) ≥ c > 0 for all x ∈ R+ . In this case Condition 4.4
implies that g(x) ↓ 0 as x ↓ 0, and hence there exists a d > 0 such that
Z Z
ε
p(x, y)dy = ψ(z)dz ≤ for almost all x ∈ [0, d), (4.17)
A∩Ga A∩Ga
g(x)
2
owing to the fact that A ∩ Ga is bounded away from 0. For x ≥ d, g(x) ≥
c0 = min[g(d), b] > 0, where b is the positive constant in Condition 4.4.6 In
this case, an argument similar to that given above for the case g(x) ≥ c > 0
implies that
Z Z
ε
p(x, y)dy ≤ ψ(z)dz < (4.18)
A∩Ga A 2
c0
Asymptotic Distributions
5.1 Introduction
84
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 85
sums. The first question concerns a law of large numbers (LLN) result, while
the latter concerns a central limit theorem (CLT) result.
It known that both the LLN and the CLT result are realized for the general
discrete-time concave stochastic optimal growth model when the shock has
compact support [58, 17, 5, 7]. Central to the proofs is boundedness of the
productivity shock, which, in combination with Inada conditions, allow the
state space to be taken to be compact.1 When the influence of the shock is
not bounded, however, compactness of the state space fails. In this case it is
unclear whether or not LLN and CLT properties continue to hold.
which studies the LLN and CLT properties of nonlinear dynamical systems
perturbed by uncorrelated noise.2 The question of asymptotic statistical
properties for the general concave one-sector optimal growth model with
unbounded shock is left open. It is hoped that the methodology used here
can be extended to the general problem.
Section 5.2 formulates the problem and gives the major definitions. Section
5.3 provides a general stability result. Section 5.4 gives applications. Section
5.5 gives proofs.
To briefly recall the main ideas from Chapter 2, random outcomes are selected
from some measurable space (Ω, F) by probability measure P, and mapped
into X by random variable ε : Ω → X. Corresponding to ε is a finite Borel
measure Ψ ∈ P defined at B ∈ B by Ψ(B) = P[ε−1 (B)]. The measure
Ψ is called the distribution of ε, and, as usual, the distribution satisfies
f [ε(ω)]P(dω) = X f (z)Ψ(dz) for any real B-measurable function f .
R R
Ω
for all B ∈ B.3 The equilibrium is unique if there exists no other point in P
satisfying (5.2).
Suppose that the growth model (5.1) has a unique equilibrium ϕ. For the
purposes of this paper, (5.1) is said to satisfy the law of large numbers if, for
any Lipschitz function g : X → R,
N −1 Z
1 X
g(xt ) → g(x)ϕ(dx) (5.3)
N t=0
3
As before, 1B : X → {0, 1} is the characteristic function of B ∈ B.
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 88
The economy is said to have the central limit property if, for any g as above,
N −1
1 X
√ g(xt ) → N (m, σ 2 ) (5.4)
N t=0
5.3 Results
Loskot and Rudnicki [47] consider stochastic models that satisfy the following
contraction condition.
Definition 5.1. The pair (T, Ψ), where T is the map in (5.1) and Ψ is the
distribution of the shock ε, is called an average contraction with respect to %
R
if there exists a Borel function λ : X → R such that E(λ) = λ(z)Ψ(dz) < 1
and
%(T (x, z), T (x0 , z)) ≤ λ(z)%(x, x0 ), ∀x, x0 , z ∈ X.
By adapting the results of Loskot and Rudnicki and using additional restric-
tions on the space X, we obtain the following stability condition.
Theorem 5.1. Let (T, Ψ) be the stochastic dynamic economy of Section 5.2.
Let the state space X be both locally compact and σ-compact in the topology
4
A real function g on X is called Lipschitz if there exists a constant λ such that
|g(x) − g(x0 )| ≤ λ%(x, x0 ) for any x, x0 ∈ X.
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 89
metrized by %.5 If the growth model defined by the law of motion T and the
distribution of the shock Ψ is an average contraction with respect to %, and
if there exists at least one point x̄ ∈ X such that
Z
%(x̄, T (x̄, z))Ψ(dz) < ∞, (5.5)
holds, then the model also satisfies the central limit property (5.4).
5.4 Applications
Example 5.1. Consider first the unit-elastic decreasing returns model u(c) =
ln c, f : (k, ε) 7→ Ak α ε, A > 0, α ∈ (0, 1). For such a specification, the
optimal policy consumes a fraction 1 − αβ of realized output Ak α ε, implying
the law of motion
kt+1 = αβAktα εt . (5.9)
Evidently E(λ2 ) < 1 also holds. If, in addition, E[(ln ε)2 ] is finite, then (5.6)
is satisfied for x̄ = 1, and the CLT result (5.4) obtains.
Remark 5.1. The conditions E| ln ε| < ∞ and E[(ln ε)2 ] < ∞ can be viewed
as restrictions on the left- and right-hand tails of the distribution. See the
discussion in Stachurski [55, Remark 4.1].
Example 5.2. The second example is from Mirman and Zilcha [46, Example
A, p. 333]. The state space X, the shock ε, the discount factor β, the
productivity parameter A and utility u(c) = ln c are as before. Let α be a
Borel function from X into (0, 1). The production function is (k, ε) 7→ Ak α(ε) .
For such a specification, the law of motion is
Z
α(ε )
kt+1 = ᾱβAkt t , ᾱ = α[ε(ω)]P(dω). (5.10)
Ω
Moreover, E(λ2 ) < 1, and (5.6) holds for any shock ε when x̄ = 1, implying
that the CLT condition (5.4) also holds.
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 92
5.5 Proofs
For f ∈ C0 and µ ∈ M+ ,
Λ(f ) = hf, µi (5.11)
Loskot and Rudnicki [47, Theorems 1 and 3] proved that when (T, Ψ) is an
average contraction, (X, %) is complete and separable, and (5.5)–(5.6) holds,
then there exists a unique distribution ϕ ∈ P such that
Z Z Z
f [T (x, z)]Ψ(dz) ϕ(dx) = f (x)ϕ(dx), ∀f ∈ Cb , (5.12)
and, moreover, the LLN and CLT results (5.3) and (5.4) both hold for ϕ.
Every locally and σ-compact metric space is both complete and separable.
Thus to establish Theorem 5.1 it suffices to verify that the condition (5.12)
characterizes the set of Brock-Mirman equilibria under the hypotheses of the
theorem.
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 93
Lemma 5.1. Let (X, %) be a locally and σ-compact metric space, and let ϕ
be any finite Borel measure on X. The measure ϕ satisfies (5.12) if and only
if it also satisfies (5.2).
(This is just the Markov operator associated with (T, Ψ).) The operator P
is “adjoint” to P ∗ , in the sense that
hf, P µi = hP ∗ f, µi (5.13)
for every bounded Borel function f and every finite Borel measure µ ∈ M+ .
To see this, pick any B ∈ B. Evidently (5.13) holds when f = 1B . By
linearity of the inner product, (5.13) also holds when f is a step function
taking only finitely many values. This can be extended from step functions
to any bounded nonnegative Borel function by pointwise approximation and
a monotone convergence result in the usual way. Linearity then implies the
result for an arbitrary bounded Borel function f , which can always be written
as the difference between two nonnegative parts.
hP ∗ f, ϕi = hf, ϕi, ∀f ∈ Cb .
CHAPTER 5. ASYMPTOTIC DISTRIBUTIONS 94
Therefore,
hP ∗ f, ϕi = hf, ϕi, ∀f ∈ C0 . (5.14)
Linearization of Stochastic
Economic Models
6.1 Introduction
95
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 96
However, it must be recalled at all times that the linearized system is auxiliary
to the analysis: it is valuable only to the extent that it provides insight into
the dynamic properties of the true model (6.1). In this connection, we stress
that for stochastic systems such as (6.1), it is not in general legitimate to
infer such properties as existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibrium
from similar properties as they may or may not occur in the linear version.
In this final essay we begin to address this issue by giving a formal justi-
fication for log-linearization of stochastic models. It is shown that for this
particular case parallel existence, uniqueness and stability results hold for
equilibria in the original and linearized models.
Section 6.2 formulates the problem. Section 6.3 states results. Section 6.4
gives an application to the multisector macroeconomic model of Long and
Plosser. Section 6.5 gives proofs.
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 97
In this section we briefly recall the definitions of equilibria and stability for
the model (6.1). Let topological space X be the state space for (6.1). That
is, xt ∈ X for all t, and, assuming that εt also takes values in X, the map T
satisfies T : X × X → X. Let B = B(X) be the Borel subsets of X, and let
P = P(X) be the set of probabilistic measures mapping events B ∈ B into
probabilities in [0, 1]. In other words, P is the class of countably additive,
real valued functions ν on B such that ν ≥ 0 and ν(X) = 1. As before, P is
metrized by the total variation norm.
The shocks εt in (6.1) are all drawn independently according to some fixed
distribution Ψ ∈ P. Given an initial condition x0 , a shock ε0 is drawn, and
x1 is realized according to (6.1). The process then repeats. Evidently xt is
an X-valued random variable. We denote the distribution of xt by νt ∈ P.
We use again the following conventions. The symbol 1E denotes the char-
acteristic function of E ⊂ X. The notation x ∼ ν means that random
variable x has distribution ν; for function g, the notation g n means the n-th
composition of g with itself.
6.3 Results
Consider now the case where (6.1) is log-linear. Let R++ = (0, ∞). The
general form of a stochastic log-linear (log-affine) system on Rn++ = ×ni=1 R++
is
Here γ = (γi )ni=1 ∈ Rn++ , and the vector of shocks εt = (εit )ni=1 ∈ Rn++ is
assumed to be serially independent and distributed by Ψ ∈ P(Rn++ ).
6.4 Application
ogy
ai1
yi,t+1 = `biti xi1t × · · · × xaint
in
εit , i = 1, . . . n, (6.3)
1
The objective of Long and Plosser was to generate fluctuations in time series con-
sistent with the business cycle from a general equilibrium framework and without serial
dependence in external noise.
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 100
subject to (6.3) and (6.5), where β ∈ (0, 1) is a discount factor. The optimal
controls are
λi
xijt = aij βyjt , (6.6a)
λj
n
X −1
`it = λi bi λj b j L, (6.6b)
j=1
a11 a1n
y1,t+1 = γ1 y1t × · · · × ynt ε1t
.. ..
. . (LP)
an1 ann
yn,t+1 = γn y1t × · · · × ynt εnt ,
Following Long and Plosser, we can convert (LP) into a linear form and
observe global stability of the latter. By virtue of Proposition 6.1, this implies
conditions under which (LP) is itself globally stable. Formally,
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 101
Proposition 6.2. Let ε be the vector of sectoral shocks in (LP). If, for some
norm k · k on Rn , the expectation E k ln εk is finite, then the economy (LP)
has a unique, globally stable equilibrium in P(Rn++ ).
The spectral radius of any nonnegative matrix is less than or equal to the
maximum of the row sums [37, Theorem 7.2.1]. In the case of A, these sums
are all strictly less than one by (6.4). It follows that, under the hypothesis
E kε̂k < ∞, (6.7) has a unique, globally stable equilibrium in P(Rn ).
But then E k ln εk < ∞ implies that (LP) has a unique, globally stable
equilibrium in P(Rn++ ) by Proposition 6.1.
Remark 6.1. The hypotheses of Proposition 6.2 are satisfied if, for example,
E | ln εi | is finite for each i. This condition enforces small left- and right-hand
tails on the distributions of the sectoral shocks εi . These small tails prevent
the economy from either collapsing to zero or growing without bound.
2
See, for example, Lasota and Mackey [40, Proposition 12.7.1, Theorem 12.7.2].
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 102
6.5 Proofs
In this case, (6.8) has a unique, globally stable equilibrium (i.e., fixed point
x∗ of g on X such that lim g t (x) → x∗ as t → ∞, ∀x ∈ X) if and only if (6.9)
has a unique, globally stable equilibrium. These results are well-known [3,
Section 3.3] and not difficult to verify. For example, if x∗ is a fixed point of
g on X, then x̂∗ = Hx∗ is a fixed point of ĝ on X̂, because g(x∗ ) = x∗ , and
therefore ĝ(x̂∗ ) = HgH −1 Hx∗ = Hg(x∗ ) = Hx∗ = x̂∗ .
CHAPTER 6. LINEARIZATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS 103
Thus to prove Proposition 6.1, it remains only to rewrite the nonlinear and
linear systems (NL) and (LV) in the form of (6.8) and (6.9), and show that
they commute with a suitable homeomorphism.
Consider again the generic system (T, Ψ) on X discussed in Section 6.2. Let
νt ∈ P(X) be the marginal distribution of the random variable xt , and let
νt+1 be that of xt+1 . Then νt and νt+1 are connected by the recursion
Z Z
νt+1 (B) = 1B [T (x, z)]Ψ(dz) νt (dx), ∀ B ∈ B(X). (6.10)
To repeat, the intuition is that the right hand side of (6.10) sums the proba-
bility of the state moving to B from x in one step over all possible values of
x, weighted by the probability νt (dx) of x occurring as the current state.
Denote by P and P̂ the Foias operators associated with the log-linear system
(NL) and the linear version (LV) respectively. These two systems can now
be represented as
Note that the pair (6.11) and (6.12) are in the same deterministic form as
(6.8) and (6.9). Thus to complete the proof of Proposition 6.1 we need to
establish a homeomorphism H from P(Rn++ ) onto P(Rn ) such that P and P̂
commute with H, in the sense that P = H −1 P̂ H on P(Rn++ ).
But then
Proof. Prior to the main proof we briefly recall how to integrate with respect
to the induced measure Hν [1, Theorem 12.46].
Also, note that the system (NL) can be expressed more compactly as
Hence
Z Z
(P̂ Hν)(B) = 1B (ĉ + Ax + z)(HΨ)(dz) Hν(dx)
Rn Rn
Z "Z #
= 1B (ĉ + Ax + ln z)Ψ(dz) Hν(dx)
Rn Rn
++
Z "Z #
= 1B (ĉ + A ln x + ln z)Ψ(dz) ν(dx)
Rn
++ Rn
++
Z "Z #
= 1exp B [exp(ĉ + A ln x + ln z)]Ψ(dz) ν(dx),
Rn
++ Rn
++
But the representation (6.15) shows that this is just HP ν(B), which proves
(6.16).
Bibliography
[4] Rabah Amir, A new look at optimal growth under uncertainity, Journal
of Economic Dynamics and Control 22 (1997), 67–86.
[5] Rabah Amir and Igor V. Evstigneev, A functional central limit theorem
for equilibrium paths of economic dynamics, Journal of Mathematical
Economics 33 (2000), 81–99.
107
BIBLIOGRAPHY 108
[8] Michael Binder and M. Hashem Pesaran, Stochastic growth models and
their econometric implications, Journal of Economic Growth 4 (1999),
139–183.
[10] William A. Brock and Leonard Mirman, Optimal economic growth and
uncertainty: The discounted case, Journal of Economic Theory 4 (1972),
no. 3, 479–513.
[12] Luc Devroye and Laszlo Györfi, Nonparametric density estimation: The
L1 view, John Wiley, New York, 1985.
[13] John B. Donaldson and Rajnish Mehra, Stochastic growth with correlated
production shocks, Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983), 282–312.
[16] Steven Durlauf and Danny Quah, The new empirics of economic growth,
Handbook of Macroeconomics (John B. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds.),
Elsevier Science, North Holland, 1999, pp. 231–304.
[17] Igor V. Evstigneev and Sjur D. Flåm, The turnpike property and the cen-
tral limit theorem in stochastic models of economic dynamics, Statistics
and Control of Stochastic Processes (B. L. Rozovskii Yu M. Kabanov
and A. N. Shiryaev, eds.), World Scientific, London, 1997, pp. 63–101.
[19] Jianfeng F. Feng and David Brown, Fixed-point attractor analysis for a
class of neurodynamcis, Neural Computation 10 (1998), no. 1, 189–213.
[20] Shaul R. Foguel, The ergodic theory of Markov processes, Van Nonstrad
mathematical studies, no. 21, Van Nonstrad, New York, 1969.
[22] Oded Galor and Harl E. Ryder, Existence, uniqueness and stability of
equilibrium in an overlapping-generations model with productive capital,
Journal of Economic Theory 49 (1989), 360–375.
[23] Oded Galor and J. Zeira, Income distribution and macroeconomics, Re-
view of Economic Studies 60 (1993), 35–52.
[24] Jerry R. Green and Mukul Majumdar, The nature of stochastic equilib-
ria, Econometrica 43 (1975), 647–660.
BIBLIOGRAPHY 110
[29] Bernard Hopf, The general temporally discrete Markov process, J. Rat.
Mech. Anal. 3 (1954), 13–45.
[32] Mohan C. Joshi and Ramendra K. Bose, Some topics in nonlinear func-
tional analysis, Wiley Eastern Limited, New Delhi, 1985.
[37] Peter Lancaster, Theory of matrices, Academic Press, New York, 1969.
[38] Andrzej Lasota, Invariant principle for discrete time dynamical systems,
Universitatis Iagellonicae Acta Mathematica 31 (1994), 111–127.
[41] Andrzej Lasota, Micheal C. Mackey, and Joanna Tyrcha, The statistical
dynamics of recurrent biological events, Journal of Mathematical Biology
30 (1992), 775–800.
[42] John B. Long and Charles I. Plosser, Real business cycles, Journal of
Political Economy 91 (1983), no. 1, 39–69.
[44] Leonard J. Mirman, On the existence of steady state measures for one
sector growth models with uncertain technology, International Economic
Review 13 (1972), 271–286.
[45] , The steady state behavior of a class of one sector growth models
with uncertain technology, Journal of Economic Theory 6 (1973), 219–
242.
[46] Leonard J. Mirman and Itzhak Zilcha, On optimal growth under uncer-
tainty, Journal of Economic Theory 11 (1975), 329–339.
[47] Krysztof Loskot and Ryszard Rudnicki, Limit theorems for stochastically
perturbed dynamical systems, Journal of Applied Probability 32 (1995),
459–469.
[48] Danny Quah, Convergence empirics across economies with (some) cap-
ital mobility, Journal of Economic Growth 1 (1996), 95—124.
[61] John J. Tyson and Kenneth B. Hannsgen, Cell growth and division: A
deterministic/probabilistic model of the cell cycle, Journal of Mathemat-
ical Biology 23 (1986), 231–246.
Existing Conditions
R
(iv) the mean E(ε) = zψ(z)dz is finite and, moreover, E(ε)a < 1;
(v) there exists a λ > 0 such that E[(g 0 (0)ε)−λ ] < 1; and
115
APPENDIX A. EXISTING CONDITIONS 116
Proof. Evidently Conditions 4.2 and 4.4 of the theorem are satisfied. It
remains to verify Condition 4.1. To this end, let λ be as in (v). If we set
V (0) = ∞ and V (x) = x−λ + x for x > 0, then V is a Lyapunov function on
R+ , and
Z Z Z
−λ
V [g(x)z]ψ(z)dz = [g(x)z] ψ(z)dz + g(x)zψ(z)dz. (A.1)
Consider the first term in the sum (A.1). By (v), there exists a positive
number σ so small that
Z
[(g 0 (0) − σ)z]−λ ψ(z)dz < 1. (A.2)
Regarding the second term in the sum (A.1), (iii) implies that
Z
g(x)zψ(z)dz ≤ E(ε)ax + C1 , x ∈ R+ , (A.5)