Harrassowitz Verlag
Harrassowitz Verlag
Harrassowitz Verlag
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Harrassowitz Verlag is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Asian
History.
http://www.jstor.org
INTRODUCTION
HYPOTHESES
less unable to put the State finances into any sort of order, in fact
according to Rashîd al-Dïn he led the countryto complete financial
ruin.
Furthermore,Sadr al-Dīn did not manage the State revenues any
less unscrupulously and extravagantly than did the Ilkhān himself,
as all contemporarysources are agreed. And this will be adequately
demonstrated by examples.60 On him as Sāhib Dīvān, "Minister of
Finance", devolved the duty of refillingthe State treasurywhich had
constantlybeen plundered by himself,but particularlyby Gaykhâtû
and the court. He succeeded in doing this by establishinghigh credits
which, to judge by informationsupplied by Vassāf, ran up to 500
tūmān (= 5 million gold dinārs)61 during his two years' tenure of
office.The methods by which these loan transactions were effected
were forthe most part devoid of any sound economic foundation,and
as they began to have an unprecedentedeffecton the whole economic
life of the time they led to a certain anarchy which was not to be
remedied until Ghāzān introduced his reforms.Without subscribing
entirelyto Rashīd al-Dīn's unconditionalcondemnationof the practices
of Sadr al-Dīn and his period, one can in general agree with his asser-
tion if one makes allowance for certain exaggerations which must be
pardoned him in his role of enthusiasticbiographerof his great ruler.
And his account appears all the more plausible when we considerthat
in all essential details it coincides with the picture of Sadr al-Dīn
handed down to us by other historiographers.Within the bounds of
the present essay it is of course not possible to present a picture of
those troubled times such as Rashīd al-Dīn has depicted. All that is
envisaged at presentis to offertranslationsof two especially character-
istic fragmentsof his History that concern Sadr al-Dīn personally. In
regardto the text I would referto my already mentionededition of the
Historyof Ghāzān-Khān,62
I.: "When Sadr-i Chaovī (i.e. the man who introduced the chao
became vizier, usurious trade increased to an extent that is im-
possible to describe in words. But, as the subject is under dis-
cussion, one very minutepart (of it) must be mentioned.(This is)
no empty twaddle, forthose living at the time were all witnesses
of what is to be told. Thereforethe followingwill appear strange
to those who may some day read it.
The provincial tax-gatherersat that time were the basest crea-
tures of their period. They were acquainted with Sadr al-Dīn's
custom of sellingan ox fora calf and they lent sums of money at
an extortionaterate ofinterestand offeredit to him as a ťgift'That
which was worthten dinārs they borrowed for twenty and gave
to him for thirty.And he accepted it, but said: 'The dīvān (i.e.
the State chancellery) is in need of money.' The tax-collector
thereupon answered categorically: ťIn this place money is lent
at interest- the sum I have presented you with was only procur-
ed by means of a thousand ruses.' To which he replied: ťYou will
not lose by it; as soon as you receive it, give it all to me.' Hardly
had that person(i.e. the tax-collector)producedthebond beforethe
amount and the usuriousinteresthad been calculated. For every-
thing that was worth 10 dinārs he received thirtydinārs and he
gave it to him (Sadr al-Dīn) for fortydinārs. But the remaining
ten dinārs he (the tax-collector) at once spent. And when Sadr
al-Dīn was in urgentneed of money his lieutenants used to say:
'True, it is worth ten dinārs, but it will not fetch more than six
dinārs.' And they kept the fourdinārs forthemselves. Briefly,of
the total sum of fortydinārs he received no more than six, and
these too were the propertyof the dlvān. who squandered them
away.
One of his assistantsboughtseveral thousand sheep forhim froma
merchant for five dinārs apiece, to be paid at the end of two
months. But when payment became due there was no money
available. As in the meantime most of the sheep had perished or
were in a wretchedcondition,he orderedthe rest to be sold at a
low price and to use the proceeds to cover the interestdue on the
two months.The contract,i. e. the date on which the debt was due
to be paid, was however deferredfor another two months.
There is no doubt that the wealth of the kingdomwas squandered
away by such transactions and that the state treasury had no
revenues to register.Of the assignmentsof money made by Gay-
khātū that can be attributedto his generosity,the assignees did
not receive one dānug (= one quarter dirham), and the same
applied to the pay of the troops, the salaries and other regular
expenses. This was also the reason why the army hated Gaykhätü.
Sadr al-Dīn was neverthelessconstantly bankrupt and when he
died he had become guilty of thousands and again thousands of
injustices towards the nation; how many houses full of valuables
and comfortshad he not robbed the people of!"
II.: "But such dealings (the reprehensible method of levying
taxes was under discussion) constitutedthe whole of his activity.
He was expert at it and carried such abominable practices and
injustices to great lengths. The result was that he plunged the
realm and the governmentinto complete ruin. In his time it was
impossible for any one to collect a sum of money guaranteed by
a berät(bill of exchange issued by the State) on a province (irre-
spective of which). None of the legitimate pensions and salaries
were properlypaid out, forall berātsand bills proved to be nothing
but tricksand frauds.
It frequentlyhappened that he issued a draft for five hundred
dinārs to one of the dervishes,sheikhs or deservingpersons who
came to him at his request or forsome otherreason. Such a person,
now, who had never set eyes on as much as hundred akcha (small
silver coins) in his life,would then talk about the vizier's gener-
osity and rejoiced greatly and, before he even set out to obtain
payment of his capital, resolved in view of his credit of five
hundred dinārs, to borrow one hundred dinārs to cover the cost
of his riding-animal,his equipment and his food for the journey.
He calculated that aftersettlinghis debt he would have hundred
dinārs leftand, drivenon by that hope, went on in tirelesspursuit
of the money, even to the extent of forgettinghis dignity as a
sheikh and learningthe professionof a beg, a tax-collector.When
all this proved fruitless,he (the debtor) finallyfledfromthis (his)
creditor.
As a resultofthis mismanagementand waste of money,most ofthe
Before the Sāhib Dīvān submitted to the Ilkhān his proposal for
the issuing of paper money (probably at the beginningof Jumādā II,
693 A. H. = end of April or beginningof May 1294), he had already
discussed the question with some of his emirs on more than one oc-
casion.69Accordingto Vassāf it was the councillorand vizier Muzaffar
ben Muhammad ben 'Amid- who appears to our author as the
-
physical and mental quintessence of loathsomeness and depravity70
at whose instigationSadr al-Dīn resolved to take the step. Just as in
the empireof the Great Khān, paper currencywas to take the place of
metal in the Iran of the Ilkhāns, while all of the latter was to flowinto
the treasuryof the Ilkhān. It was believed that in this way an impetus
would be given to trade and an improvementin social conditions
would be assured.71Gaykhätü, whom Sadr-i Jihān's proposal suited
very well since he saw in it an opportunityforprocuringwithoutmuch
trouble the enormoussums of which he was constantlyin need, never-
theless applied to the deputy of the Great Khān at his court, Emir
Pūlād Chīnksānk,72with the purpose of obtaining furtherinformation
on the subject. This man, an ambassador of long standing at the court
of Khânbâlïq and presentedby Rashīd al-Dīn as an eminentauthority
on the historyof Mongolia,73instructedGaykhätü on the nature of the
ch'ao, explaining it as a paper endorsed with the seal ( tamghā) of the
Great Khān and valid in all parts of the Chinese Empire in place of
cast metal coinage. But ready money, he said, was the bãlish,74and
is quite possible that this was indeed the case in view of administrative
customs114prevalent elsewhere.
The continuerof Bar Hebraeus finallystates that as regardsmaterial
the money certificatesor notes were of paper made frompapyrus,115
whereas Vassāf, Rashīd al-Dīn, Mīrkhvānd and Khvāndamīr speak
constantly only of paper.116From this informationwe can therefore
draw no definiteconclusionas to what species of paper was employed.
The native paper industrywhich, as is known, owed its existence to
the firstencounterbetween the world of Islam and the Middle Empire
in the 8th centuryA. D.,117generally made use of linen and hempen
rags.118But in addition, paper was probably manufacturedfromthe
bark of the paper-mulberrytree (broussonetia papyrifera)119 and
the fruit." "In other words", says Rashīd al-Dīn, "the people were
completely at the mercy of this ill and the poor raised their hands
imploringlyin prayer".142Compared with the prosperity(that Tabriz
had formerlyenjoyed), no words are able to express the hunger,dearth
and want which had then befallen the city, writes the continuer of
Bar Hebraeus.
Vassāf 's descriptionof the same events agrees in essentials with that
of the historian just quoted. According to his assertions, also to be
found in Mīrkhvānd and Khvāndamīr, the effectsof the ch'ao were
already felt only three days after its issue:143the town was deserted
and-trade and commercewere completelyparalysed. The price of food
rose so high that one dlnār-i-rābihfora portion of bread sufficientfor
one person was considered cheap.145An idea of the maximum prices
reached at this time at the horse-marketat Tabriz is conveyed by an
amusing little scene imparted by Vassāf s informant:the price of a
horse, forwhich 15 dinārs would probably have been twice its value,
was finallyfixed at 150 paper dinārs. But beforethe transaction was
concluded, the seller, most likely out of his head with joy at the high
price his animal had fetched,swung himselfinto the saddle and rode
offbeforethe astonished gaze of the spectators.146The original price
was thus in this case increased ten to twenty-fold.As a result of the
disastrous effectof the ch'ao on commerciallife,we are told by Rashīd
al-Dīn, steps were taken to withdrawthe ch'ao fromcirculationwith-
out furtherdelay.
In addition to the passive resistance offeredby the people to Sadr-i
Jihān's reforms,there was also violent public opposition. The target
of the animosityand indignationof the masses was of course in the first
place the men responsible for the institutionof the measure, namely
Izz al-Dīn Muzaffar147 and Sadr al-Dīn. The formerwho, in recognition
of his services in this matterhad been granted the title of "'Amīd al-
Mulk", i.e. Pillar of the State, by Sadr-i Jihān, succeeded only by a
piece of luck in escaping the death whichthe tumultuousmasses in the
mosque had intended for him and his followers.148 Mīrkhvānd and
Khvāndamīr state that he was indeed put to death on thisoccasion.149
SimilarlySadr al-Dīn's brother,Qutb al-Dīn, the Qad! al-Qudāt, found
himselfso dangerously threatened by the people during the Friday
service in the Tabriz Masjid-i Juma1that the only way to save himself
was finallyto give permissionforfoodstuffs to be sold forcash. Rashīd
al-Dīn reportsthat a large numberof people were killed in conjunction
with this affair.150
The crowd,which did not acquiesce in the use of the despised paper
notes,151succeeded in forcingits way through to the Sāhib Dīvān.
The words with which he replied to theirabuse and scorn met with no
response. Astonished and disconcerted,he is said to have stood there,
for he was quite aware that to go back on his decision would mean
shaking his moral position to its foundations,but that on the other
hand he would be unable to forcehis will on the people152With these
fewphrases the continuerof Bar Hebraeus has succinctlycharacterized
the perilous position in which the governmentfound itselfand at the
same time has anticipated but leftunspoken the one and only accept-
able solution. When one day Sadr al-Dīn was riding through the
market- so we are told by Rashīd al-Dīn- a dervish seized his
bridle and called out to him. "The whole world smells of burnt liver
hasn't your sensitive nose smelt it yet?" Startled by these words,
Sadr al-Dīn, in consultation with his followers,is said to have got
Gaykhâtû to issue a yarlïghto the effectthat business in foodstuffsat
any rate was temporarilyagain allowed to be carried on for ready
cash.154Though we must admit that Sadr al-Dīn, who was nothingif
not courageous, allowed himselfto be intimidated by the threats of
148Vassāf,op. cit.p. 274.
149Mīrkhvānd, op. cit.,p. 291,Ind. ed.,Vol. 5, p. 125; Khvāndamīr, op. cit.
p. 80: "He is reported to have beenkilled."
150Rashīdal-Dīn,cf.AbāģābisOaihātū, Jahnp. 87; 'Alīzādah,op. cit., p. 241
(Persian).
151Continuer ofBar Hebraeus,op. cit.,p. 497.
152Ibid.
153Rashīdal-Dīn,cf.AbāģābisGaihātū, Jahn,p. 88; 'Alīzādah,op. cit.p. 241
(Persian).
154Ibid., 11. 7-8.
the populace, these same threats would never have induced him to
withdraw the paper currency, had it not been that the hoped-for
higherrevenues did not come up to his expectations,and, as a resultof
the ruinous effecton commercewhich only now really began to make
itselffelt,neitherdid the regularincomes. The decline in revenue from
taxation in trading centres such as Tabriz could not but have had
catastrophic effectson the state treasury in the long run. The repre-
sentations made to Gaykhätü by the Sāhib Dīvān and his followersto
persuade him to issue the yarlïghare thus, according to Vassāf, quite
understandable: "If this state of affairscontinuesfora few more days
the gloryof the empirewill be (irretrievably)lost forthe future".155
The date on which the yarlïgh came into force- which in theory
meant the end of the shortreignof the ch'ao - is unfortunatelynot to
be deduced fromthe Islamic sources. As the continuerof Bar Hebraeus
speaks of a period of two months during which trade and commerce
were at a standstill,it could at the latest have been about the middle of
the Dū'1-Hijja 693 A. H. (= about the middle of November 1294 A.
D.).156 In any case it appears fromthe list of contents of the yarligh,
merelytouched upon by Rashīd al-Dīn but more clearly indicated by
the continuerof Bar Hebraeus, that the ciïao was not withdrawnfrom
circulationat once but only gradually and with a well-advisedlenience.
The decree was welcomed with great joy and satisfactionby the whole
population and led to a speedy returnto normal conditions.157
So completelyand permanentlydid the Iranian ch'ao disappear that
not even its name has survived in the Persian vocabulary.158But in
rejectinga new regulationthat was regarded as a nuisance, the whole
of the Islamic world surrenderedone of the greatestgiftsfromthe Far
East, the art of printing.