The Failure of Italian Nationhood The Geopolitics of A Troubled Identity
The Failure of Italian Nationhood The Geopolitics of A Troubled Identity
The Failure of Italian Nationhood The Geopolitics of A Troubled Identity
Stanislao G. Pugliese
Hofstra University
Series Editor
This publishing initiative seeks to bring the latest scholarship in Italian and Italian American history,
literature, cinema, and cultural studies to a large audience of specialists, general readers, and students.
Italian and Italian American Studies (I&IAS) will feature works on modern Italy (Renaissance to the
present) and Italian American culture and society by established scholars as well as new voices in the
academy. This endeavor will help to shape the evolving fields of I&IAS by reemphasizing the connec-
tion between the two. The following editorial board consists of esteemed senior scholars who act as
advisors to the series editor.
ALESSANDRO PORTELLI
Università di Roma “La Sapienza”
Manlio Graziano
the failure of italian nationhood
Copyright © Manlio Graziano, 2010
All rights reserved.
This book was originally published in Italy by Donzelli Editore under the title Italia
senza nazione? Geopolitica di un’identità difficile, copyright © 2007 Donzelli Editore.
Where this book is distributed in the UK, Europe, and the rest of the world, this is
by Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in
England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21
6XS.
Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has
companies and representatives throughout the world.
Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States, the United
Kingdom, Europe and other countries.
ISBN: 978-0-230-10413-6
DG442.G7513 2010
945.092—dc22 2010007421
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
This book, written by an Italian purposely for a foreign public, was first published
in France, where I live and work, in 2007. It attempts to explain the profound
changes that are under way in Italian politics and, more generally, in Italian soci-
ety. This book comes out in the United States just a few months before the 150th
anniversary of the unification of Italy, and, with unpremeditated irony, illustrates
why Italy was never really unified. People who, for different reasons, are interested
in current Italian affairs are usually eager to understand the nature of “Berlus-
coni-ism,” a cultural, political, and social phenomenon that has lasted, by now,
for longer than 10 percent of the entire time that the Italian state has existed. The
brilliant thinker and politician Piero Gobetti, killed by fascists in 1926 at the age of
twenty-five, described fascism once as the “autobiography” of the Italian nation.
Today, it is possible to describe “Berlusconi-ism” as the most recent version of this
country’s autobiography.
This is the reason why almost no changes have been made to the original ver-
sion of the book, published when Italy was ephemerally led by a center-left gov-
ernment. That short period was exceptional; since then, Italy has recovered its
“normality,” which is the actual subject of this book.
This book, therefore, lacks any reference to the 2008 global economic crisis,
which substantially modified the character of international relations, upon which
Italy is, as I have tried to demonstrate, particularly dependent. But since this is a
study of historical and structural trends and not an “instant book,” the 2008 crisis
did not compromise any analysis done before this date.
I want to take advantage of this short introduction to the American edition
to thank all the people who made this publication possible: Professors Stanislao
Pugliese, of Hofstra University, and Osvaldo Croci, of Memorial University of
Newfoundland, who submitted the text to Palgrave; Chris Chappell and Saman-
tha Hasey, from Palgrave; Brian Knowlton, my very patient translator; Professor
Vera Negri Zamagni, whose expertness is exceeded only by her kindness; and my
friends Constance Cooper and Paolo Rampini, who encouraged—and helped—
me unfailingly.
Manlio Graziano
Paris, February 1, 2010
This page intentionally left blank
Introduction to the English Edition
were formed in Parliament) is seen as the only way to govern a country with such
diverse cultural and economic conditions. The fascist dictatorship is judged as an
effort to produce a coherent government for a country that was no longer ame-
nable to a peaceful democratic coexistence, while the never-ending north-south
dualism is seen as a failure to build a common set of rules of behavior, in spite of
the unified legislation in existence. The long discussion that Graziano offers of
the ambiguous role of Catholicism is of great interest in this context: on the one
side he recognizes that the Catholic identity could be a deeply unifying element of
the Italian nation, though hardly a really distinctive element because of the well-
known supranationality of Catholicism; on the other side he points out that the
many efforts to contrast Catholicism by building alternative secular identities were
unsuccessful, but served to increase divisions.
On the whole, we can say that the picture Graziano offers of successive Ital-
ian governments shows how they tried to bypass the problem rather than facing
it, putting in place strategies to keep the country together without lessening the
differences. In this context the present political move toward “federalization” is
explained as an acknowledgment by the Italian elites of the failure to make Italy
a nation, but it also offers the chance to raise some extremely interesting final
thoughts.
Indeed, if the lack of an effective national identity could have been a handicap
for Italy in the past, in the present transition of the European nation-states toward
entrusting increasing shares of sovereignty to the European Union, Italy might
suffer less and be better equipped to live under a “glocal” regime: global institu-
tions on the one side and local governments on the other side. The author speaks
in this connection of an “advantage of backwardness.” It should never be forgotten
that in Italy practically nothing is brand new because nearly everything has been
experimented with in some other form in the past. So the present “local” dimen-
sion has in Italy antecedents in the premodern times that were quite advanced and
flourishing and could easily be revived within an entirely new framework.
As every good book does, this one too opens up a number of questions previ-
ously not raised. The book’s thesis implies a counterfactual, namely, that a country
in modern times can produce better political and economic results if it enjoys a
stronger national identity. Indeed, a cohesive nation can express a more coherent
and sustained set of policies, both domestically and in the international arena, but
it can also breed a tendency toward warfare and economic protectionism. The lack
of a strong national identity did not spare Italy the horrors of two world wars. This
book raises questions that are relevant today not only for Italy.
Vera Zamagni
University of Bologna, 2010
Introduction
I n 1987, Prime Minister Bettino Craxi announced that Italy, having surpassed
the gross domestic product (GDP) of Great Britain, had become the fifth world
power. This declaration was followed by a storm of polemic, in particular from
the British, who accused ISTAT (the Italian Office of National Statistics) of hav-
ing modified its method of calculating the GDP to their advantage. This was, to
some extent, true. But it was also true that the Italian economy was proving, at
that point, to possess a dynamism superior to not only that of Thatcher’s Britain,
weakened by a strong dose of liberal medicine, but also that of France, where the
Italian “nouveaux condottieri,” as L’Express had labeled them two years previously,
were seizing hold of the media, the banks, the insurance sector, and even one of the
symbols of French national pride, the famous sugar company Béghin-Say.
In reality, the ruse was not so much falsification of the figures as the fact that,
while the other countries were restructuring their economies and their public
administration, Italy was managing to sidestep the obstacles by playing the cards
of low wages, devaluation of the lira, and public debt.
Twenty years later, Italy had fallen to seventh place among the major powers; in
2006, its GDP was not more than 78 percent of Great Britain’s, and in 2004 it was
overtaken by China.1 From 2001 to 2005, Italy was recorded as having the weakest
rate of growth in Europe, and its share of global trade fell from 5 percent in 1987
to 3.6 percent in 2005, which was the level at the beginning of the 1960s.2
The main political and economic players tried to place the blame for this
downturn on each other: in the second half of the 1990s, when the ruse of arti-
ficial growth had ceased to work, it was the so-called “First Republic” and its
figurehead, Bettino Craxi, that found themselves on trial. Then, the two oppos-
ing coalitions, born out of the crisis, held each other accountable for the feeble
economic performance of the country, without the slightest allusion to their
own responsibility, nor a nod toward the influence of the global economy, unless
in order to absolve themselves.
And yet, ten years after Craxi’s triumphant statement, Sergio Romano sug-
gested that the problem was structural; at the end of the period of the “economic
miracle,” Italy, to his mind, had strong chemical, iron and steel, and information
technology industries, and had the potential to be a civil nuclear power. “All of
these assets have disappeared over the years,” he concluded.3
* * *
2 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
In this book we will be studying Italy with reference to structural elements that are
verifiable and quantifiable.
In 1859 through 1861, Italy came together out of an unusual combination of
factors, predominantly international ones, with the major powers realizing the
benefits of adding a new pawn to their geopolitical chessboard. It was not born,
like many other nation-states, from the bourgeois struggle against the limitations
that hampered its own development. This singular trajectory—at least among
the great and middle powers—has meant that in Italy the prevailing cultural and
political inclination is more oriented toward official and, even more often, unof-
ficial diplomatic maneuvering than toward the necessities of the economy.
Among the ruling classes of the country, concern for immediate particular
interests has nearly always predominated over the necessity of defining the general
interest. Consistently with this habit, politicians have managed public resources for
the sake of privileging first and foremost their electoral “clients,” even if this means
contradicting the rules of development. Thus from the end of World War II to
the end of the 1980s, the small peasantry, artisans, shopkeepers, transporters, and
small-scale bankers (all in sectors of low productivity) were sheltered from specific
legislation. When this policy of protectionism was revealed to be unworkable, the
tendency was to absorb the excess workforce into public administration.
All of these factors have flowed into the persistent low productivity of the coun-
try: the industrial horizon has always been dominated by small businesses; transport
and distribution networks are among the most fragmented in Europe; the organiza-
tion of the education system and of research remains among the most inefficient;4
and, finally, the number of public-sector employees—at 3.36 million in 2006—is less
than that of France, but more than that of Germany in relation to the population,
and much greater than that of countries whose economic results have been among
the best in the whole of the European Union (EU) in recent years, such as Spain
and Ireland. Together, these conditions have contributed to the progressive decline
of Italian industry, so much so that we may speak of the “eclipse” or even, to quote
Luciano Gallino in 2003, the “vanishing” of Italian industry.
Gallino underlined the fact that the weakness of industrial production was not
without geopolitical consequences. In the twenty-first century, he wrote, as in pre-
vious centuries, and perhaps even more so, a country that lacks a large manufac-
turing industry “risks becoming a sort of colony, subordinated to the economic,
social and political needs of other countries possessing such an industry.”5 Ital-
ian passivity in international relations can also be explained by this fundamental
structural characteristic.
In a text from 1993 entitled Stato senza nazione, Zeffiro Ciuffoletti, referring
to the period after the unification, suggested a link between the lack of “nation-
alization of the masses” and the lack of industrial development in the country.6
Furthermore, in their text about the history of Italian foreign policy, Giuseppe
Mammarella and Paolo Cacace returned insistently to the connection between the
“lack of clear vision of national interests” and “the interrelation between foreign
and domestic politics.”7
* * *
INTRODUCTION 3
Examining the structural characteristics of the country will help us to avoid the
risk of getting lost in what Bollati has defined as “the ethnic ether.”8 It equally
means we can avoid the tendency to moralize, which never actually changes the
facts of reality.
In this book we will be principally concerned with what is “constant” in the physi-
ognomy of the country, knowing full well that “constant” does not mean “immu-
table.” On the contrary, we are forced to put the most emphasis on the idea of process,
on the transformation of different phenomena. For example, “crises of internation-
alization” are present throughout the whole history of unified Italy, defined by its
traumatic collisions with major upheavals in the global economy and international
politics; nevertheless, it is obvious that, with each collision, as much its subject as its
object changed—both in form and dimensions. The crisis of 1866 was, like that of
1992, a “crisis of internationalization” that had a significant impact upon the politi-
cal and economic face of the country; but the national and international contexts,
the personalities and the factors involved can in no way be compared.
* * *
One section of this book will be devoted to the “crossing of the desert” from 1494
to 1861. Our aim will be to understand in what way the country’s “original char-
acteristics,” its fundamental elements, have determined how contemporary Italy
came together and took shape. Our aim will be to understand why, on the eve of
1861, very few leaders of the ruling classes of the different Italian states were con-
templating the possibility of the unification of the peninsula, indeed, why most of
them actually opposed any impetus that led in this direction.
Educated by the lessons of 1848 through 1849, the Lombards feared that a union
with the Piedmontese would remove them from the geopolitical orbit of central
Europe without actually freeing them from their status as a political minority, which
they suffered as part of the Austrian Empire. The Piedmontese, who had not partici-
pated in any essential moment in the life of Italy up until that point, were thinking
only of a dynastic extension of their territory, which would bring to the house of
Savoy the rich regions of northern Italy, as well as a loose confederate link with the
other parts of the peninsula. The Sicilians were struggling for their own indepen-
dence. The Neapolitans were determined to protect the integrity of their kingdom,
which was threatened by separatism and the local potentates. The Pope, quite sim-
ply, identified unification with the loss of his temporal power, and when his fears
were realized, he excommunicated the whole of the political community, withdrew
inside the walls of the Vatican, and ostracized the nascent state. Last but not least,
regarding the unitary patriots, since the failed revolutions of 1848 and 1849, either
they had signed on to Cavour’s “diplomatic revolution” or they had squandered their
energy and credibility in the fabrication of implausible insurrections.
* * *
The exceptional circumstances leading to the unification of Italy will be the sub-
ject of a special analysis at the beginning of this book, because they help us to
4 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
understand one of the main characteristics of the country: its constant subordi-
nation to the interests of other great powers. When the military alliance between
France and the Kingdom of Sardinia against Austria in 1859 provoked the unin-
tended result of insurrections in central Italy and Sicily, Great Britain swapped
its initial caution for unreserved support for unification. Therefore, from its very
birth, Italy was often to be an instrument used by the major powers. Trying to
find a place in the shadow of whichever power enjoyed the most prosperity at
any given moment, Italy has been pitched from one alliance to another accord-
ing to the dynamics of interests that were hardly ever its own.
At the beginning of the twentieth century, the German chancellor Bernhard
von Bülow expressed his annoyance at Italy’s habit of “waltzing” with Germany’s
enemies. From that day on, the vagaries of Italy’s foreign policy were regularly
denounced. What have been rarer, however, are attempts to explain why it vacil-
lated so.
The outstanding performance of the Italian officers who, in the centuries before
unification, were in the service of France and Austria; the undeniable brilliance of
Garibaldi’s armies; the demonstrable heroism of soldiers abandoned by the state
after September 8, 1943; and even the political and diplomatic qualities of two
“Italians” who led other countries, Napoleon Bonaparte and Sonia Maino Gandhi,
spare us the temptation of creating an “ethnic” link between the foreign policy
of the country and its population. If the problem does not reside in the Italian
“character,” then it resides in other factors of a historical nature, be they economic,
social, cultural, or institutional, or as is most likely, all of these put together.
* * *
In this book we will try to clarify systematically the link between a weak national
identity and an uncertain presence on the international stage.
While other countries pursue power politics in order to serve national interests,
in Italy there has been, since the unification, a trend to support the need for the
country to pursue power politics in order to discover what its interests actually are.
Each time this trend announces itself, it reveals the lack of a guiding principle in
foreign policy—that is, the lack of a sense of aim and initiative when attempting
to act on the international stage. Each time this trend resurges, Italy heads straight
toward risking new humiliation.
We may note quite rightly that the phrase “lack of national interests” encour-
ages a degree of confusion, in the sense that it could lead one to think that Italy
does not have its own interests. In reality, the problem is the exact opposite; across
the Italian peninsula there exist a great number of disparate interests that, inca-
pable of identifying themselves in collective will, create a host of divergent foreign
policies, potential or actual. The major cities, the regions, the different productive
sectors, the economic groups more open toward international markets, those who
are oriented more toward the domestic market, the Catholic movements (often
laying claim to differing positions, even while serving ultimately the same cause):
all these particular interests rarely manage to synthesize their will with the general
interest.
INTRODUCTION 5
The form of political action that is designed to cater to multiple interests and
that, instead of achieving a general synthesis, seeks out short-term provisional and
partial synthesis is referred to as “transformism.”
* * *
This book will give ample space to the question of transformism. We could even
say that it is a book about transformism, if this did not suggest that it is, by the
same token, a book on the weak identity of Italians and on the wavering trajectory
of the foreign policy of their country.
This is not another history of Italy. In fact, it is rather an attempt to sketch out a
history and an analysis of the social and political mechanisms that govern Italy as a
unitary state and their correlation with the social psychology of Italians. A history,
because we are retracing the abiding nature of these mechanisms throughout the
whole existence of the country; an analysis, because we are trying to understand
the reasons for their existence.
It is necessary to try to establish a reason why a country born without an identity,
without a well-defined international role, established upon political structures that
were transformist in essence, found itself, almost 150 years later, still suffering from
a weak identity, an unstable international position, and a transformist employment
of political power. We locate this reason in the country’s endemic low productivity.
A country like the Italy of 1861, with an essentially rural economy and very
little industry, all of which was of small or very small proportions, could only
ever be a country of low productivity. The fragmentation and the isolation of the
bourgeoisie as well as its fundamentally agricultural identity as a result made it
difficult for different interest groups to align themselves in powerful coalitions
capable of acting as figureheads for the general interest. In addition to this, the
international patronage of the country had, to some extent, absolved the ruling
classes of the necessity of strategically evaluating their own development. As they
were not being solicited by active coalitions of interests, the political community
operated through a process of carefully co-opting the productive sectors of society,
and welcoming them with transformist initiatives, with the ultimate aim of pre-
serving the stability of social relations and avoiding all potential social dislocation.
One of the first consequences of transformism was that general productivity
remained low. The second consequence, strongly linked to the first, was that the
social dislocations were almost always imposed from abroad.
* * *
The history of Italy is also the story of a long succession of “crises of internation-
alization.” These crises were brought about by changes in international economic
and political relations, which in turn had brutal repercussions for the internal sta-
bility of Italy. Another constant is that the greater the attempts to keep the influ-
ence of foreign upheaval from Italy, the worse the problem became.
The chapter devoted to the internationalization crisis of 1866, which marked
the end of the internal balance of powers upon which Italy had been founded,
6 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
examines what was, to some extent, the prototype of a long series of transforma-
tions generated, or at least stimulated, by international events. The end of the free-
trade cycle in the 1880s, the French conquest of Tunis in 1881, the expansive Belle
Époque period, the Eastern Crisis, World War I, German rearmament in 1935, the
Keynesian cycle resulting from the Great Depression, and the beginning of the
new free-trade cycle from the second half of the 1970s: there we have a brief list of
some of the major international upheavals that had violent repercussions for the
Italian nation.
Only once did the breach of stability come from within; at the end of the 1960s,
when major strikes meant the end of the social compromise of low salaries, one
of the keys—indeed, for many, the only key—to the “economic miracle” of the
1950s and the 1960s. But on this occasion, the opposite happened: in the absence
of major international upheaval, the temporary crisis was overcome by the trans-
formist co-optation of the Italian Communist Party (PCI) in the governmental
majority, which put a halt to salary growth, and by a phase of economic expansion
contrived by the “competitive devaluation” of the lira.
The lowering of salaries and the depreciation of the currency were the two
shortcuts that allowed Italy to harbor, for another ten years, the illusion that it
could exist without a radical overhaul of its structures in order to ensure a system-
atic increase in productivity.
* * *
Italian state was “the greatest entrepreneur to the west of Dnepr,”9 the coinci-
dence becomes understandable. The combined pressure of German strength and
international free trade had shaken the structures of all countries with a mainly
state-governed economy, which had stood firm up until that point thanks to the
geopolitical safety net assured by Yalta.
Italy welcomed the “European constraint” wholeheartedly. Any other option
meant the risk of isolation from the motor of development moving through the
rest of Europe. The regionalist factions that had developed in the 1980s expressed,
whether consciously or not, a determination to maintain their link with the rest of
Europe, with Italy or without her. Although everyone was aware of the risks, and
although everyone was aware that liberalization was the only possible solution,
people were equally convinced of the fact that it was up to “others” to suffer the
burden of this decision and sacrifice themselves for the good of the country.
To put an end to the deadlock, it was necessary, as Federico Rampini said in
1996, to summon the European “bogeyman,”10 who alone was capable of conquer-
ing all opposition. Among the most vociferous resistors were the major Italian
political parties, born in the state-capitalism era and incapable of playing the lib-
eral role put upon them by the new free-trade era. The “Clean Hands” judges were,
to a certain extent, the “secular arm” charged with administering the European
verdict that condemned this torpid political system.
* * *
In his book on Italy in Europe, Mario Monti remembers having said one day to
Margaret Thatcher that Italians needed Maastricht because they had “never had a
Margaret Thatcher.”11
In France, some commentators think that Mitterrand’s liberal awakening in
1983 left behind few concrete measures and a considerable amount of antiliberal
doctrine. In Italy, not only was there no Thatcher, but there was not even a Mit-
terrand. We could even go so far as to say that in Italy the situation was exactly
the inverse: Mitterrand became liberal while maintaining a language that was
“Socialist;” in Italy, the country continued to be “Socialist” while using a liberal
vocabulary. The reason lies in the fact that the political and economic players were
inexorably linked to the state; even the largest private industries received loans
and orders from the state, profited from the mass acquisition of public shares at
an attractive price, exported successfully due to the favorable value of the lira, and
ultimately got their credit from state-owned banks.
Silvio Berlusconi presented himself as a free-marketer. In reality, he is no
such thing, neither by his origins—the Socialist Party led by Bettino Craxi hav-
ing assisted considerably in the domestic expansion of his business—nor through
his political actions. Under his second government, tax came to represent, in
2005, 45.4 percent of the wage in comparison to an average of 37.3 percent in the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries;
in the same year the level of debt as a percentage of GDP had increased by 2.5
points compared to the year before, reaching a total of 106.4 percent. The current
account surplus went from 6.6 percent of GDP in 1997 to 0.4 percent in 2005. In
8 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
addition, between 2001 and 2004 productivity decreased by 0.1 percent, whereas
in Germany it increased by 11.8 percent and in France it increased by 8.9 percent:
according to the Global Economic Forum, in 2005 Italy was forty-seventh in the
global rankings of productivity. Growth, having remained fixed below 1 percent
from 2002, reached a level of stagnation at 0 percent in 2005. As a result, Italy’s
part of the global market fell from 4 percent to 3 percent between 2001 and 2005.12
* * *
One cannot help but stand up and take notice when a new paradox emerges in
which the right wing acts as the party of laxity and the left wing presents itself as the
party of discipline. This new paradox was accompanied by another that saw the left
wing and the pacifists greet the Italian military mission to Lebanon with enthusiasm,
while the right wing and the nationalists expressed trepidation. An Italian in hiber-
nation since the 1960s, reawakening in 2007, would surely feel disoriented.
The problems encountered by the second government of Romano Prodi
(2006–2008) must not be attributed exclusively to the strength of the far left in
the coalition, as suggested by the Anglo-Saxon press and the employer’s federa-
tion, but rather they should be attributed to the risk of alienating the electorate by
attacking its social status. It is a difficulty encountered by the left and the right, by
every government; indeed, it is the challenge of all politicians subject to the judg-
ment of the voters. The Italian particularity, when it comes to this issue, is that
the left wing as well as the right wing are culturally strangers to the free-market
mentality and any profound change is only possible if it is imposed by a foreign
“bogeyman” at the gates.
The first and certainly the most important step in the Italian turnaround was
the weakening of protectionism under the first government led by Giuliano Amato,
in 1992. Many public assets were privatized and public expenditure was subject to
the biggest reduction in the entire history of the Italian Republic. Some of the
“historic” institutions—for example, the famous “Cassa per il Mezzogiorno”13—
were dismantled, as well as one of the biggest state conglomerates in the Western
world, the Institute for Industrial Reconstruction (IRI).14 The Italian market was
fully opened to external competitors, many diverse sectors were deregulated, and
vast reform of the public administration as well as an initial reorganization of the
banking system began.
We must remember that Amato had had the good fortune to be prime minister
when the parliamentary right to veto was almost nonexistent: 205 out of 630 dep-
uties were in fact prosecuted on May 18, 1993,15 and consequently they were ready
to vote for any government rather than risk the dissolution of the parliament,
and probably time in prison. This “extraparliamentary” character of the govern-
ment broke down the traditional transformist mechanism, and Amato was able to
submit the country to European guidelines. This submission brought about more
structural changes than forty years of democratic elections.
Some other transformations induced by the European process concerned the
political field more directly. From the unification until 1994, the Italian political
system always centered around a single party; with the exception of a short period
INTRODUCTION 9
in the mid-1870s, two opposing coalitions never presented themselves before the
electorate with the same chances of success. After its victory in 1876, Agostino
Depretis’ Sinistra became the “single party of the bourgeoisie,”16 and the Destra
progressively ceased to be a real party of opposition and eventually disappeared.
In the decades that followed, debate about the possibility of having several parties
was even the subject of theoretical discourse. Benedetto Croce, to name but one
example, suggested in two essays from 1912 and 1928 that such a thing was artifi-
cial. Between the publication of Croce’s first and second text, fascism had imposed
de jure the single-party system. In the postwar period, the Communist Party never
represented a real danger to the monopoly of the Christian Democrats (DC), as
the international stage did not allow it any access to power.
The changes on the international stage in the 1980s and 1990s altered the situ-
ation. Thanks to her relationship with Europe, Italy not only avoided a fate like
that of Yugoslavia or the USSR, or even that of Argentina in 2001, but also became
a “normal country,”17 at least in the sense that two coalitions could now compete
for power.
Governmental stability was the other important modification to take place in
Italy over the last decade, at least with the Silvio Berlusconi governments. After
Alcide De Gasperi in the period between 1948 and 1953, Berlusconi was the sec-
ond president of the Italian Counsel to be in office for an entire term; the govern-
ment he led from June 2001 to April 2005 was the longest lasting in the entire
history of the republic: 1,414 days, which is more than a third longer than the
former record, held by Bettino Craxi, for some 1,083 days between 1983 and 1987.
Very few commentators have noticed that this shift occurred in all the major Euro-
pean countries, in which the process of Europeanization had imposed greater sta-
bility. Italy became a “normal country” in the sense that it became less Italian and
more European.
* * *
Among the permutations of recent years, one of the most striking is the emergence
of a “personalization” of politics. This phenomenon does not simply stem from
the European process, but is also part of the “natural” evolutionary trend of parlia-
mentary politics, discernible in many different countries with diverse customs and
institutions. In Italy this trend was worsened by the frenetic search for a “substi-
tute” for traditional politics, at least from the 1970s onward. Used for the first time
by Craxi, provoking both skepticism and sarcasm, the “personalization” card was
abundantly played during the years of the great crisis, especially by Silvio Berlus-
coni. The latter certainly took it up a notch, and his adversaries have been equally
vocal in contributing to his iconization, even if contemptuously. For this reason
we have too often seen Berlusconi as the man being talked of, without interrogat-
ing Berlusconi-ism—a social and psychological phenomenon whose roots lie, we
might say, in the whole history of Italy.
Since the birth of this country, numerous political leaders and intellectuals—
not to mention the Catholic Church—have praised frugality, and considered it as
a sort of Italian fatality: the nationalists and the Fascists went so far as to transform
10 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
it into virtue, as a moral crutch to be used in the fight against the “five meals a day”
nations, as Mussolini used to refer to the “rich countries.” In the postwar period,
the DC and the PCI competed fiercely for the virtue of temperance, right up until
the second half of the 1970s, when these two parties began their governmental col-
laboration under the twin mottos of “austerity” and “sacrifice.”
But meanwhile—since the time when it was said that the sun was the only
industry that suited Italy, the time of “proletarian Italy,” the time when the frugal-
ity of the rural family was held up as an example to the whole of the nation—an
essential change had occurred in the lives of Italians: they had ceased to be the
beggars of neorealist movies—they had gotten rich. The immigrants, the sciuscià,
and the bicycle thieves18 were now coming from the Balkans, from North Africa,
and from the Far East, and all trying to land on the Italian coast.
Many within the political and intellectual communities failed to recognize these
changes and, more to the point, failed to understand them. This created a division
between the Italians who wanted to benefit from their new conditions without feel-
ing guilty and their political and intellectual leaders. Some years before Berlusconi
gave his name to this phenomenon, the president of Fiat, Gianni Agnelli, visited a
secondary school where he was greeted with enthusiasm by the students, who excit-
edly suggested that he grab the reins of the country himself and kick out the “petty
politicians.” This welcome left the political community flabbergasted, in particular
the left wing, for whom Agnelli still personified the “enemy of the people”.
The shades of this new climate were recognized by Bettino Craxi. In abolishing
one part of the mechanism of index-linking salaries, Craxi launched a challenge
to the trade union power that was tightly linked to the PCI. In the referendum on
this issue, 54.3 percent of the electorate voted with the Socialist prime minister
and against the unions and the PCI. We could say that Berlusconi-ism was born
on that day.
* * *
Fifteen years after the beginning of the lengthy Italian crisis, the polemic about the
political “caste”—that is, despite the Indian metaphor, the “untouchables” who are
ready to defend their privileges at any cost—is resurfacing, along with the threat
of another great political turmoil.
There exists a long tradition of the myth of the “antipolitical” that took root in
the whole history of postunification Italy. A minister of the last Prodi government,
Tommaso Padoa Schioppa, noted that “artists, administrators, lawyers, advertising
executives, trade unions, and entrepreneurs are as much a ruling class as the gov-
ernment.” We return once more therefore to the problem of the ruling classes and,
as Padoa Schioppa would suggest, to the issue of bad habits, and the worst habit
of all, that of trying to solve the mystery of their own historical weakness through
finding a scapegoat.
In recent years, studies on the absence of an Italian sense of civicness have
become more common. Some have attributed this to “amoral familism,”19 oth-
ers to the Counter-Reformation, some to the rampant cult of individualism sanc-
tioned by the “Berlusconian way of life,” and others to the political parties and
INTRODUCTION 11
the so-called cost of politics. Some have spoken of the limited resources of “social
capital,” meaning, in sociological terms, “a sense of the responsibility towards oth-
ers and institutions—solidarity and participation.”20 In sum, a general observation
is that there is great reluctance from individuals to sacrifice even a small part of
their own particular interests in the name of the general good.
The Italy of today is still characterized by marked “political fragmentation”—
the absence of a “center” already observed by Giacomo Leopardi in 1824. In
addition to having introduced certain corrections and, in certain cases, certain
solutions to some of the structural problems of the country, the European process
has offered a place in which this fragmentation—inherited from its history and
its geography—has been acknowledged and, little by little, has begun to disap-
pear. Italy became, for a while, a sort of model of supranational integration, of
polycentrism, of voluntary (and sometimes even eager) cession of sovereignty in
the framework of a new plurality of institutions that leaves behind the traditional
concept of a “Europe of regions.”
From the phase of stop and go experienced in Europe between 2005’s referenda
in France and the Netherlands (but probably from the “Letter of the Eight” in
2003) and the election of Nicolas Sarkozy in 2007, media campaigns used fear of a
possible return to 1992 as a warning to the political community. When the Euro-
pean process slows down, Italy risks falling back into bad habits, which are now
less likely to succeed, given that the ministers and central bankers can no longer
use the ruse of competitive devaluation. On the other hand, when the European
process speeds up again, the squabbles of Italy’s political leaders, the backwardness
of the country’s infrastructure, the low wages, and the burden of public debt and
increasing taxation are all factors capable of preventing the country from follow-
ing the continental pace.
The problematic national identity of Italy, from whichever angle it is examined,
has been and is of geopolitical significance.
This page intentionally left blank
Foreword
The “Original Sin”
A t the moment of its unification, Italy was one of Europe’s most backward coun-
tries, in both economic and financial terms. Agriculture, which accounted
for 56.7 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), employed 70 percent of active
workers, while industry, which contributed 20.3 percent to GDP, employed only
18 percent, with most of those working at home and in sectors using low-level
technologies (notably textiles). The state, indebted to the tune of 500 million lira
(about 2 billion euros at the 2002 equivalent), had neither the capital nor, as we
will see, the political will to foster a shift from a largely traditional phase, involving
modest forms of manufacturing, to an industrial phase.
Modern industrial establishments were exceedingly rare (there were only
ten blast furnaces on the peninsula), and even if they were nearly all linked to
railway construction, the rail network itself remained very limited (1,829 kilo-
meters), relying heavily on imported equipment. The banking system, without
the stimulation of the industrial demand, managed to attract only 1.4 per-
cent of national revenue and included almost none of the medium-term credit
establishments that are indispensable to industrial financing. The backward-
ness of industry was also linked to low primary-sector productivity: by some
estimates, revenue per hectare amounted to barely 80 lira, compared to the
equivalent of 170 lira in France and 213 lira in England, while wheat produc-
tion was a mere nine hectoliters, compared to fifteen in France and thirty-two
in England.2
Given a demographic growth rate weaker than the continental average, and
modest industrial development, the process of urbanization was extremely slow,
despite an urban tradition far more ancient than in most other European coun-
tries. Thus Naples was the country’s most populous city, with 447,000 inhabitants,
followed by Turin (250,000), and Rome and Milan (each with 185,000). The lack
of a well-qualified labor force weighed further on development, more than other
factors, as both an effect and a cause of the country’s backwardness. While 54 per-
cent of the working population was illiterate, only a mere 12 percent could truly
read and write. Of the 15 million people age eighteen or older, only 120,000, or 8
percent, had completed any secondary education. Finally, per capita revenue was
only one-third that of France, and one-fourth that of Great Britain.
Italy was not the only European country with economic and social indicators
that trailed countries like France and Great Britain. Backwardness is a relative con-
cept and cannot be measured purely by statistical data. But Italy’s backwardness
became a first-order geopolitical handicap at the very moment when the new state
pretended to rank among the great powers, regardless of its grave structural defi-
cits. This made the country appear, as Bismarck sarcastically proclaimed, “like a
creature of great appetite but weak teeth.”
The Italy of the second half of the nineteenth century displayed none of the
characteristics that typically give rise to an “autonomous” or “national” unification
movement. The historic rupture that led to the integration of the different parts of
the peninsula was provoked by an extraordinary set of circumstances far beyond
anyone’s expectations. In his reflections on the Risorgimento—Italy’s “rebirth”—
Antonio Gramsci ascribes this unexpected development to a “determined historic
European connection:” the reciprocal weakening of the two great continental
powers—France and Austria—and the emergence of a third great power, Prussia.3
In other words, the formation of the Italian state resulted in large part from the
spreading seismic waves that were shaking Europe’s geopolitical balance of power.
Count Cavour and Napoleon III, with the hypotheses they concocted in 1858,
hardly foresaw the unification of the country; moreover, the Piedmontese ruling
class was far from possessing the force required to imagine such a solution. That is
why it had to hastily “invent” a political product lacking cultural or popular bases
in hopes of achieving within mere decades what neighboring countries had spent
centuries constructing.
The Piedmont’s domination of the other regions—heavy-handed for the Mez-
zogiorno, but humiliating as well for Lombardy, one of Europe’s most evolved
regions—and its subsequent co-option by the great-power concert, imposed the
need on this new Italy to have a direction even before it had an identity. Having
lacked a direction a priori, the fruit of a rational political plan—which existed
only in the minds of the patrioti, who had played a negligible role in the country’s
birth—it was necessary to look for a direction a posteriori. Thus was invented the
legend of an Italy that “si è fatta da sé”—had made itself—and thus too was forged
the religion of the Risorgimento, a mythical epic in which a few powerful actors
had managed to bend reality to their will.
“Artichoke” Politics
of turning the neighboring powers against each other. Therefore Piedmont was no
longer able to apply its traditional politics and found itself at the rearguard of the
national movement.
The historian Francesco de Sanctis was the first to sense, from the early years of
the new kingdom, the need to use history as a political weapon by celebrating an
imaginary compromise between the moderates and the democrats as a sort of
founding act of the unified kingdom. His objective was to give ideological legiti-
macy to the new state against those who would deligitimize it (above all, the Cath-
olic Church) by giving it a certain consistency in the eyes of the masses, who were
indifferent or even open to the clerics’ arguments. With de Sanctis, the syncretic
vision of the Risorgimento arose and placed in the same Olympus such diverse and
irreconcilable figures as Victor Emmanuel, Mazzini, Garibaldi, and Cavour. Little
by little this political weapon became a sort of collective and retrospective myth:
the king, the liberals, and the ordinary people marching together, arm in arm,
toward the common objective of “making Italy.”
In fact, the kings had been fiercely hostile to anything remotely suggestive of
unification, to the point that the Piedmontese censor had banned, as late as the
1840s, the very use of the words “Italy” and “nation”, always replaced by a more
anodyne “country.” The liberals and the masses, for their part, felt little common
bond. The former saw no way that their elevated ideals could possibly have any-
thing to do with the mundane needs of the latter, while the latter were left baffled
by the obscure formulas employed by the former.
If this triad—the king, the liberals, and the people—was but a chimera, invented
a posteriori (the way the Galls were for the French or the Goths for the Germans),
then just who were Italy’s true “founders”? Put another way: Did any force exist in
Italy capable of leading a national movement?
Theoretically, yes. For example, the thousands who, under Napoleon, had held
civil or military posts—young, ambitious, talented people, sensitive to the political
and cultural problems of their era, regretful that this was not an epoch in which
a career was offered to people of talent. The latter could only reject the “intel-
lectual hell” that dominated in Turin (the phrase comes from Camillo Benso, the
Count of Cavour, who was peremptorily asked to leave the kingdom after having
published in Paris in 1846 an essay on the railway system in Italy and its unifying
role in the peninsular market). Indeed, their influence within the army played
a determining role during the insurrections of Naples in 1820 and Piedmont in
1821. But the resounding failure of both the revolts sufficed to exclude them from
among those who might have been able to take leadership of an eventual Italian
national unification process.
For a while the hope of a “patriotic” Pope was the hypothesis most discussed
in Italian intellectual circles. The neo-guelfi (neo-Guelphs) argued that the Pope
could use his moral authority to bring together the “Italian race,” which was politi-
cally divided, but united by ties of blood, religion, and language. But when several
armies from different states of the “Italian race” began pursuing the routed Austri-
ans in April 1848, Pope Pius IX declared that he “rejected the disconcerting sugges-
tions contained in newspapers and other writings by those who would make the
Roman Pontiff the president of a certain new republic to be constituted with the
support of all the peoples of Italy.”6 This about-face by a Pontiff who had seemed
at first to support the liberals’ aspirations was not, however, the only reason for
the failure of the neo-Guelph plan. In fact, as Gramsci observed, the great powers
probably would not have accepted that “the cultural function of the Church and
its diplomacy, already sufficiently encumbering . . . gain further strength by basing
itself on a large territorial state and a proportionally important army.”7
The bourgeoisie was actually the only class with any direct and immediate
interest in achieving a unified national market. But with isolated exceptions, this
class produced few theories and even less action toward this end.
The modern idea of nation arrived in Italy on the tips of the bayonets of the revolu-
tionary French bourgeoisie: the standardization of institutions and of legal codes,
the adoption of the decimal metric system, and the improvement of communica-
tions that, after the Napoleonic conquest, was applied to the entire peninsula left a
concrete taste for the benefits to be gained from national unification.
In March 1816, Marshal Heinrich Joseph de Bellegarde, governor of Lombardy,
wrote in a dispatch to Vienna that after Napoleon, the Italians would never again
accept a simple reconstitution of the small states of yesteryear. In particular, Bel-
legarde added, Milan, as the capital of the former Italian kingdom, had acquired
considerable political importance.8
Notwithstanding his confusion between “the” Italians and a small minority of
them, Count Bellegarde had seized on a key point: the political importance of
Milan. But he had attributed to it a certain scent of Italianness that was not actu-
ally so clearly discernible. It is true that while the first revolts against the Vien-
nese-imposed order had broken out in Naples and in Turin, the true capital of the
liberal political movements was Milan.
Il Conciliatore, a journal founded in September 1818 by Count Federico Con-
falonieri, comprised a group of young people with liberal political aspirations and
a shared interest in economic and educational reform. In ensuing years this ten-
dency produced numerous offshoots. Among them, the group gathered around
the Politecnico, another journal created in Milan in 1839 by Carlo Cattaneo, was
doubtless the one that placed greatest emphasis on the link between industrial
progress and the expansion of constitutional liberties. Moreover, the agrarian
transformation had favored the development in Lombardy of a conspicuously
larger bourgeoisie than in other regions of Italy, beginning in the mid-eighteenth
century.
The Austrian Empire, which after 1815 included also Lombardy and Veneto
was not about to impede the development of the Lombardian bourgeoisie, if only
because of the wealth it could amass through taxation. Indeed, the budget of the
In 1821 the traditional duplicity of the House of Savoy manifested itself, with
two different kings applying two different policies. Victor Emmanuel abdicated
because of the insurrection, and Charles Albert—the self-proclaimed regent—
accepted the constitution and named as minister of war the head of the con-
spiracy, Santorre di Santarosa, in order to prepare for the inevitable conflict with
Austria. Charles Felix, the legitimate heir, dismissed Charles Albert and Santarosa
and called on the Austrians to come to his aid. Charles Albert, fearful of losing his
right to the succession, renounced the conspirators and, when he became king in
1832, went so far as to exclude them from the traditional amnesty.
When the insurrection of 1820 erupted in Naples, the equilibrium established
in Vienna in 1815 was still too recent for the English to respond to the insurgents’
calls for help. Unable to profit from dissensions among the great powers, the Ital-
ian insurrection of 1820 through 1821 foundered.
International influence in the affairs of the peninsula was clear during the two
revolutionary crises that shook Europe shortly afterward. The French revolution
of 1830 gave rise, in 1831, to a series of small uprisings, which were almost imme-
diately put down. And in 1848, after the insurrections of Paris, Vienna, Budapest,
and Prague, the antifiscal furies that, from the beginning of the year, had the Mila-
nese boycotting tobacco and lottery games—following the model of the Boston
Tea Party—turned into armed revolt.
For some years Charles Albert, having lost all hope of annexing a part of Switzer-
land, and having realized that the Austrians were not disposed to back his expan-
sionist aims in the direction of France, had turned toward Lombardy, long coveted
by the House of Savoy. This is the reason why, fearful of the risk of a republican
contagion in Turin, he decided to march on the Lombard capital on March 24,
1848, to seize the initiative from the liberals. Thus, divisions among anti-Austrian
parties, Piedmontese indecisiveness and military insufficiencies made Milan the
first insurgent capital of the Empire to be brought back, on August 6, under the
authority of Vienna.
Nonetheless, Austrian revanchism and the proclamation of the Tuscan and
Roman republics—the latter under highly popular leaders like Mazzini and
Garibaldi—forced the Piedmontese to resume the war with the goal of reestab-
lishing order in the interior under the cover of “national” action. This decision
was surely made less painful by the certainty that England and France, as Denis
Mack Smith reminds us, guaranteed that the Piedmontese kingdom would suf-
fer no territorial loss, even if it should be defeated yet again.11 “We cannot win,”
Massimo d’Azeglio frankly acknowledged to Silvio Spaventa a few days before
hostilities resumed, “but we will fight anew: our defeat will be the defeat of this
party that pushes us today to resume the war, and between a defeat and a civil
war we choose the former.”12
If defeat was the goal, it was achieved barely three days later, ingloriously, at
Novara: the king abdicated, but the dynasty was safe. As Mack Smith notes, the
hypothesis that Italy was created “by itself ” was revealed as manifestly absurd. As
the Tuscan liberal Bettino Ricasoli bitterly remarked: “Italy no longer does any-
thing by itself.”
The sine qua non of Italian unification was thus the modification of the
geopolitical framework that emerged from the Congress of Vienna. This order
suffered in the second half of the century: industrialization, having spread to
other regions, began to transform the relationships between the powers. This
new phase was marked by three major conflicts: the Crimean War, the Ameri-
can Civil War, and the war between Prussia and France. The conflict on the
shores of the Black Sea, according to Paul Kennedy, put an end to the diplo-
macy of the European concert and caused each of the “flank” powers—that is,
Russia and England—“to feel less committed to intervention in the center.”13
Prussia, not yet the hegemonic power of the German world, and Austria, still
wrestling with numerous problems engendered by its years of decadence, left
France to emerge as the dominant power in continental Europe, even if this
was a domination by default.
It was as this new international context was coming to a head that Count
Camillo Benso di Cavour, now prime minister in Turin, launched his strategy
of trying to “diplomatize the revolution.”14 The English and the French, aim-
ing to placate Austria, did everything in their power to engage Piedmont in the
Crimean War, thereby lessening any temptation it might have to take advantage
of the situation to attack Lombardy. Cavour was thus invited to the Congress of
Paris of 1856, during which the “Italian question” was dealt with rather sum-
marily. The brief references to it had no practical consequences; nevertheless,
Cavour obtained two relatively significant results: the increase of Turin’s pres-
tige in Italy, as the Piedmontese kingdom was the only and the first state on
the peninsula to be represented in an international assembly, and, above all, the
An Italian “Miracle”
In the mid-1850s, Napoleon III concluded that conditions were in place for the
“Vienna order” finally to be modified. The major obstacle was, obviously, Austria.
Therefore the “Italian question” served primarily as a pretext to weaken Vienna. As
to Cavour, who was perfectly aware of the geopolitical constraints facing the king-
dom and the Savoy family’s traditional politics, he explicitly offered the French the
geostrategic advantage of controlling the Po Valley.
The relationship—equivocal, to say the least—between the head of the Turin
government and democratic terrorism circles led some historians to suspect him
of inspiring, directly or indirectly, the attack on Napoleon III perpetrated by
Felice Orsini on January 14, 1858. While this was never proved, the attack clearly
could not have come at a better moment for those on either side of the Alps.
Amplifying the revolutionary threat through his resort to spectacular police
measures, Cavour sought to demonstrate that, absent a diplomatic solution to
the “Italian question,” it was going to be difficult to contain all the bombers
roaming around Europe and taking the French emperor as their favored target.
In France, Orsini’s act helped put in motion the process of unraveling the trea-
ties of 1858, supplying Bonaparte with an occasion to prepare public opinion for
a decision bound to be far from popular.
Between July 1858 and January 1859, the pacts between France and Piedmont
were sealed. The map of a new Italy was drawn up, providing for the birth of three
states: the north plus Emilia was attributed to Piedmont, which would cede Savoy
and Nice to France, the center to Napoleon III, and the south to Lucien Murat,
the son of the last king of the Napoleonic Kingdom of Naples and Sicily, Joachim
Murat. These three states were then to be confederated under the presidency of
the Pope. Each protagonist had grounds for satisfaction: Bonaparte because he felt
he had “reconquered” the peninsula, and Cavour, who, considering the thought of
unification as so much nonsense (“corbellerie”),17 hoped for the birth of a homo-
geneous state, limited to the rich northern regions and led by Turin.
The war and its consequences confirm the validity of the thesis that society’s
history is the terrain on which countless wills and forces confront and collide,
with a result rarely corresponding to the protagonists’ initial plans. In fact, the
war provoked not only the expected intervention of France, but also insurrec-
tion in Emilia and Tuscany, which proclaimed their allegiance to Piedmont; the
deep anxiety of the Pope, of whom Napoleon III was the international protector;
the threats of Berlin in Paris and, last but not least, a completely new English
perspective on the Italian question. All these factors, even if separately predict-
able, completely transformed the landscape when they arose all at once. The
emperor, just as the revolutionaries had foreseen,18 decided not to pursue the
routed Austrians, instead signing an armistice with them in Villafranca, near
Verona, on July 8, 1859.
The events of 1859 through 1860 were a sort of archetype of the Italian attitude
on the international stage—imposed by objective circumstances, but nearly always
presented as the result of an autonomous and subjective choice—consisting of
relying on its own weaknesses as if they were elements of strength. Having fur-
nished Napoleon III with a troop contingent significantly smaller than promised,
and after having been accused by Victor Emmanuel of “playing at making revolu-
tion in central Italy,” Cavour resigned after the French-Austrian armistice, slam-
ming the door and denouncing the king as a “traitor” for having signed it.
Yet, these mutual recriminations between the two heads of the Piedmontese
executive did not prevent them from reversing roles later. Victor Emmanuel,
who had signed a treaty guaranteeing the return of the “legitimate sovereigns” to
Florence and Modena, took his own turn at “playing at making revolution” with
Garibaldi, even as he assured Pope Pius IX and the king of the Two Sicilies of
his respect for the integrity of their states—and this just twenty days before the
departure of the Garibaldinian “Red Shirts” for Sicily. Cavour, who had returned
to power under the insistent pressure of the English ambassador in Turin,
reached agreement with Napoleon III to exchange central Italy for the Savoy
(fatherland of the king) and Nice (fatherland of Garibaldi). Later, using as a pre-
text the risks inherent in a breakthrough by the Garibaldinian “bands”—which
he had done nothing to stop—he finally obtained from the French emperor
the authorization to traverse—and to annex on his way through—Romagna,
Marche, and Umbria, which belonged to the states of the Church, thus achieving
the unification of the peninsula.
Several “historical determined connections” thus contributed to the success
of this “Italian miracle”: an official alliance with France, which was trying to
resolve its historic rivalry with the Germanic world; a permanent sort of black-
mail exercised against France itself, based on its weaknesses and fears; an unscru-
pulous game between the varied revolutionary movements; and finally, the room
for maneuver that the Mediterranean policy of the British Empire allowed (and
sometimes encouraged). Among all these factors, the latter was doubtless the
most important.
An English Creation
Having crossed the Mediterranean for Algeria in 1830, colonial France pursued its
expansion under the Second Empire in the direction of Africa and the Far East. In
1854 Ferdinand de Lesseps obtained from the viceroy of Egypt, Mohammed Said
Pasha, a concession to begin excavation for the Suez Canal. Work began in 1859.
To satisfy the demands of an expansionist and Mediterranean politics, the French
fleet was reinforced, to the point that in 1859 it raised apprehensions in London.
From 1859 to 1860, Great Britain’s attitude regarding the “Italian question”
passed through three distinct and apparently contradictory phases that might
appear contradictory but which make sense given traditional Anglo-Saxon prag-
matism: a first phase, during which London wanted to prevent any modification
of the status quo that had served well enough for nearly five decades; a second,
following the armistice of Villafranca, during which English diplomats grew
concerned at the possible expansion of French hegemony on the peninsula; and
finally a third, marked by the insurrections of central Italy and Garibaldi’s expe-
dition to Sicily, which was seen as the definitive collapse of French ambitions,
and in particular as the occasion to integrate the peninsula in a stable manner
into a new balance of power more favorable to the ambitions and interests of the
British crown.
It was for that reason that the British ambassador in Turin “imposed” Cavour’s
return; he was the only man positioned to successfully lead the annexation of the
former states of central Italy. It was also for that reason that the warships of the
Mediterranean fleet “protected” the vessels of the Garibaldinian fleet from any
threat by the Neapolitan navy. And when the Pope and the former king of Naples,
exiled to Rome, threatened to add an international political-military alliance to
the pontifical anathema against the new state, the British made public a fiery dec-
laration justifying Italian unification in the name of the principle of nationality.
This declaration, along with the immediate recognition of the new state, signified
that Italy was henceforth placed under the protection of the Empire of Her Gra-
cious Majesty. Compared to the subalpine kingdom that had served since 1815 as
a buffer state between France and Austria, unified Italy offered added value in its
fortunate geopolitical position.
Having long made the government of the Two Sicilies a pillar of their regional
hegemony, the English now gladly abandoned a contested and vacillating king of
Naples for a young and dynamic Kingdom of Italy whose future Mediterranean
ambitions, at times openly encouraged by other powers, were likely to conflict
with French designs without constituting the slightest threat to English supremacy.
Thus opened what Sergio Romano calls Italy’s “historic cycle of Mediterranean
policy”19 under the shadow of Great Britain. It would continue, almost without
interruption—if not without numerous infidelities—until 1935.
Among the varied protagonists of the Risorgimento, those who, like Cavour, played
an active role managed to do so by rapidly adapting their actions to the actual
movements of the international balance of power. Others, like Garibaldi, played a
role that was, in truth, passive.
Nonetheless, it is the character of Garibaldi who most fascinates those who
have written the history of the Risorgimento. In 1854, even before the actions that
would reinforce his aura—the Expedition of the Thousand, the Aspromonte and
Mentana battles—he received a particularly warm welcome from workers groups
during a visit to London. After 1860 the figure of Garibaldi became the prisoner of
P ostunitary Italy, far from presenting a well-defined face, is the unstable com-
bination of some particular characteristics. The first of these is the fragile dia-
lectic between the various geographical pieces that make it up: the “thousand bell
towers,” the regional particularities, the use of dialect as a badge of local identity,
the relations between the center and the periphery—most particularly, between
the north and the south, ever a source of jealousies, haggling, and friction.
When, beginning in the 1880s, the governments of the Sinistra attempted to
bind up certain of these divisions, they began by co-opting emerging interest
groups, or those previously excluded from power (the southern elites, above all),
and did so simply by juxtaposing them to the already dominant interest groups.
Political institutions thus became the venues of incessant bargaining. The forma-
tion of these fragile and temporary alliances between particular and sectoral inter-
ests was referred to as “transformism,” a process that has accompanied the entire
history of united Italy. This fragmentation hampered the search for a national
“common interest” and consequently prevented the development of any long-
term national strategy.
The impossibility of defining objectives not at the mercy of such transactions
hindered the formation of national political parties able to represent alternative
interests in any enduring way. The problem, which Francesco de Sanctis described
as early as 1877—“We are now at the point where there are no solidly constituted
parties, except perhaps for those based on regions and on clientele, Italy’s two
scourges,” he said1—was a constant of Italian history up to the 1990s. Until that
time, the peninsular political system, lacking viable alternatives, always pivoted
around a sort of “single party”—at times surreptitious, at times official. The liberal
monarchy, fascism, and the Christian Democratic republic all experienced, under
different forms, governmental mechanisms incapable of any change except by
traumatic rupture. Opposition parties were thus always forced to choose between
“subversivism” (different from subversion, which they never practiced) and more
or less open collaboration with power; they sometimes managed simultaneously
to be both subversive and governmental.
28 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
In the early years of the country’s existence, these opposition groups, though
kept at a distance from official political life, possessed a capital that the forces
of the government and the administration lacked: identity. The democrats, the
Catholics, and the Socialists benefited from having strong and clear identities,
which were even more salient in contrast to the governing powers, which lacked
any clearly defined personality.
The fragmentation of the ruling class, the fortuitous character of unification,
the mistrust of politics, and the “pragmatism” of the transformist governments
thus deprived this new creature of a clearly defined national character. At the
beginning of the Italian adventure, the country’s new leaders—the Destra—were
preoccupied with building from nothing the structures of a new state with sud-
denly enlarged borders, and they had little time to abhor any ideological vacuum.
But this changed once Italy found itself projected into the center of a system of
international relations in which it supposedly had a role to play; the difficulty
of defining a plausible national identity began to pose a major problem when
compared to other countries that had constructed their own over centuries. From
that point forward, any shift in the international order had repercussions for Italy,
provoking a more or less serious internal crisis that aroused new doubts about
its identity.
Dynamic Constants
A Heavy Heritage
Generally those who have sought to explain the traditional weaknesses of the Ital-
ian ruling class without resorting to shortcuts like fatalism, moralism, or even rac-
ism, have insisted on the backwardness—or backwardnesses—of the country. We
should keep in mind that the notion of backwardness is relative and based on
multiple factors. It necessarily implies a comparison with other entities presumed
to be more advanced, or examined under different points of view. It also supposes,
naturally, the existence of a competition, of whatever nature.
Italy, even while expressing fairly early on a subjective will to compete with
the other powers of the “European Concert,” found itself from its very birth in
objective competition with those powers, by reason of its history, its “geopolitical
capital,” and the uses the other powers sought to make of it. In the Middle Ages,
Italy was the leading capitalist country in the world, both chronologically and in
terms of its importance. That conferred certain responsibilities: the commercial
expansion led by the Venetians and the Genoese, the financial importance of the
Lombard and Florentine bankers, the prodigious cultural splendor dispensed by
the universities, the literary schools, the centers of pictorial and musical arts, all
left a concrete heritage, of which the use of Tuscan as the lingua franca of many
intellectual and commercial circles was long the most salient sign. If we add to that
the role of universal spiritual power played by one of the peninsular states and, no
less important, the aura of ancient Rome, we can see that the Risorgimento myth
30 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
of a “Third Rome” was far weightier than anything the bards of Italy’s “manifest
destiny” could support.
The Italian colonies present on the Adriatic, in Malta, in Tunis, in Alexandria,
in Istanbul, in the Aegean, and even on the shores of the Black Sea endowed uni-
fied Italy, virtually, with a far from negligible political capital that it could have
used, at least proportionately, the way de Gaulle used the Francophone community.
Although there were no substantial initiatives to this end, the inheritance of the past
nonetheless helped the new country occupy a space—and not just geopolitically or
geoeconomically—with which others, and Italy itself, would henceforth have to deal.
The ruling class in Piedmont that now found itself in command, preoccupied
with internal concerns and accustomed to dealing with other powers from a sub-
ordinate position, reacted slowly to the new international reality. Relations with
the outside world were perceived without the problem of the saltus really being
raised—and consequently, without necessary connections to internal problems
being made. The theoretical awareness of the gap between ambitions and the
means to achieve them emerged slowly among most of the ruling class: yet, it
was precisely this gap that was to mark the subsequent history of the country and
make its backwardness a problem without a solution.
The Destra, despite a rich theoretical tradition far superior to the disordered
eclecticism of the Sinistra, lost its bearings once unification was achieved. Not
only had the imperatives of centralization drained it of its decentralizing liberal-
ism, but also the Destra incorporated the interests of a dispersed class of property
owners who were weak, few in number, and, with rare exception, insensitive to the
requirements of industrial development. Its conservatism was dictated not only by
its will, however understandable, to preserve the social relationships from which
it drew its wealth, but also by the quite natural sociopsychological reflex through
which all human groupings tend to persevere with the mechanisms that made
their success possible.
One idea originating in England, and to which the property owners were
evidently sensitive, was that “the Italians’ steam is their sun,”5 as the industrial-
ist Richard Cobden told Massimo d’Azeglio in 1847. During the debate on the
commercial treaty with France of 1863, the deputy Carlo de Cesare explained to
the chamber his free-trade choice by noting that “the climate, the air, the sun, the
countryside of Italy will never permit us to become eminently industrial like the
English and the French. One struggles in vain against the laws of nature.”6 The pre-
eminence of “natural” social relationships, deemed so because of their bond to the
earth, led several representatives of the Destra to posit a sort of “agrarian fatalism”
as one of the “laws of nature.”
When the first serious difficulties appeared, coming on top of the crisis of the
southern brigantaggio, the need for a more profound consideration became clear.
Thus one observer went so far as to describe unification as a distortion of the
laws of history and geography and to observe, as did the southern liberal Giustino
Fortunato, that the new country had a cumulative “lag of several centuries vis-à-
vis other civilized nations.”7 Once the problem of Italy’s “lag” or backwardness
was posed in these terms, a small minority began the search for its causes, and the
means to attack it.
HOW PREMATURE DEVELOPMENT BECAME A FACTOR OF BACKWARDNESS 31
A “Too-Early” Comer
Among the paradoxes of Italian history, one of the most singular is that the coun-
try, generally considered as a “late comer,” is in truth a “too-early comer,” if one
can put it that way. The decline and then the decadence of the peninsula after
the Renaissance are in direct relationship to the precocity of its development: too
much commerce, too much production, too much wealth, and cities that were too
large for the economic, political, or military conditions of the era.8
Without wading into the debate on the causes of Italian decadence, let us briefly
consider a few points that may illuminate the political factors in contemporary
Italy and of the social psychologies behind them.
It is necessary first to set aside a few simplifications. While the conditions for
the decadence of the richest Italian cities were present by the end of the fourteenth
century, it would be inexact to suggest that the Italian economy of the Renaissance
was decadent. At the end of the fifteenth century, for example, Florentine banks
kept capital reserves two to three times what the bankers Peruzzi and Bardi used
in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries. More significantly, as the economics
historian Vera Zamagni states, at the end of the seventeenth century, Bologna was
the most highly industrialized city in Europe.9 The decline thus stretched out over
a very long period, and it was not until the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries
that we can really speak of decadence.
Thus the prevailing notion that the great geographical discoveries of the late fif-
teenth century constituted the direct and immediate cause of Italian decline must
be considered with caution. They doubtless catalyzed—but did not provoke—a
process rooted in developments at least a century earlier. When one considers the
reasons for decline in their entirety, both economic and political, it becomes clear
that many of them are linked to “excess” growth, that is, a physiological defect
of capitalism that Italian development highlighted for the first time in history:
overproduction.
Among the causes of Italian weakening, Vera Zamagni cites above all the accu-
mulation in a few hands of the wealth engendered by prosperity.10 This accu-
mulation was due to several causes, starting with the substantial stability of an
internal market that, as the misery of the masses persisted, offered few prospects
for enlargement outside those guaranteed by the rich merchants, bankers, aris-
tocrats, and princes of the Church, ever more refined and demanding. Then, the
increasingly limited dimensions of the world market on the one hand and of tech-
nological capacities on the other probably made it difficult to contemplate major
investments that would render productivity more extensive or intensive, and this
further encouraged the tendency toward what we now would call nonessential
consumption.
According to Maurice Aymard, the technological deficit also contributed
to inflexibility in different sectors of production. This was true notably in the
countryside, in the face of increased demand provoked, again, by growth. Sup-
ply shortages pushed up wheat prices, in turn leading to increased salaries for
manufacturing jobs, and consequently, a transfer of capital into agriculture, where
development potential could be realized only slowly.11
32 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Finally, we must not forget the rigidity of corporations, which tend to perpetu-
ate means of production and levels of remuneration even when they are no longer
appropriate.
The “corporations of artisans and tradesmen” began appearing in the second
half of the twelfth century, at first simply as associations for defense and mutual
assistance; but later, they rapidly became a necessity of economic life in towns and
cities, the inevitable consequence of the closed nature of communal markets. The
proliferation of autonomous communes—born in just a few decades on the bases
of the old Roman cities—had the corollary effect of producing a complete divi-
sion of work between country and city. Thus each commune, needing to establish
a vital relationship with the surrounding countryside, found itself in a state of
near-constant hostility, open or latent, with the neighboring commune, typically
thirty to forty kilometers distant. In these conditions, the city and the countryside
had no choice but to preserve at all costs their mutually indispensable economies.
Toward that end, they created mechanisms to regulate, limit, or prevent free com-
petition within the commune. Clearly this artificial equilibrium—which allowed
the artisan or small merchant to forecast the precise quantity of merchandise that
he would be certain to sell to his restricted and guaranteed clientele—could not be
maintained in an era when certain cities had reached far higher levels of develop-
ment. It was at that moment, in the second phase of the communal age, particu-
larly between the second half of the thirteenth century and the first half of the
fourteenth, that corporations became major impediments to growth, a key cause
of the decline of certain regions to the profit of others with more flexible and
lower-cost labor forces.12
At this stage of economic and social evolution, the potential offered by the
organization of the state began manifesting its clear superiority over the cit-
ies: the internal monopoly guaranteed by communal organization was over-
whelmed by this newer form of organization that could regulate, protect, and
encourage commerce both internally and externally. That gave rise, in effect, to
converging movements of the commercial bourgeoisie toward the absolute state
(helping it extend the means of communication and defend against the nobility
and competitors), and of the absolute state toward the commercial bourgeoisie
(furnishing it, through taxes and credit, with the means to finance its adminis-
tration and its wars).
This tendency toward the formation of national states (as they would be called
much later) took shape at a time when the decline of the Italian states had already
reached a relatively advanced stage. But the new economic problems alone do not
sufficiently explain this missed rendezvous that, in the final analysis, would prove
fatal for Italian development.
When the Europe of the fifteenth century—this “hodge-podge of petty king-
doms and principalities, marcher lordships and city-states,”13 as Paul Kennedy
describes it—began witnessing the formation of the first states of a certain size,
the Italian cities, which had developed far beyond the limits of the old, small
communes, arose as a final insuperable obstacle preventing the constitution of
an absolute Italian state. The great modern monarchies, on the other hand, had
the good fortune not to encounter, on their paths toward unification, any serious
HOW PREMATURE DEVELOPMENT BECAME A FACTOR OF BACKWARDNESS 33
urban obstacle.14 It is not by chance that the south, where urban civilization was
much less developed, had been the only region on the peninsula to unify, for better
or for worse.
Of course, other factors contributed to this outcome: demographic movements,
growth in external trade, the expansion of the monetary economy, the appearance
of new competitors in central and southern Europe as well as in Mediterranean
trade, the threat presented by Turkish advances, and finally, geographic discover-
ies, although their real effects would become clear only much later.
But if one wanted to synthesize this abortive process, one could say that each
of the five city-regions that then dominated on the peninsula—Milan, Florence,
Rome, Venice, and Naples—was too strong to allow one of its rivals to impose
hegemony on it and too “weak” to succeed in imposing it. Thus began a period
characterized by a long series of debilitating wars, with frequent appeals to foreign
powers and the progressive deferment of any hope of being able to manage the
creation of a central power or, at a minimum, to reform a fragmented market.
These initial characteristics marked the history of the peninsula so profoundly
that they would remain present even after unification.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 2
but one: “The Third (Estate) thus embraces everything that belongs to the nation;
and everything that is not the Third cannot be viewed as being of the nation.”2 So
it should not be surprising that the Napoleonic Wars, the first attempt at bourgeois
unification in Europe, were fought under the banner of the nation. Nor should it
be surprising that, having modified social relationships in the conquered coun-
tries, they would have awakened “national” sentiments there, at times taking the
form of collaboration and at times opposition to the French armies.
The supposed contradiction between a sort of “civilizing mission” of nation-
alism and its “thirst for domination” is in fact an inevitable consequence of the
contradictory nature of the bourgeoisie. This class has always combined its par-
ticular national interests with its universal interests, everywhere attempting to cre-
ate favorable conditions for its businesses. The implementation of the “principle
of nationality” at Versailles in 1919 confirms that pure national states have never
existed, but that all states have adopted the “national” form as a political cover for
their modernization and expansion.
National Europeanism
This gap between the dynamic economic power of Italy and political structures
incapable of supporting its interests in the face of international competition is
not, however, an exclusively Italian occurrence. Being composed of men, states,
along with their bureaucracies, their institutions, their political parties, their trade
unions, and their economic groups, are ever vigilant, as is any living organism,
about their own preservation and reproduction. Toward that end, they sometimes
tend to encroach on one another’s areas of competence. One could almost say
that a degree of confusion about roles and prerogatives constitutes a physiological
“anomaly” common to every political system. In Italy, in any case, this “anomaly”
has often produced a pathological degeneration: Fascism went so far as to codify
this, by superimposing the roles of the party and the state, and by the latter’s seizure
of key economic sectors; the republic roughly maintained this confusion, despite a
strictly liberal constitution, by perpetuating organic links between a Christian Dem-
ocratic “party-state” and the key centers of economic control. It is thus not surpris-
ing that once this mechanism ceased functioning in one direction—from politics
toward the economy—it began functioning in the opposite direction. The ascen-
sion to the highest offices in the state of Carlo Azeglio Ciampi (former governor of
the Bank of Italy), of Romano Prodi (former chairman of IRI, Italy’s biggest state
38 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
all for Italy to avoid giving the impression that it was a country whose various
parts were available to the highest bidder.
These two theses, considered in their pure theoretical formulations, appear
radically opposed, and incompatible. That did not prevent the two political for-
mations which represented the most extreme versions—the Northern League and
the former Fascist National Alliance—from reaching governmental and electoral
agreements, almost without interruption, within the center-right coalitions.
The accession to the European Monetary System (1978) and the subsequent
signing of the Treaty of Maastricht (1991) drastically reduced the number of “het-
erodox” options available, notably the possibility of a competitive devaluation
of the lira. From that point on, despite some bitter disagreements and oratorical
jousting, at times bordering on the grotesque, all the Italian political groupings
have been, to varying degrees and at varying times, Europeanist, federalist, and
national, with the partial exception of the Northern League, which sometimes
added—for purely extortionate purposes—a secessionist nuance. The neo-Fascist
party headed by Gianfranco Fini was, for its part, anti-European, so long as it
continued to see itself as being excluded a priori from any possibility of directly
controlling power. Once this possibility became reality for the first time with the
electoral coalition of 1994, not only did it throw overboard all its Mussolinian-
derived ideological bric-a-brac but also it converted to Europeanism—moderate
and nationalist, to be sure, but still in phase with the imperatives of Italian eco-
nomic power. This proves that, polemical excesses aside, there simply was no other
path possible but the one indicated by Brussels.
The editorial board of Limes was quite aware of this. In the issue mentioned,
General Carlo Jean gave concrete dimension to the geopolitical quest for a national
identity: “Interests cannot be mapped in concentric circles of decreasing intensity,”
he wrote. “The only objective parameters allowing us to identify them are the size
of economic exchange and the number of Italian citizens in the various zones.”7
Based on the first of these two parameters, most observers agreed that Italy’s inter-
ests lay, above all, in Europe.
According to data furnished by Patrizio Bianchi,8 in 1992 to 1993, 41.7 percent
of direct foreign investment by Italian industry went to Western Europe, 27.1 per-
cent went to Eastern and central Europe and the former USSR, for a total of 68.8
percent of all investment abroad. Investments for corporate control amounted
to 74.3 percent of all investments for the whole of Europe. The objective for the
“optimists of will” was therefore not to disengage from the European process, but
rather to try to more effectively advance Italian interests within Europe, or as Jean
put it in a frank and direct manner: “We cannot permit Italy to be useful to Europe
unless Europe is useful to Italy.”
Unfortunately for the “optimists of will,” in 1994 the season of national Euro-
peanism had not yet arrived. If it were to have any hope of following the rhythms
and meeting the deadlines of the European process, Italy still had many exams to
pass, many companies to privatize, much debt to reduce, many tangles to unravel.
It was in no position to insist that Europe demonstrate, any more than Bianchi’s
data had already done, how it could “serve Italy.” The immaturity of this line of
reluctant Europeanism was one of the principal reasons—perhaps the principal
40 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
one—for the very early end of Silvio Berlusconi’s first attempt to rule the coun-
try. Thus “passive Europeanism” became, paradoxically, the only way for Italy to
overcome its backwardness and lessen the fluctuations due to the gap between its
economy and its politics.
Northern Europeanism
In an essay published in the August 1996 issue of Limes, Jacopo Turri analyzed four
ways that the risks posed by the Northern League might evolve: a “Belgian” model,
involving increasing autonomy for the regions, which, however, would not dare
go to the point of a rupture; a “Czechoslovak” model, characterized by a peaceful
and consensual separation; a “Soviet” model, born from the implosion of the state
“envelope”; and a “Yugoslav” model, where separation would carry “worrying and
bloody” implications.9
None of these four models applied to the Italian case. In fact, the author him-
self imagined a fifth hypothesis—even though he termed it extremely unlikely—
of a “neutralization of the League” through its co-option within the system and
its transformation into one of the elements of a new political balance built on
bipolarity. Ultimately this “co-option” took place: it was one of Silvio Berlusconi’s
fundamental achievements, and it helped propel him to victory in the elections of
May 2001.
The long and durable governmental collaboration between the Northern
League and the center-right beginning in 2001 should not make us forget that the
party of Umberto Bossi had been, in December 1994, the parliamentary faction
responsible for the fall of the first Berlusconi government, nor that it later assured,
along with the parties of the center-left, the survival of the government of Lam-
berto Dini until the elections of 1996. Thus when, in June 1995, the League created
a “Parliament of the North,” with the objective of writing the constitution of the
“Italian federal republic,” the head of the opposition at that time, Silvio Berlusconi,
termed the initiative a “grotesque bit of buffoonery,” while the head of the Demo-
cratic Party of the Left (PDS; the former Italian Communist Party) and future
prime minister, Massimo D’Alema, termed it a “normal political initiative, lacking
any subversive character.”10 A few months later the same D’Alema explained that
the League had much in common with the left, above all a “strong social contigu-
ity,” as Bossi’s grouping was in the majority among the workers of the North.11
Even after the electoral victory of the center-left in 1996, the new prime minister,
Romano Prodi, offered the League the chairmanship of two parliamentary com-
mittees, including the one in charge of regional affairs.12
The apprehensions regarding the “secessionist” threats of the League redoubled
in intensity when the grouping, electorally weakened, flatly renounced any pos-
sibility of an alliance with the left and again became the object of Silvio Berlus-
coni’s earnest attentions. Virulent campaigns ensued, and they were all the more
virulent because everyone knew that the elections of 1996—when the center-right
forces victorious in 1994 had increased their electoral pull—had been carried by
a center-left coalition only because of the electoral division between Berlusconi’s
THE PHANTOM NATION 41
“House of Liberty” coalition and the Northern League. It was at that moment
that a certain number of leftist intellectuals discovered the virtues of “republican
patriotism,” in order to oppose the “risks of the disintegration of the nation.”
In fact, the exaggeration of the risks represented by the League was often the
form taken in the political battle over assuring its support—or demonizing it
when it was moving toward the opposite pole. Rare were those who grasped the
real motivations; among them was Sergio Romano, who said: “If Italy does not
enter into Europe on the first of January 1999, the unity of the nation is in danger.
He who truly believes that the country’s northern regions would accept, tomor-
row, being left in the bosom of Piraeus, Andalusia and Estremadura, while see-
ing themselves separated, perhaps irremediably, from the Tyrol, the Carinthians,
Bavaria and the Alpine departments of France, well, this man would be commit-
ting a serious political error.”13
In this utterly explicit “egoism,” one finds the reasons for the strength of the
League starting in the late 1980s, but one also finds their antithesis, which is to say,
the reasons that led to its electoral weakening, starting precisely in January 1999. To
simplify, the regionalist movements reflected the fierce determination of a few of
the most dynamic economic groups to remain bound to Europe (if only to be rid of
the parasitic burden). A sort of direct relationship was thus established between the
strength of the League and the delay in the movement toward European integration.
And vice versa, for, even as the various steps in the rapprochement to the European
process were taken by the “country-system” as a whole, the determination of one
part of these groups changed direction toward the “passive Europeanism”, their prin-
cipal aim still being not to lose contact with the Tyrol, the Carinthians, Bavaria, and
the Alpine departments of France.
“Passive Europeanism” thus seemed to satisfy this demand. In the wake of his
victory in 1996, Romano Prodi confirmed his government’s intention to adapt
his country as quickly as possible to the criteria of the Maastricht Treaty.14 This
decision was supported not only by the will of the head of government but also by
the opening of credit from Europe, and from Germany in particular, which culmi-
nated on November 24, 1996, with the readmission of the lira into the European
Monetary System, a sort of holding room on the path to the common currency.
That is why, little by little, the League lost part of its electoral influence, to the
benefit of the parties of “national Europeanism,” which had been hunting on more
or less the same ground, geographically and socially. In the elections of 1996, this
open competition resulted in what was called a “vendetta of the North” between
the League and Forza Italia, with the result not only of allowing the center-left
to win the elections but also of excluding from the first Prodi government any
representation of Milan (outside the existing links between Minister Antonio
Maccanico and Mediobanca15), or of Lombardy and the northeast. The political
convulsions that flowed from the crisis of the 1990s thus raised anew the existence
of an unresolved “southern question.”
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 3
I n his “Prison Notebooks,” Antonio Gramsci contends that all Italian intellectual
life up to the twentieth century was no more than a “phenomenon of French
provincialism”:1 it pretended to have its foundations in historic antecedents in
Italy, but in fact these antecedents were well rooted in the culture and traditions
of France.
When national identities are invented, reciprocal borrowing is the rule. But for
the Italian ruling classes and intellectuals, France was long the almost exclusive
reservoir of ideas, taste, institutions, and symbols. The centralism, the system of
prefects and of education, the literary, philosophical, and scientific trends, even
the flag of the Cispadane Republic—everything was based on the French model.
Remarking on this “intellectual and moral hegemony of foreign intellectuals,”
Gramsci concludes that in Italy there is no “national intellectual and moral bloc.”2
His undeniably perceptive observations notwithstanding, Gramsci some-
times overestimates the capacity of intellectuals to influence historic events,
either positively or negatively. In observing the process of Risorgimento, one
might better explain the cultural hegemony of the “moderates” by the very
nature of a national “revolution”—which was meant to take place without pro-
voking ruptures or, above all, involving the masses. In short, by hoping to have
a revolution without a revolution, the Italian bourgeoisie condemned itself to
seeking awkward compromises with the old dominant groups, thus perpetuat-
ing its own divisions and all the constraints caused, among other factors, by
structurally unequal regional realities.
The intellectuals who committed themselves to the Risorgimento were not in a
position to forge a national identity; at times, they even explicitly refused to do so,
as was the case with Vincenzo Gioberti. But it is not enough to merely say this; one
must also seek to identify the “objective responsibilities” that help determine the
subjective responsibilities evoked by Gramsci. It is in seeking these that one finds
the elemental basis of a connection between an Italian “national question” and the
“northern question”: indeed, the only bourgeoisie within the geographic confines
of the peninsula that was truly in a position to support the cause of national iden-
tity was the Lombard bourgeoisie. And yet, it did not do so.
44 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
As the historian Giorgio Rumi noted,3 when one deals with the question of
Italian decadence, one often returns to Milan and its incapacity to become the
“European bridgehead of the country,” its incapacity to play a significant role in
the political life of the country. And this incapacity is a constant of Italian history,
at least up to its most recent Berlusconian variation.
The social psychology of the northern Italian elites—who placed the jealous defense
of their territory’s dynamism above all nonepisodic involvement in any other activ-
ity4—has been solidifying for centuries. In a text presented at the Sixth Italian Scien-
tific Congress of 1844, Carlo Cattaneo dates from the time when the ancient Roman
municipalities reappeared—between the late first millennium and early second—
the first wave of transformation of the serfs into the free peasants, transformation
that, in subsequent centuries, spread through all of Europe.5 This emancipation of
feudal law, achieved in the name of old Roman right, allowed numerous Lombard
cities to give birth to a civilization founded on what Cattaneo calls the “occupations
of peace”: commerce, trade, and industry. Even in modern times, Cattaneo proudly
points out in another text,6 “the streets of Paris and of London carry the names of
Lombard bankers; and ‘Lombard,’ in France, meant banker.”
This historic phase culminated with the Duchy of Milan, whose state power
and territorial expansion were proportional to the prosperity of its economic
activities. Still, we must again point out that the appetites born from this exuber-
ance were behind the decadence that was to follow. Like all Italian states—too
weak to absorb others, too strong to let themselves be absorbed—Milan relied
on foreign assistance and entrusted its political ambitions to the army of the king
of France Charles VIII. Despite the multiple and successive twists and turns of
Ludovic Sforza himself, the Lombard capital lost forever its political independence
and, at the same time, lost some of its importance relative to other great cities
of the north—Venice, Genoa, Turin—which, themselves, maintained their role as
political capitals.
Thus opened a new phase in Milan’s historic existence, characterized by the
divorce between its economic strength and its political power. As Rumi put it,
then began “a destiny of civil magnificence and political impotence.”7 The seeds
of the Lombard social psychology that have been transmitted down through the
centuries were sown.
Control of the ancient duchy of the Sforzas passed into Spanish hands in 1535.
The decadence that followed brought economic decline and a shrinking of bor-
ders. According to Cattaneo, it was a certain “contempt for the trades and for busi-
ness”—which the Spaniards considered “work suitable for infidels and the impure
castes”8—that led to this decadence. The Austrian conquest, two centuries later,
did not restore the city’s political prerogatives, but favored a rebirth of the hard-
working traditions of the local populace, returning a certain degree of administra-
tive autonomy to the municipalities while simultaneously abolishing feudal rights,
which were replaced by a modern cadastral system within a substantially unified
THE NORTHERN QUESTION 45
commercial space. Vienna’s solicitude allowed the Lombards to return to their old
traditions of productive intensity.
According to Cattaneo’s calculations, the Lombard peasants enjoyed produc-
tivity rates twice those of their French counterparts. Besides, the city of Milan
alone employed some 450 engineers, while the French Department of Bridges and
Highways (Ponts et Chaussées) employed only 568 for the entire country.9 This
pride in producers who were “more brave than lucky”10 strengthened the convic-
tion that Lombardy was summoned by a singular destiny to give birth to not just
any sort of civilization, but precisely to an “economic civilization” that could com-
pensate for the loss of political supremacy.
In fact, this conviction reflected reality: Lombardy was not only the most pros-
perous region south of the Alps; it was the richest in all the Austrian Empire. But this
conviction also reflected the real state of things, in that “political impotence”—along
with “civil magnificence,” to be sure—left the dominant Lombard classes without a
state of their own to count on. This obliged them to engage with the central authori-
ties in a sort of permanent negotiation. This situation gave rise to a series of recipro-
cal dependences which—when examined in all their complex and often conflicting
intertwinings, marked by suspicion, subtle calculations, ruses, and collusion—might
help us unravel the tangle of the Italian nation.
For a long time the “northern question” was merely the rhetorical, polemical
counterpart to the more famous “southern question.” It became a real political
problem only when Milan found itself no longer satisfied to play its traditional
role as “moral capital” and began demanding greater involvement in the manage-
ment of political power.
The early beginnings of this came in the late 1970s and the early 1980s, and its
causes were the same as those that later were to provoke the upheaval of the Ital-
ian political panorama. At that time, the “northern question” manifested itself in
two apparently distinct forms: the stormier of the two, and thus the one bound to
arouse the curiosity of the media, had to do with the local electoral lists referred
to as “civic” lists (i.e., not linked to existing political parties), which, while existing
more or less throughout Italy, in the north ultimately federated themselves into
several leagues, and finally into the Northern League; the other form, reminiscent
of the course of an underground river, led in 1983 to the nomination of Bettino
Craxi as head of the government, the first Milanese president of the council in all
the history of unitary Italy.
The League’s “folkloric” forms of public activity masked the distant roots of
the “northern” factor. For the historian Marco Meriggi, the League’s anticentral-
ism and antifiscal polemic can be seen as a resurgence of a trait that has recurred
through the history of these regions, where development and wealth are concen-
trated to the highest degree.11
For these reasons, it can be difficult to understand Italian political events of the
latter part of the twentieth century if one ignores certain constants in the social
46 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
In short, at the end of the nineteenth century, some of the constants of the
social psychology of the dominant Lombard classes—the defense of the particu-
lar prerogatives of different municipalities; the feeling of being subjected to a
sort of systematic pillage of wealth produced; the polemic against the “foreign”
capital of the pillagers—had ample political echoes. The ideologies that resulted,
however, were merely the forms in which this social psychology was historically
incarnated.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 4
Inventing Ancestors
Plebeian Jacqueries
T he idea that production and good administration are more important than
the management of public affairs is a legacy from the Lombard bourgeoisie to
the rest of the country.1 In the early decades of unified Italy, the productive bour-
geoisie remained largely at a distance from political power and made no attempt
to define a vision of the whole, a general “national” perspective. It thus remained
prisoner to its own regional and cultural divisions, the two often going hand in
hand. The absence of a coherent ideological horizon left room for a sort of ersatz
conscience that Giulio Bollati has identified in history and in the invention of the
“national character.”2
Bollati wanted to avoid the traps of the “pure idea or ethnic ether,”3 and pro-
posed measuring and verifying the concrete manifestations of Italian social psy-
chology. His first step was to define the historic circumstances and the temporal
space in which the Italian made his first appearance as a social species unto its own,
between the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century. Previously, the author
suggests, Italians were nothing more than a highly confined group of speakers
of a capricious and often arbitrary language that had outlived its past glory. The
inhabitants of the peninsula had almost nothing in common on a cultural level
and, in their near totality, were ignorant of even the most elementary rudiments of
the spoken language—or, as we shall see, the written—used by the confined group
mentioned above.
The principal characteristic of the history of this mass of uncultivated natives
was precisely its lack of history: they had scarcely played any role in the diverse
historic processes that had unfolded on the peninsula. Or more precisely, they
had participated the way slaves participated in the construction of the great classic
civilizations.
This phenomenon has been explained in various ways. According to Galli della
Loggia, for example, the resigned and passive submission of the Italian peasant
masses stemmed from the fact that they were politically controlled not by a feudal-
type aristocracy, as in the classic European model, but by cities and by the Church.
50 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
As everywhere else, this control was based on a relationship of forces; but it also
depended on the prestige enjoyed by the communes and on the Church’s ability
to remain close to rural communities and thereby neutralize any temptation they
had to revolt.4 Thus, in the absence of serious peasant movements in medieval and
early modern Italy, it was the urban plebes—from the Vespers of Palermo to the
Revolt of the Ciompi, from Cola di Rienzo to Masaniello—who were the protago-
nists of sporadic episodes of rebellion.5
In the cases mentioned, conflicts were more often provoked by profound
political crises than by social crises, as with the German peasant revolt of 1525 or
the French peasant reaction during the “grande peur.” The explosions of Italian
anger mentioned above were brief, indecisive, and quickly subdued. They were
not the action of a class or of a coalition of classes, but rather of an ambiguous
mass of the lower classes, of “plebes” without history, roots, defined interests, or
premeditated designs.
It is notable that such keen observers of Italian reality as Giuseppe Prezzolini,
Luigi Barzini, and Indro Montanelli employed nearly identical images to draw a
sort of “analogical portrait” of Cola di Rienzo as a paradigm of one form of the
Italian political struggle, comparing him to Benito Mussolini. “He embodied the
inflamed and angry temperament of the ignorant and frustrated commoners,”
wrote Montanelli. Di Rienzo, he added, was “a typical Italian troublemaker who,
when he speaks, gets drunk on his own words and ends up believing them, thus
losing all sense of reality and proportion.”6
Naturally, analogies between Cola di Rienzo and Mussolini must be viewed
with caution, given the differences between the two periods. Nonetheless, once
one starts in this direction one must not stop with external coincidences, one must
consider the symptomatic conditions that surrounded the birth, six hundred years
apart, of these two very similar political phenomena: first is the existence of a sort
of social and political sediment that filters into any space vacated by state author-
ity and generates the sort of banditism that, Prezzolini says, Italians idealized as a
revolt against the established order; next comes the composite pragmatism of the
political “programs” built on this slippery, viscous mire; and finally, the readiness
of Italians to succumb in times of crisis to a fascination with the “providential
man”—these three factors are often found in Italian history.
Fabricating Ancestors
Each country, at the moment when it creates its national identity, discovers a cer-
tain number of more or less legendary figures in its past who are then raised to the
rank of ancestors. But the question arises: How are these figures chosen?
The shadow of Rome, of course, extends over much of Italian history. But, as
Theodor Mommsen pointed out, the Italians, divided, undisciplined, and defeated
in almost all their wars, can be considered heirs of the Romans—who for their
part unified the civilized world by force of arms and law—only in the way that
maggots can be considered heirs of the carrion of a once proud and noble horse.7
INVENTING ANCESTORS 51
Classical writers—Virgil, above all, but also Cicero and Titus Livius—
“explained” Rome’s greatness as flowing from the particular favor that the Urbs
enjoyed among the gods. Augustine and other fathers of the Church “explained” it
as providential design. To Dante, the divine seal on the “Eternal City” made collab-
oration between the Church and the empire indispensable. This insistence on the
providential character of Rome contributed to the creation of a myth, more politi-
cal than religious, that others through the ages have drawn upon, from Petrarch to
Machiavelli, from Alfieri to Mazzini, from Carducci to Mussolini. Still, there is no
Roman who, in Italian mythology, fills the role occupied by, for example, Vercin-
getorix in French mythology.
One explanation could stem from the fact that national ideologies began form-
ing during the eighteenth century, at a time when they had, first, to distinguish
themselves from the French model. Thus, instead of Greco-Roman mythology,
or the mythology of the Mediterranean world, upon which France had a corner,
it was the rustic thatched cottages of northern Europe that were celebrated. The
new national cultures were forged by opposing “their bodies to the threat of the
universal monarchy imposed by Rome,” in the words of Fichte,8 where, behind
Rome, one must read Paris.
Divided between their admiration for philosophical and revolutionary France
and their desire to free themselves from its domination, Italian intellectuals thus
hesitated between several myths. Those drawn to the “thatched villages” of north-
ern Europe summoned up a mythical peasant who, however, had one major draw-
back—he could easily be compared to other, actually existing, peasants. The actually
existing peasants could not boast of the imaginary characteristics that their mythical
“colleagues” own and, moreover, had to be kept at a distance from the creation of
unitary Italy. The result was a sort of latent schizophrenia that would do nothing to
strengthen the “feeble popular legitimation of the Italian state.”9
other types of domination. In this double oppression was the sort of total cultural
submission of the peasants that Galli della Loggia describes; they were reduced to
a state of political insignificance and “covered, anthropologically, with discredit.”10
We mentioned the “overlapping” between the ruling classes of the city and
those of the country: the former “offered” the latter the cultural instruments of
their domination, the latter brought to the city the “minor tradition” of a popular
culture of which they, too, were the guardians. That explains the persistence of
the “agrarian cultural paradigm” that feeds some in the intelligentsia aiming to
prepare the terrain for a national Italian ideology.
This “peasant ideology,” nonetheless, is neither exclusively nor specifically Ital-
ian. Almost everywhere, the second phase of identity construction is that in which
the real peasant continues to be treated as a negligible quantity, but the literary
peasant begins assuming the “coelacanth function”11—a living fossil, guarantor of
the reconstitution of the ancestors—embodied until then by a “people” lacking
concrete reference. In the eyes of the urban intellectual sitting at his desk by the
fireplace, the peasant becomes the most authentic expression of the relationship
between a nation and its land, and his mores become ethical references.
At this stage of the construction of identity, Italian intellectuals were far from
being an exception. The real Italian specificity is manifested by the discovery of
the deep roots of “ancient peasant civilization” decades before other European
cultures—late in the eighteenth century—when the process of forming national
unity was still in gestation. Unequal economic development was reflected—in the
medium or, more often, the long term—by an unequal ideological development
whose effects were sometimes surprising. Thus, in Italy, the particular mixture
of capitalism’s precocious rise (and precocious fall), and the way it then increas-
ingly trailed behind other potential competitors, led to a singular phenomenon
of anticipation, which one might define as a sort of “Italian path to Catonism.”12
For centuries, as we have seen, peasants had been condemned by their subordinate
cultural state not only to political insignificance but to “anthropological discredit.”
Testifying to this discredit is the lexicon in which nouns relating to the peas-
ant condition have often become adjectives used to describe someone crude or
grubby: villano, rustico, cafone, zotico. From Tommaso Garzoni (1585) to Giuseppe
Baretti (1769), literature, too, offers evidence of the disdain with which real peas-
ants are viewed.13
It may be of interest to note that in apparent opposition to this “anthropologi-
cal discredit,” only a few years after Garzoni’s work was published, the Bolognese
writer Giulio Cesare Croce published Le sottilissime astuzie di Bertoldo (1606) and
Le piacevoli e ridicolose semplicità di Bertoldino (1608), two books that, according
to Prezzolini, defend “the countryman against the city, the wisdom of tradition
against academic culture” and even “poor nations against rich nations.”14 While
G. C. Croce himself affirmed in his autobiography that “sod and soil are [his]
Latin,”15 his work does not seem to step beyond the confines of the republic of
INVENTING ANCESTORS 53
A ccording to Paolo Greppi, at the end of the eighteenth century Italian land-
owners found themselves caught between the Napoleonic armies and the
peasant masses who, he said, seemed ready at any moment to “cry, ‘To the winner
go the spoils’ and to help the French pillage the rich”1; so it was urgent, he contin-
ued, for these same landowners to persuade the ministers of the various peninsu-
lar states to deploy “two armies in the field, each of one hundred thousand men.”2
In the notes of this gentleman of Lombardy, Bollati sees evidence of three capital
discoveries: first, the existence of a country of seventeen million inhabitants; next,
the possibility, even the obligation, for landowners to federate out of common
interest; and finally, the necessity, if this federation is to survive, to transform the
peasants into consenting citizen-soldiers and turn them away from any tempta-
tion to rebel.3
None of Greppi’s wishes came to pass, for reasons worth further analysis, but
of these the most important surely is the polyphony (indeed, the cacophony) of
reactions to the suggestions coming from revolutionary France. Even if one con-
siders only those who did not militate against the Napoleonic armies, at least two
dissonant refrains emerge: first, the pragmatic realism of the Greppi’s, the Melzi
d’Eril’s, and other Lombard landowners; and, second, the idealism—ranging from
sentimental purism to dogmatic rigorism—of the leaders of the Parthenopean
Republic of 1799.
The lawyer Vincenzio Russo can be considered an archetype of metaphysi-
cal revolutionary idealism. After having been arrested and banished from the
Kingdom of Naples, he wrote from Rome, where he had taken refuge during the
ephemeral republic of 1798 to 1799, a sort of radically antimodern manifesto. The
theoretical postulate of his platform was that “he who extends commerce beyond
simple barter has forged the first links in the chain of slavery.” Russo went on to
preach the destruction of Italy’s leading ports, “a source of corruption,” and the
disappearance of the great cities, “favorable to despotism.”4 While the real people
of Rome revolted against the French troops barely two weeks after their arrival,
56 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Russo’s notion of ideal humanity was rooted in the “sterile regions”: he cited the
mountain folk of Switzerland and the Apennines as models to follow.
One of his political adversaries was his friend Vincenzo Cuoco, a fellow leader
of the Neapolitan revolution of 1799. With Cuoco, the speculative bent of the
southern intellectuals, which in Milan had come into contact with the hard core
of social and political conflicts, transformed itself, to a degree, into the “conscious-
ness from without” introduced to a ruling northern class whose empiricism often
prevailed over coherent theoretical thought. It was not the first time, nor would
it be the last, that the “philosophy” of the south would come to the rescue of a
northern “pragmatism” lacking in great concepts.
Although he was critical of the dogmatic fervor of Vincenzio Russo, it was from
him that Cuoco borrowed the notion of a “peasant philosopher,” in order to forge a
“prototype of an Italian” whose health and vigor emanated precisely from his rural
origins. This ideological reversal of the relationship between city and country-
side could be explained by the possibility—rendered concrete by the conscription
of the masses—of resolving the problem of a national army, a problem that had
haunted partisans of Italian unity since Machiavelli. It was no longer a question,
as had been the case for Greppi, of improvising a military mobilization to face the
French, but rather of laying the bases of an institution on which the legitimacy
of a state would reside. Vincenzo Cuoco thus threw himself into the pedagogical
task of explaining to the landowners that the time for disdain of the people was
past, for it would henceforth be their responsibility to ensure the continuity and
the defense of property. Instead of disdain, it was now time to seek consensus: It
was necessary for the “predominant class” to share with “the servant class” all “the
benefits of civil life.”5
Other intellectuals, such as Berchet, Borsieri, Gioberti, and, especially, Man-
zoni, undertook the task of accompanying this peasant in his encounters with
industrial civilization.
Philanthropic Paternalism
The political immobility of the countryside, Galli della Loggia asserts, was a “con-
stant” of Italian life at least until the second half of the nineteenth century, mainly
58 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
An Imaginary Crucible
Paul Kennedy, in describing the situation of the different powers on the eve of
World War II, wrote that Mussolini’s Italy was one of the rare cases in all the his-
tory of human conflict when a country’s entry into war did more damage to its
allies than to its adversaries.22 What might at first seem like a “bon mot” or a para-
dox is in fact a thesis amply illustrated by a minutely detailed summary of the
structural fragility of Italy in the 1930s: a fragility due, according to Kennedy, to
the persistent dependence on small farming.23
Under Mussolini, the peasantry‘s “Catonist” function—as a rampart of social
stability—reached its apogee. It was no accident that the “virtues of rural life” and
of corporatist ideology were being glorified at the same time. But the resurrection
of corporatist theory from the fogs of medieval history was an ideological opera-
tion, one that cannot be attributed to fascism. It dated back another fifty years,
when Catholic social circles, pointing to the experience of the Catholic Friend-
ship Society of Joseph de Maistre, gave birth in June 1874 to the movement of
l’Opera dei Congressi, the Work of the Congress. Opposed to capitalism, bearers of
an individualistic and conflictual conception of social relationships, they exalted
the virtues of rural society, while viewing the cities as hotbeds of corruption and
impiety. Rerum Novarum, the encyclical promulgated by Pope Leo XIII in 1891,
offered a systematic framework for this social doctrine, founded on an unyielding
opposition to liberal economy, a reevaluation of the corporatist system, a condem-
nation of capitalism, and a demand for a “just salary.” The first “modern” Catho-
lic labor union, the Italian Confederation of Labor (CIL)—founded in 1919 to
stem the rapid rise of the General Confederation of Labor (CGL), the trade-union
60 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Linguistic Dirigisme
A Dead Language
As we have seen, the linguistic tools used for centuries by the various populations
that were now brought together under the virtual name of “Italians” created more
division than cohesion. The persistence of dialects is like a dust cloud left by the
peninsula’s history of fragmentation; the Italian language, for its part, was just
A CULTURE WITHOUT A NATION 63
one more sign of not only regional and local divisions (sometimes even divisions
between a city’s neighborhoods)7 but also of social divisions.
As asserted by Carlo Gozzi, Manzoni himself, Luigi Settembrini, Antonio
Gramsci, and others, Italian was for centuries a “dead language,” resuscitated with
the goal of becoming the koinê—a standard language—of populations of dispa-
rate origins and languages, a little like Hebrew for the state of Israel.
After the fall of the communes and the affirmation of the principalities, writes
Gramsci, Italian became “yet again, a written and not a spoken language, of the
learned and not of the nation,”8 like Latin before it. The same intellectuals who,
even in the nineteenth century, saw the resurrection of Italian as offering a here-
tofore absent “linguistic motherland,” actually used it almost exclusively in their
writing, and often as a second language, after French or a dialect.
Before unification, the “language question” had remained in the domain
of artistic production; with unification, it was supposed to be rethought with
a view to serving the communications needs of the new Italians. The failure
of the Manzonian approach shows that it had become impossible to favor any
other approach based on personal preferences. The theses of the “dirigistes” were
opposed by the “liberal” theses of the man considered the most eminent linguist
of his time, Graziadio Isaia Ascoli, who placed his hopes for the diffusion of
the national language in the improvement of the cultural, economic, and social
conditions in the country.9
In fact, it was not until certain major upheavals shook the bases of “social
immobility” that the Italian language started, however slowly, to become the
collective patrimony of the Italian people. As with other social phenomena, the
moments when this historic movement sped up or slowed down (such as political
unification, the world war, or the “economic boom” of the 1950s) were also the
moments when the propagation of the Italian language sped up or slowed down.
Tullio De Mauro describes four social processes that were largely responsible for
the progressive linguistic unification of the country: the actions of the organs of
the unitary state, industrialization, urbanization, and interregional demographic
exchanges. In fact, the rural flight, which underlay the migration toward cities and
industrializing countries—is simply the flip side of industrialization. If industrial-
ization was the most important social vector of linguistic unification, then clearly the
“agriculturalist” policy adopted by the first unitary governments (despite Cavour’s
resistance) retarded any benefits that the “invisible hand” could have brought—in
language, too—to the puny and vacillating “visible hand” of the state.
As for the latter, the institution on which Manzoni’s hopes largely resided—
schools—probably contributed the least to the diffusion of the Italian koinê. In
contrast, the establishment of a unitary bureaucratic apparatus played a hardly
negligible role. On the one hand, it favored the concentration in Rome of a ruling
class, drawn from the regions, which was forced on a daily basis to use the com-
mon language; on the other hand, by conferring tasks on the peripheral organs of
the new state, it established them as outposts of the Italian language.
Nonetheless, as we have seen, it was compulsory military service that played
the central role in the diffusion of the language. If a schools inspector in Palermo
province in 1864 could deem “satisfactory” an attendance rate of 30 percent for
64 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
boys and 18 percent for girls10—this, though attendance supposedly was “obliga-
tory”—the state was far less yielding in dealing with those who sought to avoid
mandatory military service, going so far as to deport, or even summarily execute,
draft dodgers.
During the first decade of the twentieth century, one could see empirical
evidence that a direct and proportional relationship existed between the end of
“social immobility” and the spread of instruction: During this period of the first
“economic miracle” on the peninsula, the avoidance rate for mandatory schooling
fell rapidly, to 25 percent. Moreover, the zones of “linguistic conservation,” the
countryside, began to depopulate, as people moved to the centers of “linguistic
innovation,”11 that is, the cities. “Thus,” wrote the linguist Matteo Giulio Bartoli in
1930, “the cities, which yesterday were the cradles of dialectal variety, will become
their tombs.”12
the peninsula, lay behind the emigration of the most active and gifted of Italians.
In order to be able to exercise their talents, the latter found themselves having
to put themselves in the service of some foreign power, thus losing all specifi-
cally “Italian” character. The reason Christopher Columbus sailed in the service of
Spain and not of an Italian republic, Gramsci observes, “must be sought in Italy
and not among the Turks or in America,” those generally blamed for the decadence
of the peninsula.18
Leaving aside the emigration of laborers, which began on a massive scale only
late in the nineteenth century, the Italians who gained fame and importance
outside their native land in the most disparate areas were like the “adventurers”
described by Giuseppe Prezzolini. This group, as Prezzolini wrote, would—had
they grown up in a “civil and well-ordered society”—have become “ministers of
state and the most distinguished of diplomats, eminent generals or admirals, pro-
fessors capable of arousing their students’ intellectual curiosity, excellent writers
rich in ideas”; yet all of them, Prezzolini concluded, for want of a supportive state,
elected to try their chances abroad.19
Among a great number of examples, Gramsci recalls that, in the war of Flanders
in the late sixteenth century, a large number of military men, many of particular
genius, were Italians.20 One might also cite two other illustrious examples, both
of them paradigmatic, yet verging on the paradoxical. The first is that of the fate
of Prince Eugene, the only representative of the Savoy family who is still famous
through much of the Christian world for his military virtues.21 Another example
is the battle of Lissa in 1866, where Italian admirals in the service of the Austrian
Empire prevailed rather easily over the quite new military fleet of the Italian king-
dom commanded by Admiral Persano.
This “cosmopolitan function of the cultivated Italian classes”22 had a prejudi-
cial effect on the birth of an Italian cultural identity, a prejudice that men of letters
inherited and in turn passed on through the centuries.
As to the defeat of 1866, Pasquale Villari observed that its reasons should not be
sought so much in the “quadrilateral” of Mantua, Verona, Legnago, and Peschiera,
as in the “quadrilateral of 17 million illiterates and of 5 million Arcadians.”23 As
conservative as he was, Villari did not content himself, as did some of his contem-
poraries, with snide references to the cultural inadequacies of the lower classes; he
was equally critical of the shortcomings of the ruling classes, imbued over the cen-
turies with a cultural education that was dominated, as Gramsci put it, by “empha-
sis, the declamatory style, and stylistic hypocrisy.”24
During the same period when, in France, a generation of men “of science, of
arts and of crafts” began to rally together in the pursuit of “common ideas of com-
mon interests”—thus giving birth to a veritable “party of philosophers”25—in Italy,
each intellectual was entrenched in his own garden, protecting it fiercely from any
outside influences. In France, by bringing together their scattered energies, phi-
losophers had applied themselves to studying their times, with the conviction that
66 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
it was only by exploring the limits within which one operates that one learns to
move beyond them. In Italy, all the cultivated classes remained prisoners of their
situation, even when the French armies brought them the “liberty” that they had
not managed to achieve on their own.
In the eighteenth century, Italian cultural circles remained essentially under
French influence. After the “Great Century,” France’s political, economic, and cul-
tural influence radiated across virtually all the so-called civilized world. But its
effects were particularly important in Italy, because it did not enrich and complete
a vibrant local culture, but, in a sense, replaced it, filling the voids left by an inad-
equate national tradition. Inasmuch as the Italian language was arbitrary and very
rarely used even by representatives of the “cultivated classes,” another linguistic
medium was needed to foster the circulation of ideas and of men as well as of mer-
chandise, which even then had long ago spilled beyond the narrow confines of the
“shadow of the local bell tower” within which one spoke one’s own dialect. This
medium was, quite naturally, French.
The linguist Melchiorre Cesarotti observed, regarding the end of the century,
that there “was no even slightly cultivated person for whom [the French language]
was not familiar and almost natural: the library of worldly women and men is only
French.”26 During Napoleon’s domination of the peninsula, the historian Carlo
Denina, analyzing the junction between the subjective demands of the nascent
Italian bourgeoisie and the existing cultural and political conditions, went so far as
to propose the outright adoption of French as Italy’s national language.27
Most of the authors responsible for the literary glory of the eighteenth and
nineteenth centuries had to struggle to achieve a mastery of Italian that equaled
the ease with which they had mastered French and their own dialect. Vittorio
Alfieri recounted in his autobiography how he had first written in French before
“sinking into the grammarian’s abyss” in order to put himself “in a condition to
know [his] language, as a man of Italy.”28 Francesco de Sanctis writes that Alfieri
had decided to go live in Florence to “disfrancesizzarsi” (de-Frenchify) and “into-
scanirsi” (Tuscanize) himself; and once, after having worked and reworked some
verses, he cried out: “Gira, volta, ei son francesi” (Turn them and turn them again,
they are still French!).29 Manzoni, in a personal letter, compared the “ease” with
which he had written the Lettre à M. Chauvet sur l’unité de temps et de lieu dans
la littérature (1820), in French, with the “suffering endured” during the rewriting
of Promessi Sposi.30 Before becoming a celebrated writer and the author of impor-
tant dictionaries of the Italian language, Niccolò Tommaseo, born in Sibenik, on
the Dalmatian coast, where Venetian dialects competed with Croatian, began his
apprenticeship as a writer in dialect and in Latin, displaying “a skill that his first
compositions in Italian did not manage to equal.”31 Having noticed, during a stroll
in Rome, that Giovanni Verga expressed himself “with difficulty and with numer-
ous imperfections” in Italian, whereas he spoke easily in Sicilian with some sailors
he chanced to meet, the writer Edoardo Scarfoglio wondered “why Verga doesn’t
have the Sicilians he writes about speak in Sicilian.”32 Through the first half of the
twentieth century, several of the most celebrated writers—Gabriele D’Annunzio,
Filippo Tommaso Marinetti, Giuseppe Ungaretti, and Curzio Malaparte, for
example—continued to write with equal ease in French or Italian.
A CULTURE WITHOUT A NATION 67
One might say, as Sergio Romano did, that the entire history of Italian literature
in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries is marked by a certain linguistic precar-
iousness, by a sense that the relationship between the artist and his principal tool
was, in a real way, artificial.33 But, as Gramsci reminds us, “Every time the question
of language resurfaces one way or another, it is because a series of other problems
are lining themselves up at the front of the stage.” The most important of these was
“the development and the enlargement of the ruling classes.”34
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 7
A Rib of France
The Savoy dynasty worked to reassemble the feudal mosaic. It used as its base
communications routes that were often shared but that depended on control of
the peaks through which trade transited between northern and southern Europe:
Mont Cénis and the Saint Bernard passes. This family, with its ancient Burgun-
dian roots, whose authority extended to the Rhone and the banks of Lake Geneva,
considered itself a repository of the frontier culture that united the French, Italian,
and Swiss worlds. When, in the wake of the peace of Cateau-Cambrésis in 1559,
Emmanuel Philibert transferred the capital of the duchy from Chambéry to Turin,
there was no particular sense that it had changed countries, all the more so since
the new capital lived entirely under French influence.5
The decision to transfer the capital to Turin indicated a fundamental politi-
cal reorientation. This was not, however, dictated by a supposed Italian national
vocation, but rather it was due to the uncomfortable position of the duchy, which
existed as a sort of earthenware pot lodged between the cast-iron vessels of France
and the Empire. After the Hundred Years War, the political homogenization of the
French kingdom and the wars of Italy, Savoy’s western possessions found them-
selves under objective threat. Thus the choice of bilingualism, along with other
measures geared toward a progressive “Italianization” of the duchy, had an emi-
nently political significance. This held not only a defensive character vis-à-vis
France but also a view toward later enlargements of the kingdom, which were cer-
tainly more likely in the direction of a weak and divided Italy—and, conceivably,
of Switzerland—than of a strong and centralized France.
Finally, to the extent that one can speak of an “Italian choice,” one cannot do so
before the eighteenth century. It was then that Charles Emmanuel and his entou-
rage broke the precarious bilingual equilibrium and encouraged the use of Italian.
The attestation of Cesare de Laugier shows, nevertheless, the point to which Pied-
montese life remained foreign to these measures, which went against the entire
historic and cultural tradition of the region.
In a famous passage of his De vulgari eloquentia, from 1303, Dante Alighieri defini-
tively excludes (“et si quis dubitat, illum nulla nostra solutione dignamur” [if anyone
doubts it, we would not consider this worthy of a response]) Piedmontese from
the list of commonly spoken Italian tongues.6 As we have seen, Montaigne largely
confirmed this judgment 250 years later. For the former Florentine prior, as for
the chairman of the Parliament of Bordeaux, this was an empirical observation;
modern linguistic studies would later provide scientific confirmation. Linguists
grant Piedmont the particular status of “border land,” with all the ambiguity the
term implies; the specific political calculation involved added to the ambiguity.
The choice of bilingualism for the duchy of Savoy carried with it (and, in a
way, implied) a fundamental contradiction. On the French side, it merely institu-
tionalized the use of a language already widely employed, even among the lower
classes, in view of an effective political unification. But on the Italian side, it was
a juridical fiction, to the extent that there was an attempt to impose by decree
THE DIFFICULT ITALIANIZATION OF THE PIEDMONT 71
a language hardly known outside intellectual circles, and even intellectuals were
highly divided as to its use.
Constanza Arconati noted that, three centuries after the arrival of the dukes in
Turin, the “three national languages [of Piedmont] are French, Piedmontese and
Genovese,” even though, as she underlines, “only French was understood by every-
one.”7 As we have seen, the princes of Savoy themselves used Piedmontese and
French as “national languages”: the use of dialect helped to create a sort of famil-
iarity with their subjects, even the most humble of them, paradoxically facilitating
their sociocultural integration in their chosen region.8
But it was not just Piedmont’s linguistic specificity that marginalized the region
in comparison to the rest of the peninsula. There was also the fact that Piedmont
had not experienced the urban flowering that was such a salient characteristic
of Italian history, and that while in the rest of communal Italy the first collec-
tive emancipations of serfs dated to the thirteenth century, Emmanuel Philibert’s
sixteenth-century attempts to abolish the significant remains of servitude in his
state collided with a highly conservative social and historic framework.
According to Bollati, the effort at renewal, which stemmed from a desire to
follow modern Europe’s footsteps, led not to the birth of the early core of a future
national state, but to “a veritable national state itself,” on the model of the great
monarchies.9 State structures were transformed and consolidated; the goal was to
reinforce the principle of subordinating private interests to a central power. Par-
liaments were the key instrument of this action, while the creation of provinces,
prefectures, and a Council of State helped in forming a modern administrative
structure. As we will see, this evolved form of state was to constitute Piedmont’s
specific contribution to the Italian cultural panorama of the eighteenth century,
and would be a particularly important trump card for Turin during the nine-
teenth-century process of Italian unification. But it was in terms of military orga-
nization that the process of modernization begun by Emmanuel Philibert left the
most enduring mark, from at least three viewpoints: of the independence of the
state; of the subjection of feudal potentates; and in the birth of an alleged Pied-
montese specific “nature”10.
As for this last aspect, it was the military tradition that, according to Balbo,
explained the “greater solidity and the lesser vivacity”11 of the Piedmontese when
compared to the Lombards. This “natural” quality intermingled with the nature
and history of the dynasty: the habit of commanding and obeying the confidence
“in the calming values of bureaucratic regularity”12 were legacies that Piedmont
transmitted to Italy. This heritage was to prove vitally important during Italy’s
critical moments, but would be a major handicap in times when Italy was at its
most dynamic.
Piedmont’s Lag
According to Piedmontese historians of the first half of the nineteenth century, the
region’s “natural” quality reflected a mixture of military tradition, administrative
solidity, and social conservativism. If this correlation of factors indeed underlay
72 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Piedmont’s social order, it clearly was destined to morph from a stabilizing ele-
ment into a multiplier of instability once any of the factors entered into crisis. That
has been the case each time the jealously preserved principle of social homogeneity
has collided with some new historic development. So it was in the eighteenth cen-
tury, when certain eastern regions were incorporated into the Kingdom of Savoy
whose social relationships dominating in the countryside differed significantly
from those typifying rural Piedmont.13 And so it was certainly when Piedmont
felt the shocks of various international upheavals: whether political catastrophes
like occupation under Napoleon; or new conditions emerging in world markets,
as in the 1870s, when the end of the free-trade cycle gave a coup de grace to the
“agriculturist path to economic development” that the Piedmontese had followed.
It is important to recall that Piedmont’s lag behind the rest of Italy proved both
a blight and a blessing for the House of Savoy. There is no doubt, for example,
that the region’s social conditions at the point when the capital was transferred to
Turin were among the peninsula’s worst. Yet this immaturity put the duchy in a
potentially favorable situation compared to the other Italian states; while the oth-
ers found themselves at the start of a phase of senescence, the duchy could be seen
as having a certain youth, with prospects of considerable growth and develop-
ment. Moreover, from the end of the sixteenth century, Piedmont-Savoy appeared
(along with Venice, which was possibly even less Italian than Turin) to be the only
Italian state that had maintained its independence in the face of the omnipresent
Spanish guardianship ratified at Cateau-Cambrésis.
But the Savoys’ objectives were not national, they were territorial and dynastic,
and their policy of state reform must be placed in this strategic perspective. Even
at this point, Piedmont’s development lagged behind the rest of the peninsula.
When Victor Amedeus II reformed the administration of his state, developed the
University of Turin, and fought against abuses by the clergy and the nobility, notes
Procacci, the Medici still reigned in Florence, Naples had yet to regain its indepen-
dence, and Habsburg reformism had not yet reached Milan. But the advantage was
only apparent, and it was transitory. Rather than anticipating the great reforms of
the eighteenth century, the Kingdom of Piedmont attempted to create for itself
structures worthy of a “great European monarchy,” but based (though with a few
decades’ delay) on the classic scheme of absolutism. Thus, by opting for a protec-
tionist mercantilism, the Savoy king completely ignored the liberalization of land
and merchandise that was taking shape in Lombardy and Tuscany, and he encour-
aged the trends toward the integration of a nearly invisible bourgeoisie with the
diffusion of the “bourgeois gentilhommes” who financed the public debt even as
they shed their entrepreneurial vestments.
Moreover, the new “ruling class,” created to manage the apparatus of absolutism,
was composed of skillful, hardworking, and meticulous executors, but, as Quazza
writes, men lacking “the general capacities of judgment that politics demands.”14
Finally, the reforms engendered a malaise among the traditional nobility by accel-
erating a process that marginalized them, to the benefit of a “service nobility.” The
result was that the old dominant classes felt threatened by change even though
other social classes did not feel advantaged.
THE DIFFICULT ITALIANIZATION OF THE PIEDMONT 73
Thus some of the factors that had touched off the decline of France from
the end of the seventeenth century to the beginning of the eighteenth century
found their way to the Piedmont, aggravated by the latter’s backwardness vis-à-vis
the rest of Italy and of Europe. The signing of a concordat with the Church, the
resumption of persecutions of the Jews and the Waldensians, the arrest of cer-
tain intellectuals like Alberto Radicati di Sostegno15 and Pietro Giannone, and the
dismissal from the university of these same professors who had supported the
reform process were, from the first half of the century, among the telltale signs of a
stunningly rapid regression: Turin, as Procacci writes, rapidly became the grayest
of Italian capitals, the best protected against the spread of the Enlightenment, by
imposing the barrier of censorship, “the barracks and the Boeotia of enlightened
Italy,”16 Piedmont’s noninvolvement in the tumultuous and changing history of
the rest of the peninsula made possible this original process, which helps under-
stand the seeming mystery that allowed this region, “politically and intellectually
underdeveloped”17 in the eighteenth century, to take a role, a century later, leading
the unification of Italy.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 8
The Difficult
Piedmontization of Italy
I n 1824 Giacomo Leopardi wrote that “as the nation has no center, there is not
really an Italian public.”1 The situation had not greatly changed thirty-seven
years later. When Italy unified, it suffered from two main defects, as Sabino Cassese
put it: that of being “a state without a nation” and that of suffering from a “chronic
weakness of its ruling class.”2 As we go forward, let us keep in mind this correlation
between the absence of a “center,” the weakness of a national “ruling class,” and the
absence of an “Italian public.”
The notion of a “center” involves several characteristics, including the geo-
graphic, cultural, and economic senses; the Italy of 1861 lacked all three at once.
The principal reason, as we have seen, lay in the very conditions of the process
of unification, which resulted not so much from the work of politicians emerg-
ing from the struggles of the Risorgimento as from a fortuitous mixture of sev-
eral exceptional circumstances. It was thus necessary to create from scratch a new
ruling class, and to do so with men lacking both in experience and in national
vocation.
It would not be accurate, however, to suggest that the Italy of the 1860s was
completely lacking in political leaders with a sense of the “national interest,” as
we understand that term today. To the contrary, the problem was that there were
too many of them. There was a Piedmontese “national” ruling class, a Lombard
“national” ruling class, another from Emilia, and others from Tuscany, Rome,
Naples, and Sicily, just to mention the most important of them. As the preuni-
tary states were at such highly different stages of development, the organization
of interest groups within the new Italian state entity occurred not “horizontally,”
which is to say through the representation of the interests of the various classes,
but “vertically,” that is, through the representation of the interests of the regions.
This was evident even at the level of parliamentary groupings: within the Des-
tra, there was notably a standing Piedmontese delegation, a Tuscan faction (called
Consorteria), a Lombard faction and an Emilian faction.
76 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The state of emergency in the early years of the new state’s existence justified, even
in the eyes of the Lombard Stefano Jacini, a “temporary dictatorship.”8 For the
federalist and southerner Gaetano Salvemini, a centralized administration was an
absolute necessity, considering the administrative anarchy of southern Italy.9
This centralized regime, however, proved to be far from “temporary.” To the
contrary, it became an almost distinctive mark of Italian political life. It survived
the transformist earthquakes, was raised to the level of a state religion by fascism,
and, finally, was surreptitiously preserved by the republican regime despite the
great decentralizing principles set out in the Constitution of 1948. Even in June
2006, Italians rejected, in a referendum, a constitutional reform calling for the
devolution of greater powers to the regions, a reform sought by the center-right
coalition and fiercely resisted by the center-left coalition.
Thus unification took political responsibilities away from the regional capitals,
without, however, managing to grant them to a strong central power. It is true
that the essential policy lines undertaken by Cavour were, in a certain measure,
determined by events themselves. Still, it is impossible to deny that their applica-
tion gave rise to a sort of heterogenesis of ends. With the sacrifice of democrats as
potential political personnel, the thus-impoverished ruling class had to deal, with-
out the necessary practical experience, with problems far exceeding its capacities
of adaptation and response. What is more, “Piedmontization” soon transformed
into a force of conservation, indeed of self-conservation.
The determination of Cavour and of the moderates to free themselves from
all democratic and Garibaldian interference was both an inspiration and a neces-
sity of the strategy of unification. To be sure, the most determined elements of
the Italian national avant-garde were found in the camps of the democrats and
THE DIFFICULT PIEDMONTIZATION OF ITALY 79
the republicans. But their actions had led to a litany of failures, whereas Cavour’s
strategy had been crowned with success. Not only were the democrats, with their
subjectivism and unpredictability, incapable of developing a strategy based on the
interests of a class aspiring to become a national ruling class, but they constantly
risked undercutting that strategy. Gramsci emphasizes that the moderates repre-
sented a relatively homogeneous social group, which means that their politics saw
relatively modest swings, whereas the democrats, as Gobetti put it, comprised “a
people of originals, of unemployed and of civil servants,”10 and thus had such large
swings of position that the moderates could easily exploit them.11
The “Piedmontization” of public life extended into the administration of the
state from its summit to its periphery, from the formalization of juridical continu-
ity between the Piedmontese and Italian kingdoms to the holding of plebiscites,
from the decision to maintain the dynastic continuity of Victor Emmanuel to the
choice of prefects; it included the laws of 1859—extended to the entire peninsula
in 1865—and the men given ministerial responsibilities in the different postuni-
tary executives.
By Emilio Gianni’s calculations, of the fifteen Italian governments in the period
1861 through 1876, the men of Piedmont occupied 28.8 percent of the posts, fol-
lowed by Tuscany with 11.6 percent, Emilia with 10.3 percent, and finally the south
with 11.6 percent. Of the eight presidents of the Council of Ministers, five were
Piedmontese (Cavour, Rattazzi, La Marmora, Menabrea, and Lanza) and three were
“Piedmontized” (Farini, Minghetti, and Ricasoli). The same trend can be seen in
those who held the principal ministries: interior, foreign affairs, and justice.12
But if governments change, bureaucracy endures. It is thus extremely significant
that the “central core” of the latter was based on the ancient Piedmontese bureau-
cracy, facilitated by a superior familiarity with legislation largely transferred from
the Kingdom of Sardinia to Italy and by the political support it enjoyed.
Despite the supposed desire to keep it “temporary,” Piedmont’s predominance
continued for several decades. Even at the end of the century, one-quarter of senior
civil servants were Piedmontese, and among military officers, the figure was a still
higher, 36 percent, even though the population of Piedmont was a mere one-tenth
of the total Italian population.13 As for the prefects, in 1861, 30.5 percent had come
directly from the former Piedmontese bureaucracy, a percentage that rose to 45.8
percent in the years of administrative unification (1865–66), before sinking again
to 27.5 percent in 1871.14
Given these conditions, it is not difficult to see why, in the early years of the
kingdom, political struggle took on the color of a struggle between regions and,
more specifically, of a struggle for or against Piedmontese occupation of the state.
It was not until the end of the liberal regime and fascism that Piedmont finally lost
its predominant role in Italian public life.15
Thus the most delicate period in the formation of the new state was based
largely on a single regional experience. The process of integration that ensued
was not seen by the affected populations as a process of adhesion to a common
national state and common national values. The “Italianization” of the country
continued, but very slowly, at a rate inversely proportional to the influence exer-
cised by Piedmont and the Piedmontese.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 9
The “Brigantaggio”
Church in the peasants’ eyes, the Church that reminded them of the virtues of a
time when feudal lords still had obligations and responsibilities to them.
The spread of capitalist social relationships was at the origin of the break
between peasants, on the one side, and property owners on the other, with their
retinue of lawyers, shopkeepers, employees, and minor intellectuals. The “alliance”
of 1860 between the Jacquerie and the “democratic revolution” could have been
merely tactic and temporary. When the police of the Kingdom of the Two Sicilies
took flight, Jacquerie no longer knew any restraint and the “democratic revolu-
tion” quickly changed its priorities. Denis Mack Smith affirms that Garibaldi rap-
idly realized that “his only chance” of lasting success lay in the support of property
holders, and he quickly launched a policy of widespread repression.4
The actions of the intellectuals and military men of Piedmont (as well as the
“Piedmontized”5) sent to “pacify” the south were dictated, quite simply, by fear,
by concern, and by misconceptions. The fear: all those who had put their eggs in
the basket of unification were haunted by the specter of 1799—the counterrevo-
lutionary Jacquerie organized at the highest level and with international support.
The concern: the imponderable attitude of the democrats vis-à-vis the Jacquerie.6
The misconceptions: a profound misunderstanding of the southern situation and
a conviction that applying philosophical and economic principles that had seemed
logical in the north would overcome all the problems. It is now clear that those
misconceptions shaped the practical steps taken to confront the fears and the con-
cerns that, in fact, had very real foundations.
Among these misconceptions was the notion that it was poor governance by
the Bourbons that had kept the supposedly untapped richness in the south from
being developed. This idea, according to Salvatore Lupo, was in turn supported by
a typically positivist conviction that would leave a deep and lasting impression on
the history of the country: the notion that economic development is “natural”, and
that imbalances therefore reflect “anomalies that imply inadequacies more than
they demand remedies.”7
But this conviction had a flip side, as Sergio Romano put it: “a sort of racism
toward those who appear irremediably corrupt and allergic to liberal therapy.”8
The lieutenant of the King, Luigi Carlo Farini, contrasted the civic virtues of the
Bedouins to the “barbarity” of the “cafoni,” the southern peasants. Even the Garib-
aldians considered the southern peasants as “Bedouins,” speaking an “African-
like” language.9
The resignation of the very popular Liborio Romano (elected in eight districts)
from the Council of Lieutenancy; the purging of the local bureaucracy, where the
Garibaldian petit bourgeoisie had begun to install itself; the dissolution of the
100,000-strong Neapolitan army, suddenly reduced to joblessness; the liquidation
without severance of the Red Shirt army; the law suppressing most religious orders
(which destabilized the liberal clergy): one way or another, all these measures ulti-
mately fed the growth of banditism. Thus, among the “scum” denounced abroad
by Ricasoli, one found, along with the “apostles of reaction,” the newly jobless cre-
ated by the new regime, but also some of those who had cooperated in putting the
new regime in place or who, at the very least, had been disposed to support it; and,
above all, was the mass of angry and exasperated peasants.
THE MODERATE SOCIAL BLOC 83
Only when the war against the brigantaggio ended did the “southern question”
officially arise, that is the ascertainment that if Italy was now undeniably a juridi-
cal entity, the Italian nation itself was still far from reality.
The “southern question”—which was the point of contact between two very dif-
ferent stages of development—arose during the rigid administrative centraliza-
tion of 1859 to 1865. According to one witness with a privileged perspective,
Cavour’s personal secretary Isacco Artom, the cause of regional autonomy ran
aground precisely over “the question of Naples”10: the fear of peasant revolts in
the south was the real reason for abandoning any plans for decentralization; all
other causes were subordinate.
Undeniably, the largest part of the Italian bourgeoisie—of whatever regional
origin, economic power, or political leaning—was shaken, and sometimes gen-
uinely terrified, by the upheavals of 1859 to 1861. But what exactly was it that
inspired such fear?
“Fear of revolution” was on everyone’s mind, but it was a vague fear, not
entirely justified by actual circumstances. To be sure, there were memories of 1848
to 1849 and the “specter of communism.”11 But again, these fears must be attrib-
uted more to French intellectual and moral influence than to the actual state of
social life in Italy, where the industrial proletariat was practically nonexistent. In
fact, the democratic revolutionary tempest of the midcentury had provoked two
sorts of opposite reactions: while in the other Italian states repression had raged,
to varying degrees of severity, in the Piedmontese kingdom the task of reestablish-
ing calm and quieting the democrats’ passions was left to the Statute, a sort of
constitutional chart.
According to Charles Albert’s juridical counselor, Federigo Paolo Sclopis, the
charter could open the way to the integration of the “educated middle classes”
in the management of public affairs.12 At the same time, the liberal choice had
allowed the Piedmontese kingdom to absorb a large part of the energetic ele-
ments—a sort of intellectual avant-garde of the bourgeoisie—whom the other
governments of the peninsula had banned.13 While only a small number of them
had lastingly integrated the structures of the Piedmontese state,14 these exiles
exerted significant influence, directly or indirectly, on the Piedmontese culture
of the 1850s, as seen in the moderates’ developing hegemony and in the con-
comitant decline in the democrats’ influence.
The democrats having been left on the margins of political life after 1848,
the question on the origins of the “great fear” remains. It was certainly fanned
by the threat of peasant revolts. But the real risk was not one of a “rural revolu-
tion”; the social conditions for this were missing, as was a serious political plan
of action and leaders capable of imposing it. The real risk was represented by the
“specter of 1799,”15 which, as it developed, took on the contours of an organized
and permanent Jacquerie.
84 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The defense of property and of the barely achieved unification seemed worth
the sacrifice of some vaguely decentralizing principles. “The aim is clear, and it is
not open to discussion,” wrote Cavour on December 14, 1860, at the moment of
his “Jacobin adaptation”: “to impose unity on the most corrupt, the weakest part
of Italy. And as to the means, no doubt is permitted: moral force and, if it proves
insufficient, physical force.”16
Beginning in March 1861, an occupation army of 120,000 men proceeded to
reconquer southern Italy, using summary methods and violence of every sort that
left thousands of victims in its wake. This intervention had been demanded—and
carried out, so long as they were still in positions of responsibility—by the demo-
crats themselves.
Moderate Hegemony
By 1849 Cavour had become convinced that a “democratic revolution” in Italy had
little chance of succeeding. He had reached this conviction through an analysis of
the social bases of the democratic party: lacking support among the masses, he
wrote, it could count on support only from the middle and, to an extent, the upper
bourgeoisie, “and they have many interests to defend.” Had the social order been
truly threatened, he said, he was persuaded that even the most extreme republi-
cans would have been in “the front ranks of the conservative party.”17
Cavour saw rather lucidly what the real situation was regarding a question—
that of the “democratic revolution”—that historians would later spend more than
a century sorting through. He understood that the radical democrats’ social base
was still too young, too limited, and too timid to achieve a real unity of interests
that could be translated into a substantial plan of action. Facing a murky outlook,
these new societal groups increasingly found ways to accommodate themselves to
a reality that allowed them to satisfy their immediate interests. This might have
been less enticing in terms of grand ideals, but it was certainly more attractive in
terms of the conditions of their material existence.
These new groups had begun taking on social weight under the absolute mon-
archies at the end of the eighteenth century, with the establishment of a profes-
sional bureaucracy in which recruitment was based on ability, not birth. The
French contamination and the adoption of the civil code—with its repercussions
on social relationships—meant that the influence and the role of these bourgeois
sectors gradually grew. The Restoration seemed to frustrate their political ambi-
tions, leading some of the most dynamic elements to embrace the cause of the
democratic revolution, yet economic evolution continued to strengthen their
influence. The subjectivist idealism of the doctrinaire democrats, who failed to
understand the correlation between economic facts and political facts, was lost
in their vague theoretical constructions. Their futile attempts to force reality to
conform to their fantasies gave rise to senseless abortive uprisings that ended up
decimating the revolutionary avant-garde.
The ever-starker contradiction between the economic emergence of these new
bourgeois groups and the political failure of those who should have been in their
THE MODERATE SOCIAL BLOC 85
front ranks was synthesized by Turin’s liberal choices, with its policy of integrat-
ing the middle classes in public affairs, and by the strategy of Cavour’s “diplomatic
revolution.” In political terms, this choice translated as the “connubio” (marriage) of
1852, the parliamentary alliance between the center under Cavour and the center-
left under Rattazzi.
If, as Rosario Romeo attests, the evolution of primitive accumulation is behind
the development of new layers of society, and if their development in turn explains
the need to integrate them into the management of public affairs, it is indispens-
able for us to ponder, however briefly, the question of primitive accumulation in
the Italy of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, while noting that findings on
this subject are far from unanimous.
To Romeo, for example, it goes without saying that the sources of capitalist
accumulation in Italy were less numerous than in other countries, since trade and
colonial exploitation must be excluded. It was, rather, the revolutionary actions of
the French occupiers, he continues, that allowed the bourgeoisie to appropriate
a good part of the ecclesiastical property and that erased all juridical distinction
between feudal property and bourgeois property.18
According to Vera Zamagni, the elements of capitalist transformation of the
countryside gave the agricultural economy a much larger role than that of a simple
producer of foods and raw materials: they encouraged the birth of rural industries,
enlarged the markets for services (transport, credit and insurance), favored the
rise of entrepreneurial aptitudes, and stimulated the importation of machines and
of raw materials. Moreover, the increase in agricultural productivity made possible
the forceful eviction of country labor, which could then be put to use in other
activities.19 This latter aspect corresponds, according to Marx, to a fundamental
stage in the process of primitive accumulation.20
We must also underline the importance of what Franco Bonelli calls “externally
induced agricultural accumulation”. The increase of revenues in more industrially
advanced European countries had provoked a demand for products—raw materi-
als and semifinished products, food products, and to some extent even services—
that the Italian economy was in a position to provide.21
This expansion of wealth and economic activities thus upset the existence of
the traditional social classes—notably by making the nobility more bourgeois22—
while giving rise to other, more numerous classes. Beyond the big property owners,
who were traditional beneficiaries of this “agrarian surplus,” there were a growing
number of actors occupied in new industrial or semi-industrial activities linked
somehow to agricultural accumulation. And there were others who profited indi-
rectly from the new wealth, including those in commercial activities or financial
and liberal professions (bookkeepers, notaries, lawyers) linked to the multiplica-
tion of properties. Here, in flesh and blood, were the “middle classes” that Sclopis
envisaged integrating into the management of public affairs and who would con-
stitute, under Cavour, the real actors of Piedmontese acceleration in the 1850s.
86 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
According to Indro Montanelli, another result of the terror of a popular revolt was
the creation of a “closed oligarchy.”23 Piedmontese electoral law, extended little-
changed to the rest of the country, reflected the criteria that had inspired the con-
cession of the statute, that is, the desire to co-opt the “middle classes.” The proof
of this is that the democrats had accepted it since 1848 because, as one of their
more radical members, Angelo Brofferio, put it, it opened the doors to “indus-
try, to art and to intelligence of every sort.”24 Moreover, the Piedmontese elec-
toral corps could brag of far broader bases than those that existed in France under
the July Monarchy, which was considered a “bourgeois monarchy” par excellence.
And while the electoral law of 1861 foresaw, in keeping with Cavour’s desire, a
reduction in the number of electoral districts in the turbulent south, these same
democrats did not oppose this either. It was only much later that the latter, by then
transformed into the Sinistra, would have become the almost exclusive representa-
tives of the interests of the new bourgeois classes, particularly in the south. These
groups would gradually but surely be involved in the management of “public
affairs” from 1876, the date of the massive entry of the southern bourgeoisie into
the executive, and 1882, the date of the new electoral law that tripled the number
of voters.25
The cultural hegemony of the moderates had become firmly established in the
1850s, at the point when the promises implicit in the statute, in the electoral law,
and in the “connubio” had seemed to translate into a sort of “Get rich!” invitation
extended to all levels of the Piedmontese bourgeoisie.
With a population equivalent to only 11.2 percent of that of the peninsula,26
in 1857 Piedmont and Liguria provided 18.1 percent of total agricultural produc-
tion (while Lombardy furnished only 15.3 percent); in 1859, 46.4 percent of the
entire Italian rail network was on the territory of the two regions of the Savoy
kingdom (28.5 percent of it was in the Lombard-Venetian Kingdom). In 1858 they
were also leaders in imports (36.9 percent of the total, compared to 21.5 percent
for Lombardy-Venice) and exports (30.9 percent to 26.6 percent); also in 1858,
37.9 percent of all employees in the mechanical industry were concentrated in the
Turin and Genoa regions, while only 15.1 percent were in the two Italian regions
of the Austrian empire.27
Beyond the numerous polemics that have muddled this discussion, it seems
rather clear that the question of Piedmontese hegemony can be explained by these
three fundamental, and fundamentally linked, factors: (1) an exceptional concen-
tration of intellectual energy in Turin and Genoa; (2) Cavour’s political acuity,
which provided a national strategy in the framework of international constraints;
and (3) the capacity for these influences to spread socially as Piedmont rapidly
gained tangible economic supremacy over the other Italian regions (which, let us
not forget, were in a concomitant phase of economic slowdown).
Piedmontese hegemony, in any case, entered into crisis at the very moment
of unification, because the material conditions that had determined it changed
abruptly. As the newly unified country engaged increasingly with the world mar-
ket, Piedmont’s economic power, which had seemed so vigorous compared to the
THE MODERATE SOCIAL BLOC 87
other Italian states, suddenly looked pallid in comparison to the other powers. In
1840 the Italian states accounted for 10.8 percent of the total economies of the six
leading European powers; this rate declined inexorably for the rest of the century
to 10.5 percent in 1850, 10.05 percent in 1860, 8.6 percent in 1870, and 8.3 percent
in 1880.28 And if one makes the comparison to the most dynamic economy of the
era, that of the United States, the gap is even clearer and more dramatic. In 1830
the two countries’ relative shares of world industrial production were approxi-
mately equivalent (2.3 percent for the Italian states and 2.4 percent for the United
States), but by 1860 American industrial power was 2.9 times that of Italy, and in
1880, 5.9 times.
Thus the bases of the implicit pact proposed by Cavour to the Piedmontese (or
Piedmontized) bourgeoisie had collapsed at the very moment when that pact had
achieved its goal.
This page intentionally left blank
Part II
The Permanencies
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 10
Transformism
endanger the structures of the young state. Thus, in its origins, the transform-
ist process was not really an ambitious project for renewing the country, but an
attempt to consolidate gains “through enlarging the social base of the nation and
the legitimacy of power.” Seen from this angle, transformism was responding, in
Romano’s eyes, to “a physiological necessity of the political country.”10
Other historians have emphasized the purely defensive character of the opera-
tion: a convergence of the liberal right and left toward the center in order to isolate
and reduce the intrinsically subversive extreme wings. The seditious elements that
the transformist operation was designed to curb were on the one side the Catholic
Church and on the other the far left—republican and socialist. The country hav-
ing been unified without (and against) them, they were not only strangers to the
system, naturally enough, but also its declared enemies.
In fact, the far left of the 1870s and the 1880s represented an even lesser threat
than the democrats in the time of Cavour. It was the remnants of the preceding
democratic tradition, stripped of their bourgeois social base, that had merged into
the Sinistra. Now, wrote Gramsci, this left wing represented nothing more than the
“miserable, impoverished, illiterate” part of the country and could express itself
only through “sporadic, disjointed, hysterical forms, a series of anarchist, subver-
sive gestures, with neither consistency nor a concrete political direction.”11 More-
over, Gramsci added in another note, even the most superficial of analyses showed
that in the 1870s the economic and social conditions hardly existed to create a
socialist party that could genuinely threaten the liberal state.12
Only the Catholic Church was a serious danger in the eyes of the liberal ruling
class; subjectively, because of the personal convictions of the men of the Sinis-
tra (a number of them having anticlerical political backgrounds), and objectively,
because of the violently hostile attitude of Pius IX and part of the ecclesiastical
hierarchy toward the new state.
Several elements suggest that this supposed danger was, in fact, less than had been
claimed. First, after unification, and especially after 1870, the “Pius IX generation”
had bet heavily on what could be called “a strategy of refusal,” implying a nostal-
gic, if fading, hope for a reestablishment of the pope’s temporal power.13 In other
words, Catholic energies were largely concentrated upon the goal of reconstituting
the pontifical states, not conquering Italy. It was only after the defeat of Napoleon
III’s France that the idea of a role in Italian affairs began, timidly, to emerge. None-
theless, this idea long remained embryonic, largely because of the opposition from
those who complained of the plundering inflicted by the Italian state.
Another reason a Catholic uprising was unlikely: in Italy, the Church lacked
a homogeneous social base. Without this, it could not create a synthesis of inter-
ests and establish an alternative strategy to the power in place. At the moment of
unification, the Church represented—the landowning clergy aside—a part of the
Ancien Régime nobility, the small and negligible mass of the Roman Lumpenprole-
tariat whose revenue was assured by public charity, and above all, the great major-
ity of the peasantry. The church’s influence upon the latter merely kept them away
from the parliamentary political system.
The only attempt to create an English-style two-party system came from a
group of property owners—“the national conservatives,” to use Stefano Jacini’s
94 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
In texts dealing with the Italian crisis of the 1990s, different definitions of trans-
formism sometimes refer to the same object, and the same definition can suggest
different objects. Nearly all specialists agree, however, on the description of the
phenomenon, while disagreeing on names and dates.
According to Roberto Cartocci, for example, the transformist practice was dom-
inant between 1945 and 1992, meaning until the moment when the first Giuliano
TRANSFORMISM 95
of Italians who voted for the Fascists in April 1924 having almost all voted anti-
Fascist three years earlier; of the millions of members of the Christian Democrats
(DC) and the Italian Communist Party (PCI) in 1946 who, three years earlier, had
held Fascist party membership; and finally, it explained the mass abandonment
of the Christian Democrats and the Socialist Party between 1992 and 1994. The
Piedmontese in 1859, the Fascists in 1922, the anti-Fascists in 1943, Berlusconi in
1994,28 all profited from the collapse of the old regime, but they did not provoke it.
If we follow the timeframe suggested by Sergio Romano, we see political cycles
of around twenty years each: the rupture of 1859 to 1861, the transformism of
1876 to 1881, the crisis of the end of the century and Giolittism; the post–World
War I period and fascism; World War II and the republic; the “crisis of imbalance”
at the end of the 1960s; and the crisis of 1992 to 1994.
Internal Italian quarrels, influenced for a quarter century by a dispute over
institutional reform, can lead to the conclusion that the crises were provoked by
the lack of or inadequacy of shared rules. In fact, with the exception of the Fascist
period, these rules have always formally existed and, in the case of the republi-
can phase, they were shared even by the political forces that, whether government
or opposition, had together drawn up the constitution. So the determining cause
must be sought elsewhere, and precisely in the degree to which Italy was exposed
to international, political, and economic influences.
Regarding 1859, a series of factors linked to European politics—principally that
of Napoleon III devising a plan to undermine the balance of power decided in
Vienna—shook Italian politics to the point where every old state but one had col-
lapsed. From the late 1870s to the early 1880s, the crisis of the global free-trade
cycle and its direct implications on international politics obliged the political class
that had run the preceding phase to withdraw gradually from affairs. The turn-of-
century crisis had been brutally linked to the encounter with global competition
and its political manifestations (especially the colonial wars). The two world wars
had a devastating impact on the whole of Italian society, with no traces of the
preexisting systems remaining. The “crisis of imbalance” was the product of accel-
erated industrial development by the integration of Italy into the ascendant phase
of the world economic cycle (particularly through integration in the European
Economic Community). And the crisis of the 1990s was provoked by the collapse
of the Soviet Union, German unification, and above all, the rapid acceleration of
development in Asia and its influence on globalization.
But the reasons these international influences touched off a transformist rup-
ture were the primary weakness of the unitary state, the fragility of its institutions,
and its chronic lack of legitimacy. Again, we can point out the fundamental prob-
lems of the Italian bourgeoisie: its late emergence, its fragmentation, and conse-
quently, its difficulty in finding a balance of power within the state. These inherent
weaknesses always made it particularly susceptible to major movements in inter-
national economics and politics.
Vera Zamagni reminds us that Italy was a country “of numerous towns and
numerous agricultures,” and indeed numerous ideologies, thus the profound
significance of transformism consists, according to her, in its constant search for
“operational convergences allowing the country to be governed in the presence of
such plurality of ideologies and interest”29: quod erat demonstrandum.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 11
Internationalization Crises
and Transformism
T he second half of the 1860s was marked by the early signs of the crisis that
would end with the arrival in power of the Sinistra. In this phase, social groups
previously excluded from power began to wield sufficient weight to disrupt the
previous balance, but not enough to allow them to forge a new one.
Between 1861 and 1880, Italian industrial production as a share of total gross
domestic product (GDP) shrank from 20.3 percent to 17.3 percent, despite
an annual mean growth in industrial production of 1.4 percent to 2.2 percent
(depending on the source).1 The sector was thus undergoing a profound restruc-
turing. This included the disappearance of thousands of small and very small
enterprises, halfway between artisanship and home-based production, often
closely linked to agricultural activities, and the progressive, but extremely slow
birth of a more modern industrial sector, with higher levels of production.
The year 1866 marked a turning point. It was a particularly painful year for
Italy, politically, economically, and militarily: with an army of 400,000 men—more
than all the forces of the British Empire, according to Denis Mack Smith2—and a
fleet twice as large as Austria’s, Italy was defeated in two major battles, on land near
Custoza, and in the Adriatic see, near the island of Lissa.
But the humiliation suffered at the hands of the Austrians was only the most
glaring of the misfortunes that struck the kingdom barely five years after its birth.
These misfortunes were due largely to its dependence on foreign countries, and in
particular France;3 that is, they reflected the coincidence of an economic crisis and
an international political crisis, the effects of which were multiplied in Italy by the
coefficient of its economic and political weakness. The country was struck, in a
manner of speaking, by the first big “internationalization crisis.”
That the crisis of the mid-1860s was rooted in the world market is beyond
doubt. It also appears to be a classic example of a crisis provoked by overinvest-
ment during a favorable period (1862–1863), which manifested itself first through
a depletion of the money supply in circulation, then by an unprecedented rise in
the key rates of the Bank of England (which reached 10 percent in May 1866), and
100 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
finally, by a recession that spread first through the British Isles and then the con-
tinent. But it was also the first manifestation of “globalization,” in the sense that
Europe was struck with the effects of a political crisis that had exploded in another
part of the planet, namely, the United States. During the American Civil War, in
fact, a considerable flow of American capital left the country in search of safer
investments and poured across the old continent, helping saturate the markets.
Later, at the end of the war, not only was part of this capital repatriated, but the
resumption of American production led to a drop in the price of cotton, a key area
of Italian industrial activity.
Italy was doubly affected: first, because of its economic dependence on other
countries; and second, and less directly, because of its political subordination.
Thus in 1859 (and later during all the great turning points in international rela-
tions), to pursue its own foreign policy objectives, it had to try to insinuate itself
into disputes between other powers. Since the armistice of Villafranca, the return
of Venice had become, along with the annexation of Rome, one of the two over-
arching objectives of Italian foreign policy; the tensions between Vienna and Ber-
lin after 1864 were thus considered an occasion not to be missed.
But the major “external constraint” was represented by Napoleon III, who over-
saw the peninsula as a sort of “semiprotectorate.”4 Candeloro suggests that the
excessive prudence with which the Italians took part in the war—a major reason
for the debacles of Lissa and Custoza—was also the consequence of a note slipped
by Napoleon III to Costantino Nigra, the ambassador in Paris, recommending that
the Italians not fight “with too much vigor.”5
But the chief cause of the defeat lay elsewhere: not only Italy’s military man-
power, but also its larger ambitions were greater than what the country’s economic
potential could afford. The effects of the international crisis were multiplied by
internal Italian weaknesses. The run on the banks provoked by credit restrictions
was inflamed in Italy by the plunging value of public debt securities as French
investors dumped them in mass. This, along with some exceptional financial deci-
sions, soon led to a veritable stampede as war approached.
From that moment on, the country had no choice but to rely on its own
resources. On May 1, 1866, the forced circulation of the virtually irredeemable
lira put an end to convertibility between the Italian currency and gold. Two other
measures were taken at the same time: the imposition of a loan from the Banca
Nazionale to the state of 250 million lira at an interest rate of 1.5 percent, and
the legal circulation of bills from four preunitary banks, guaranteed by the Banca
Nazionale itself.
For finance minister Quintino Sella, the reestablishment of the state’s financial
authority, by balancing the budget to create conditions favorable to private inves-
tors and to expanded industrial activity, quickly became a question of survival for
the country. At the same time, economic groups of the center-north began to talk
of seeing the state play a larger role in defending industrial interests. The erosion
of the old ruling class’s bases of power had begun.
INTERNATIONALIZATION CRISES AND TRANSFORMISM 101
In November 1869 an alliance of mixed interests brought about the fall of the
Menabrea government, but without giving rise to an alternative majority.
The most important economic sectors demanding a new political balance
within the Italian state were industry, credit, and the southern bourgeoisie. This is
a rather schematic breakdown; there does not, of course, exist a single interest of
the financial bourgeoisie or, even more obviously, a single interest of the south-
ern bourgeoisie. But what brought these three disparate groups together was their
desire to emerge—that is, to transform their economic weight and influence into
political weight and influence.
The crisis brought on first a decomposition and then a recomposition of the
two traditional political families along the lines of regional fractures and interests:
the ultraliberal Tuscan Destra found common interests with the southern Sinistra
more easily than with the northern Destra, which, for its part, often joined forces
with certain sectors of the radical Milanese Sinistra and, in particular, with the
“statist” dirigiste and “social” factions of the southern Destra.
In its earliest years, the Kingdom of Italy had adopted a policy that was “natu-
rally” pro–free trade, which enjoyed wide support if one considers that the 1863
free-trade convention with France was ratified by a vote of 257 to 49. In the same
period, Italy also concluded commercial treaties with the Ottoman Empire (1861),
Sweden (1862), Great Britain (1863), Belgium, Denmark, The Netherlands, Russia
(1864), Austria and the German Zollverein (1865), Switzerland, Uruguay, Japan,
China, Tunisia (1868), and Spain.
The capital needed to develop the “natural industries,” and thus to form a vast
national market, could be found only through close connections to the world mar-
ket, as Cavour asserted in his last parliamentary address. In the prime minister’s
view, a free-trade policy would make it possible for agriculture to accumulate the
capital necessary for future industrial development.6 It is noteworthy that Cavour,
on this occasion, was responding to a speech by Quintino Sella, who was to become
the finance minister of the Destra in 1864, and who was delivering his first address
before the Chamber of Deputies to support the possibility of accumulation and
development based above all on the “combination of factors available internally
within the country.”7 And the necessary precondition for productive internal com-
petition, according to Sella, had to be protection from foreign competition.
Two years later, during the parliamentary debate on the convention with France,
a deputy from Turin denounced the parliamentary commission for having failed
to consider the fact that thirty of the thirty-one chambers of commerce opposed
it, as did the 23,000 heads of enterprise who had signed petitions in opposition to
the treaty. During the same debate, the Lombard cotton industrialist Ercole Lualdi
listed numerous grievances against England and France, which he accused of
preaching free-trade policy only after having conquered every market through the
protections they had enjoyed for centuries; he proposed the formation of a com-
mission of inquiry on industry. Giovanni Ricci, a Genoese deputy, demanded that
France be stripped of the right to practice petit cabotage. Two Garibaldian depu-
ties, Antonio Polsinelli and Antonio Mordini, put forth for the first time the thesis
102 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Quintino Sella was one of the rare political leaders of the era who attempted to
offer all the disparate interests the outline of a common strategic perspective.
Sella’s strategy, as we have seen, was to create favorable conditions for invest-
ment and for industrial expansion. His origins, his studies, and his accumulated
political experience combined to inspire in him, as in Cavour before him, the con-
viction that industrial development was the necessary path to lead the country into
the modern world. Thus, when he took up his battle to balance the budget—a fun-
damental precondition necessary to free up capital for productive investment—he
found himself in conflict with the financial aristocracy who had drained out most
of this money at a time when state securities were more profitable than invest-
ments. It was impossible to establish this equilibrium, as Marx wrote in regards to
the July Monarchy, “without encroaching on interests which were so many props
of the ruling system—and without redistributing taxes.”10
But Sella felt that redistributing taxes was his “mission,” the most important
measure in his strategy for balancing the budget.11 The increase in fiscal charges
was accompanied by borrowings from the Banca Nazionale, cuts in the budgets
of the military ministries, the transfer to the provinces of the expenses of second-
ary instruction, the reduction of the royal appanage, and the sale of some Church
assets and some state properties (including the rail networks).
The financial aristocracy resisted Sella’s policies for another reason, and while
this stemmed from something as immaterial as social psychology, it was no less
real a force: the conviction that, as the banks held the capital needed by the indus-
trialists, the latter were subordinate to the former. It was a subjective impression,
but it strengthened the objective resistance.
Sella, however, was far from being naturally hostile to the capitalist banks. A
capitalist himself, he was aware of the irreplaceable role of financial intermedia-
tion and he had been, as minister of finance, the protagonist of numerous treaties,
INTERNATIONALIZATION CRISES AND TRANSFORMISM 103
including that of November 1864, when the sale of certain of the kingdom’s assets
was confided to a syndicate formed by the Credito Mobiliare of Turin, the Banco di
Sconto e Sete, also of Turin, and the Cassa di Sconto of Genoa. Sella persisted with
Cavour’s old attempt to discipline the way credit was organized by uniting all the
issuing banks into a single bank, then a common practice in the more advanced
countries. But like Cavour, his predecessor at the Ministry of Finance, he met stern
resistance from numerous local groups, until in the end his attempt failed.12
After the fall of Menabrea, a new majority struggled to emerge. Lanza having
renounced any interest in forming a government, General Cialdini13 tried in vain
to do so with the leaders of various parliamentary groups. In the end, Lanza was
again called on and succeeded in forming a government in which Quintino Sella
was the finance minister, and this despite the rivalries between the two politicians
and with the Piedmontese Destra (although both men were from Piedmont and
part of the Destra). Despite the fundamental hostility of the Tuscan Destra, the
government obtained the confidence of parliament, thanks to the favorable vote of
Marco Minghetti, who was linked by personal and political connections to Floren-
tine circles, and whose support was supposed to condition, to a degree, the actions
of the government. But from the moment the government took office (in Decem-
ber 1869), the deep-seated hostility was transformed into a veritable guerrilla war
of attrition. The series of financial measures presented by Sella were examined by
no fewer than four parliamentary committees, and the debate, begun in the spring
of 1870, produced a positive vote of parliament only on August 11, 1870, barely a
month before the annexation of Rome.
The length of the discussions reflected deep divisions within the ruling class,
and Mazzini thought the moment was right to launch a series of attempted raids,
which led, as usual, to the dispersion of fragile republican groups and the arrest
or death of some of their leaders. Nonetheless, the press of the Destra, especially
that part under Tuscan influence, used this as a pretext to attack the government,
accusing it of excessive weakness.
The attempts to overturn Lanza took place not only in the heat of the discus-
sion over his financial intervention plan, but also in the midst of the Franco-Prus-
sian War, at a point in time when much was being asked of the young structures of
a state born under international protection. We should add that at the beginning
of the war, two of Victor Emmanuel’s former counselors, Antonio Gualterio and
Luigi Federico Menabrea, had attacked the government with the aim of replac-
ing Lanza with someone closer to the king,14 and that the king himself had sent
General Cialdini on August 3 to attack the system of parliamentary government in
order to regain the diplomatic initiative and carry Italy into war alongside France
against Prussia.15
As we can see, the concept of a “national union” was still far—very far—from
seeing the light of day within a ruling class where the numbers of those preferring
chaos to the risk of sacrificing even a part of their private interests were still legion.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 12
Emerging Sectors
and Transformism
Finance
I f one were to sketch an outline of the history of banks in Italy, one could say
that Italian financial institutions, over the course of a century and a half, were
numerous, fragile, and protected, and once the state stopped protecting them,
directly or indirectly, they became prey to sturdier foreign institutions better
versed in the rules of competition. Recent years have seen a rather timid reversal
of that trend, but it is too early to draw firm conclusions.
In Italy, banks managed to fashion around themselves an original juridical
framework, that of the “universal bank,” halfway between the Anglo-Saxon model
of total integration with enterprises and the German model of complete separa-
tion. The state first intervened directly in the activities of the credit sector in the
great rescues of 1888 through 1893 and 1931 through 1936, and later by taking
control, after World War II, of 70 percent to 80 percent of all bank activities.1
Whatever the case, and whether under a regime in which public property was
dominant or one almost exclusively favoring private property, the major bank-
ing institutions rarely missed a chance, in the decisive battles, to influence state
policy in the direction most favorable to their interests. This battle of influence
took different forms: at times it was subtle and indirect, through the banks’ pres-
ence within industrial groups or financial or insurance companies; at other times
through political relations, involving pressure that was more or less legal; and at
yet other times through what one might call “confidential” diplomacy, something
at which Enrico Cuccia, the most celebrated banker of the second half of the twen-
tieth century, was a master.2
According to Gianni Toniolo, the decision to move toward the forced currency
for the lira in 1866 was the first important rescue operation undertaken in Italy
by the “lender of last resort.”3 It is an interesting point of view, not only because it
predates by some three decades the year in which the central bank—in substance if
not in form—was established, but also because it corroborates the theses of those
for whom the existence of Italy corresponds to the existence, in the country, of an
economic system dominated by state capitalism.
106 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
When the Banca d’Italia was officially established, in 1893, it began to fulfill the
institutional task of “monetary power,” supervising the general monetary interests
of the country, in keeping with the regular tenets of capitalist development. In this
context, the central bank does not play the role of one credit institution among
many, defending its particular interests while others do the same; it acts rather as
a traffic cop for different private interests, and not only for banking interests but
also for all economic sectors as it works to safeguard the “general interest.”4
This specific role is imposed by facts, not by desire. In 1870, four years after the
decision on the forced currency, issuing banks held 66.9 percent of all paper cur-
rency in circulation. Ten years later, these same banks held only 36.5 percent.5 In
absolute numbers, the total sum of circulating currency in the hands of the issuing
banks had declined by an almost imperceptible amount (going from 621 million
lira in 1870 to 557 million lira ten years later); this means that the total mass had
grown in the meantime (from 929 million to 1.527 billion), but more importantly,
that a slew of new financial actors were now competing for it. In fact, from 1870
to 1874 there was a veritable boom of banking institutions. The number of ordi-
nary credit institutions rose from 36 to 121 and the number of “banche popolari”
(industrial cooperative banks) rose from 48 to 109.6
The general framework of the Italian economy was beginning to mature. Inte-
gration between finance and industry became so evident that the activities of ordi-
nary credit banks began to grow and contract in close conjunction with the cycles
of industrial production.
According to an Italian political tradition, the responsibility for these changes
was found not in the dynamic of the Italian economy within the world market,
but in the subjective choices of governments. Thus, in 1873, Lanza was forced to
resign by a new coalition of interests that felt threatened; Minghetti was finally
able to take his place, with the goal of reducing the power of the Banca Nazionale
by creating a cartel of minor banks, notably southern ones. Around them emerged
much of the growing opposition of the Sinistra.
The Minghetti government thus constituted a sort of intermediate step toward
new balance. But these new equilibria had a difficult time establishing themselves,
confronted with the greatest upheaval the Italian social structure had faced in cen-
turies: industrialization.
Industry
almost entirely wind powered, and sail ships were poorly suited for navigating
the Red Sea.12 But there were other factors, one internal—the Brindisi port was
too shallow for the high-seas vessels traveling to the Red Sea and back—and one
external—the high tolls charged by the canal discouraged a considerable amount
of traffic. And finally there was a factor tied to the growth of the world market,
which reduced the gap in prices of products and raw materials from different parts
of the globe, putting an end to the day when a merchant could derive a profit from
the large price differentials between distant markets.
Thus, rather than serving to promote Italy’s progress and development, as
any good free-marketer might have expected, the newly built Suez Canal merely
served to aggravate its backwardness. The Rubattino shipping company, which in
December 1869 had purchased a concession in the Bay of Assab in Eritrea as a for-
ward post for Italian commercial penetration in the Red Sea, had to resell it to the
government thirteen years later. The shipyards that popped up like mushrooms
after rain when the canal opened had to rapidly scale back their ambitions or, in
many instances, file for bankruptcy.13 The involvement of the Italian fleet in inter-
national trade, rather than growing, was drastically reduced, and even the share
of internal commercial navigation handled by Italian vessels fell from 52.6 per-
cent of the total in 1881 to 31.4 percent in 1891, despite the establishment, in the
meantime, of significant protectionist tariffs.14 Finally, the considerable decline in
the price of maritime shipping contributed to a sharp drop in the price of some
imported foodstuffs, in particular wheat and rice, thus accelerating the crisis in the
country’s agricultural sector.
The example of the Suez Canal clearly demonstrates the damage that can result
from an incapacity to provide a strategic perspective for Italian capitalist develop-
ment, leaving it reliant on the “ephemeral favors of fortune.”
In 1873 the world experienced the first great depression of contemporary eco-
nomic history. It was provoked by the creation, in Germany after the victory of
1870, of joint-stock companies and banks specialized in investments that favored
the development of a “bubble” in rail and real-estate values, to the point of trigger-
ing the classic mechanism of rising costs and prices and falling markets.
Opinions are divided on the direct influence this crisis had on the Italian situa-
tion. For some, the economic weakness of the peninsula helped preserve the coun-
try, while for others the impact on the lira was strong, causing its value to plunge15;
for Cafagna, it had at least the merit of putting an end to the “plaster” economy
born in a time of market effervescence.16
The impact of this crisis—coming just years after the first major shock of
1866—affected the whole of the Italian ruling class, and in particular, sectors that
had scarcely participated in the major political choices, or who considered them-
selves damaged by the political choices they had made up to that point. With an
abstention rate of 55.4 percent of voters (and as much as 70 percent in the large
northern cities), the elections of 1870 sent 170 new deputies to the chamber,17
EMERGING SECTORS AND TRANSFORMISM 109
most of them representing not traditional parties, but local interest groups—an
extremely significant signal of the malaise that the crisis of 1873 was to catalyze.
The new sectors of the economy, still fragile because of their youth, were naturally
more exposed to the effects of the latest crisis and reacted by accentuating their
political pressure.
When discussing interest groups keen to play a more consequential role in
managing the country’s affairs, we must not forget a part of the ruling class, much
older and more substantial than those mentioned above, which had been almost
totally excluded from national power practically since unification: the southern
bourgeoisie. The necessity of integrating it into the management of public life was
felt ever more acutely, starting in the late 1860s and especially in the early 1870s, as
demonstrated by the attention Minghetti paid to its expectations.
But Minghetti merely added to the frustrated ambitions and dashed expecta-
tions of the dominant southern classes, constrained as he was to pursue the rigor-
ous budget-balancing policies inaugurated by the preceding governments. Thus
the dominant southern classes definitively cast their lot with the Sinistra.
Loyalty to the Sinistra was built around the question—crucial to landowners—
of the equalization of property taxes. The provisional calculation of property tax
assessments, established shortly after unification, favored southern landowners.
Faced with a likely reform of this calculation, that group held that differences
in property-based revenues owing to different conditions of viability, trade, and
culture should have been taken into account. Two separate regimes should have
been institutionalized—one for the south and another for the rest of the coun-
try—which was the negation of a national unitary policy and which was to be the
fundamental characteristic of Italian “dualism.”
The results of the 1874 elections—which saw voter participation jump by 10
percentage points from the previous electoral exercise—anticipated this “dual-
ism,” giving a territorial character to the political divide between the Destra and
the Sinistra. The Sinistra won 100,350 votes, 63.4 percent of them in the south and
the islands, and the Destra won 116,129 votes, of which 76.5 percent were in the
north and the center.18
From 1874 to 1876, the political struggle was feverish. Matters descended to
the paradoxical level—even more absurd if one thinks of the results of the insti-
tutional referendum of seventy years later—of dangling the specter of separation
between a republican south and a monarchist north. What is certain is that from
1874 to 1876, the Sinistra ended up representing—partly through profound con-
viction, partly through opportunist calculation—a deeply mixed coalition repre-
senting every faction that wanted to confirm the break with what remained of the
previous equilibrium. These disparate interests came together around two classi-
cally liberal demands: to reduce the tax burden and to defend the free movement
of the “invisible hand” against any state interference.
As for taxes, the country felt that the spartan policies imposed by the Destra
had seen their day. Indeed, it is no coincidence that after the elections of 1874, the
Chamber of Deputies rejected any proposed tax increase, although the Destra held
a majority. And when Silvio Spaventa, minister of public works, suggested putting
an end to the hypocrisy of “private” rail companies supported by extensive public
110 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
aid and proposed nationalizing the sector outright, the “enraged Smithians” (as
they were called) of the Tuscan Destra and the Sinistra found common cause: The
day after the announcement that the budget had been balanced, the Minghetti
government was disavowed by the chamber and had to resign. As Denis Mack
Smith writes, the Destra had “completed their task of tightfisted and unspectacular
administration. New times called for new men.”19
Chapter 13
L iterature devoted to the “southern question” began appearing between the elec-
tions of 1874 and 1876. The first to specialize in this new discipline were men
of the Destra who were struggling to understand the reasons for their crushing
electoral defeat of 1874 in southern Italy. Thus the Tuscan Leopoldo Franchetti1
traveled to Sicily to meet the historian Pasquale Villari, author of Lettere meridi-
onali [Southern Letters]. Discussions between the two men led to the conclusion
that the new laws and the new institutions that unification had brought to the
south had worsened conditions in the Mezzogiorno, not improved them. In two
later texts, Franchetti pointed the finger at the “economic and class relationships
that prevented the civil development”2 of these regions.
The Sinistra angrily rejected Franchetti’s conclusions, seeing them as an attack
on existing property relationships, launched with electoral objectives in mind.
The debate on the “southern question,” with the themes and position-taking that
would accompany it for more than a century, was thus opened.
The theme that cropped up most often in the debate was what Luciano Cafagna
described as the “impostazione rivendicativa risarcitoria” [demand for damages and
compensation]: The Mezzogiorno, by this logic, had a right to demand damages,
with interest, from the Italian political class for losses provoked by unification.3
The basis for this view was easily found in the conclusion that Villari and Fortu-
nato had reached during their meeting in 1875: in observing that conditions in the
Mezzogiorno had worsened after unification, they were describing an incontestable
reality; yet by placing all responsibility for this on the new laws and institutions,
they were asserting a causal link that was arbitrary to say the least.
For those who have carefully analyzed this question in recent decades, unification
simply placed the two parts of the country into a direct relationship within a uni-
form institutional framework, submitting them to the same policies; yet this attempt
to make two such different regions uniform merely focused the gap separating them.
Most historians now conclude that, in the first postunitary decades, neither part of
the country developed to the detriment of the other. Between north and south, they
asserted, there was substantial “economic indifference,” in the wider context of an
absence of interchange between the different “economic Italies.”4
112 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
In fact, the widening of the north-south gap was due to unification only insofar
as unification accelerated the integration of the Mezzogiorno into the world mar-
ket. Postunitary free-trade policies put Italy in contact with the more advanced
parts of Europe, favoring agricultural exports from the south as well as the north
and sparking an industrial restructuring in all parts of the country. This process
would eventually have produced comparable results in the Mezzogiorno even with-
out unification.
If unification widened the gap, it did not create it. Even a superficial study of
the history of the peninsula demonstrates that this “dualism”—and more gener-
ally, all the disproportions between the “economic Italies”—has roots extending
long before unification. Pasquale Villani calculated that in the continental Mez-
zogiorno of the late eighteenth century, two-thirds of the population was depen-
dent on ninety families. This level of concentration made it extremely difficult to
effect genuine “democratization” of agricultural property by dividing it into small
lots.5 A closed rural economy dominated in the south; an internal market and
export flows that were very limited and thus had no need for evolved financial or
commercial institutions, nor of an effective transport system. At the moment of
unification, the rail network consisted of a mere ninety-nine kilometers of track
in the entire kingdom, and the credit system was essentially based on a few private
institutes and on two public banks in Naples and Sicily, each of them with a sub-
sidiary in Bari and another one in Catania.6 As for manufacturing, beyond state-
owned industry and a few foreign investments, it was essentially limited to rural
and family-based activities, closer to self-consumption than to a market.
Agriculture in the south, of course, faces serious geographical and climatic
handicaps, from the mountainous terrain to the limited availability of hydro-
logical resources, from the torrid temperatures six months a year to the narrow,
clay-filled plains subject to catastrophic seasonal flooding. But we should avoid
the temptation to explain the region’s lag in agricultural production by a sort of
“geographic determinism,” when the shallowest of historic reviews offers a more
nuanced picture. We know that in the time of the grandeur of Rome, Sicily was
the “granary of the Empire,” while during the same period, Lombardy was a deso-
late and unproductive land. According to David Abulafia, even at the end of the
Middle Ages the agricultural production of the southern regions was greater than
that of the north.7 We must conclude that responsibility for the radical changes in
the relationship between the two parts of Italy lies in the actions of man and not
of nature.8
The cumulative effects of the actions of man and the actions of nature form the
substratum of later development. This is why the territory of a modern national
state is never homogeneous and, when the different parts come in contact, it
merely accentuates their respective inequalities and future “dualisms.” The case of
Italian north-south “dualism” is no exception.
THE SOUTHERN QUESTION 113
Vera Zamagni writes that in most great countries, “including the United States,”
important dualisms have long existed.9 Piero Bevilacqua, for his part, notes that at
the end of the 1990s, the ratio between the gross domestic product (GDP) of the
richest region and the poorest was the same in Italy and in France (2.4) and nearly
the same in Germany (2.3).10
But these “dualisms” and “inequalities” affect not only territories separated
by great distances—geographically or structurally; they can be found even in the
interior of regions considered economically and socially more “homogeneous.”
To take the case of Piedmont, the imbalances between the mountainous zones
and the plains or hilly country, as well as the inequalities between the different
provinces, are found in every social indicator, sometimes by a ratio of two to
one. From 1824 to 1861, the urbanization process in the cities of Novara and
Vercelli grew 64 percent, while in Cuneo and Asti, the rate was lower than that
of Aosta. In the province of Turin, according to data from 1883, the average life
expectancy of a mountain dweller was only thirty-eight years, while in the plain
it was forty-five to fifty years. The rates of illiteracy among those called to mili-
tary service was 24 percent for young men from Cuneo province, 22 percent for
those from Alessandria province, 18 percent for those from Novara, and 12 per-
cent for those from Turin. In the same period, the rate of industrial employees
among all workers was 2.6 percent in the province of Alessandria, 2.9 percent in
the province of Cuneo, 6.2 percent in the province of Turin, and 7.6 percent in
the province of Novara.11
As for the phenomenon of rural exodus toward urban centers, it first affected
the north, and massively so; only in the late nineteenth century did emigration
from the south start to take on considerable dimensions. And yet, contrary to
widespread belief, since unification the countryside of the north has been depopu-
lated at rates and in numbers far larger than those of the south.12
Once we have brought the supposed Italian specificity—and within it the sup-
posed southern specificity—into a more realistic context within the “universal”
framework of the laws of development, we must nonetheless reconsider the partic-
ular situation of Italian “dualism,” and its exponents. That is, we must reexamine
the way in which the south’s historic backwardness, its uneven development, and
the miserable conditions faced by the enormous majority of the population were
used by the southern bourgeoisie for political purposes.
Having been inaugurated by intellectuals of the Destra, the “southernist” theses,
as they were to be called, grew more elaborate, but also more diverse, until they
were left with only two points in common: the insistence on southern specific-
ity, and the fact of being exploited by all those for whom the Mezzogiorno repre-
sents the main flaw of Italian development. On every other question—questions
of substance, since they were supposed to concern proposed solutions—the vari-
ous approaches were miles apart, even totally opposed. From the “social” wing
of the Destra, “southernism” evolved into one frankly reactionary faction, under
Pasquale Turiello, and another into a syndicalist faction, under Arturo Labriola. At
the same time, “southernists” included men like Pasquale Villari, Sydney Sonnino,
114 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Napoleone Colajanni, and Francesco Saverio Nitti, all of them partisans to vary-
ing degrees of state intervention in economic matters. Alongside them there were
intransigent free-traders like Antonio De Viti de Marco and Gaetano Salvemini,
federalists like Salvemini and Colajanni, rigorous centralists like Fortunato, impe-
rialists like Leopoldo Franchetti, and also pacifists. According to Salvatore Lupo,
the absence of a unique “southernist” discourse can be explained quite simply by
the absence of unique southern interests.13
All these confused or even antithetical tendencies gave rise to two contradictory
movements: on the one hand, the persistent demand for political action to reduce
the gap, and on the other, an inability to formulate concrete proposals on how best
to do so. It was a contradiction, however, that could be synthesized by the “demand
for damages and compensation,” as Cafagna calls it. Starting with the protection-
ist laws enacted progressively from 1878 to 1887 and, more particularly, with the
“special legislation,” no measure of public intervention was considered sufficient
to definitively resolve the problems, which meant more “special legislation” was
required, and so on. Thus the gap between north and south, as Gianfranco Viesti
wrote, became the pretext employed by a large part of the ruling class to obtain the
greatest quantity possible of public allocations.14
This attitude highlighted a conception of the function of the state that is the
historic product of several heritages: by constantly demanding favors, the south-
ern elites seemed to propose to the liberal state what Paolo Macry calls a “courtisan
paradigm.”15 This relationship with the state revealed another of the south’s his-
toric handicaps, and not the least important.
At the moment of unification, and for fifteen years afterward, the Destra govern-
ments had excluded even the possibility that the southern ruling classes should
play a direct role in managing the affairs of the new state; they were considered
too querulous and too preoccupied with managing public matters as if they were
private affairs. The “Piedmontized” southern intellectuals were the most deter-
mined about this. They refused, on the one hand, to separate the interests of the
Mezzogiorno from that of the entire nation, while on the other hand, based on
their experience in their home regions, they imagined the transformation of Italy
into an “ethical state” that could make up for the traditional lack of a civic sense.
According to Aldo Schiavone, in the social psychology of the inhabitants of the
peninsula, the notions of state and ethics are most often in contradiction. This
mistrust of established power, he asserts, was born from foreign domination, fol-
lowed by the failure of “the relationship between bourgeois development and the
construction of the state” in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries. As they grew
accustomed to this domination from the outside, the Italians began to associate
public power with the invader, and force to pillage, thus establishing a direct rela-
tionship between the state and the stifling of their own identity.16 This sentiment,
common to the entire peninsula, was displayed most flagrantly in the south due to
the almost uninterrupted subjection of these regions to foreign powers, and to the
THE SOUTHERN QUESTION 115
judged the new Italian government’s moralizing ambitions as not only extrava-
gant, but dangerously out of place. “Do you know,” Pasquale Villari wrote Gover-
nor Farini on December 9, 1860, “that in Naples, destroying corruption amounts
to destroying the country?”21
It is also unsurprising that, in these conditions, the Piedmontese would prove
reluctant to involve the southern ruling classes in the management of the state;
all the more so because Cavour belonged to a generation (and a class) unaccus-
tomed to resolving social problems by creating jobs, of greater or lesser utility,
within an administration, and equally unaccustomed, as Cavour himself said,
to a “system that consists of reconciling men’s differences at the expense of the
State treasury.”22
For fifteen years, the men of the Destra lived under the illusion that the prac-
tices of transformism and clientelism were the result of free choices, and conse-
quently they rejected them. They could not yet know—and their political culture
inhibited such awareness—that these practices constituted what Cafagna consid-
ered a “regular and constant tendency” of a democratic state, which would expand
as the bases of electoral consensus expanded.23
The men of the Sinistra, for their part, displayed a more pragmatic approach,
progressively adapting to the new situation. Those deputies elected in 1876,
accused by their opponents of representing corruption and intrigue, may have
lacked the prestige of their predecessors, but they had sufficient moral stature to
embody the transformist process—a process, Carocci wrote, “of which the growth
of democracy was the cause and the degeneration of democracy was the effect.”24
The social enlargement of the bases of power having gone hand in hand with
geographic enlargement, one can say that the leaders of the Sinistra constituted
the first truly national governments. At the same time, however, their transformist
practices led them to renounce any notion of a “nationalization of the masses,”
that is, to renounce any structural effort to stifle particularisms in order to seek a
theoretical national interest in which Italians might recognize themselves.
The Sinistra had been carried to power by a coalition of interests intent, in
part, on weakening, if not abolishing, the rigorous restrictions imposed on pub-
lic spending by the Destra. After several years, enlarging the bases of consensus
through public spending became the mechanism of ordinary functioning of the
state. This mechanism essentially worked in two directions: it extended the elec-
toral base, as per the law of 1882, while expanding the bureaucratic apparatus.
With the law of 1882, the habit of regularly electing a town’s notable, particu-
larly in the south, leapt to a new level. The end of the organic relationship between
elected and elector led these notables increasingly to entrust the representation of
their interests to new political professionals, markedly this “small crowd of South-
ern lawyers” that Romano describes.25 The function of the latter was to haggle
with each minister, offering their votes in exchange for certain local interests being
taken into account.
THE SOUTHERN QUESTION 117
As for the enlargement of the bureaucracy, the period of 1883 to 1891 brought
13,000 new civil servants, a growth rate of 20.3 percent in eight years.26 It was now
more closely aligned to geographic criteria, unlike the earlier “Piedmontization” of
public structures in the first years of the kingdom. This increasing “southerniza-
tion” mainly affected the lower layers of bureaucracy, while executive functions
remained primarily in Piedmontese hands for some time to come. This phenom-
enon—which gave structure to the “Turin-Naples axis” on which, according to
Galli della Loggia, the Italian state project would be built—is one effect of the
capacity for negotiation the Mezzogiorno acquired after its rise to power (the oth-
ers being linked to the “policy of compensation” put in place by the special legis-
lation). As Jean Meynaud writes, the “Southernization of public life” was a trend
responding to the pressure of a petit bourgeoisie lacking in local perspective or the
means to ensure its existence.27
The renunciation of the nationalization of the masses resulted directly from
what Lanaro calls “transformism as the extreme sublimation of the clientelist rela-
tionship.”28 It was a renunciation in terms of national moral cohesion, for trans-
formism implies the loss of all legitimation not founded on negotiation, and a
“legitimation” subject to constant challenge can hardly provide a stable marker of
identity. And it was a renunciation in terms of the material cohesion of the nation
because, as a result of this “sublimation,” the center ceded in the face of local pres-
sures and began progressively to adapt different rules for the Mezzogiorno.29
The special legislation and the enlargement of the bureaucratic apparatus (and
later, the military expeditions into Africa) were financed by those regions of Italy
that could do so, which is to say, mainly those in the north.30 This transfer of funds
is justified as an imperative of national solidarity that is apparently absolute but
that in the real world takes place only to the extent that it corresponds roughly
to the interests and social psychology of those controlling the purse strings. The
strength and importance of the hesitations and the resistance are always directly
proportional to the opacity of the “national contract.” When the most important
groups and sectors of the dominant class have difficulty seeing the benefits they
might gain from representing a supposed “general interest,” they tend to tighten
their grip on the national purse and to contest the right of those ostensibly repre-
senting them to speak in their name. They exploit every means at their disposal to
challenge the defined balance.
Thus, in transformist Italy, the versatility of political relationships was the rule.
Each time a proposal, an idea, or a demand surfaced somewhere in the country,
there was an effort to isolate it from the others and to give a particular, specific
response. The “historic bloc” between the industrialists of the north and the big
property owners of the south that, according to Gramsci, prevailed throughout the
phase that began with the adoption of customs tariffs in 1887 should only be con-
sidered as a specific and episodic tactical alliance that brought together, around
protectionist demands, powerful interests with little else in common.
Shortly after the arrival in power of Francesco Crispi, it was Milan that set the
tone for the campaigns against the government headed by the man whom the
Socialist Filippo Turati referred to as the “cynical Sicilian bumpkin.” The “true
118 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
bourgeoisie,” Turati declared, had nothing in common with the “brazen banditry
and crookedness of the bumpkins and thugs who made Crispi their hired gun.”31
The opposition of the “State of Milan” marked the collapse of the last attempt
by the ruling class of the Risorgimento to endow the Italian bourgeoisie with a
“positive” political identity, capable of measuring up to the Catholic and Socialist
identities. Born from the failure of efforts to base national legitimation on trans-
formist mediation, this attempt foundered on the same reef: the social bases of any
plan for a “sacred union” between the classes were still too weak and the habit of
pitting different interests against each other in the search for state support drained
all meaning from any striving for national concord.
Crispi resorted to the old Garibaldian expedient of attempting to bypass the
obstacles of reality through subjective voluntarism, but this transformed him into
a sorcerer’s apprentice of social movements—riots, insurrections, and military
adventures—with catastrophic consequences for the new Italy. In the ensuing cri-
sis, Giovanni Giolitti recognized that the social and political actors no longer had
anything in common with those of forty or even twenty years earlier. His attempt
to create a new “unique party of the bourgeoisie” marked the final effort to seek a
national Italian identity, and it led to two political and military catastrophes: the
Libyan War and the Great War.
Part III
A Counter-Reformist Identity
I n a 1999 essay, the then archbishop of Bologna, Giacomo Biffi, wrote that the
gravest error of the Piedmontese ruling class in the 1860s was to underestimate
“how deeply rooted Catholic faith is in the Italian soul, and its near consubstanti-
ality with national identity.”1
The voice of Cardinal Biffi was but one of many to be raised from within the
Catholic hierarchy during the 1990s to explain that the fundamental reasons for
the identity crisis then shaking Italy lay in the separation between the develop-
ment of the state and the national spiritual tradition. The bishops were sounding a
polemical theme that the Church had previously taken up during the celebrations
of the fiftieth anniversary of Italian unification. On that occasion, the Holy See’s
daily newspaper had observed that the masses were indifferent, even hostile, to
the state because liberalism had failed to represent “the true interests of Italy and
the Italians.”2 In 1929, immediately after the signing of the Concordat, the Jesu-
its’ review blamed the “Piedmontese government” for the failure of the “national
league” proposed by Pius IX in 1848: the pope and the cardinals, far from opposing
unification, simply wanted “to achieve it differently.”3 Sixty years later, a revisionist
Catholic school of historiography again took up and emphasized these polemical
themes, which had been put aside in the name of a Christian Democratic republic:
The real trustees of the national identity, according to this school, were not Garib-
aldi and Victor Emmanuel, but Cardinal Ruffo and Pius IX.4
The Church’s investment in Italy bore fruit: today, in the peninsula, the voice
of the Vatican is not only heard and respected, but it has become the axis around
which many great decisions of the country revolve, whatever the coalition in
power. This investment, however, does not date from the 1990s, it dates from
the moment when the popes renounced any intention to reestablish their tem-
poral power on the right bank of the Tiber in order to devote themselves to
the conquest of both banks, that is, of all Italy. It is a long-term strategy, which
began with the transformation of the Church from a feudal to a financial power,
continued with the creation of the first national Catholic organizations, refined
itself with the substantial support of the Italian clergy for the military effort of
the Great War, and culminated with the birth of the People’s Party in 1919. The
122 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
destroyed all piety and religion in Italy.”9 To this moral grievance he added another
that we would now describe as geopolitical: the Church was sufficiently strong to
constitute its own state, but not enough to unify the peninsula, often requiring the
aid of foreign powers to protect its temporal power.10 It is interesting to note that
even those who, like Guicciardini, did not necessarily view the division of the pen-
insula as a problem, they nevertheless shared Machiavelli’s thesis on the divisive role
played by the Church.11
But the debate on the failure to unify the peninsula faded as the real possibil-
ity of overcoming its division receded. The more distant its prospects became,
the larger did Church influence loom over the entire Italian population. Certain
historians have observed that the Counter-Reformation shaped Italian anthropo-
logical identity as few phenomena have done. The fear of punishment, the habit
of acquiescing without necessarily approving, and thus the necessary recourse to
duplicity and dissimulation had a depressing moral effect on the Italian mind,
not unconnected to the weak public morality of the peninsula’s inhabitants.12
Another important heritage that the Counter-Reformation bequeathed to Italy’s
later destiny was the progressive but ineluctable decline of intellectuals as a social
group, who, though limited in size, were still potentially able to exert and claim a
“national” ruling function.
The intellectuals’ decline should not be seen as a regrettable bit of “collateral dam-
age” from the Counter-Reformation; rather, it was central to the Church’s six-
teenth-century rebirth from the ashes of the Italian Renaissance. At the moment
when the collapse provoked by the Reformation suggested an irreversible decline
of the Catholic institutional structure, religious life was surprisingly “ardent and
intense.”13 It was a popular religiosity, impregnated with superstition and the
residual influence of ancient polytheistic cults. Facing such vitality, Machiavelli
and some others hoped to channel it toward mundane political ends; others
wanted to purge it of its superstitious elements and restore its original purity; still
others wanted to use it to lessen the difficulties facing the Church. It was the latter
approach that prevailed.
According to Giordano Bruno Guerri, it was Cardinal Roberto Bellarmino, pro-
tagonist of the trials against Bruno, Campanella, and Galileo, who was the first to
acknowledge the loss of northern Europe; he advocated a strategic retreat to make
it easier to safeguard those border countries that had remained Catholic, starting
obviously with Italy.14 Toward this end, all available weapons were deployed, and
not just repressive action. The most important and lasting result was to appropri-
ate the form and contents of popular religiosity by disciplining them and oppos-
ing them to the schisms and wars that result whenever one attempts to eradicate a
people’s most deeply rooted beliefs.15
According to the sociologist Enzo Pace, writing about Italians’ religious prac-
tices in the 1990s, “primary religious socialization” has resisted secularization, still
affecting more than 90 percent of the population. Pace used that phrase to define
124 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
the “sort of comfort” that religion and its structures provide during certain fun-
damental life experiences, whether suffering, death, marriage, or birth.16 There
is a singular coincidence between the characteristics Pace attributes to “primary
religious socialization” and what certain Renaissance intellectuals denounced as
the ultimate essence of superstition. In 1539 the Tuscan jurist Enrico Boccella
described as superstitious all those who turn to God only in a moment of fear or
when faced by a material problem that they do not know how to solve. True reli-
gion, Boccella added, should concede nothing to external rites or to the “egoisms
of individual appetites.”17
The Counter-Reformation condemned such positions, which it said were dic-
tated by “haughty intellectuals,” and it rose to the defense of the sancta simplicitas
of the people. During the seventeenth century, Italy witnessed a proliferation of
religious cults, miracles, and revelations, and a multiplying of new saints, prodi-
gious images, and religious relics. In this way the Church renewed its traditional
ties to the people while marking the limits of its agreement with Reformation
theses. For a time, a series of “scholars” were put on trial, even as a systematic cam-
paign was undertaken first against the press—as a technological invention—and
then against publishing and books. Pope Paul IV created in 1557 a congregation to
monitor the application of the Index librorum prohibitorum. When the Inquisitors
put a stop to the attempted resistance of Venice, where, by then, two-thirds of Ital-
ian books were being printed, they had ten thousand to twelve thousand volumes
burned, though the government first obliged them to purchase the tomes to avoid
a revolt by bookstore owners and printers.18
And yet, the cultural policy of the Counter-Reformation did not consist solely
of repressive measures. The trials and the book burnings cannot, by themselves,
explain its successes. For Gramsci, the explanation lay in the fact that in Italy,
religion did not represent “an element of cohesion between the people and the
intellectuals.”19 But there is another reason, again identified by Gramsci: culture
had developed in Italy in the Middle Ages in the cities from which the struggle
between the bourgeoisie and the feudal nobility began; the premature interrup-
tion of this process weakened the bourgeoisie and thereby deprived the royal pow-
ers (whatever their form) of the possibility of pitting this class against the nobility
to keep both in check. This brings us back to the fundamental problem breaking
the straight, ascending line of Italian bourgeois development: the absence of the
material conditions indispensable to the formation of absolute states.
In this framework, the pitting of “the simple folk” against the “scholars” is rem-
iniscent of Sylos Labini’s thesis regarding “lazzarone absolutism” in the Kingdom
of Naples. But there was a sizable difference: in the latter case, it was not simply a
question of the problematic power of the monarch in Rome (the Pope) over the
subjects of his kingdom (the Papal States), but of the power of all ecclesiastical struc-
tures over all subjects on the entire peninsula. The “favors of every nature” that the
Church was able to dispense to the plebes and peasants were incomparable to what
other states could offer. Even if one disregards properly religious questions—and
they are hardly negligible—the decisive difference lies in the clergy’s capacity to tend
to the most elementary needs of society’s lower levels, a capacity that for centuries
made the Church the only Italian institution that was genuinely popular.
A COUNTER-REFORMIST IDENTITY 125
dwellers, the educated and the illiterate, were at that moment united in “the cry
of ‘Long live Pius IX!’” Yet, when the pontiff ostensibly abandoned the national
cause, “this religious link that had united intellectuals and the plebeians of our
Italian countryside in common aspirations was broken.”30
According to Gramsci, the breaking of this bond meant that, in the Italian
Risorgimento, the democrats—who, in an ideal (and abstract) scheme, should
have represented the “Jacobins”—expressed none of the essential demands of the
masses31; the real “theoretical Jacobins,” the true strategists, were the liberal Catho-
lics. This group, however, was destined to fail, for it could only lead the masses to
the extent that it was prepared to wed itself fully with the policies of the Church.32
The Italian bourgeoisie thus found itself a prisoner of its traditional histori-
cal contradiction: that of being a class that both needs change but also fears it.
Once again, this fundamental indecision left it as a hostage to the Church. And
the Church, once it learned this lesson, exploited to its own benefit this trace of
national spirit that it had never had.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 15
Church’s still-strong influence in the countryside, and the desire of many bour-
geois liberals for appeasement.
Its real presence in society’s most remote corners allowed the Church to exert
the full weight of the political blackmail represented by its absence from political
competition. This absence was all the more strongly felt since part of the bour-
geoisie was beginning to think that the closest peril was no longer represented by
sanfedism in the interior or by a hostile alliance of Catholic powers in the exte-
rior, but by socialism. Even as a parliamentary discussion continued in Rome
on the Law of Guarantees, in Paris, said the Foreign Minister Visconti Venosta,
blew “the impious breath that extinguished all moral sense and all sentiment of
honor among the masses.”. In the Parliament, the former head of government
Luigi Federico Menabrea warned against acting like the Byzantines in 1453:
“Rather than continuing to wage a war against a group that no longer represents
any danger, let us unite to exorcise the common enemy.”2 In the struggle against
the “revolutionary peril,” the Church undeniably held a solid lead. While it could
draw on the capital accumulated during centuries of implacable struggle against
“revolution,” the Italian bourgeoisie had only just waged its own revolution, and
a timid one at that.
The absence of a real workers movement in Italy meant that the repression of
Thiers in France sufficed to remove the fear of “red peril” for several more decades.
But, Jemolo writes, the “impious breath” had left Church hierarchies and Italian
bourgeoisie believing that a society without private property constituted a graver
threat than a society that allowed divorce.3 The accords of 1929 would merely give
such thinking a juridical underpinning.
The real problem facing the Italian state in the early decades of its existence was not
to defend itself from the lower classes, which posed no concrete threat, but rather to
find broad legitimacy among the ruling class. What united Church and state from
the start of the unification process was the vital and primordial problem, for both, of
survival. Yet, since their reciprocal hostility was real and unavoidable, the difficulty
consisted in finding a balancing point between rapprochement and repulsion.
Thus, Candeloro writes, having eliminated its temporal power, confiscated part
of its assets, secularized its laws and some of its structures, “the bourgeoisie satis-
fied itself with what it had achieved and even offered the Church the possibility of
involving itself in the new state of things.”4 The Church, while officially rejecting
this implicit truce offering, was not about to ignore the proposal, taking advantage
of it to begin the long work of economic and organizational transition.
Underlying this transition, writes the most important historian of the Azione
cattolica, Gianfranco Poggi, was the clear awareness that a simple attitude of refusal
“would have been disastrous.” Secularization tended to loosen the attachment of
the faithful, an attachment that risked disappearing for good if the Church did not
decide to approach the new context with more constructive attitudes.5 It thus pro-
ceeded toward a more rigorous centralization and a broader opening to lay people
A CIVIL “GUELPH” RELIGION 131
to give the latter direct responsibilities within ecclesiastical institutions; these were
strictly interdependent measures, for the larger the number of lay people speaking
in the Church’s name, the more necessary it is for them to come under hierarchi-
cal control and strict discipline. These choices prefaced the creation of a national
organization of coordination of all Catholic associations. During its Congress of
1874, this organization made known its principal demands, particularly concern-
ing education and family policy.
Although it had rejected the notion of a conservative Catholic party, the Vati-
can nonetheless maintained various forms of organization at the national level, and
remained willing to intervene through appropriate political instruments in local sit-
uations where it had specific interests to promote or defend, as in the city of Rome.
In the kingdom’s new capital, the main act of the Church’s metamorphosis was
being played out. Having had to abandon its final links to the remnants of the feu-
dal world, the Church was being pushed to make its grand entry into the capitalist
system, with the status of a great financial power.6 In this turning point lies the
main explanation for its survival amid the bourgeois tempest.
The liquid capital that the Church had managed to conserve came partly from
the custom of “Peter’s pence,” a sort of economic billows for the universal Church,
but above all from the transfer of its property holdings, largely effected in the short
period between the conquest of Rome and the application of the laws against the
congregations. This capital led to the creation of a vast financial system, which made
it possible to buy back some of the same properties that had once been the “inalien-
able” assets of the feudal Church. A multiplier mechanism kicked in, boosted by the
dizzying rise in property values: The banks provided the indispensable capital for
property investors and builders, and in turn, these investments, yielding phenom-
enal profits, supported an unprecedented expansion of the credit sector.
Since Rome had become the country’s capital, numerous enterprises had
opened offices there and thus came into contact with the Catholic economic
forces dominating the city. Productive bonds, at times conflicting, but more often
cooperative, were thus forged between Vatican finance and the rest of the Italian
capitalist world. In these linkages one finds the fundamental reason that many
moderate liberals sought common ground with the Catholics.
At the time of the Libyan War, in 1911, the Banco di Roma—the largest of the
Catholic banks, directed by the uncle of the future Pius XII—distinguished itself
as a key supporter of the colonial mission.7 It was no accident if the “baptism
by fire” of Italian imperialism in Libya was followed almost immediately by the
suspension of the non expedit (the Vatican policy, enjoined on Italian Catholics,
of abstaining in parliamentary elections), by the concession of universal suffrage,
and by the entry into parliament of the first Catholic deputies. During World War
I, the Church gained entry among the fundamental forces of the state by institu-
tionalizing its instruments of support, assistance, and comfort.
132 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Social Transformism
prejudice” no longer made any sense. The riots of Milan, Spadolini continues,
had laid bare the interweaving of the interests of the secular bourgeoisie and the
new Catholic bourgeoisie, leading the latter to understand that a collapse of the
liberal state would have taken with it many of the group’s positions and zones
of influence.
Despite the convergence of interests, Giolitti’s attempts at a policy of assimilation
did not produce the anticipated fruits. This was partly because of the Socialists’ irre-
ducibility, but primarily because of the immaturity of Italian capitalist development
and the necessity not to break with old social classes that were already integral to the
new system. Thus, having failed to define the contours of a “national interest,” that is
an agenda capable of unifying the conscience of Italians, the ruling liberal class again
resorted to a case-by-case negotiation for political consensus, using the same meth-
ods Depretis and Crispi had employed: bargaining at every level, corrupt practices,
pressures of every sort, seizure of prefectures and their local administrations, and
electoral intimidation. A witness of the time, Ettore d’Orazio, described the majority
as “the temporary coalition of different groups, having different leaders and divided
by tradition, by interests and by tendencies.”11
To simplify, one could say that the “Giolittian” strategy was based on three prin-
cipal objectives: to enlarge the parliamentary majority; to integrate the new actors
that had arisen from development into the management of the state; and to create
a national collective conscience. Of these three objectives, the first was achieved
(though at the cost of the most brazen parliamentary maneuvers), the second was
not realized (because of the Libyan War and, especially, World War I), and the last
failed owing to the constant resort to transformist practice.
In 1911, even a liberal monarchist like Benedetto Croce acknowledged seeing,
fifty years after unification, the decline of social unity. Individuals, the philosopher
wrote, “no longer feel linked to a grand whole,” and if such division cannot be
overcome, he concluded, it was vain to hope that “Italy will ever become great.”
As we have seen, the Catholic bourgeoisie had realized for some years that its
interests did not differ substantially from those of the rest of the Italian bour-
geoisie. Thus even those bourgeois Catholics who expected no direct benefit from
Italy’s participation in the war rallied to the ambient patriotism for fear that they
otherwise would be accused of being unpatriotic and might lose, as Candeloro
puts it, “the political, economic and administrative positions they had attained in
the preceding years.”13
The Church thus found itself having to manage the contradiction between
its universalism (which required it to continue being the Church of Catholics in
Austria, France, Belgium, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Poland, etc.) and the “national”
interests of the bourgeois Catholics in those countries. It dealt with this awkward
position by allowing the faithful to deal with the distinction between the Church’s
universal position and that of the Catholics in the nations involved in the conflict.
Thus, on May 20, 1915, four days before Italy’s attack on Austria, Catholic deputies
joined their votes to those of the majority (407 to 74) in granting full powers to
the prime minister “in case of war.” In June 1916, the first Catholic deputy, Filippo
Meda, entered the government as minister of Finance.
This transition from neutrality to engagement took place not just at the top
of the social ladder, but, more importantly, at its very bottom. The 2,400 army
chaplains that the commander in chief of the Italian Army presided over among
the 25,000 clergymen mobilized were part of a veritable infiltration of the army.
The Pope not only authorized the chaplains to serve but also created a special dio-
cese within the army, with its own bishop—who immediately obtained from the
state the rank of general. It was a clear case of do ut des (“I scratch your back, you
scratch mine”) in which each of the contracting parties served its own interests,
and it anticipated the Concordat.
During the war, the clergy officially regained its traditional role of social
mediator between power and the people, a role that it had never lost despite the
secularization that accompanied modernization. The state now recognized the
importance of this role, both to boost the morale of the troops and to bolster
failing backup. The parishes managed 11,932 charities, 8,088 money and clothing
collection centers, 4,177 information offices, 1,963 day-care facilities, and 3,084
committees for civil mobilization and assistance.14
Militarily, and in terms of international politics, the Italian war was won by the
English and the French, with decisive help from the Americans. Morally, and in
domestic political terms, the Italian war was won by the Church.
The Church did not hesitate to present its bill. Not only did the state take it
upon itself to increase the emoluments provided to priests, but also, starting in
1920, it undertook serious negotiations to resolve all outstanding disputes. The
most significant change, however, came in the birth of the People’s Party, which
Gramsci described at the time as “the most important event in Italian history since
the Risorgimento.”15 The Church had renounced the demand for the restoration of
the temporal state, because now it harbored a far more vast ambition, involving
the identification between the Italian nation and the Catholic nation. The Vatican
now aimed, Candeloro writes, for the creation of an integrally Christian state,16 an
ambition that would lead, inevitably, to the confrontation with fascism.
A CIVIL “GUELPH” RELIGION 135
The conviction that a reintegration of God in both legislation and public affairs
was under way was reinforced by a series of measures taken by the new fascist
government: the return of the crucifix to schools and courtrooms, mandatory reli-
gion classes in school, the education reform of 1923 that placed public and private
schools on an even footing, and the establishment of Sacred Heart of Milan, the
first Catholic university.
When the Concordat was signed in February 1929, the “Roman question” died
away for good. It was at that moment that the latent conflict between two religions,
both aspiring to provide spiritual direction to the Italian masses, burst into plain sight.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 16
I taly, writes Gian Enrico Rusconi, has known no form of “civil religion”—nei-
ther the American form, which emphasizes the noun in that phrase, nor the
French form, which accents the adjective. This void, according to Rusconi, was
filled by the Church, which exercises the role of a “substitute civil religion.”1 The
Italian case is unique in this regard. Unlike other Catholic countries like France,
Austria, and even Spain, where the ecclesiastical apparatus has had to confront an
entrenched royal power since at least the fifteenth century, in Italy the authority of
the Church has long faced no real state obstacles.
At its birth, the Kingdom of Italy lacked all the common qualities that puta-
tively create a sense of belonging to a single nation: unity of language, unity of ter-
ritory, and unity of tradition. Above all, the new country lacked “a common way of
thinking, a common principle, a common goal,” that is, the very essence of nation-
ality in Mazzini’s eyes. The Destra lost little sleep over this. It had other priorities,
starting with the need to build structures that could extend state power across the
entire peninsula; the national principle was not part of its cultural mentality. The
ruling Piedmontese class was accustomed to dealing with subjects, not citizens,
and the conditions under which the country had unified gave it little motive to
abandon its traditional vision.
It was only when the Sinistra arrived in power that the ambition of an Italian
“civil religion” began to find practical application. This was not only because of
the different cultural education of the men who had come to power in 1876, nor
was it simply because the Paris Commune had shown, early in the decade, that
the people were not merely a sum of individuals, but a mass whose moods had to
be recognized and disciplined. It was also because the Sinistra had been the first
manifestation of a real enlargement of the bases of power, and it had to attempt
to bring a certain form and coherence to the new and composite interests that it
had pulled together.
For Francesco de Sanctis, minister of public instruction, but also a literary
critic, this task was the responsibility of the schools and of literature, guardians
138 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
not only of a national identity but also of a national pedagogy. That said, the edu-
cation system was weakened by profound structural inadequacies, as we have seen,
and the patriotic literature of De Amicis, Carducci, Pascoli, D’Annunzio, and even
the futurists continued for a very long time to address itself to a very limited public
with diversified tastes; moreover, this literature was deeply influenced by French
literary production.
The attempt to apply the pedagogical virtues of the French Third Republic to
Italy had failed not only because Italy was not France but also because the terms
of the relationship between the grandeur of the country and a national conscious-
ness in Italy had constantly been reversed. The “nation” was only a abstract con-
cept in France before the distribution of land to the peasants, before the civil code,
and before the Napoleonic conquests. British pride, for its part, was not a condi-
tion of the creation of the empire, but its consequence. The Americans did not
conceive of themselves as a “nation” with the objective of throwing the English
into the ocean and creating the first constitutional republic in human history, but
rather in the aftermath of these two titanic enterprises. National consciousness
is a consequence of real strength. It can grow as a function of the growth of real
strength; it never replaces it and, a fortiori, never creates it.
In Italy, like in many weaker countries, it is the voluntarist factor that has domi-
nated the concept of nation. De Sanctis’s idea that literature could permit Italy
to rise above “second-rank” status and aspire even to “convert the modern world
into a world that we own”2 does not date from the Sinistra’s accession to power.
It comes from the conviction, which grew during the Risorgimento, that Italy had
to be the “educator” of humankind, even the “verb of God among the races,” in
the words of Mazzini. This idea was popularized, if one can say it, by Vincenzo
Gioberti and also by Mazzini himself, who offered historic, cultural, religious, and
even geopolitical justifications for it.
This idea of a “civilizing mission” clearly influenced the first leaders of unified
Italy—“even the most realistic and those most aware of the country’s real condi-
tions,” writes Emilio Gentile—to reject the possibility that the new country might
limit itself to a modest neutrality in the concert of nations.3 Given the circum-
stances of its creation, its objective weight in demographic and economic terms,
and its geographic position, Italy had no real possibility of remaining neutral for
long. The lack of realism among the leaders of the country thus lay not so much
in their thoughts of an impossible neutrality, but in the conviction that the new
country could prevail over other powers.
As we have seen, lacking policies of their own, the democrats of the 1850s were
in fact guided by Cavour and the moderates. A similar thing occurred on the
international policy scene, especially among men of democratic background. In
an April 1868 letter, Otto von Bismarck offered a lesson in geopolitics to Mazzini,
exploiting the latter’s notorious francophobia: Italy and Germany, the Prussian
chancellor wrote, “exert their action in such different directions that Italy can
never aspire to dominate the Baltic, nor Germany the Mediterranean”; at the same
time, “the configuration of the terrestrial globe being unchangeable, Italy and
France will always be rivals and often enemies.”4
THE QUEST FOR A CIVIL ITALIAN RELIGION 139
The most Mazzinian politician of the new Italy, Francesco Crispi, recognized
that the grandeur of Italy and its national conscience would be born of its suc-
cesses in international politics, notably, if they were achieved through military
means. Italy, he asserted in 1866, the year of the humiliations of Custoza and
Lissa, “needs a baptism by fire: she owes it to herself, so that the great nations of
Europe know that she, too, is a great nation, and that she is sufficiently strong
to demand respect in the world.”5 Yet, the “baptisms by fire” that Italy was to
experience under Crispi’s leadership—Amba Alagi and Macallé in 1895, Adwa in
1896, not to mention the Fasci Siciliani—destroyed Crispi, diminished respect
for Italy in the world, and lessened the possibility that Italy might one day be
able to construct its own “civil religion.”
Italian Fatherlands
On the eve of World War I, the competition between those presenting them-
selves as the sole true trustees of the “fatherland” was fierce. The conservative
liberals pointed to the undeniable progress achieved since 1861 and, in the
fiftieth-anniversary celebrations, made official the syncretistic vision of the
Risorgimento advocated by de Sanctis as early as 1862. The republicans, for their
part, condemned the “lie” of an official Italy, which they said was physically but
not spiritually united because it “lacked a popular soul.” As natural heirs to the
Mazzini’s “voluntarist shortcut,” they conceived the “true fatherland” as the real
country purged of its flaws; they made of this a moral postulate.
The living conditions of the people outside the public arena were also a polemi-
cal target of the Catholics and the Socialists, hostile to a state seen as “foreign” to
Italians’ real interests. But, unlike the republicans, the Catholics and Socialists had
deep roots among these same people. Because of the continuity of their institu-
tions, the propagation of their religion, and their centuries-long symbiosis with
the peasant world, the Catholics also claimed to represent the true fatherland of
the Italians, which was naturally different from the liberals’. They knew that so
long as they were not called on to manage the state, it could not truly be a state
for all, and this, indirectly, would give them political strength. On top of that, they
would bring to the negotiating table with the liberals the trump card of their social
doctrine. Embodied in state structures, it could provide a dowry to the common
fatherland—a solution to the “workers question,” that is, social peace.
Among the different fatherlands proposed to the Italians, one was actually
Socialist. For Filippo Turati, “Italian, worker and citizen” are but one; separated,
they unmasked the “lie” upon which the official Italian state was founded.6 But
here again was an underlying offer of collaboration: the proposal to transform
the proletariat into a social pillar of the Italian state. It is not incidental that this
suggestion came from the leader of the reformist wing of the party who, during
the Giolittian decade, had come close to throwing his support to a majority that
today we would call center-left. But the Socialist Party was very divided and, in
1912, it was the maximalist (extremist) faction that emerged to take the reins,
140 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
declaring war on “bourgeois patriotism” and expelling four of its deputies for their
“nationalist and warmonger” positions.
All the political groups mentioned were in fact divided at their cores: the
liberals were motivated by their ideals, of course, but also by their transformist
management of public affairs; the republicans oscillated between a liberalism
barely more radical than that of the government and revolutionary subversiv-
ism; and the “modernist” tendencies troubled the consciences of many Catholics,
before being energetically condemned by Pius X in his 1907 encyclical Pascendi
Dominici Gregis.
To be sure, among the republicans and the Catholics there were factions and
individuals who were unalterably hostile to the liberal state, but most of Mazzi-
ni’s heirs seemed more interested in “pursuing their business interests within the
shadow of the monarchy” than in overturning it, as one can read in a report by the
prefect of Forlì, a republican stronghold.7 In any case, outside Romagna and the
Carrara region, their political influence was negligible. Catholics, for their part,
had already begun their slow ascension toward the conquest of the state; their hos-
tility toward it was tactical, though a few took it literally. Support for the Libyan
expedition and the elections of 1913—when Catholics were responsible, accord-
ing to Count Ottorino Gentiloni, for the election of 195 of the 305 deputies in the
liberal majority—testified eloquently to this fact.
Outside of these minorities—reactionary Catholics, revolutionary republi-
cans, extremist Socialists, and anarchists—one other political grouping declared
open hostility to the liberal state: the nationalists. If the Socialists were the direct
product of the Giolittian era’s “economic miracle”—representing, as they did, a
proletariat that had grown in quantity and in quality8—the nationalists were the
indirect product, the still uncertain expression of new forces that had begun to
raise questions about the old balance but that were not yet able to create new one.
During the Giolittian period, industrial production rose from 50 percent to
twice that, depending on the source.9 Imports tripled and exports rose by a factor
of 2.5 in less than twenty years.10 The agricultural consumption of chemical prod-
ucts rose by 9.25 times between 1893 and 1913, and this had a multiplying effect
on the rural exodus.11 The number of Italians leaving the countryside each year
rose from 310,434 in 1896 through 1900 to 679,152 in 1909 through 1913 (hav-
ing hit a high of 739,661 emigrants per year in 1905 through 1907).12 At the same
time, the cities grew more and more crowded as they went from 24 percent of the
population in 1881 to 31.3 percent in 1911 (four-fifths of this increase stemmed
from migratory flows).13
During the early years of the decade, the combined effects of protectionism,
expanded credit and production, plus increasing purchasing power seemed to
create a virtuous circle that could satisfy all demands. Transformism as an occa-
sional exchange of favors soared to new heights. But the crisis of 1907, born
out of the first great financial panic in the United States, brought to light all the
contradictions that growth had hidden. Banks refused to continue long-term
financing, creating a liquidity crisis for large industry; industry then demanded
more substantial aid from the state and abandoned the policy of direct negotia-
tions with workers. Consumption diminished, and the most export-dependent
THE QUEST FOR A CIVIL ITALIAN RELIGION 141
It was only during the Giolittian decade and, in particular, in connection with the
1907 crisis that some in Italy first theorized about the necessity of a “party of the
bourgeoisie.” This notion arose precisely at the moment when the “sole party of
the bourgeoisie,” based on transformism, faced a crisis.
The first to seek to give a political conscience to the productive bourgeoisie
were the nationalists, united around the journal Il Regno. For them, “the life of
Italy” was embodied by those “courageous industrialists who increase our pro-
duction, fight for the markets of England [and] conquer Asia Minor and South
America”; their factories, these nationalists continued, would have an advantage
over the “word factories” of parliamentary politics.15
Francesco Saverio Nitti, however, was the first, or one of the firsts, to speak in
terms of an actual party. Writing in 1907, Nitti offered the outlines of a platform
meant to reflect the general interest of the bourgeoisie, and in particular of the
industrial bourgeoisie; the party was not seen so much as an organization as it was
a “conscience.”16 On the creation of a “coherent conscience of the bourgeoisie after
the economic malaise of the years after 1907,” according to Carocci, the work and
action of the economist Vilfredo Pareto, a theoretician, with Gaetano Mosca, also
dealt with the power of the economic elites.17 Pareto would become, over the years,
the advocate of a “national” or “imperialist” socialism; and it was with a socialism
transposed from class struggle to the struggle between nations that Enrico Cor-
radini, considered the “theoretician” of Italian nationalism, also aligned himself.
The nation, to Corradini—like the proletariat for the Socialists—without theo-
retical conscience is a class in itself, but not a class for itself: the task of the Social-
ists, he said, had been to “teach the proletariat the value of class struggle,” while the
task for the nationalists was to “teach Italy the value of international struggle.”18
If, for Socialists, class consciousness developed through struggle and strikes, for
nationalists, Corradini concluded, national consciousness developed through
imperialist war: “Nationalism should give rise in Italy to the desire for victorious
war.”19 Corradini drew up a list of seven reasons why, even in 1911, “Italy does not
have a developed national conscience”: (1) it had never been a nation; (2) it had
not had (and still does not have) a national language; (3) it was not the product of
142 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
a revolution; (4) it was, instead, the product of “diplomatic maneuvers and foreign
arms”; (5) it was the theater of too much antagonism; (6) it was the theater of too
many social conflicts; and (7) its political class was “the residue of servile times.”20
Beyond the polemical exaggeration, the description is correct, but, as with a bor-
rowing from Marxism, it stops at the surface. Rather than finding “the organic
process that necessarily determined these conditions,” Gobetti wrote, the national-
ists merely “came back to Gioberti’s poor dream of despair.”21
The nationalists celebrated the Libyan War as the beginning of Italian gran-
deur and the displays of patriotism that accompanied it as the beginning of
national consciousness. They had seen only the surface and the potential of eco-
nomic transformation in the just-ended decade and ignored its contradictions:
growth and power for them were merely a question of virtue and desire, and
only immorality and a failure of will could stop the triumphal march of the
bourgeoisie in Italy.
Over the course of the decade, industrial monopolies, created with the com-
plicity of protectionist policy and with the direct participation of the major banks,
had taken on greater and greater importance, to the point that even Luigi Einaudi,
a sworn enemy of any state intervention in economic affairs, had begun to worry.
Protected from foreign competition, the steel industry long continued to use
techniques that necessitated no great capital investments or particularly qualified
manual labor, but the steel thus produced cost twice as much as English steel. So
it was normal that with each economic slowdown, with each crisis putting Italian
production in even slightly greater contact with foreign production, the monopo-
lists felt lost and called on the state to help. In 1911 the Banca d’Italia responded
to such appeals by creating, along with the Banca Commerciale and the Credito
Italiano—the two largest banks in Italy at the time—a syndicate designed to pro-
vide ninety-six million lira to troubled enterprises.22 Also in 1911, Italy declared
war on Turkey and invaded Libya.
The foreign policy of transformism was the exact mirror of domestic policy:
Italy was allied with everyone at once and promised its support to all the parties in
the various conflicts. In June 1902, Foreign Minister Prinetti signed an accord with
France, which was in a state of open hostility with Germany, two days after having
signed the renewal of the Triple Alliance with Germany and Austria. In October
1909, Minister Tittoni signed an agreement with Russia against, among others, any
Austrian expansion in the Balkans, just four days after having ratified a pact with
Vienna providing for compensation for Italy in the event of Austrian expansion in
this same region, and committing the two countries to make no agreements with
third states on the subject of the Balkans.
The whole “organic process that necessarily determined” the gestures of Italian
imperialism was foreign to the nationalists, who made this simply a question of
“courage,” of “moral integrity,” of “national pride.”
When Italy launched its Libyan adventure, the patriotic effervescence and the
triumphalism of the nationalists joined to conceal international perplexity over the
gap between Italian ambitions and the reality of the country’s development.23 The
war itself necessitated sending a contingent three times larger than anticipated. It
lasted a year and ended in October 1912 with a unilateral retreat of Turkish army
THE QUEST FOR A CIVIL ITALIAN RELIGION 143
from Libya, under pressure from the birth of a hostile coalition in the Balkans.
During World War I, the Libyan Arab tribes succeeded in chasing out the Italians,
and the “pacification” of the region would be announced twenty-one years after
the start of operations there, in January 1932, by Governor Pietro Badoglio.24
In fact, despite the performance of the Giolittian decade, Italy’s lag behind other
great powers was remarkable and, owing to protectionism, had even grown wider.
Its share of total world manufacturing production declined from 2.5 percent in
1900 to 2.4 percent in 1913. This also explains the undulating character of foreign
policy, buffeted by the military difficulties, but also by the incapacity to find other
domestic political balance beyond the transformist approach.
In 1913 Italian industrial production was 2.5 times less than that of France, 3.6
times less than that of Russia, 6 times less than that of Germany or England, and
13.3 times less than that of the United States. Despite the steel-making monopo-
lies, its steel production was only one-third that of France, barely 5.3 percent that
of Germany, and a mere 3 percent that of the United States. Its energy consump-
tion, to conclude this brief comparative tableau, was 17.6 percent that of France,
5.8 percent that of Germany, and 2 percent that of the United States Nothing in
these data seems to justify the optimism of the editors of Regno regarding the
capacity of Italy’s “courageous industrialists” to fight for English markets or to
conquer “Asia Minor and South America.”
In 1913 Gaetano Salvemini wrote that the nationalists had a “megalomania-
cal vision of the capacities of Italy,” and added that he personally felt more like a
citizen of “the Italy of today, only beginning to rise up from the intellectual, moral
and economic misery of several centuries.”25 For Gobetti, the nationalists were
the “grand party of a dreary and infantile Italy.” For them, concluded this young
liberal—who would be killed by the Fascists in 1926, at age twenty-five—“colonial
expansion and militarism are not specific desires, but dogmatic vices.”26 It was
these dogmatic vices that would lead Italy to catastrophe during the two world
conflicts just ahead.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 17
A Petit-Bourgeois Fatherland
F ascism represented the most coherent attempt to create an Italian civil reli-
gion—a homogeneous body of values, feelings, and behaviors to be shared
among all the peoples of the peninsula.1 But everyone knows how catastrophically
this turned out: in 1945, after two years of civil war, with Italians on both sides
swapping accusations of betrayal, all mentions of the nation, the fatherland, or any
other symbol even remotely suggestive of the Fascist experience were abandoned.2
After the question of national identity resurfaced in Italy following the political
crisis of the 1990s, many people said that it was fascism and the war that had kept
it on a back burner for more than forty years. Fewer dared to link this “disqualifi-
cation” of a sense of identity to the successes achieved earlier by the Mussolinian
regime in attempting to forge such a sense: a social compromise with the petite
bourgeoisie founded on promises that could not be kept.
It may seem paradoxical that the petite bourgeoisie should have become so
politically important at the precise moment when it was starting on a downward
curve in economic and social affairs—that is, when large numbers of peasants
were abandoning the countryside to become hourly laborers, and when small-
scale production and distribution were hit by the first big processes of concen-
tration. Historically the petite bourgeoisie has been the first to benefit from the
gradual enlargement of political institutions in newly maturing capitalist societies,
making it a mass base for liberal democracy, and an unavoidably pivotal social
element. Its political importance has helped slow its downward curve, socially and
economically, as have legislative initiatives; this braking action has grown more
decisive as social and economic decline have become more pronounced.
In Italy, the growth of the political strength of the petite bourgeoisie largely
took place in just a few years, between the repression of the Milanese riots of 1898
and the entry into World War I in 1915. The group’s arrival on the political scene
was marked by a pronounced hostility toward the old ruling classes, which the
petit bourgeois wanted to replace, and by an equally sharp hostility toward the
proletariat, whose demands were seen as a direct threat to the economic well-
being and social prestige so recently acquired. Let us not forget that from 1901 to
1913, while average income increased by 17 percent, workers’ salaries rose by 26
146 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The European war immediately transmitted to Italy the effects of the stock market
collapse, the interruption of credit and foreign trade, and the consecutive failure
of banks and of enterprises, and it caused numerous emigrants to return home.7
In December 1914 the state created an entity—the Consorzio per le sovvenzioni
sui valori industriali—to inject capital into troubled banks and industries. The
A PETIT-BOURGEOIS FATHERLAND 147
money came from the Banca d’Italia, which, to fund this program, had to enlarge
the monetary mass in circulation. When the country entered the war, the new
Ministry for Arms and Munitions gave rise to another organization aimed at cen-
tralizing industrial production. The 1,976 enterprises connected to it benefited
from military orders, easy access to credit, energy, raw materials, transportation,
and exemptions from military service for some employees. This was a windfall for
many industries—even those that had been hostile to participation in the war—
and they absorbed a number of their competitors and saw their turnover, profits,
and activities soar. The manufacturing industry’s share in gross domestic product
(GDP) creation rose from 25 percent to 30 percent.8 Meantime, workers, though
they had been militarized during the war, saw their salaries rise afterward, and the
intense social struggles of the period—more than twenty-two thousand days lost
to strikes in 1919 and more than thirty thousand in 19209—reinforced this trend,
leading to passage of the forty-eight-hour maximum work week, social insurance,
and minimum wages.
This tableau would have been depressing enough for the petite bourgeoisie—
which had dreamed of resolving all society’s complexity in a single “national mid-
dle class”—if it had not been for the fact that, while the peasants paid the highest
tribute in blood during the war, it was the petit-bourgeois who paid the highest
economic cost. The state—to pay its suppliers, prop up the banks and enterprises
involved in the military effort, reimburse interest, at least, on the debts contracted
with the allies and through the purchase of public securities—resorted to taxes
(although they covered only 32 percent of the public deficit in 1918), issuing new
state securities, borrowing, and above all, to the printing of paper money. Thus,
in 1920, the volume of the monetary mass was six times what it had been in 1915.
The lira had depreciated in comparison to the dollar by a factor of five from 1914
to 1919, and the wholesale price index by a factor of 5.9 between 1913 and 1920.
Italian inflation, writes Michèle Merger, was the most pronounced in Europe, fol-
lowing that of Germany.10
After inflation, forever its most terrible nightmare, the petite bourgeoisie was
frightened by the successive waves of labor unrest in industry and agriculture,
more so than the haute bourgeoisie, which, for its part, had the economic and
organizational strength (the Confederation of Industry was officially founded in
April 1919) to resist the shock. Some major employers, bolstered by their substan-
tial war profits, even considered exploiting the trade union struggles of 1919 to
1920 to induce hourly workers and technicians to join a sort of reformist alliance
of the productive classes by way of salary and contract concessions.
The fear of expropriation, indeed, of revolution, played in favor of the grad-
ual abandonment of any reformist hypothesis, but the decisive factor, in the end,
was the global overproduction crisis of 1920, which culminated a year later in
Italy with the collapse of the reference bank of one of the most important Italian
industrial groups, Ansaldo. It was only then that the Fascist option began to make
headway among industrialists. But whether the preferred solution was reformist
or authoritarian, it was clear that Giolittian transformism, already in decline just
before the war, had breathed its last.
148 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Attitudes in the run-up to the war were decided outside the usual mediating
channels of Giolittism, which were the king’s palace, the corridors of the Foreign
Ministry, the embassies, the newspapers, and the universities. To the contrary,
from the summer of 1914, parliament was consulted only once, to approve a deci-
sion already taken, on May 20, 1915. According to Denis Mack Smith, in the first
year of the European war, the Corriere della Sera became a political institution
far more influential than the Chamber of Deputies.11 Historians of the right, the
left, and from abroad have spoken of a “coup d’état” against the monarchy and
the government, in favor of a few press organs of the boisterous interventionist
minorities that had invaded the streets.12 Whatever the case, the parliament barely
convened through the duration of the conflict, and legislative activity was handled
by government decree. The machine for mediation and transformist recomposi-
tion had broken down.
At the end of the war, the first elections, in 1919, were dominated by the Social-
ists and the Catholics, two parties that based their actions more on motivations
of a general order than in defense of small interest groups.13 At the same time, the
new electoral law—calling for proportionality, larger districts, and preference to
electoral lists and not to candidates—further loosened the bond between depu-
ties and their electors. But more than that, the coup de grâce to Giolittism came
from the fact that transformism does not work without constantly integrating new
interest groups as soon as they take on social importance. And at this point, the
new interests knocking on the door of the state were those of the peasant, worker,
and petit-bourgeois masses. In the face of the full social variety of mature capital-
ism, and shaken by war’s calamitous consequences, the political machine of liberal
Italy, born in 1861, came grinding to a halt.14
Apprenticeship in Consensus
Mussolini and his collaborators were the first representatives of the ruling Italian
class called to manage what would later be referred to as a “mass society.” As a
general rule, the management of a “mass society” requires the “learning of con-
sensus,” which is nothing more than what we might define as “the final stage of
transformism.” This pursuit of consensus can (and to a degree, must) become a
veritable creative forge of values; but consensus can never be founded exclusively
on a sharing of abstract values. According to Gian Enrico Rusconi, the virtues
of “citizenship”—namely, “loyalty” and “civic solidarity”—can be learned only in
a “concrete manner.” They become shared values only when “citizenship allows
access to specific assets,” whether these be “rights” or “benefits induced by social
policies.”15 By shining a direct light on the close linkage between “citizenship” and
“benefits,” Rusconi, and Cafagna with him,16 reveal for us some of the fundamen-
tal workings of the mechanism of consensus in developed capitalist societies. It
matters little if this is manifested in democratic forms or otherwise. What matters
is that the more “benefits” there are to distribute, the broader will be the consensus
and the more those enjoying them can aspire to create a collective mythology, a
framework of common belonging to the nation.
A PETIT-BOURGEOIS FATHERLAND 149
Mussolini and his regime believed it possible to found a collective Italian iden-
tity on the idea of Italy as a great power. But this idea, to enjoy any credibility at all,
had to be backed by a tangible demonstration that the well-being of Italy and the
well-being of the Italian people could, to some extent, coincide. Thus the second
half of the 1920s was characterized by the “battle for quota 90” (a rate of 90), a
brutally deflationist policy in defense of small savers that aimed to bring the Italian
currency back to an exchange rate of 90 lira per pound sterling, after it had sunk
to 148.87 in August 1926: and indeed, on April 25, 1927, the lira reached its high
point of 85.75 per pound.
Moreover, after having founded, in 1925, the Opera Nazionale Dopolavoro—
with the mission of organizing “after-work” leisure activities, vacation out-
ings (especially for workers’ children), trips, and cultural events—the regime in
1934 instituted the forty-hour work week. The welfare state was reorganized and
expanded, notably with the institution of family allowances, temporary layoffs,
and public health measures. During the 1930s, public spending steadily increased,
rising from 16.5 percent of GDP in 1926 to 33.4 percent in 1936.17 All of this was
built around a promise to end the humiliations suffered by the Italian people in
the past, especially those that had led to emigration.
On these bases, fascism attempted to create a national mythology—a “civil reli-
gion”—that would reinvigorate the Mazzinian plan for a “fusion of interests and
of individual and class rights in the melting pot of fatherland,” as Bollati summed
it up.18 Yet, the vicious circle in which Mussolini and his men found themselves was
typical of the contradiction that has long hampered the blooming of a national
Italian consciousness: to have any chance of creating a true civil religion, one needs
tools of social cohesion that go beyond the means the country has at its disposal.
The Mussolinian autarchy was not merely the Italian version of the widespread
protectionism of the 1930s, or an ideological backdrop to the lack of raw materi-
als, it was also a sort of sanitary cordon pulled tight around the petite bourgeoisie
so that it could contemplate its social betterment without being tempted to com-
pare it to the conditions of the “decadent demo-plutocracies.” In fact, based on
statistics on living conditions, Zamagni notes that there was not, during the Fascist
period, any real improvement of the living conditions of the “middle classes,” but
rather a “revenge” of the lower classes, a revenge that would reinstate the prewar
differences, both materially and in terms of social prestige.19
As heir to the profound social transformations of the first twenty years of the
century, fascism found itself confronted with the same corrosion of centuries-old
social relationships that the Church defines as “secularization.” But faced by these
processes, the attitudes of the Church and of fascism sometimes converged—as in
their common opposition to liberalism and socialism—while at times competing,
in a similar ambition to assume “the spiritual leadership” of the Italian masses. For
fascism, religion was nothing but an instrumentum regni, while for the Church,
the fascist regime could be an instrumentum religionis. The goal of both parties
was to master processes that by their very nature are ungovernable. The conflict
between traditional religion and “civil religion” contributed to disorienting Ital-
ians and feeding their “ethical and political weakness,” which would be, according
to De Felice, at the base of the defeatist sentiment during the war.20
150 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The fundamental error of fascism, on a political level, was to take seriously the idea
of totalitarianism and to truly believe in the “fusion of interests and of individual
and class rights in the melting pot of fatherland.” In fact, the party and the regime
were nothing but a confederation of “baronies and of big corporative autono-
mies”21—the different groups and factions of the bourgeoisie, the armed forces,
the court—that “il Duce” believed he had disciplined into a sort of national and
Fascist reductio ad unum.
Mussolini built his concept of “totalitarianism” around a confidence in the
“primacy of politics” that he had shared with many of his former Socialist friends.
He could not have been unaware that certain factions and counterfactions in soci-
ety are constantly erupting, nor that they express contradictory interests, but he
felt certain that politics—the control of the political levers of society—could keep
them in check.
The obstacles raised to emigration22 and the attempt to divert it toward the
“fourth shore” (Libya) are perhaps the most striking examples. Another case came
with the foolish ambition to lessen the influence of Church and family on young
people. Once again, not having resolved the root causes of Italian backwardness—
determinate of what would be called “amoral familyism”23—fascism attempted a
purely superficial operation aimed at “socializing” the family institution through a
sort of militarization of youth, even though the economic bases of nuclear family
life were still in place.24
The desire to “nationalize the masses” by acting such that each social group
“could find in the corporatist and totalitarian state a minimum of material and
moral advantages”25 required an ever more intense Italian participation in the
competition for a share of the world market, until the ultimate consequences
would result. On this subject, the most important historian of fascism, Renzo De
Felice, made a significant and inexplicably underestimated observation: one could
expect anything from Mussolini, he wrote, “except neutrality; at the extreme, an
intervention against Germany was more plausible than neutrality.”26 The entry
into World War II was the price the Italian bourgeoisie had to pay in exchange for
the generous state aid and social peace that had allowed its businesses to prosper
for twenty years.
Given the conditions facing Italy in 1940, as Paul Kennedy has written, only
“a miracle, or the Germans, could prevent a debacle of epic proportions.”27 The
situation in the year of the “stab in the back” was not so different from that preced-
ing Italy’s entry into World War I. The country’s industrial production had nearly
doubled from 1913 to 1938, but it represented only 2.9 percent of world produc-
tion, a smaller share than the 3.3 percent of 1929. On the eve of the conflict, its
industrial might amounted to barely more than half that of France, one-third that
of Great Britain, less than one fourth that of their German ally, one-sixth that of
the USSR, and one-tenth that of the United States.28 In terms of military potential,
the gaps were a bit smaller in comparison to France and the Soviet Union, some-
what larger compared to Germany and Great Britain, whereas a gulf separated the
A PETIT-BOURGEOIS FATHERLAND 151
military power of the United States—which was 16.7 times greater29—though that
did not stop Italy from declaring war against America in December 1941.
Certain contemporary observers and a number of historians today hold that
some Italians were motivated by a sort of cupio dissolvi, an essential defeatism,
from the very beginning of the conflict.30 To some, this pessimism had begun to
manifest itself even before Italy’s entry into the war. The bellicose enthusiasm that
had accompanied the “conquest” of Ethiopia had cooled significantly with the
realization that Italy would be facing armies hugely more powerful than that of the
Ethiopian Negus. Even Giuseppe Bottai, a Fascist deputy since 1921 and former
governor of Addis Ababa, who defined himself as an “insincere interventionist,”
noted in his journal the coolness with which the crowd assembled on the Piazza
Venezia on June 10, 1940, greeted the speech declaring war: “One perceives the
difficulty of the small groups of the faithful, full of goodwill to lead the cheers and
cries. There was the sensation of a sort of stunned discipline which the Party was
unable to brighten with its slogans.”31
During the first phase of Italian participation in the war, the Germans’ victories
were accompanied by feelings that oscillated between relief and enthusiasm. But
those victories did not entirely compensate for the alarm Italians felt in the face
of the Greek counteroffensive in the autumn of 1940, for the declaration of war
first against the Soviet Union and then against the United States, followed by the
loss of eastern Africa in 1941, well before the decisive defeats of El Alamein and
Stalingrad.
For Sergio Romano, a “mass transformism” occurs when most of the followers
and clients of a regime abandon it and take up hostile positions. But clients aban-
don their usual providers only when the latter no longer have much to offer and
the degree of loyalty is insufficiently strong to convince them to maintain their
confidence even in times of distress. The flame of popular support for fascism
had been fed by the myth of a “proletarian nation,” a myth based materially on
the promise—often implicit—of greater well-being for all. So, from the moment
when the regime proved that it was incapable of keeping this promise, the invest-
ment of confidence it had benefited from shifted inevitably toward those who
seemed better placed to fill this expectant void, thus the “massive phenomenon of
servility and transformism” that Galli della Loggia perceived in “the comportment
of many of the bourgeois and the petits-bourgeois.”32 Another chapter in Italian
transformism had come to a close.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 18
one of continuity. This can only be considered a paradox by those who genuinely
believed in the “anti-Fascist revolution,” or in those, like Benedetto Croce, who
believed that fascism was a kind of brief interlude, foreign to Italian history and tra-
dition. For others, who believed that there was never a real social or economic break
between the Fascist and post-Fascist periods, “state continuity” was never a surprise.
This gap between reality and the way it is represented made it harder to build
any sort of identity or idea of a nation, as Galli della Loggia emphasizes.5 But was
there ever really a desire for such an identity?
The ruling Italian class never saw a lack of concern toward the fatherland as
an entirely negative thing. Along with the “fiction” of a “Republic born from the
Resistance” and therefore victorious, the absence of a well-defined and declared
national interest made it possible to present Italy on the international scene as
open to all possibilities. As Sergio Romano writes, the war had cost Italy every-
thing, except its “geopolitical capital.”6 When De Gasperi insisted, on August 10,
1946, at the Paris Peace Conference, on the “meta-national” inspiration of the
new Italian leaders—“the humanitarian aspirations of Mazzini, the universal-
ist concepts of Christianity, and the internationalist hopes of the workers”7—he
was demonstrating this broad readiness to make the country’s geopolitical capital
available to the highest bidder.
The “clericalization” of Italian political life also pointed it toward “denational-
ization.” The Church and its theoreticians knew that Catholicism in Italy—unlike
in Poland or Ireland—had not been a force for national cohesion. The Poles and
the Irish, surrounded and oppressed by non-Catholic nations, had made religious
identity the distinctive sign of their very right to exist. Nothing comparable has
ever happened in Italy, all of whose neighbors are Catholic and which has never
been oppressed, in modern history, by any but Catholic powers. Thus, on the Ital-
ian side, the equation between Catholicism and Italianity suggested an availability
and an openness to universalism, to use the Catholic vocabulary, or to the pursuit
of new ties for the Italian national interest, to use the “realist” terminology.
With the end of the war, Europe became the other pole of availability. A Euro-
pean sensibility—which one can view as a desire to dilute Italy in a vast continen-
tal whole—was seen even in the late 1910s, when Fiat president Giovanni Agnelli
and the free-trader economist Attilio Cabiati drew up a plan for a federal Europe.8
But when it became clear that Italy needed Europe more than Europe needed Italy,
Prime Minister De Gasperi and Foreign Minister Carlo Sforza became the most
fervent advocates of continental unification. According to Sergio Romano, this
choice presented the dual advantage of salving national injuries by offering the
prospect of a larger European nation of which Italy would be the precursor, even
while putting all European countries on the same starting line, erasing the distinc-
tion between victors and vanquished.9
But while the vision of a united Europe was being raised, other identity stand-
ins were making an impression on Italians’ collective consciences. Above all was
that embodied by the American dream.
A COUNTRY OF LIMITED SOVEREIGNTY 155
about the fact that most of the young people who had embraced the armed anti-
Fascist struggle had been pushed to do so only when the battle front drew nearer,
and by the decree of the Fascist republic of the north condemning to death those
draft dodgers born in 1922 through 1925.
The country, divided in two, also gave rise to at least two opposed nationalisms,
each following the traditional reflex that there is no Italian nation without a for-
eign “godfather”: a “German” nationalism on the one side, and a “Russian” and an
“American” nationalisms on the other. Naturally the first condition for these three
nationalisms to exist was the rejection of any national legitimacy of the other,
even the accusation—well-founded in both cases—that the “enemy” was at the
service of one or several foreign powers. The abolition for decades of the phrase
“civil war” to describe the period from 1943 to 1945 stemmed from the necessity,
for the victors, to consider the vanquished (in this case, the Fascists) as foreigners
to the civil community in order to promote themselves to the rank of the one and
true Italian nation.
The staging of this “new” anti-Fascist Italy, which expected “a revision of the
diktat,” coincided with the drafting of the republican constitution. This document
thus reflected the major themes of the alliance among the “great popular forces.”
Once the peace treaty had been signed, and in the climate that developed after
1948, the tie was no longer antifascism, but anticommunism. While the Fascists
were largely set free, in the years after 1948 the Communist Party witnessed among
its numbers 48 deaths, 73,000 arrests, and 15,000 sentencings for a total of 7,598
years in prison, according to Walter Barberis.15 This new reality, added Galli della
Loggia, sparked a sort of constitutional short circuit for, while the constitution
derived its legitimacy from antifascism, the actual political system found its own
in anticommunism.16 This short circuit did not lead to political schizophrenia,
only because the norms provided for by the constitution were largely side-stepped;
nor did this lead to the sort of “constitutional patriotism”17 that Jürgen Habermas
describes, and even less to an American-style “constitutional faith.” Indeed, it was
precisely thanks to the absence of “patriotism” that Italy was able to regain, at
times surreptitiously, an important place among the “concert of nations.”
With fascism and the war in the past, Italy, in the striking phrase of Sergio Romano,
was “saved by its enemies,”18 first of all its international enemies. The treaty of 1947
was tough, it was said, but extraordinarily indulgent when compared to the fate
reserved for Germany and Japan. Then came its internal enemies. The Catholics,
the Socialists, and the Communists, foreigners all to Risorgimental tradition, were
better qualified to take on the management of Italy’s third incarnation because
they had played no major role in leading the first two, saving them any major
responsibility for both debacles.
The Catholics and Stalinists had been trained in the national spirit in foreign
schools, the former in the school of the Church’s universalism, and the latter in
that of Russian nationalism. It is not quite accurate, however, to describe the
A COUNTRY OF LIMITED SOVEREIGNTY 157
in 1935, where Togliatti was one of the protagonists. Until then, the national sec-
tions of Moscow Central served merely as annexes or substitutes for the Soviet
Embassy; politically, they were isolated in each country, just as the Soviet Union
was isolated internationally. The USSR’s orientation, as we know, changed 180
degrees after Hitler’s first foreign policy moves. Thus, in its introductory report
to the 1935 congress, the secretary of the Komintern Georgi Dimitrov extolled the
alliance between the working class “and the strata of the urban and rural petite
bourgeoisie,” the “respect for democratic conquests” and the “respect for national
sentiments.”26
Upon his return to Italy in 1944, Togliatti announced his intention to “take
up the flag of national interests that fascism has dragged through the mud and
betrayed.”27 Thus the policy of “national unity” was, from the Italian Communist
Party’s viewpoint, the synthesis by which Togliatti attempted to combine Soviet
interests with those of the ruling Italian class, which faced the need to reestablish
credibility after the country’s downfall under fascism. The PCI became “national”
because the interests of the USSR demanded it. It should come as no surprise that,
each time Italian national interests came into conflict with the national interests of
Russia, the party chose Moscow without hesitation. But nor should it be surprising
if, once it had become the permanent representative of certain national interests, it
dared, with time, to take a certain distance, mainly verbally, from Moscow.
The party of Togliatti lost any hope of representing the “general interests of the
country” when it conformed to the Kremlin’s directives against accepting Marshall
Plan assistance, confirming yet again that the real difficulty in Italy was not that of
being a servant to two masters, but rather of being a servant to the right masters.
On September 16, 1929, barely eight months after the signing of the Concordat,
Pius XI declared to ecclesiastical members of Catholic Action: “The day will come
when we will have need of reliable men, unquestionably honest, and we will think
of you again.”28 Despite the ecclesiastical hierarchy’s “cordial relations, infused by a
spirit of collaboration”29 with the Fascist regime—as the Catholic historian Arturo
Carlo Jemolo describes it—the hierarchy was already thinking and operating with
an eye to the future.
Under fascism, the Church always fiercely defended the prerogatives of Catho-
lic Action and other movements linked to it. Its imperative was to preserve the
relative autonomy of structures that would allow it to form an independent ruling
class, capable, if need be, of replacing the ruling class of the regime. Yet its capac-
ity to remain independent and meticulously prepare the political personnel for
a postfascism era, while a necessary condition, was not sufficient to make it the
dominant force after the war, let alone to give Italy what Jemolo calls “the cachet
of a clerical state.”30
The Christian Democrats, whose first cadres were largely men who had started
out with Catholic Action,31 were not the only “mass party” of the time. This element
A COUNTRY OF LIMITED SOVEREIGNTY 159
alone does not explain why it was the Church that left such a mark on the state.
Other factors played a role, above all the popularity of the Church itself.
The point of departure has to be the vast process of societal dislocation brought
by war and then defeat. No possibility of a radical social transformation was there
to offer the Italians hope, as had been the case during the Great War. This time,
too, the Italians were deprived of any “institutional” prospects—of being able, at
least potentially, to resort to some trustworthy authority. The state having dis-
solved itself at the moment of capitulation, on September 8, 1943, ordinary people
had to attend to the most urgent matters first, to rebuild connections by turning
first to what was nearest at hand for immediate support. The collective tragedy
had laid bare a survival instinct that, in normal conditions, is the most private of
matters. Other than the few tens of thousands of people taking orders from one of
the five authorities disputing control of the peninsula,32 the great mass of Italians
lived a sad and isolated reality of “every man for himself.” In this shipwreck, the
Catholic Church, the only surviving institution, found itself playing the role of
“defensor civitatis,” rather like during the time of the fall of the Roman Empire, as
the secular historian Federico Chabod puts it.33
The Church’s capacity to exert both civil and institutional authority reinforced
its moral authority. But while that alone might have explained its enormous influ-
ence, other factors were at play. For example, the identification of ordinary people
with the Church could only be strengthened by the common desire to forget the
many compromises, large and small, that had been made with the fallen regime;
the ordinary people could measure their chances to do so with the successes of the
Church. Its close relationship with the peasant world was another major factor,
especially in a country where the population was still largely rural. Then, too, a
part of the dominant class that was preparing, by force or persuasion, for a regime
change wanted to avoid having the new power be dominated by “revolutionary”
forces; the Church wanted the same. Finally, the Allies—the true masters of the
situation in Italy—were searching for an anti-Fascist power that met these very
same criteria.
Starting in the second half of the 1940s, the Church permeated Italian soci-
ety, influencing the lives of the entire population, independently of individuals’
religious or political convictions. Religious authorities intervened directly in
numerous decisions affecting public life. They were invited to every ceremony—
from the annual report of the Banca d’Italia to the distribution of vaccines in
the schools—and, in exchange, organized virtually obligatory religious services
in the ministries and in every public establishment. They often had the last word
on appointments to public office, and nearly always on any new law or proposal.
They controlled school texts, censorship of movies, theater, radio, and later televi-
sion, with the repressive organs of the state such as the police, the carabinieri, and
magistrates keeping close watch to ensure respect for morals and the “common
sense of modesty.”34
Although it was largely the effect of a well-prepared reconquista strategy, this
strength of the Church also reflected the weakness of the ruling Italian class and
its traditional inability to define the contours of the “national interest,” an inabil-
ity aggravated in the early postwar years by the severe constraints of an utterly
160 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
I n the late 1920s, Italian intellectuals found themselves caught up in a debate that
seemed to mirror Italian backwardness. On one side was the Strapaese faction,
representing a supposed “plebeian tradition” of Italian culture rooted in the values
of small towns and the countryside; on the other side was the Stracittà faction,
which published the French-language journal 900 and urged receptivity to recent
international cultural productions.
Stracittà—which embodied the transition between the declining influence
of French culture and the rise of American cultural influence—reflected a cos-
mopolitan aspiration to maintain contact with modernity’s leading edge, if
only in the artistic domain. Strapaese was suspicious of progress, industry, and
urban life in general, indeed of all that sociologists mean by “modernity.” Curzio
Malaparte—one of the group’s most eminent members, along with Leo Longa-
nesi and Mino Maccari—summed up its message this way: “Italians are unfit to
become modern.”1
Strapaese might be the most explicit example of what Bollati calls the “Italian
Sturm und Drang against modern civilization,”2 of the opposition mounted since
unification by intellectuals, the Church, the political class, and, sometimes, indus-
trialists themselves. Some observers attribute the “molecularity of the collective
behavior” of Italians precisely to this will to oppose the national conscience and
“modernization.”3
Fascism’s intrinsic limit had been that it represented an overly bottom-
heavy synthesis of the Italian bourgeoisie’s interests. In seeking to make Italy a
great power even while “ruralizing” it, Mussolini’s regime was plunging unstop-
pably toward catastrophe. This “bottom-heavy imbalance” was ideological as
well: Strapaese was a sort of cultural guarantee of the regime’s “Catonist” ideology
(which saw the peasant as a savior of the nation), a mythical transfiguration of
Italian backwardness, brandishing it as a sign of rigor and virtuous frugality, and
aiming to give value to the very modest social ascension of the petite bourgeoisie.
To tame its mass base, fascism had to improve the people’s material well-being,
but the country’s real conditions being what they were, frugality had to be made a
162 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
virtue. Thus the slogans warning against the “comfortable life” coincided with the
sugary mirages of the Telefoni bianchi and the Mille lire al mese.4
The dominant political cultures of the postwar period, the Catholic and the
Stalinist, were more coherent. Any trend toward consumerism was liable to eat
into their power bases. The Church saw the attack as direct, for development and
affluence tend to undermine two pillars of its influence: rural life and the fam-
ily. For the Italian Communist Party (PCI), rooted in a zone where social migra-
tion occurred mainly within the petite bourgeoisie (between country dwellers,
cooperatives, craftsmen, and small businesses), the direct effects were probably
less immediate, but noticeable nonetheless in a growing disaffection for militant
political life. So both sides based their prescriptions on the precepts of temper-
ance and abstinence, tinted with a hatred of change built around the presumed
“authenticity” of Italian life and tastes.
In a 1946 speech, Pius XII underlined the link between the defense of “authen-
tic rural civilization” and the possibility of perpetuating values like “work, sim-
plicity, purity of life, and respect for authority,” without which life would lose its
meaning and be transformed into an “unbridled pursuit of personal gain.”5 That
same year, the Christian Democrats’ secretary (and minister of education), Guido
Gonella, depicted modern civilization, and radio in particular, as “an invisible
and silent atomic bomb that has torn the family apart.”6 The PCI, not wanting to
be left behind, contrasted the hypocrisy of the “bourgeois family” to the “greater
modesty and simplicity” of the Soviet-style “Socialist family,”7 and the Union of
Italian Women (UDI), one of the party’s “mass” organizations, made the “happy
family” the theme of its national congress in 1947.8 In December 1950, an arti-
cle in the PCI’s youth monthly vehemently condemned the publication in Italy
of a review titled “Sexual Digest,” with its “disgusting” and “obscene” articles of
“evident American origin” and full of “psychoanalytical vocabulary.”9 The Cath-
olics, for their part, did not limit themselves to verbal condemnation: the Cen-
tral Bureau for Cinematography, headed by Giulio Andreotti and then by Oscar
Luigi Scalfaro, provided detailed judgments on what was licit and what was illicit,
“advising against,” for example, the projection of “scenes likely to excite the senses,
such as of kisses or of prolonged and sensual embraces.”10
These attitudes were the ideological and political mirror of the concerns felt by
social classes that had just learned from the Fascist regime that when one toys with
the existing equilibrium, immense catastrophes can result.
Republican Transformism
Costa, the head of the Italian industrialists’ union, asserted that big industry in
Italy was “against nature.” And Gaetano Marzotto, who led the largest garment-
making group, even declared that it was necessary to “take a step backwards,”
because big industry undermined the true character of Italian production, which
could never really go beyond the stage of “grand craftmanship.”13
It is difficult to know whether the major postwar parties represented the inter-
ests of small producers and small distributors because of their “antimodern”
sensibility or whether, to the contrary, they ended up embracing the Strapaesane
reservations because of the ideological influence of their social reference classes.
Regardless, even while promoting the trend toward a vast economic state network,
these parties worked first of all to defend the petit-bourgeois interests they had
protected since their birth.
The ideological and political inertia of the PCI and the Christian Democrats
were doubtless provoked as well by the international division of labor as well as
by their dependence on, respectively, the Soviet Union and the Catholic Church.
Moreover, the PCI, by its defense of rural- and village-based national traditions
that it said were threatened by “monopolies,” the “market,” and “America,” cut
itself off culturally from any chance of becoming the sort of social-democratic
labor party that could usefully have contributed, as Gianni Agnelli put it, to a
“clarification of Italian political life.”14 The Christian Democrats, for their part,
drew on governmental connections to do everything possible to deter the increas-
ing concentration of production and distribution and to open the public admin-
istration’s doors to some victims of these processes.
To slow a massive rural exodus,15 a series of laws and decrees were approved
beginning in 1948 to facilitate land purchases, so much so that by 1956, some 1.4
million hectares had passed into the hands of small farmers. The number of crafts-
men remained stable from 1951 to 1971 and, because of the legislative obstacles to
opening supermarkets16—the first of them arrived in Milan in 1957—the number
of small businessmen actually rose, from 1.35 million to 1.7 million. In 1971, 8.7
percent of the working Italian population consisted of shop owners, compared to
6.6 percent in France (in 1968) and 2.2 percent in Great Britain (in 1966).
The presence of civil servants in the overall workforce grew in direct propor-
tion to the rural exodus, rising in the 1951 to 1971 period from 4.6 percent to 8.1
percent.17 And then there were the enti pubblici—bodies attached to the executive
and created to fulfill temporary missions, but often serving to do little more than
distribute revenues. They numbered 44,500 in the 1960s, and 70 percent of the
public funds allocated to them ended up paying salaries.18
The production of such “artificial middle classes,” as Lanaro called them,19 is
one form that transformism assumed in its republican version. The PCI, while
in the opposition, not only did not seek to block legislation in this direction, but
often contributed to it, and decisively so. Most of the laws, and particularly those
concerning the sorts of interests we have just discussed, were approved in parlia-
mentary commissions sitting during legislative sessions where each group’s vote
is distinguishable only over the long term. Thus, according to Musella’s review of
all votes, the PCI took positions against the majority one time in three in the first
164 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
legislature, one time in seven in the second, one time in sixteen in the third, and
one time in six in the fourth and the fifth.20
The constitutional expert Giuseppe Maranini, in 1967, described the republi-
can parliament as “a sort of echo chamber of contracts that had been ratified else-
where,” contracts “between small and mediocre feudal systems, and sometimes
between minuscule groups, even individuals; minor contracts which, through
the quasi-secret legislative actions of the commissions led to disorder, immoral-
ity and incoherence.”21 The description might rather easily have applied to the
epochs of Depretis, Crispi, and Giolitti, and it anticipated by exactly twenty-
five years the chorus of indignation that arose upon the “discovery,” early in the
1990s, of the existence of these mechanisms upon which Italian transformism
has resided since the beginning.
but now they were “offering” help with reconstruction. Needless to say, in the peo-
ple’s eyes the responsibility for the damage and destruction lay entirely with the
Fascists and the Germans. Much of the population also appreciated the Americans
as the major reason the country had not fallen into Communist hands.
Thanks to the example from the other side of the ocean, Italians began to believe
that frugality was not, after all, their unavoidable destiny. People even began to see a
connection between the “five meals a day” that the Fascists had asserted that the Brit-
ish indulged in25—and that the Fascists ritually denounced—and the hegemony that
first Great Britain and later the United States had managed to impose on the world.
But for the Church and for the PCI, the “American dream” presented a threat.
For Togliatti’s party, hostility toward consumerism was reinforced by the political
and cultural anti-Americanism flowing from Moscow’s new line in the autumn
of 1947. Thus, for ten years, through obeisance to the mother party, the PCI mar-
ginalized itself. Even while it accentuated its patriotic rhetoric, it fiercely opposed
the Marshall Plan and the Atlantic Pact—the two initiatives that gave Italy both
the oxygen for reconstruction and the international political context in which to
resume business dealings interrupted by war.
This “anti-imperialist” orientation, with its nationalist, populist character, was
not unknown in Catholic circles either, particularly by those most attuned to Vati-
can sensibilities. Those who had done ideological battle with fascism could not
stand idly by while what they considered the Trojan horse of secularization and
the “unbridled pursuit of profit” penetrated the fortress of Catholicism. But the
Christian Democrats, by fair means or foul, had to consider international politi-
cal imperatives, and De Gasperi, more by fair means than foul, tried to preserve
for Italy its room for negotiation and autonomous initiatives. This would play an
important role in the years to come.
Despite the massive influence of the Church and the PCI, however, public opin-
ion felt the persistent lure of the American way of life until the new European
myth finally began to take hold in the last decade of the twentieth century. That
does not mean that other traditional benchmarks had been abandoned: one could
devote oneself to the magic rituals of fecundity26 even while coveting the real or
imagined affluence seen in American films. It was a case of “the slum dwellers who
had managed to buy a television,” as Pasolini complained in 1963. Long after the
era of “modernization” opened, it cohabited with lifestyles and ideologies rooted
in a long-ago past.
In these “slums,” it was the native Italian elements—the hyperlocal nature of
the “thousand bell towers”—that divided the inhabitants of the peninsula, while
what united them in common hope for a better life were the elements imported
from abroad. While the absence of a “center” fed into all the particularities of the
outlying areas, popular acculturation was based on models borrowed from the
United States.27
Later, when the “modernity” that some had tried to neutralize took its revenge,
assuming “the resounding form of an immoderate and unstoppable bulimia,”28
what seemed to be the realization of the American dream emerged as a new model
of social integration—the social integration that the national ruling classes had
never managed to achieve.
Chapter 20
W hen mass consumption shifted for the Italians from aspiration to satiation,
they gradually began to shrug off the pedagogical grip of the two dominant
cultures that found cause for present temperance in the promise of future ethereal
happiness. This involved not a peaceful, linear transition, but rather a series of
profound upheavals provoked by what we commonly call the “economic miracle.”
This phase of intense Italian economic development—generally said to have
lasted from 1953 to 1973, or some say from 1958 to 1963, when average annual
growth reached 6.3 percent—brought a typical succession of events. The accel-
eration of the rural exodus sparked by the development of industry (particularly
mechanical and chemical) lured millions of people into industrial cities, where
their production contributed further to the conditions that had provoked them to
abandon the countryside in the first place. In the 1961 census, industrial workers
(38 percent) and those in tertiary sectors (32 percent) surpassed farm laborers
(30 percent) for the first time. Internal migration in 1955 through 1971 involved
nearly one-third of the population, with 9,140,000 people leaving their regions of
origin for good. Between 1951 and 1967 the population of Rome rose from 1.65
million to 2.6 million, that of Milan from 1.27 million to 1.68 million; and that
of Turin from 719,000 to 1.12 million. Coinciding with these internal movements
were the migrations out of Italy of 956,458 people from 1959 to 1968. For the first
time, Italy found itself confronting a series of problems linked to immigration and
urbanization.
One characteristic of the unequal development that occurs amid accelerating
growth was the coexistence of profound social difficulties—many people experi-
enced a clear degradation in their quality of life—with increasing consumption.
Thus in the same years when immigrant families were piling four or five to a room
in subdivided apartments in central Turin’s basements or attics; when infant mor-
tality began rising again and public schools had to operate two or three shifts a
day; when manifestations of racism became more frequent and apartments were
often not rented to southerners,1 in these same years per-capita income rose in
168 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
Italy more rapidly than in any other European country but Germany: 3.7 times
more than in France and 4.2 times more than in Great Britain.
The first “revolution” in Italians’ lives was the daily presence of meat on their
tables. Once this stage had been reached, everything became simpler and priori-
ties started to change. The physical benefits of durable consumption constituted
a new divinity to be worshiped. In the years from 1958 to 1967, the number of
families owning a television rose from 12 percent to 49 percent of the population,
and of those possessing a refrigerator rose from 13 percent to 55 percent. Between
1950 and 1964, the number of private automobiles increased more than 13.5 times
(from 342,000 to 4.67 million), and the number of motorcycles more than 6 times
(from 700,000 to 4.30 million).
These new manifestations of wealth represented not only a material conquest
but also the fulfillment of a long psychological journey. It had begun with the
Mussolinian dream of Italian greatness that ultimately produced the “mass trans-
formism” that led first to the fall of fascism and later, in the 1950s, to an impatient
wait for better days. When this aspiration first evolved into a sense of concrete pos-
sibility, it was difficult to express openly, often accompanied by a sort of implied
guilt, as if those who dared nourish such hopes were foreigners to a national tra-
dition of frugality and sacrifice. Lanaro asserted that material enrichment, and
the sharing of new means of expression and communication, meant an “impov-
erishment of the collective symbolic universe.” The move to modernization and
its social transformations, the “nationalization of words and of signs” of a people
brought together by migration, speaking for the first time one language—that of
television—all this came about without any attempt to provide any underlying
meaning or value.2
As the country continued to develop, the ruling class and certain intellectuals
retained a sense of nervous distrust regarding “modernity.” The search for col-
lective myths to make sense of material well-being gradually shifted elsewhere,
beyond the political and institutional representations Italians had known. The
gap between economic development, the functioning of the state apparatus, and
the “collective symbolic universe” became brutally clear in the late 1960s. Lan-
aro speaks of 1968 as a metaphor for “the aspiration to a ‘civil life’ in keeping
with the outsized potential of the ‘economic life.’”3 The student movements repre-
sented the demand for social mobility of the recently acculturated middle classes.
This demand pointed to the material bases of a new step for transformism: a step
that, having not been fulfilled with the co-optation of the ruling Socialists, would
impose itself in the form of crisis thirty years later, involving the emergence of
original phenomena and political personages.
reduces costs and unit prices, making possible the creation of less-expensive prod-
ucts, as well as the payment of higher wages, which in turn stimulates the market.
And yet, weak productivity and low salaries did not prevent Italy—before
World War I—from joining the fight for economic market share. But the portion
of social capital destined for foreign investment was only a small part of a well of
overall capital that was also small.4 Italian imperialism drew great profits from its
zones of influence when the relationship was purely economic. Afterward, at the
moment of military conquest, the costs of maintaining them always surpassed the
benefits and, at times, the political chaos that ensued ultimately depressed eco-
nomic activity. If the Libyan War cost 1.30 billion lira, emptied the state’s treasury
and arsenals, and provoked the crisis of the Banco di Roma, for the Mussolinian
“empire” it was worse. In Ethiopia, the destruction and the massacres of people
and livestock by poison gas provoked a crisis of production and exportation, to the
point that the minister of colonies, Alessandro Lessona, was forced to admit that
“external trade flourished more during the time of the Negus.”5
Fascism was certainly voluntarist, and even succeeded in putting into place the
beginnings of a welfare state. But as for guaranteeing higher working-class wages,
it went in the direction opposite to what Corradini described. The priority was to
“nationalize” the petite bourgeoisie, with the costs paid by other sectors of society.
Part of this fell on certain groups of the upper bourgeoisie, as in the case of the
“battle for quota 90,” but the largest part was paid by the working class. Accord-
ing to Sylos Labini, the policy of systematic wage reductions was a distinctive trait
of fascism at that time. Up to 1940, he notes, real salaries had fallen in Italy by
about 20 percent, much more than the 5 percent in Great Britain or France.6 This
reduction allowed the regime to gain the sympathy of sectors of the bourgeoisie
unhappy with the “bottom-leaning synthesis,” and because industrial profits were
thus increased, to enlarge the shares for pensions, commerce, and taxes.
In the nascent phase of imperialism, Italy had become a favored destination for
foreign investors, drawn by its generally low costs and its labor force. It drew the
same sort of attention now reserved for certain former Soviet-bloc countries or
Southeast Asian nations: foreign entrepreneurs established businesses or subsid-
iaries there or made investments there.7 The ample availability of unskilled labor,
following the massive rural exodus, helped keep wages low. The policy of salary
restrictions boosted competition and helped offset other deficiencies (lack of raw
materials, inadequate infrastructure, weak financial system, modest level of tech-
nological training, near-total absence of research), but it discouraged fixed invest-
ments, postponing indefinitely the solution to the structural problems linked to
low productivity.
There was nothing uniquely Italian about this. The specificity lies in fascism’s
choice to “steer” wage policy as it had “steered” monetary policy. Thus an objective
blot on development was transformed into a (subjective) virtuous choice, part of
the consoling myth of the “proletarian nation.”
The costs of reconstruction after World War II were also essentially paid by
wage earners, who were hit by inflation (salaries fell by half in real terms during
the war), the role played by trade unions in boosting the “national reconstruction,”
and by massive layoffs.8 The path to liberal reconstruction taken by the parties of
170 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
national unity, including the PCI,9 resulted from the confluence of three factors:
(1) international constraints, which left no alternative; (2) the traditional deficien-
cies of the productive system, aggravated by the war, which could be only partially
offset through wage compression; and (3) the interclass character of the mass par-
ties, which forced them to take measures that did not harm the petite bourgeoisie.
In any case, reconstruction and, later, the “economic miracle” owed much of
their success to wage reductions, although such reductions were relative. Amid
growth, from 1951 to 1958, of national revenue by 43.93 percent, of imports by
90.18 percent, of exports by 138.93 percent, of net investments by 118.61 percent,
and in the face of an 89 percent increase in industrial production from 1953 to
1960 and of productivity by 62 percent, real salaries declined over the same period
by 0.6 percent.10 The situation changed little in the years immediately afterward:
Between 1964 and 1968 the annual rate of increase of compensation per worker in
industry, including employer-paid national insurance contributions, was the low-
est of any country in the European Community, except for Luxembourg. In 1968
the average annual salary of Italian industrial workers was $2,000, just two-thirds
of that paid to their German colleagues, a bit more than half that of the French,
and less than one-quarter the average salary of American workers.11
Even if the largest part of new production was destined for international mar-
kets, Italy experienced a strangling effect typical of development. Growth required
an enlargement of the domestic market, which necessarily required wage increases,
which cut into or even canceled the competitive advantage of Italian industry.
Some major entrepreneurs began to think that, in order to consolidate growth,
there was an urgent need to break out of the cycle of low salaries and help new
social groups enter a sphere of more mature consumption. But, as noted earlier,
this option implied the need to drastically boost industrial productivity in par-
ticular, and the productivity of the system in general, by overcoming its structural
deficiencies.
The transformist political operation that should have made it possible to “shake
up” the Italian productive system and enlarge the social bases of democracy was
the center-left. But the processes that this operation attempted to launch ended
up, yet again, in failure.
In 1957 Amintore Fanfani, the Christian Democrats’ secretary, declared that the
goal of the rapprochement between his party and the Socialist Party was to “recover
vast popular social strata, evidently not the conservative ones, for the democratic
base of the state.”12 In these words from an architect of the “opening to the left”
of the early 1960s, one sees the explicit basis for a new season of transformism.
However, to fully understand this political operation—and its failure—one must
look beyond a strictly Italian framework and consider the reformist dynamic of
the center-left in the context of the international dynamic of the time.
From a macroeconomic viewpoint, the Italian “miracle” meant an increasing
presence of “made in Italy” sales, from 2.2 percent of the world market in 1951 to
THE FAILURE OF “DEMOCRATIC NATIONALIZATION” 171
3.4 percent in 1960 and 4.6 percent in 1970. Its relative weight more than doubled
in less than twenty years, causing a proportional increase in influence globally,
and particularly in Europe. Italian success would not have been possible without
the boost provided by the development period 1945 to 1975 (the so-called Trente
Glorieuses, the glorious thirty) and without integration into the European market.
Against a broader framework of increasing trade worldwide, the volume of mer-
chandise destined for the five European Economic Community (EEC) partners
rose twice as fast as the overall increase of exports: between 1953 and 1964, Italian
production destined for Germany, France, and the Benelux countries rose from 23
percent to 40.2 percent.13 Yet constraints increased along with benefits: Italy found
itself ever more exposed to the imperatives of the market—from the prices of
imported raw materials to those of exported industrial products—while its capac-
ity to influence the latter remained limited. Thus the problems relative to levels
of productivity and concentration, always the principal cause of Italy’s backward-
ness, now presented themselves with such urgency that they could no longer be
ignored without risk to the gains so recently achieved.
Because of their greater public visibility, the major groups often seem to be the
only economic actors in a country, which is never the case. In the Italy of the 1960s,
95 percent of the members of the Confindustria employers association were small
or very small entrepreneurs. It was from this group that the greatest resistance
emerged. Since the electric monopolies took up the fight against any nationaliza-
tion of the sector, a “natural” alliance formed between the employers group and
the petite bourgeoisie, which had achieved its own miracle thanks to low wages
and the absence of trade unions.
Late in the decade, faced with the delaying tactics and timidity of the center-
left governments, some large private groups like Fiat, Pirelli, Olivetti, and a major
public monopoly like ENI attempted to break this “conservative” alliance in the
name of efficiency, which they now proposed as the standard of industrial manage-
ment, rather than the simple pursuit of profit. These groups represented the most
dynamic contingent of the Italian economy. They had had to adapt to a far greater
level of competition than they had been used to and thus needed what Lucio Car-
acciolo referred to, in his mentioned 1994 editorial, as a “country-system” capable
of supporting their penetration into external markets. Their proposals, backed by
certain press organs and some important research centers, were presented in the
form of a vast reformist project, both more organic and ambitious that what big
capital had attempted in the aftermath of World War I. Collaboration with the
trade unions was foreseen, even a convergence with them on some fundamental
objectives that reached far beyond simple industrial relations: the reform of the
legal code, public administration, taxation, and education systems; unification of
the sanitary system; new housing legislation; and above all, a policy of investment
in the Mezzogiorno.14
All these reformist recipes—particularly when combined with a policy of col-
laboration between the big industrial groups and the trade unions, which made
wage concessions possible—provoked the inevitable hostility of the small pro-
duction and small commerce sectors, which, in the short term, could only be
172 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
According to Lanaro, the real failure of the 1964 to 1970 period lay less in the inca-
pacity of the ruling class to reform society than in the lost opportunity to achieve
a “democratic nationalization,” that is, a sharing of common values, “starting with
the predominance of general interests over individual demands.”19
The center-left not only was born of a loose assembly of differing desires and
designs but also had encountered some tenaciously opposed interests, firmly
bound to their prerogatives. In fact, what ensured the convergence of such dispa-
rate interests was, again, the low-wage policy. So long as wages remained moderate,
the “programmation”—this magic word of the center-left—could be seen as an
attempt to channel, to tone down, or to dilute the disturbing effects of accelerat-
ing global development on Italian society. Urbanization and full employment had
sparked a rise in consumption that, though moderate, had enlarged demand in
the marketplace. Because the generally low productivity of the Italian system—in
particular in agriculture and commerce—were unable to fulfill the new demands,
the only way to satisfy consumers was to increase imports. When, as early as 1953,
the governor of the Bank of Italy Donato Menichella used his annual report to
denounce the new imbalances in Italian society, he was thinking above all about
the commercial imbalance. His recipe for reducing imports focused on a “dam-
ming up” or “regulation” of consumption.
In 1962, for the first time since the 1940s, the country faced inflationist pres-
sures. Some historians attribute this to a tendency of wages to exceed the ceilings
set by national contracts.20 The relationship between wage growth and inflation is
the same as that between the number of ill people and hospitals; and yet no one
would suggest that it is hospitals that generate sick people. In the Italy of the “eco-
nomic miracle,” consumption was merely the last act of a process during which the
product had to pass through the long gauntlet of a nit-picking bureaucracy full of
redundancy and overwhelmed by new tasks, then be transported over a seriously
174 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
inadequate road network, and, last but not least, face an extremely fragmented
distribution system. All of this could only add to the final sales price.
In the immediate postwar period, Italian workers paid a high price in the strug-
gle, first, against inflation provoked by the war, and then by the peculiar monetary
policy of the occupation authorities. They paid again in the 1960s to guarantee to
the parties their electoral petit-bourgeois clienteles, the true cause of the currency
devaluation. As Menichella had done in 1953, Ugo La Malfa devoted part of his
efforts in 1962 to establishing a policy of “wage moderation” through an explicit
offer of collaboration with the trade-union world, and its insertion into a reform-
ist circuit in which the PCI could not tread directly, owing to international con-
straints. A few years later it was the Socialist Party that claimed credit for helping
to overcome “the most dramatic moment of the economic crisis by imposing two
years of austerity on the working masses.”21
But the events of 1962—the year of the rioting at the Piazza Statuto in Turin
against an agreement reached between Fiat and the social-democratic trade union
UIL—had taught two important lessons: first, that any serious notion of reform
could not avoid the question of increasing productivity and, therefore, wages; and
second, that once one meddled with productivity and wages, the result was cer-
tain panic among the petite bourgeoisie. The struggles late in the decade for the
renewal of collective labor contracts—the celebrated “autunno caldo” of 1969—
led to a wage increase equal for all, a workweek of forty hours, the extension of
union rights for apprentices, the national unification of wage scales that had var-
ied by region, the right to organize paid assemblies during working hours, and so
on. The Corriere della Sera summed this up by writing that the country had found
itself “at the edge of a precipice.”22
Despite their efforts at self-preservation, the parties saw their role as collec-
tors of clienteles undercut as their former clients attempted to confront their vital
problems on their own, or collectively. The traditional political system no longer
seemed to respond to the varied expectations of the diverse interests it represented.
The Christian Democrats were weakened by a rural exodus that drained its tradi-
tional reservoirs of support, and even by the open contestation of a significant part
of the Catholic world, including institutions like Catholic Action (AC), Catholic
Association of Italian Workers (ACLI), and the Catholic labor union (CISL). The
Socialist Party meanwhile suffered a new schism in July 1969, just five years after
the first split, in January 1964, with the departure of adversaries of the center-left.
As for the PCI, its membership fell from 2.11 million in 1950 to 1.50 million in
1970, with an even more marked loss of influence among the working class. The
number of PCI groups in companies dropped from 11,272 in 1950 to 2,977 in
1971. Forced for the first time after the war to confront a movement born outside
of, and in opposition to, its directives, the PCI suffered a rupture of its own in
1969, with the exclusion of the group united around the journal Il Manifesto.23
The traditional “absence of a center” compounded by the “nongovernment”
led to a multiplication of independent power centers, which Lanaro defined as an
attempt at “unbridled self-government by all the corporations, old and new,” the
“shadow states.”24 The failure of “democratic nationalization” resulted in a con-
trary phenomenon. All those wielding even a fragment of power—legal, semilegal,
THE FAILURE OF “DEMOCRATIC NATIONALIZATION” 175
Italian Metamorphoses
Involuntary Unification
As for “fiscal reform,” wage withholding was confirmed, yet measures to control
independent workers remained problematic. In 1977, when the PCI was part of
the governing majority, Mario Salvatorelli wrote in La Stampa that wage earn-
ers deserved “the Oscar for best tax-payer,” because they provided 80 percent of
declared revenues, even as tax evasion remained massive.3 At the beginning of the
following decade, the first Craxi government risked provoking a crisis when its
finance minister, Bruno Visentini, proposed stricter controls on tradesmen, who,
on average, declared receipts that were actually less than the wages they paid their
employees. When, in 1989, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) reported that
housing taxes in Italy produced fiscal receipts that were just half those of similar
countries, the president of the Confedilizia (the Association of Building Own-
ers), Attilio Viziano, explained that in fact 50 percent of buildings were simply
“unknown to the tax authorities” because the housing law of 1978 imposed a sort
of “political rent” that led their owners to expect to be paid the market price, but
under the table.4 By 2005, declarations to the tax administration showed that the
situation had not changed; car dealers, for example, claimed revenues less than
those of automobile metalworkers. Still in October 2006, Finance Under-Secretary
Vincenzo Visco declared to parliament that in certain Italian provinces, there were
fiscal irregularities in more than 50 percent of declarations.5
As we have seen, the possibility of staging referenda had transferred to the
“sovereign people” some parliamentary prerogatives. This was true not only
institutionally but also from the viewpoint of the social reality that parliament
was supposedly representing through the parties. The most striking demonstra-
tion of this came the first time the procedure was used, on May 12, 1974, when
Italians were asked to vote on whether to maintain or reject the divorce law of
December 1970. A modification of the law, even a wording change, could have
averted the referendum. But the intransigent Catholics did everything possible
to bring the matter before the people, persuaded that Italians would reestab-
lish the primacy of Christian values that had been undercut by the eruption of
“modernity.” The Christian Democrats, despite their initial reservations linked
to their governmental relationship with the “prodivorce” parties, ultimately fol-
lowed in the Catholics’ footsteps, seeing the referendum as a way to relaunch a
party facing a crisis of legitimacy.
The result revealed that the various political powers were far from understand-
ing what the country had become in the course of its “economic miracle”: 59.3
percent of the voters supported continuation of the law, with much narrower
margins between deeply Catholic parts of the country and others. Moreover, the
margins between the north and the south of the country were much smaller than
those recorded in 1946 in the referendum between the monarchy and the republic.
This trend was confirmed even more clearly seven years later, when the 1978 law
on abortion was submitted to a referendum: 67.9 percent of the voters supported
it; so did every Italian region except Trentino-Alto Adige, which missed doing so
by only 0.3 percent. For the first time in history, Italians had expressed themselves
nearly unanimously on a question concerning their whole society.
The referenda on “civil rights,” beyond their specific goals, constituted a sort of
reactive indicator of a new relationship among Italians, flowing from three major
ITALIAN METAMORPHOSES 179
correlated and concomitant changes affecting them all: the growth in consump-
tion, the “melting pot,” and the great trade-union struggles.
In this regard, we should recall above all the linguistic unification of the coun-
try. Italy, in the second half of the twentieth century, was the European coun-
try in which social and regional linguistic distances were most rapidly reduced.
According to De Mauro’s calculations, in 1955, only 10 percent of Italians cor-
rectly spoke the national language, and nearly all of them still used a dialect
for their daily communications. After the cinema, which for most Italians was
the first “teacher” of Italian, radio and television generalized the use of the
national language, while resolving in a practical way the theoretical dilemmas
that had divided nineteenth-century linguists. The media, in effect, did not create
the language, as De Mauro notes, but adapted themselves to existing tendencies,
and those tendencies, since the unification of the country, have developed in the
major economic, demographic, political, and intellectual centers of the country:
in Turin, in Milan, and in Rome. It was there, and not in Tuscany, that radio and
television spontaneously drew their lexical and pronunciation models, which they
then spread to the rest of the peninsula: one result was to make the Tuscan pro-
nunciation of Italian seem provincial.6
But the increasing uniformity of some aspects of Italians’ behavior did not mean
they were being “nationalized.” Those who had been brought together by their
trade-union demands were only a portion of society, and the very circumstances
of their rapprochement ruled out any feeling of “national” solidarity with repre-
sentatives of the classes who had opposed them in the season of struggles. The
solidity of their gains, moreover, was shaken once the big company owners began
a counteroffensive. But the chief reason why “modernization” did not generate
a common national identity is that even with the standardization of behavior
that followed the increasing turn to mass consumption, no “Italian” specificity
emerged. Instead, mass consumption brought an inhabitant of Milan closer to a
citizen of Paris or New York than to someone from Matera or Cuneo.
The small party that had made itself the herald of “civil rights”—the Radical
Party7—was referred to quite appropriately as “transnational.” Its battles repre-
sented the tendency of the upwardly mobile strata of society to align their behav-
ior with that of the social groups in more-developed countries that had already
achieved such success.
As marketing experts know, consumption, however massive, remains a fun-
damentally individual act. Thus the possibility to consume more is always seen
as an individual victory and the social behavior that accompanies it is seen as the
securing of a long-denied right. There is an almost perfect correlation between
crossing a certain threshold of consumption and the appearance of specific social
behaviors. The improvement of the quality of life regularly leads to a decrease
in the birth rate. Thus even though each couple feels certain it is deciding freely
how many children it desires, at the moment when improved living conditions
180 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The new behaviors provoked by the social impact of the economic boom pointed
to an ever-clearer emancipation from the cultural guardianship of the two domi-
nant ideologies in the republic’s early decades. But while this led to a steady erosion
of the influence of the PCI, that of the Church, paradoxically, would be strength-
ened, to the point that it became an inescapable force in all political equations as
matters settled after the earthquake of the 1990s.
Those seeking an explanation for this “miracle” often look to the undeniable
weaknesses of “secular thinking,” ever more on the defensive for its inability to
make sense of the contradictions of “modernity.” Some university professors, hav-
ing successively been Maoists or followers of Sartre, Adorno, or Nietzsche, revealed
ITALIAN METAMORPHOSES 181
contraceptives, was not abrogated by the Constitutional Court until 1971. All
this fed into an atmosphere of massive illegality, which only grew as “modernity”
imposed its laws. Thus when the drop in the birth rate began to create labor
shortages, lawmakers found themselves bankrupt for ideas; not so, needless to
say, the Church.
These shortages could be overcome, at least partially, only through immigra-
tion, but this was likely to produce a negative, identity-centered reaction, at least
psychologically. Over these social and psychological repercussions, the Church
was able to recover some of its credit in the eyes of the country.
In a series of articles published in February 1989 on the occasion of a closed-
door session of the Italian episcopal conference on the question of immigration,
the bishops’ semiofficial journal, Avvenire, offered an analysis of the phenomenon.
Immigration, the Catholic journal wrote, is inevitable for three key reasons: (1)
the demographic imbalance between the north and south coasts of the Mediter-
ranean, (2) the fact that many immigrants came from oil-exporting countries,
and (3) the demands of the Italian labor market. “An industrial country,” said a
commentary in Avvenire, “needs reserves of low-cost manual labor: farm workers,
domestics and seasonal laborers.”12 This was thus an inevitable destiny in the eyes
of the bishops, but also a threat to the social equilibrium of the country, and one
that in Avvenire’s estimation only the Church could prevent. For it had known
how to defeat slavery in the Roman Empire “not by opposing it, but by telling the
slaves: Subjugate yourselves to unjust masters, too.”13
The Italian secular culture, which in the meantime had ceded to Catholic cul-
ture the monopoly of ideals, of solidarity, and of the means to practice it, could
only follow the Church’s path on questions that had long split it between its do-
good instincts and apprehensions that were more or less culturally justified. Faced
with a proposal by Biffi in a pastoral note of September 13, 2000, that immigra-
tion from Catholic—or at least Christian—countries should be favored, the most
famous Italian political scientist, Giovanni Sartori, wrote “in his capacity as a lay-
man” that the remarks of the cardinal of Bologna were “holy words, to say the least.
And very responsible.”14
Thus some twenty years after the referendum on divorce, the authority of
the Church had again begun to radiate a light so bright that few shadows dared
intrude, and the supposed superposition of the Catholic and the Italian identities
was restored to prominence with scarcely any resistance from intellectuals or the
public authorities of the peninsula.
Chapter 22
T he Italian crisis of the 1990s began in the early 1970s in Washington, D.C.,
Basel, and Kuwait City. The end of the gold-dollar standard, announced from
the White House on August 15, 1971, by President Richard Nixon, the creation of
the European monetary “serpent,” decided in the Swiss city on April 10, 1972, and,
finally, the oil crisis that followed the decision by the Organization of Petroleum
Exporting Countries (OPEC), on October 17, 1973, in Kuwait, to raise the price of
oil from $3 to $5.15 a barrel touched off a seismic movement whose aftershocks
would shake the entire Italian system twenty years later.
With the failure of a timid deflationist policy decided after the wage increases
of 1969, each Italian social and economic actor reacted, once again, by pursuing
its own immediate interests. Many small and medium entrepreneurs closed their
businesses or profited from the largess of the state, either by selling troubled busi-
nesses or by profiting from the generous financing meant to support investment
in the Mezzogiorno.1 Others decided simply to export their capital abroad, while
some shifted higher production costs to consumers; nearly all of them practiced a
sort of fiscal self-indemnification, seeking to pay the lowest taxes possible.
Public enterprises, for their part, continued to produce at a loss. At the end of
1978, Castronovo points out, while private enterprises were reporting 613 lira of
debt per 1,000 lira of turnover, state-owned companies were declaring more than
1,100 lira; in other words, debt exceeded their turnover.2 In 1971 the state-owned
EFIM (Agency for Participation and Financing of Manufacturing Industry), IRI
(Industrial Reconstruction Institute), ENI (National Hydrocarbon Agency), and
IMI (Istituto Mobiliare Italiano), each of them loss-makers, gave birth to GEPI
(Società per le Gestioni e Partecipazioni Industriali), whose aim was, as its found-
ing statute declared, to “contribute to the maintenance and the growth of jobs
compromised by the transitory difficulties of industrial enterprises,” that is, to
purchase private companies poised at the brink of bankruptcy.3 Thus, from 1969
to 1973, state involvement in economic affairs grew steadily, increasing from 19.9
percent of all employees to 25.2 percent, and from 31 percent of capital to 39.2
184 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
percent, a trend that would continue until the 1980s.4 From 1970 to 1975, the flow
of public money destined to enterprises rose from 6 trillion to 17 trillion lira, and
in 1992 the European commissioner Lord Leon Brittan complained that 28 per-
cent of the country’s deficit went to subsidizing companies.
Bit by bit, a new “social compromise” took shape, thanks to the Keynesian and
protectionist policies of the state, supported by public debt, which rose from 38
percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 1970 to 55 percent in 1982, reaching
120.2 percent in 1997. This policy took three directions: direct (subsidies) and
indirect support (orders, trade and fiscal protection, etc.) to industry; expansion
of the bureaucratic apparatus; and, above all, an inflationist policy intended to
support exports.
After the February 1973 decision to allow the lira to float on currency exchanges,
the mechanism of “competitive devaluation” thus became the principal weapon of
the “doped-up” competition of the 1970s and 1980s. While the great powers were
beginning successively to follow the painful path of deregulation, Italian industry
kept afloat thanks to this expedient. Not until the arrival of the single currency was
Italy definitively deprived of the option of resorting to this form of competition.5
The other weapon was also a return to tradition: the attempt to reestablish pre-
1969 wage conditions. If the aims remained the same—and helped re-create “class
solidarity” between the petite and the grand bourgeoisie, between the private and
public sectors—the methods could not help but change. Gianni Agnelli, president
of Confindustria since 1974, had two years earlier described the perspective of this
new phase of social relations thus: “We have only two possibilities,” he said. “Either
a frontal shock to impose a lowering of wages or a series of courageous initiatives
to eliminate the more intolerable phenomena of waste and inefficiency. Needless
to say, we have chosen the latter.”6
In short, this was a new attempt to adopt the path of “great reform,” but this
time employing every decisive force influencing the agents of society. The simul-
taneous launching—just days before the oil crisis of the fall of 1973—of a political
plan for “historic compromise” by the secretary of the Italian Communist Party
(PCI), Enrico Berlinguer, was more than simple coincidence. The strategic objec-
tives of the head of Fiat and the boss of the PCI were in agreement, even to the
choice of words: Berlinguer, too, effectively committed himself to fight “waste and
dissipation, the exaltation of the most immoderate particularities and individual-
ism, the most brazen consumerism.”7
The PCI was welcomed into the governmental majority less than three years later,
in the summer of 1976. Its willingness to play the role that, ten years earlier, had
belonged to the Italian Socialist Party (PSI) enjoyed trade-union support—support
the center-left never had—for a veritable “pedagogy of austerity.” The secretary-
general of the Italian General Confederation of Labor (CGIL; the union close to
the PCI), Luciano Lama, announced that this austerity would consist of “not mar-
ginal, but substantial sacrifices”: wage moderation, restriction of the wages guar-
antee fund mechanisms, “real” mobility for hourly workers, and “an end to the
system of permanently subsidized labor.”8 Arguing that unemployment tends to
rise when wage levels are too high in comparison to productivity, Lama presented
his as the only way to defend employment. In fact, he was defending the traditional
BETWEEN EUROPE AND THE MEDITERRANEAN 185
practice of attacking wages in order to avoid dealing with low productivity. Real
wages diminished without reducing unemployment, which in fact rose from 5.9
percent in 1975 to 7.7 percent in 1979. Still, thanks to a series of successive devalu-
ations beginning in the first half of 1976, exports revived, creating the conditions
that would allow the adventures of the nuovi condottieri in the 1980s.9
In legislative terms, the period of “national solidarity”—the name given to the
phase of Christian Democrat–PCI collaboration that would last until 1979—pro-
duced modest results, probably less important than the achievements a decade
earlier during the first years of center-left rule. Disappointment was even more
crushing since the PCI had presented its participation in the governing majority as
the act through which the working class would “become” the state (“si fa Stato”),
as per the famous slogan of 1977. In the elections of 1979, the PCI paid dearly
for its policy of austerity, especially in big-city working-class neighborhoods and
among the young. Even as its overall share of the vote dropped by 11.75 percent
compared to 1976, the loss among voters age eighteen to twenty-one saw the PCI’s
share fall by more than a third (–35.41 percent). The progressive decline, which
would lead to the party’s ultimate dissolution a decade later, had begun.10
But the failure of “national solidarity” went beyond the fortunes of the par-
ties that had promoted it. One could say about this new “missed opportunity”
just what Galli della Loggia had said about the impossibility of building national
sentiment on the fiction of a “republic born from the Resistance”: it “clashed too
obviously with the concrete experience of the majority of the population.”11 The
“pedagogy of austerity” and the ethic of sacrifice were not in tune with the trans-
formations of Italian society and with the relative enrichment of multi-income
families, who measured their social progress in terms of consumption. To be con-
vincing, wrote Enzo Pace, an ideology must seduce both emotionally and ratio-
nally, but also must “produce useful social effects, both in collective terms and in
individual incentives.”12 “National solidarity” did neither.
Among the electorate there also arose, in the following decade, “a new political
animal.” This voter, as the journalist Mariella Gramaglia portrayed him in 1987,
loved money and power, was “irritated by egalitarianism,” and was seduced by
“guts and effrontery as virtues that he would like to possess and that he imitates
as best he can.”13 This “political animal,” who voted in the 1980s for the PSI of
Bettino Craxi, would become the protagonist, in the 1990s, of the Berlusconian
“revolution.”
“External Constraints”
In August 1974, the Bank of Italy was constrained to pledge part of its gold reserves
in exchange for a $2 billion loan from the Bundesbank. Afterward, the lira’s inter-
national standing was downgraded to a level below that of the Mexican peso. The
subordination to Germany that was formalized by this loan provided added proof
that international factors would play an ever greater role in determining the situ-
ation of Italy. This became even more evident after the oil crisis and the recession
of 1974 to 1975.
186 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The crisis of the early 1970s revealed a new global configuration after thirty
years of unequal development. In 1974, while the industrialized countries saw
their manufacturing production drop by 0.5 percent, that of the newly industrial-
ized countries continued to grow at an annual rate of 7.2 percent. For the old pow-
ers, the need to deregulate and to restructure the productive apparatus of the state
began to appear urgent and inevitable if they were to stay ahead of these dynamic
countries, so rich in labor and free of parasitic burdens and social preoccupations.
The need to deal with these new actors would lead to a new global free-trade cycle
and a new liberal cycle in the domestic politics of different countries. Margaret
Thatcher, Ronald Reagan, Helmut Kohl, and François Mitterrand (after 1983)
would be the political agents of this crisis of restructuring.
In Italy, on the other hand, the free-market tendencies long remained weak.
Adding to the difficulties arising from a political world born and nourished by
a planned economy was the resistance of a productive apparatus that hoped
indefinitely to postpone its technological reconversion by relying on its tradi-
tional resources: the depreciation of the lira and low wages. Wages, according to Le
Monde, had risen in 1974 by 4.9 percent in Germany, 1.6 percent in Great Britain, 5
percent in France, and 1.3 percent in Japan. In Italy, in contrast, they had fallen by
a full 5 percent.14 Though often overshadowed by “competitive devaluation,” low-
wage policies would long be characteristic of Italian competitiveness. Twenty years
after the data cited by Le Monde, an Organization for Economic Development and
Cooperation (OECD) estimate found that Italians were working more for less pay
than were workers in other industrialized countries.15
The Italian monetary authorities quickly sounded the alarm about the inher-
ent risks of resorting systematically to these expedients to avoid dealing with the
structural problem of low productivity. It was no accident if Guido Carli, Carlo
Azeglio Ciampi, and Lamberto Dini (two former governors and a former director
general of Banca d’Italia) occupied leading positions in Italian political life start-
ing in 1991. They were the first to argue that if Italy was unable to reform itself,
changes ultimately would be imposed by constraining European mechanisms, or
by what Carli called an “external constraint.”16
The first of these “constraints”—meant to impose on Italy an ability to com-
pete not by “the degradation of the lira,” but by “limiting costs and increasing
productivity”—was, according to Ciampi, adherence to the European Monetary
System (EMS), in March 1979. When the effects of entry into the EMS began to be
felt “in June 1980,” Ciampi said, companies came to understand that “their reorga-
nization could no longer be postponed.”17
Ciampi himself did his best to help them understand. Giangiacomo Nardozzi
recounts what happened in the summer of 1980 when the president of Fiat, Gianni
Agnelli, visited the governor of Banca d’Italia to ask for a new lira devaluation:
Ciampi turned him down “politely but firmly.”18 That September, Fiat sent out
fifteen thousand dismissal notices. After a twenty-day strike that brought down
the government, the dismissals were transformed into “temporary” layoffs, but for
twenty-three thousand workers. In the end, only a few dozen were rehired. In the
years to follow, Fiat closed its facilities in Lingotto and Chivasso. The victory of
the Turinese group in its strong-arm confrontation with the trade unions marked
BETWEEN EUROPE AND THE MEDITERRANEAN 187
The same “general law” had characterized the Italian Atlanticism of the preced-
ing three decades. As Francesco Cossiga summed up the situation, Italy depended
entirely on the international policies of the United States and NATO, but this
loyalty allowed it to exploit “the marginal utility, the geopolitical ‘income’ that
came from being a frontier country with an internal frontier which, moreover,
accommodated on its territory the Holy See.”21 Romano explains in concrete terms
how this “marginal utility” was expressed: Italy accepted its subordination to the
United States, in exchange reserving itself the right to flirt “with the enemies of
its principal friend: the Soviet Union, the PLO of Arafat, Gaddafi’s Libya, and the
Ethiopia of Mengistu.”22
Tacitly authorized by the Americans, this “Mediterranean Atlanticism” had,
of course, to be very discreet. Often this policy sidestepped the Foreign Ministry
and was conducted instead by economic groups, by Catholic organizations, and,
naturally, by the PCI, which was the privileged intermediary for matters on the
other side of the Iron Curtain. The case of Enrico Mattei, who, as president of
ENI, bypassed governments and the big international petroleum companies to
establish direct relationships with the oil-producing countries of the Mediter-
ranean, was surely the most famous example of this “parallel diplomacy,” but
hardly the only one.23
“Mediterranean Atlanticism” was the essence of republican Italy’s international
political projection until the caesura of 1989 to 1991, when it was succeeded by
the phase of “passive Europeanism” or “impotence,” of which the “forced” mem-
bership in the EMS had provided a foretaste in the 1970s. Beyond its impact on
the productive system, this membership also affected the strategic debate of the
188 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
governing class. It clearly exposed a double fault line that followed rather clear
geopolitical lines, internal and international. On the one side were the economi-
cally free-market-leaning groups and tendencies of the north; they relied on
Germany to help them seek advantage over the other side—the “Mediterranean”
groups and tendencies—which were largely protectionist.
The theses supported by some entrepreneurs in the north can be summed up
thus: even if the lands south of the Mediterranean form an attractive market, Ger-
many is the locomotive of the European economy and is the country capable of
absorbing the bulk of Italian exports; it is thus to Europe that Italian interests
must be tied. The opponents of this line, continued the northern businessmen,
are defending backward sectors of production by use of monetary protection. The
true line of demarcation, they concluded, is the one that separates the “party of
Europe” from the “party of inflation.”24
This debate had inevitable political echoes. Interest groups closer to the mar-
kets of the “deutsche mark zone” began in the late 1970s to support a rising politi-
cal phenomenon—“localism”—which was explicitly anticentralist. Transborder
associations that included Italian, Swiss, Austrian, and German regions of the east-
ern Alps intensified their encounters. A “Working Community of Eastern Alpine
Regions,” referred to as the “little EEC of the Alps,” included as its members not
only Veneto, Friuli, Carinthia, Styria, and Upper Austria but also Slovenia and
Croatia, a dozen years before the breakup of Yugoslavia. All these regional group-
ings posed rather explicitly the problem of using the north’s resources to develop
trade with the rest of Europe rather than “wasting” it on the unproductive con-
sumption of Rome and the Mezzogiorno.
The backers of the “party of Europe” could not help but find sympathy for
their beliefs within the traditional parties. At the end of November 1978, a cer-
tain Christian Democratic university professor from Bologna joined the govern-
ment. He was the head of the Il Mulino publishing house, Romano Prodi. Early the
following month, Prodi was, along with others including Beniamino Andreatta,
Giuseppe De Rita, and Umberto Agnelli, the promoter of a symposium launching
a Christian Democratic “free-trade” faction. But the party that felt most invested
in this “mission” was the small Republican Party of Italy, headed by Ugo La Malfa,
long the party of reference of the great capital of the north. In late 1978 the Repub-
lican Party attacked the PCI for its opposition to the EMS.
Adherence to the EMS in December 1978 marked the end of “national soli-
darity.” Within the PCI, not only had the traditional pro-Russian and anti-Ger-
man reflexes prevailed, but so had the factions linked to Mediterranean trade. In
December 1978, Claudio Petruccioli, a party leader, dismissed the economic and
political demands of the north as a “wave of provincial neoliberalism.” But that
was not all. The conviction also prevailed within the PCI that the monetary rigor
required by membership in the EMS had negative effects on employment and
wages: a rather unfortunate outcome for a working class that was supposed to
“become the state.”
When Andreotti resigned, Italian President Sandro Pertini turned, on February
22, 1979, to Ugo La Malfa to form the new government. Despite the failure of this
BETWEEN EUROPE AND THE MEDITERRANEAN 189
effort, it was the first time in republican Italy that this role had been assigned to a
political leader who was not a Christian Democrat.
In the meantime, other forces and other men prepared to face the future. In
early December 1978, under orders from the new pontiff, the Italian Church orga-
nized in Varese a meeting on “Christian Europe” to which was invited the head of
the Bavarian Christian Social Union, Franz Josef Strauss. For its part, L’Osservatore
Romano, the Holy See daily, expressed the desire that one day the European Com-
munity would be able to include Eastern Europe. On the “secular” front, among
the “provincial neoliberals” mocked by Petruccioli, a Milanese industrialist,
important in the business world but unknown to the general public, was mulling
the possibility of creating, in Milan, local electoral lists because, as he said, “if we
do not succeed in finding a successor to this political class, dark days await us.” His
name: Silvio Berlusconi.
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 23
The Internationalization
Crisis of the 1990s
D espite Italy’s adherence to the European Monetary System (EMS), the liberal
northern groups had merely won a battle. They were not yet sufficiently pow-
erful to remake state policies according to their demands.
The Italian situation in the 1980s was rather like Penelope’s tapestry: Italy,
goaded by European legislation, was beginning cautiously to dismantle certain
forms of protectionism, but new ones were constantly being created, particularly
through the uncontrolled growth of public spending and what Carli described,
in the rather baroque language of a Banca d’Italia official, as “the allocation of
undue sums in order to distend the natural mechanisms of competition and to
subtract a large part of the country’s economy from selective confrontation with
the market.”1 His style aside, Carli’s description illustrates the protectionist char-
acter of corruption, and it points to the reasons that the signing of the Maas-
tricht Treaty coincided almost exactly with the opening of the operation known
as “Clean Hands.”2
The political interpreter of this pendulum swing between the heritage of a
planned economy gone wild and the first timid steps toward free trade was the
Socialist Party secretary, Bettino Craxi, the first Milanese to lead the government
in Italian history. Under his government—which set a record for longevity in the
republican period surpassed only by Silvio Berlusconi—the contradiction evoked
by Carli would underlie a new form of “social compromise,” a well from which all
society’s actors, including many wage earners, would drink. The mechanism of
this compromise was the “recycling of public spending.” The state hired, and to
hire it had to indebt itself. To pay its debt, it issued high-interest securities. These
were then purchased by the people the state had hired (and debt-service payments
required the continual issuance of new high-interest securities, and so on).3 Each
social faction urgently advocated reductions in public spending, so long as it was
other factions who were renouncing their benefits. This explains the ample sup-
port Craxi received from those who had dared say “Enrich yourselves!”
192 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
The Socialist chief, of course, engendered mistrust from part of the Catho-
lic world (but at the same time, the enthusiasm of certain pragmatic Catholic
movements, like Comunione e Liberazione, for which money had long ceased to
be stercus diaboli), and the implacable hostility of the PCI. There were various
motivations for this opposition, but the principal one, summing up all others, lay
in Craxi’s proposal to repeat in Italy the French experience of strengthening the
Socialist Party at the Communists’ expense. This operation was meant to be built
on the modern, dynamic, and casual character of the Socialist Party, in contrast
to the archaic nature of the PCI, which was presented as moralistic and pauperis-
tic, for it had spent years preaching sacrifice and austerity. The attack on the PCI
came on the worker front. Craxi not only demonstrated that public-debt securities
brought more money to families, and more quickly, than protests and struggle, but
he worked to dismantle the mechanisms that still guaranteed negotiating power
to unions.
For a time, the electoral results seemed to confirm the Socialist leader’s hypoth-
esis. While the PCI was steadily losing favor in voters’ eyes, the Socialist Party
passed from 9.6 percent of votes cast in 1976, when Bettino Craxi was elected sec-
retary, to 14.3 percent in 1987, when he left the prime ministership, meaning it had
grown by nearly half, even if it did not pick up the entire eight percentage points
lost by the PCI. The Socialist Party had also managed to draw into its orbit some
of the intellectuals who had distanced themselves progressively from Berlinguer’s
party as it lost power and prestige, as well as some of those who had, until then,
adhered to the wanderings of a reduced extreme left (the list that included survi-
vors of the group once known as “extraparliamentary” ranged from 1.4 percent to
1.7 percent of the vote in those years).
This in partibus infidelium breakthrough made Craxi public enemy number 1
of the PCI, to the point that Berlinguer, in 1984, actually declared him “a danger
to democracy.”4 Despite this hostility, conveyed in daily attacks by La Repubblica,
the secretary of the PSI managed to gain the backing of PCI sympathizers and
leaders in September 1985, when he demanded that American forces turn over to
him the leader of a Palestinian terrorist group intercepted in Sicily who had just
hijacked an Italian cruise ship and killed a Jewish American tourist. The PCI, all
the anti-American factions, and the small number of self-described “nationalists”
applauded the firmness of the head of government, which was seen as an act of
defiance toward the “American imperialists.”5
In short, during the “Craxi years” people began to believe that the distance
separating the official country and the real country had narrowed, that Italy had
evolved on the international scene onto an equal footing with other powers, and
that feelings of national pride could legitimately be displayed, even outside sport-
ing events. Contributing to these impressions were the events just described:
unprecedented governmental stability, Craxi’s main role in the Socialist Interna-
tional, and the signing of the new Concordat, which had been in the works for
decades but which the Christian Democrats had been unable to bring to frui-
tion given the risk of political insider trading. But above all was the conviction
that the Italian political class had finally become progrowth. Italians were seeing
their income soar; inflation was falling (from 10.4 percent to 4.9 percent in the
THE INTERNATIONALIZATION CRISIS OF THE 1990S 193
five years of the Craxi government); gross domestic product (GDP) was rising (in
1987, the prime minister announced that Italy had become the fifth leading world
power, having passed Great Britain); the “Third Italy” of small businesses was
showing its dynamism; the nuovi condottieri—Carlo De Benedetti, Raul Gardini,
Silvio Berlusconi, Luciano Benetton—launched their assault on the world, starting
with France; and Italians were no longer emigrating. For the first time, affluence,
money, and profit were becoming positive notions in the collective imagination,
and the inhabitants of the peninsula, growing richer, suddenly realized they could
do so without a sense of guilt.
Still, this social compromise revealed its continuing fragility when it encoun-
tered its intrinsic limits—the risk of a state bankruptcy or new inflation—and,
above all, the limits imposed by its European competitors. Once Germany gave
up its politically subordinate role, the cards were on the table. The overarching
requirement for any country wanting to remain in Europe was to fight against its
public deficits and accumulated debt. For Italy, accepting this rule meant killing
the goose that laid the golden egg.
From that moment, the king was declared naked. If Great Britain had indeed
been surpassed, it was only because of a change in the way GDP was calculated.
If inflation had been defeated, it remained the highest in Europe. If industrial
productivity had increased, services, distribution, and administration had not
followed suit. Above all, even if Italians were undeniably growing richer, public
spending had risen by 8 percent of GDP during the decade.
The first sign that this new era of milk and honey was nearing an end was the
retreat of the nuovi condottieri, who, one after the other, had to shelve their dreams
of international glory. Even the lord of all the condottieri, Gianni Agnelli, after
some flashes of brilliance during the “Craxi years,” faced a lengthy crisis, from
which Fiat has only quite recently emerged. At the end of the 1980s, the “disap-
pearance of industrial Italy” would brutally accelerate. For the “disappearance of
political Italy,” such as it had been known, the wait would not to be so long.
European Constraints
United States—at least officially. But there was another reason for urgency. The
country’s fear, given the accelerating European pace, that it might definitively lose
contact with the rest of the continent and slide progressively into the Mediterra-
nean. This fear was sharpest in the north, particularly in Milan. For Lombardy, one
of the three richest regions of Europe, along with Bavaria and the Paris region, the
thought of a distancing from the heart of the continent was intolerable. Any other
solution was preferable.
Milan had “made” Craxi; now Milan “unmade” him. From the Lombard capital
emanated first the political challenge and then the judiciary challenge to the sys-
tem of power that had reigned throughout postwar Italy and was now seen as the
chief culprit behind the risk of exclusion from Europe. The many anticentralist local
electoral lists found their federating force, at the regional level and then beyond,
in a leader with both the vices and virtues of the increasingly well-off petite bour-
geoisie of the north—which he embodied down to his very verbal tics and gestures,
and with uncommon flair and political flexibility: Umberto Bossi. Joining him were,
among others, Gianfranco Miglio, former faculty president of the School of Political
Science at the Catholic University of Milan, a Craxi-era theoretician, who brought as
a dowry his long experience as an analyst of political thought.
But the Northern League was only the best known and, until 1994, the most
successful of the many attempts at a metamorphosis of the political system. Early
in the 1980s the Republican Party was the object of a major political investment
by the large groups and their leading daily newspapers—Corriere della Sera and
La Stampa—and it dreamed briefly of becoming the third major power in the
Italian political panorama, representing rigor and efficiency. Then came the turn
of “Craxi-ism,” which, as already seen, came closer to the goal of breaking up the
Christian Democrat–Communist Party duopoly. In the early 1990s, it was the son
of the former president of the republic, the Sardinian Christian Democrat Mario
Segni, who left his party to give birth to a grand federation of all those who saw the
proportional electoral system as underlying the country’s problems. The federa-
tion had its moment of glory when, in a 1993 referendum, 82.7 percent of voters
(63.68 percent of those registered) cast ballots for the abolition of the propor-
tional voting law for the Senate. Between the two decades, even the PCI attempted
a break with the past. The disappearance of the Soviet Union relieved it of its inter-
national obligations, and it tried to recycle itself as a “liberal” European party, as
its last secretary, Achille Occhetto, put it in declaring war on “ineffective, corrupt,
bureaucratic statism” in the name of “civil society.”6
From 1991 to 1993 Italians were called to vote in nine referenda, eight of them
on laws regulating the relationship between citizens and the state. Along with the
electoral system of the Senate, they abolished the single preference on electoral
lists for the Chamber (by 95.6 percent of voters); the law on public financing of
parties (90.3 percent); the laws concerning the designation of the heads of public
banks (89.8 percent), of certain sanitary services (82.6 percent), and of three min-
istries: agriculture (70.2 percent), tourism (82.3 percent), and state participations
(90.1 percent), the “owner” of public industry in Italy.
Given that in 1978 another referendum for the abolition of the same law on
public financing of parties had been rejected by 56.4 percent of voters, one can
THE INTERNATIONALIZATION CRISIS OF THE 1990S 195
measure, even quantify, how much the rejection of traditional political groupings
had grown over fifteen years, reflecting the evolution of liberal sentiment within
“civil society.” In 1970 Jacques Nobécourt described the small Liberal Party as the
party of all those for whom “the demand for liberty meant the preservation of all
that they themselves had acquired or constructed.”7 Twenty years later the Liberal
Party had disappeared, but the number of those who had acquired or constructed
something worth preserving now measured in the millions.
If they were able to ride it and at times exploit it, an ex-Christian Democrat and
an ex-Communist could certainly not channel and stably organize this “liberal”
and “antiparty” wave with its determination to break with the past. The Northern
League’s campaign against “Roma ladrona” (Rome the thief) had a greater chance
of succeeding. The party of Bossi and Miglio passed from the 186,000-vote mark in
1987 to 3.4 million in 1992, an eighteen-fold increase in its electoral base in just five
years. Thus the Italian political earthquake clearly began well before the annus ter-
ribilis of 1992. But the fact that in 1992 the traditional parties were caught unpre-
pared indicates that earlier predictions of this earthquake had been too cautious.
The predictors were considering not only the League’s folkloristic character but
also its intrinsic, structural limits, represented by its geographic confines. It could
not be the party to unite and represent the discontent and appetite for change
of all Italians because it quite simply was not an Italian party, it was a northern
regional party.
Channelling this will for change would require a force present nationwide, of a
clearly liberal nature, and which seemed to keep a certain distance from the party
system, and indeed from politics in general. In this sense, Forza Italia represented
both the “final stage” and the fruition of all the trends that were transforming Ital-
ian society. The most elemental aspect of Silvio Berlusconi’s success lay in the fact
that his eruption into a political world in profound upheaval could have succeeded
only by presenting itself as completely foreign to that world.
But Berlusconi, as innovative and “impolitic” as he was, suffered—for differ-
ent reasons, and perhaps acutely—from the same malady that afflicts the political
world in general and its Italian version in particular: subjectivism. This disease
helped persuade the political actors of the 1990s that Europe was something of
their own making, not the other way around. For without the gravitational pull
exerted by Europe, Italian political life would have taken an entirely different direc-
tion. Berlusconi’s first government fell only months after it was established, after a
fatal miscalculation that it could resuscitate the Atlantic linkage quo ante in order
to avoid European constraints. Similarly, the Northern League was “European” in
the way Molière’s Monsieur Jourdain spoke in prose (though he was surprised
to learn it). If the rise of Forza Italia at first did not erode the League’s electoral
basis—even while competing on the same northern Italian playing field—the
Bossi’s party lost more than half of its votes in the 2001 elections, after the risk of
a break with the rest of Europe had been warded off.8
The strength of the various center-left coalitions—starting with the one that
took the place of Berlusconi in 1994 (led by his former economy minister Lamberto
Dini and supported by the Northern League)—consisted of the capacity to submit
passively to European directives. In September 1996, four months after becoming
196 THE FAILURE OF ITALIAN NATIONHOOD
head of the government, Romano Prodi had attempted, it is true, to obtain the sup-
port of Prime Minister Jose Maria Aznar of Spain in order to modify the Maastricht
parameters. When the latter refused, the former doubled overnight the level of cuts
foreseen in the proposed budget, from 32,500 billion lira to 62,500 billion lira. Eco-
nomics Minister Ciampi, freshly back from a meeting of his European counterparts
in January 1997, added a further 40,000 billion lira. From that moment on, Europe
was to become both the zenith and the nadir of center-left actions.
The co-option into the Euro club on May 3, 1998, was welcomed by a sense of
general jubilation. Italy had averted the fate that had been suffered by the Soviet
Union and Yugoslavia and that would strike Argentina in 2001 to 2002. But in the
chorus of satisfaction one could also hear pride for having so quickly attained an
objective that, after the departure from the Monetary System in September 1992,
had seemed permanently unreachable.
When he became prime minister again in 2006, Romano Prodi could brag of far
closer relations with Brussels than he had enjoyed ten years earlier, relations made
even more solid by the presence in his government of Giuliano Amato, the former
vice president of the Constitutional Convention, and of the former director of the
European Central Bank Tommaso Padoa Schioppa. These were “pro-European
credentials,” which, as Quentin Peel wrote in the Financial Times, compensated for
the parliamentary weakness of the new executive and its political minority in Lom-
bardy.9 In charge of the Foreign Ministry, Massimo D’Alema, who had been prime
minister when Italy was involved in the Kosovo war, inaugurated a new phase in Ital-
ian diplomacy, one that might be called “Atlantic Europeanism,” relaunching Italy’s
Mediterranean interests under both European and American cover.
Thus it was that Italy was to furnish, in August 2006, the bulk of the Euro-
pean contingent for the United Nations mission in Lebanon. According to a view
largely shared by important press outlets, the country, having regained credibility
in European eyes, was now restoring its credibility—and usefulness—in the eyes
of the Americans.
The Lebanon mission seemed to mark a first, the birth of a genuine, autono-
mous foreign and defense policy, as the editor of La Repubblica suggested.10 Or
did it? Was it instead the latest version of the “Crimean syndrome,” leading Italian
political leaders to attach themselves to military expeditions—even highly risky
ones—with the sole objective of increasing the country’s international credibility,
as Sergio Romano asserted?11 Regardless, the Italian Army embarked for Lebanon
accompanied by the cheers of the left and the pacifists and by the cautions of the
right and the nationalists. Could anyone have imagined a more paradoxical epi-
logue to a 145-year history replete with paradoxes?
The slowing of the European process after the 2005 French referendum on the
European constitution eclipsed another debate concerning the near-term future of
Italy, a more theoretical but still interesting debate, which followed the acceptance
of European constraints: that of the “advantage of backwardness.”12
THE INTERNATIONALIZATION CRISIS OF THE 1990S 197
* * *
In this book we have barely mentioned two other major areas of change that affect
not just Italy, but also other countries: the demographic crisis and immigration.
We have done so not because these matters are of lesser importance, but rather
because each deserves a specific and much more detailed treatment.
According to the Italian National Statistics Institute (ISTAT), in 2003, while the
population of native-born Italians declined by 45,405 (544,063 births to 586,468
deaths), the number of inhabitants on the peninsula rose considerably because of
a migratory influx of 407,521 people. In 2005 the native-born population was still
in decline, but by only 13,282. In fact, while the number of newborn Italians had
declined by 1.5 percent from the year before, immigrants themselves were having
9.4 percent more children. According to the United Nations Population Fund, in
2050 the population of Italy could reach 58 million, up from today’s 50.9 million.
The trends appear to point, however, to an Italy peopled with ever fewer Italians, a
worrying perspective for some.
CONCLUSION 201
The only institution in Italy that is prepared to confront the dual challenge rep-
resented by demographic decline and immigration growth is the Catholic Church.
In this book we have described some of the principal steps along the path that
has made the Church one of the most important social and political actors on the
peninsula; indeed, the only inescapable one.7 As we have noted, the struggles—
considered rear-guard battles—against divorce, and especially against abortion,
contraception, and homosexuality, are part of a long-term probirth strategy that
has begun to bear fruit.
The failure of the 2005 referendum against the law that strictly regulates stem
cell research was determined by a massive abstention of voters, an abstention
called for by the president of the Italian bishops of the period, Camillo Ruini. The
result, some said, was revenge for the referenda lost by the Catholics on divorce in
1974 and on abortion in 1981. This was generally viewed as proof that, in Italy, it
had again become impossible to govern or legislate against the will of the Church.
This, too, may be thorny terrain that Italy is in the process of clearing for the
rest of Europe. The Church tests, in the laboratory of the peninsula, its strategies
for fighting against individualism—consciously or unconsciously Malthusian—
and for an immigration policy founded on a clever mixing of welcoming attitude
and doctrinal intransigence. If immigration is not just inevitable, but necessary
to the country’s economic survival, the new immigrants must be welcomed in all
Christian virtues, without ceasing for a moment to point out that these virtues
are Christian. Benedict XVI has stated that the peoples of Asia and Africa do not
fear the West because it is modern, but because it attempts to exclude God from
public life.
In an Italy and a Europe facing the difficult geopolitical and geoeconomic chal-
lenges of the twenty-first century, the Church is preparing to play a role rather
larger than that simply of a “stand-in” for identity.
This page intentionally left blank
Biographies
Grandson of Senator Giovanni Agnelli, the founder of Fiat. Mobilized during World
War II, he fought in Russia and Africa, and was a liaison officer with the Allies toward
the end of the conflict, helping spare Fiat’s Turinese facilities any serious devastation.
He became president of Fiat in 1966, succeeding Vittorio Valletta, shortly after the
signing of an agreement to produce vehicles in the Soviet Union.
At the end of the 1960s he embodied, with a few other big industrialists of the
north and the ENI, the sectors of Italian capitalism that saw a need to deal with
workers struggles by collaborating with trade-union organizations. In keeping
with that line, he was elected president of the Confindustria employers organiza-
tion in 1974, remaining in that position until 1976.
In 1980, faced with the refusal of the governor of the Bank of Italy, Carlo Azeg-
lio Ciampi, to again devalue the lira, Agnelli undertook the most sweeping house-
cleaning of the postwar period, laying off twenty-four thousand Fiat workers and
profoundly restructuring its factories.
Having absorbed Lancia in 1970, Fiat took over Alfa Romeo in 1987 and Fer-
rari in 1988. Agnelli gave up the group presidency in 1996 to Cesare Romiti, but
remained one of its central protagonists until his death.
He was also president, among other things, of the publishing house La
Stampa and of Juventus, the Turin-based soccer team. In 1991 he was named
senator-for-life.
President of the Catholic university students from 1942 to 1945, deputy in the
Constituent Assembly (1946), he was repeatedly reelected before being named
senator-for-life in 1991. A close collaborator of Alcide De Gasperi, and undersec-
retary in his governments from 1947 to 1953, he became a minister in 1955 and,
for a rather long period (1959–1966), was minister of defense. Named head of the
government in 1972, he served in that position a total of seven times up to 1992. In
1973 Andreotti led a center-right executive branch that excluded the Socialists, yet
in 1976, he became the head of the first government to be supported by the PCI.
In the Ministry of Foreign Affairs almost without interruption in the 1980s, he
again became president of the Council of Ministers in 1991, during the Gulf War.
204 BIOGRAPHIES
Accused of several offenses, notably for links between some of his Sicilian
friends and the Mafia, he was always acquitted. He authored more than thirty
books and memoirs, and heads two Catholic magazines, including 30 Giorni.
Despite his denials, he was considered the Vatican’s man in Italian politics. In 1999,
two days after having been accused of playing an intermediary role in a political
murder, Andreotti was publicly blessed by the pope.
He has headed the government three times: in 1994, between 2001 and 2006, and
since 2008.
An entrepreneur in the construction sector since 1960, in 1978 he created one
of the first private television networks, “Telemilano,” which became “Canale 5”
in 1980, after the birth of the financial/media company Fininvest. He followed
this with the purchase in 1982 of “Italia 1” from the Rusconi publishing house,
and in 1984 with the purchase of “Retequattro” from Mondadori. At the invita-
tion of François Mitterrand, he founded “La Cinq” in France (1986), attempting
to enlarge his activities throughout Europe, along with “Telefünf ” in Germany
(1987) and “Telecinco” in Spain (1989). In 1990, a law was passed in Italy declaring
an end to the state’s monopoly on television.
His publishing activities, which began with his investment in Indro Monta-
nelli’s Giornale in 1977, continued with the purchase of the biggest Italian pub-
lishing house, Mondadori, in 1989. Berlusconi also moved into the distribution,
insurance, and financial products sectors, with Mediolanum and Programma Ita-
lia. Since 1986 he has owned the Milan AC soccer team.
Until then, very close to the Craxi’s Socialist Party, a few weeks before the par-
liament elections of 1994, he founded his own party, Forza Italia, which carried
the elections. He formed his first government with the former fascist National
Alliance and the Northern League, which would quit the coalition that December.
He was defeated in the legislative elections of 1996 because he was unable to make
an arrangement with the Northern League. He changed that in 2001, with the seri-
ous electoral decline of the party of Umberto Bossi. Berlusconi set a record for the
survival of a postwar Italian government. In the 2006 elections his coalition was
defeated, by a margin of slightly more than twenty thousand votes. In the 2008
elections his new coalition with National Alliance and Northern League succeeded
by and large.
On Forbes magazine’s list of the richest men in the world, published in March
2009, Silvio Berlusconi ranked seventieth.
Employed by the IRI, he was a Liberal Party deputy in the Constituent Assem-
bly. In 1947 Carli was named the Italian representative to the executive board of
the International Monetary Fund (IMF). In 1957 he became minister of external
commerce and, in 1959, director general of Banca d’Italia. In 1960 he became its
BIOGRAPHIES 205
governor, a position he kept for fifteen years. In 1976 he was elected president
of Confindustria, where, until 1980, he represented continuity with the Agnelli
line. A Christian Democratic senator, he was Treasury minister until 1991. In that
position, Carli was an architect of the single currency and helped bring about the
compromise that led to the signing of the Maastricht Treaty.
Lieutenant in the Engineer Corps in 1827, he took part in the fortification of the
Alps. A partisan of the liberalism, à la Louis Philippe, in punishment he was sent
to Fort Bard fortress in Val d’Aosta. After leaving the army he became mayor of the
commune where his family owned property. In 1835 he traveled through north-
west Europe, drawn by the economic and technical progress of Great Britain. On
May 1, 1846, the Revue nouvelle published his essay “Des chemins de fers en Italie
par le comte Petitti, conseiller d’État du royaume de Sardaigne” (On the Railways of
Italy, by Count Petitti, state counselor of the Kingdom of Sardinia), which earned
him an “invitation” to leave the kingdom. The same year he became the lead-
ing shareholder in the railway linking Turin to Genoa. In 1847 he founded, with
Cesare Balbo, Il Risorgimento, a liberal journal.
As a deputy in 1848, Cavour was minister of commerce and of agriculture, and
of the navy in 1851, and became president of the council (prime minister) the fol-
lowing year. In 1857 he launched a tunnel project under Mont Cenis that would
make possible a rail link from Paris to Turin and open, according to his idea in
1846, a link from London to India via Brindisi and Suez. Having resigned after the
armistice of Villafranca in 1859, he was persuaded by the English ambassador to
Turin to return to his post in early 1860 to take the reins of the unification process
then under way. He remained prime minister until his death.
206 BIOGRAPHIES
A Socialist leader in a “red” suburb of Milan, Sesto San Giovanni, in the 1950s, he
moved into the party leadership in 1965, following the line of Pietro Nenni, who
favored greater autonomy vis-à-vis the PCI. A deputy in 1968, he became secretary
of the PSI in 1976, following its worst electoral showing since the war. He was a
severe critic of the Christian Democrats and the PCI, attempting to create a “third
pole” at the moment of the governmental alliance between the country’s two most
important parties. He was the only influential politician to favor negotiations with
the Red Brigades to save the life of Aldo Moro.
The PSI then experienced what Craxi called a “groundswell” of electoral growth,
without however reaching the goal of becoming the leading party of the Italian
left. Craxi brought his party back into the government in 1980, after a five-year
absence. Named president of the council in 1983, he headed the executive twice up
to 1987, thus giving the impression that the country had achieved domestic politi-
cal stability and new international prestige.
The chief accused in the corruption scandals that were revealed starting in 1992,
he explained, in a memorable speech to the Chamber of Deputies, the mechanisms
by which all the parties had financed themselves. He then left the country and took
refuge in Tunisia, where the local government protected him from several interna-
tional arrest warrants issued following his repeated convictions in Italy.
He was vice president of Socialist International.
in all the Mazzinian conspiracies, Crispi had to take refuge in Malta, then in
France. In 1860 he organized the arrival of the Garibaldians in Sicily and was an
official in the new provisional government. Distanced from the leadership because
of his republican and anti-Piedmontese sentiments, Crispi was, as of 1861, a dep-
uty of the far left, even after his conversion to the monarchy (1864). A supporter
of the war of 1866 and of an alliance with France in 1870, he became a minister
in the first governments of the Sinistra, despite his polemics against transform-
ism. As prime minister in 1887, he attempted to consolidate the national fabric of
the country through his effort to solve the “Roman question,” with the enlarge-
ment of the up-to-then nearly nonexistent welfare state, with the repression of
social movements, and with an expansionist policy on the international scene. A
supporter of the Triple Alliance, he was the instigator of the colonial missions to
Ethiopia, which came to an end in 1895 with the defeat at Adwa, which forced him
to resign. He was elected to parliament a final time in 1898.
Philosopher, historian, literary critic, and politician, he first met Antonio Labri-
ola in the 1890s and, having fallen under the influence of Marxism, broke with it
resoundingly at the end of the decade. This experience was, however, at the origin
of his sense of history, which he wrote about in his journal La Critica, founded in
1903 and later one of the jewels of the Laterza publishing house of Bari.
Named senator in 1910, he was minister of public instruction under Giolitti
in 1920. Having followed with intense interest the rise of fascism, he broke with it
after the murder of Matteotti in 1924. He was at the origins, in 1925, of the Mani-
festo of Anti-Fascist Intellectuals. He took to the Senate floor in 1929 to express his
opposition to the Concordat with the Church. He again became minister during
the Badoglio and Bonomi governments (1944). President of the Liberal Party, he
was elected to the Constituent Assembly.
he worked, beginning in 1929, for the Vatican library, while also contributing to
some Catholic journals.
In 1944 he became national secretary of the Christian Democratic Party and
minister, beginning with the first Bonomi government (1944). He became head
of the government in 1945 and continued in that role until 1953. He was a strong
advocate of European integration, and the first president of the European Coal
and Steel Community.
Born near Stradella, in the province of Pavia (at that time part of the Kingdom of
Savoy), he was an early disciple of Giuseppe Mazzini. Elected deputy at the Turin
Parliament in 1848, since 1862 he was several times a minister in governments led
by the Destra, in particular as minister of the navy during the catastrophic war
against Austria in 1866. After some Destra representatives joined the Sinistra, he
was called upon to form the first Sinistra cabinet in March 1876, which he led until
1878. Again prime minister in May 1881, he retained that office until his death.
Joined the merchant marine at the age of fifteen as a ship’s boy and traveled to
Odessa. Close to the Mazzinian republicans, he was sentenced to death in 1834
following an aborted conspiracy. Taking refuge in Latin America, he took part,
between 1835 and 1843, in the continent’s political and military struggles, in par-
ticular for the defense of the Rio Grande do Sul, which was in revolt against the
Brazilian empire. At the moment of the 1848 revolution, Garibaldi swore loyalty to
the King of Sardinia and became head of the provisional army of the government
of liberated Milan. In 1849 he took on the same position in the new Roman repub-
lic and in that role inflicted minor defeats on the French Army, which had come
to reestablish papal power. During the Sicilian insurrection of 1860, he raised a
volunteer army (the “Mille”, or “Red Shirts”), supported by the king and the Brit-
ish and tolerated by the Piedmont government, with which he was able to rout the
Neapolitan Army. Having conquered Naples, Garibaldi restored the kingdom to
the hands of Victor Emmanuel II. He twice attempted (1862 and 1867) to attack
the Latium, which remained in the Pope’s hands, but he was stopped once by the
Italians and once by the French. In 1866 he fought the sole victorious battle against
the Austrians, at Bezzecca, but the king ordered him to pull back. Elected to parlia-
ment in 1861, he organized in 1870 a volunteer corps to defend the French Repub-
lic against the Prussians, and then the Paris Commune against Thiers. In the 1871
election, he was elected to the French National Assembly.
A student at the University of Turin, he made contact with the city’s workers
groups and joined the Socialist Youth in 1913. An interventionist from the begin-
ning of the war, he later had a change of heart, and in 1916 began working with
the Turinese edition of the party’s journal Avanti!. He took part in the insurrection
of August 1917 and, in 1919, he was an organizer and, above all, a theoretician of
the experiment with factory councils, considered the Italian laborers’ form of the
210 BIOGRAPHIES
Soviets. The same year he founded the Communist journal L’Ordine Nuovo and
was, the year afterward, involved in the efforts that led to the birth of the Com-
munist Party of Italy, in January 1921. As a deputy in 1924, he founded L’Unità and
headed the group that, on Moscow’s orders, ousted Amadeo Bordiga from party
leadership. He was arrested in November 1926 and sentenced to twenty years and
four months in prison. It was during his detention that he wrote his notes on the
ruling class and Italian intellectuals, of which a large part, following the “purging”
desired by Togliatti, would be published after the war under the title The Prison
Notebooks. He was freed just days before his death.
Ordained a priest in 1819, he was sent to work in the apostolic nunciature of Santi-
ago de Chile in 1823. Archbishop of Spoleto in 1827, then of Imola, he was named
cardinal in 1840. Elected pope in 1846, he granted a broad amnesty to political
prisoners and undertook some timid liberal reforms, including a customs league
BIOGRAPHIES 211
with the other Italian states. Faced with the spread of the revolutionary movement
in 1848, Mastai Ferretti condemned the war against Austria and, in November,
was himself overthrown by the proclamation of the republic in Rome. Restored to
power by the French Army, he adopted a firm policy toward liberal and national
ideas. In 1864 he published the Syllabus, a list of eighty ideas condemned by the
Church, including rationalism, liberalism, and modern society in general. In 1854
and 1870 came two of the Church’s defining dogmas: the immaculate conception
and papal infallibility. In 1870, during the Italian conquest of Rome, he closed
himself up in the Vatican, excommunicated the king, the government, and its mili-
tary, and rejected the law of guarantees offered by the new peninsular state. His
pontificate was the longest in Church history. He was beatified on September 3,
2000, by John Paul II.
Grandson of Prince Marcantonio Pacelli, one of the founders of the daily Osser-
vatore Romano, cousin of Ernesto Pacelli, founder and president of the Banco di
Roma, he studied theology at the Gregorian University and was ordained a priest
in 1899. Chamberlain of Pope Pius X, he was a consultant to the Holy Office in
1911 and subsecretary for foreign affairs on the eve of World War I. Papal nun-
cio in Bavaria in 1917, he was transferred to Berlin in 1925. In February 1930 he
BIOGRAPHIES 213
was named secretary of state (prime minister) of the Vatican, under Pius XI, and
signed the concordats with Austria, Yugoslavia, and Nazi Germany.
In March 1939 he was elected pope after a single day of conclave. Having
worked to prevent the conflict, Pacelli maintained an attitude of silent neutral-
ity—an attitude that, notably, as concerns the Shoah, fueled endless discussions
and debate. His visit to the neighborhoods of Rome bombed during the war was
the first official trip by a pope outside Vatican walls since 1870. Upon the lib-
eration of the capital in June 1944, Pacelli supported the Christian Democrats
and mobilized Church structures in favor of the party. In 1949 the Holy Office
announced the excommunication of “the communists and their allies.” Pacelli was
an active partisan of the re-Christianization of Italian society.
A graduate of the Catholic university of the Sacred Heart in Milan, he was a pro-
fessor of economics and industrial policy at the University of Bologna. President
of the Il Mulino publishing house in Bologna from 1974 to 1978, he took part,
with his political mentor, Beniamino Andreatta (who had been his boss at the
university), in the birth of a free-trade faction within the Christian Democratic
Party. Minister of industry in 1978, Prodi founded the Nomisma research center in
1981, from which many of his future collaborators would emerge. In 1982 he was
named to head the largest industrial and financial holding company in Italy, the
publicly funded Institute for Industrial Reconstruction (known by its Italian ini-
tials, IRI), overseeing the majority of big Italian industries, heavy industry, naval
shipyards, nearly all banks, Alitalia, and the television system. Under his leader-
ship, IRI erased a large part of its deficit. After his term expired in 1989 he was
called back to service by the head of the government, Carlo Azeglio Ciampi, with
the aim of overseeing a substantial privatization of state properties.
With Andreatta’s support, Prodi was chosen as a candidate for prime minister
by the center-left coalition of the Ulivo (Olive Tree) in the 1996 elections. Victo-
rious, thanks to the divisions of the center-right, Prodi remained as head of the
government for two years, succeeding first in returning the lira to the European
Monetary System and later ushering it into the euro zone. He was ousted from
the government by Massimo D’Alema, leader of the Democrats of the Left (DS),
and was “indemnified” with the presidency of the European Commission. Under
his leadership, the euro would become the effective currency of eleven countries
in the European Union (EU), and ten new member countries would be co-opted
in the EU as of May 1, 2004.
Back in Italy after his term ended, he was again named leader of the center-left
coalition, narrowly carrying the elections of April 2006, and on May 16 he was
named president of the Council of Ministers. His government, which had more
than one hundred ministers and undersecretaries, resigned two years later.
214 BIOGRAPHIES
A soldier during the wars against Austria in 1848 and 1849, he became king of
Sardinia upon the abdication of his father, Charles Albert, following the defeat at
Novara, in 1849. Having concluded peace with Austria, he dissolved parliament. He
named Cavour prime minister, and a long diatribe began between the two, each
trying to diminish the authority, even the prerogatives, of the other. He maintained
close contacts with the conspirators, both democrats and republicans, and, accord-
ing to some sources, even with Felice Orsini, just days before the latter threw a bomb
at Napoleon III in Paris. He threatened to dismiss Cavour when the latter agreed to
cede Nice and Savoy to France in exchange for its war against Austria. In 1859, after
the armistice of Villafranca, he signed the peace with Vienna, and Cavour resigned.
At that point Victor Emmanuel accused the prime minister of “playing at making a
revolution” and, a few months later, made contact with Garibaldi and encouraged
his plan for the invasion of the Kingdom of the Two Sicilies.
Parliament named him king of Italy in March 1861. He decided to keep the
dynastic numeral “II” to underline continuity with the Kingdom of Sardinia and
the Kingdom of Italy.
216 BIOGRAPHIES
Son of King Humbert I, he ascended to the throne upon his father’s assassina-
tion in 1900. Considered a liberal, he left substantial latitude to his prime min-
isters, in particular Giovanni Giolitti. During the early years of his reign, Italy
evolved toward a system of constitutional monarchy. During the war he partici-
pated actively in overturning alliances that led Italy to be at war against the central
empires. In October 1922, when the Fascists invaded the capital, he refused to sign
the state of siege, and gave to Mussolini responsibility to form the new govern-
ment. After the murder of Giacomo Matteotti, he was a key supporter of the Fas-
cist head of the government. Removed from real responsibility, after the conquest
of Ethiopia he was proclaimed emperor, and after the conquest of Albania, its
king. In 1938 he signed the laws against the Jews, making them enforceable. When
the end of the conflict was in sight, he organized a coup d’état and had Musso-
lini arrested, replacing him with Marshal Pietro Badoglio. When the armistice was
announced on September 8, 1943, he fled with the latter and a large part of the
new government, without leaving any directive to the military, and sought Anglo-
American protection. While Mussolini, freed by the Germans, gave birth to the
social republic, Victor Emmanuel declared war on Germany. Having confided the
regency to his son Humbert, he abdicated only a month before the institutional
referendum of June 1946, which transformed Italy into a republic.
Notes
Introduction
1. According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the GDP of the People’s Repub-
lic of China and Hong Kong was $1.817 billion in 2004, while that of Italy was $1.680
billion. According to the World Bank, China and Hong Kong had a GDP of $1.812
billion, while that of Italy was $1.672 billion. IMF, World Economic Outlook database,
September 2005; World Bank, World Development Indicators database, July 1, 2006.
According to these Washington-based organizations, China had also surpassed France
and Great Britain in terms of GDP.
2. For the range of statistical information, see Vera Negri Zamagni, Dalla periferia al
centro. La seconda rinascita economica dell’Italia (1861–1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1990), 465. For the 2005 estimate see https://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook/
rankorder/2078rank.html. According to the same source, calculating purchase power
parity, the GDP of Italy was eighth in the world rankings in 2006 after the United
States, China, Japan, India, Germany, the UK, and France.
3. Sergio Romano, interviewed in Specchio, supplement of La Stampa, February 1, 1997.
4. The European Innovation Scoreboard, a body of the European Union (EU), ranked
the Italian education system twenty-first out of twenty-five in 2006 (http://trendchart
.cordis.lu). According to data gathered by Marc Lazar, in 2002 spending on research
and development represented 1.16 percent of GDP, “well below that of the European
average.” In terms of high-tech patents, Italy had only 7.1 per million inhabitants,
compared with a European average of 26.45 in Germany and 32 in France and the UK.
Lazar, L’Italie à la derive: Le moment Berlusconi (Paris: Perrin, 2006), 132. According
to the World Economic Forum, Italy was in forty-second place (out of 115 countries
studied) in 2006 for its level of investment in research and development, its coop-
eration between universities and business, and the quality of scientific education; in
ninety-first position regarding the rubric “absorption of technology into business
practice.” Statistics offered by Giuseppe Cassini, Gli anni del declino: La politica estera
del governo Berlusconi, 2001–2006 (Milan: Bruno Mondadori, 2007), 18.
5. Luciano Gallino, La scomparsa dell’Italia industriale (Turin: Einaudi, 2003), 3.
6. Zeffiro Ciuffoletti, Stato senza nazione. Disegno di storia del Risorgimento e dell’Unità
d’Italia (Naples: Morano, 1993), 311, 312.
7. G. Mammarella and P. Cacace, La politica estera dell’Italia. Dallo Stato unitario ai giorni
nostri (Bari: Laterza, 2006), vi. These authors return to this question at several points,
from section 4, chapter VIII, sections 1 and 2 of chapter IX, in particular pages 277,
278, 280, and 281.
218 NOTES
8. Giulio Bollati, L’Italiano. Il carattere nazionale come storia e come invenzione (Turin:
Einaudi, 1983), 40.
9. Sergio Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 201.
10. “Europe should be again to us the External Commissary, the Bogeyman who force this
anarchical and bungling country to pull itself together” Federico Rampini, Germaniz-
zazione: Come cambierà l’Italia (Bari: Laterza, 1996), 20.
11. Mario Monti, Intervista sull’Italia in Europa, under the direction of Federico Rampini
(Bari: Laterza, 1998), 164.
12. Statistics taken from the annual report of the governor of the Banca d’Italia Mario
Draghi (see Corriere della Sera, June 1, 2006); Hugues Portelli, L’Italie de Berlusconi
(Paris: Buchet Chastel, 2006), 14; Marc Lazar, L’Italie à la derive, 111, 112; Cassini, Gli
anni del declino, 18, 19.
13. Register (or Fund) for the South, created in 1950 in order to stimulate economic
growth and development in the south of the country. It was given a new status in 1984.
14. The Institute for Industrial Reconstruction (IRI) was an organization set up by the
Italian government in 1933, initially to rescue floundering companies that could no
longer afford to repay their creditors. In the postwar period, the IRI owned many
diverse businesses such as the highway system, public television, Alitalia Airlines, 80
percent of the most important banks, telecommunications companies, and several
industries (food, iron and steel, shipyards, vehicles, Alfa Romeo, etc.).
15. In Italy, deputies have immunity from legal prosecution as long as Parliament is in
session, unless Parliament itself authorizes the prosecution of one of its members.
16. Raffaele Romanelli, L’Italia liberale (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 212. The use of Sinistra
and Destra in Italian allows us to distinguish from the left and right defined by the
parliamentary “geography” of the twentieth century.
17. This phrase was made famous by Massimo D’Alema’s book Un paese normale. La
Sinistra e il futuro dell’Italia (Milan: Mondadori, 1995).
18. Shoeshine (Italian: Sciuscià, 1946) and Ladri di biciclette (released in English as The Bicy-
cle Thief or Bicycle Thieves, 1948) are two of Vittorio De Sica’s major neorealist works.
19. Edward C. Banfield, Moral Basis of a Backward Society (New York: Free Press, 1958),
118, 139, 155, 156, 161.
20. Roberto Cartocci, Mappa del Tesoro: Atlante del capitale sociale in Italia (Bologna: Il
Mulino, 2007), 13.
Foreword
8. Quoted by Giorgio Candeloro, Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. II, Dalla Restaurazione alla
rivoluzione nazionale, 1815–1846 (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1958), 27. The Kingdom of Italy
included, in 1810, the regions of Lombardy (augmented by the province of Novara and
the zone of Tortona), Veneto, and part of Emilia, Romagna, and the Marche.
9. This approximate valuation comes from different calculations suggested by J. M. Roberts,
Italia, in Storia del mondo moderno, vol. x (Milan: Garzanti, 1969), 499; Marco Meriggi,
“Borghesie,” in Dizionario storico dell’Italia unita, ed. Bruno Bongiovanni and Nicola
Tranfaglia (Bari: Laterza, 1996), 73, 74; Didier Musiedlak, “Construction politique et
identité nationale,” in L’Italie, une nation en suspens, ed. I. Diamanti, A. Dieckhoff,
M. Lazar, D. Musiedlak (Brussels: Editions Complexe, 1995), 30.
10. Carlo Cattaneo, L’insurrezione di Milano nel 1848 e la successiva guerra (Turin: Loescher,
1968), 6 (first edition, Paris, September 1848). By some calculations, the Austrian trea-
sury absorbed some two-thirds of the annual active budget of the Lombard–Venetian
Kingdom. Candeloro, Storia dell’Italia moderna, 23–24.
11. Smith, “L’Italia”, 722.
12. Quoted by Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 109. Massimo d’Azeglio served as prime minister
of the Sardinian kingdom on several occasions.
13. Paul Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers (London: Fontana Press, 1989), 234.
14. The phrase was created by Francesco Crispi: “Cavour? What did he finally do, Cavour?
Nothing but to diplomatize the revolution » - as cited in Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 149.
15. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 149.
16. Sergio Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 14.
17. Quoted by Smith, L’Italia, 732.
18. “Napoleon III will conclude a peace with Austria and stifle all efforts of the Italians
to carry on the war . . . but, should Austria be worsted in the fight, that peace will be
concluded on the Adige, which will leave the whole of Venice and part of Lombardy in
the hands of the hated Austrians.” Karl Marx, in the New York Daily Tribune, January
24, 1859.
19. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours, 9.
20. Senate minutes relative to the session of June 4, 1912.
21. “Se vogliamo che tutto rimanga come e, bisogna che tutto cambi”; this is the affirma-
tion made famous by the novel Il Gattopardo by Giuseppe Tomasi de Lampedusa.
22. The revolutionary republic of Rome (February to July 1849) provided Garibaldi with
his first opportunity to make his military virtues known: he defeated the French dis-
embarked in Civitavecchia and repulsed the Neapolitans in Palestrina and Velletri; he
was, however, defeated in the battle of Gianicolo on June 3. For the battles of Aspro-
monte, Bezzecca, and Mentana, see the biographical profile.
23. Italo Balbo, in Critica fascista, May 24, 1932, quoted by Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 165.
24. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento a nos jours, 21.
Chapter 1
Chapter 2
1. José Gil, “Nazione,” in Enciclopedia Einaudi, vol. IX, ed. Ruggiero Romano (Turin: Ein-
audi, 1980), 851.
2. Emmanuel Joseph Sieyès, Écrits politiques (Paris: Edition des archives contemporaines,
1994), 121.
3. Limes 1993, no. 1–2:10. The first article in this edition was a discussion on the theme
“In Search of the National Interest.”
4. This monograph-style edition had the thematic title “A che serve l’Italia” (What good
is Italy) and the subtitle “Perché siamo una nazione” (This is why we are a nation).
5. Lucio Caracciolo, “Editorial,” Limes 1994, no. 4:9.
6. Federico Fubini, “A Bruxelles è tramontato il tricolore,” Limes 1996, no. 3:208. Fubini is
a researcher and a journalist for the Corriere della Sera.
7. Carlo Jean, “La nostra sicurezza nel mondo balcanizzato. Linee-guida per una politica
estera e di difesa coerente,” Limes 1994, no. 4:202. General Jean was at the time the
president of the Centro Alti Studi per la Difesa (Center for Advanced Defense Studies).
8. Patrizio Bianchi, “Dove stanno i nostri interessi economici,” Limes 1994, no. 4:214. At
the time he wrote the article, Bianchi was a professor of economics for the European
Community in Bologna.
9. Jacopo Turri, “Scene da una secessione,” in Limes 1996, no. 3:.
10. Corriere della Sera, June 8, 1995.
11. La Stampa, November 1, 1995.
12. Corriere della Sera, June 1, 1996.
13. Sergio Romano, “Così muore una nazione,” La Stampa, January 11, 1996.
14. Interview with Romano Prodi, Limes 1996, no.3:24.
NOTES 221
15. Antonio Maccanico was secretary to the president of the republic under Sandro Per-
tini and Francesco Cossiga, president of Mediobanca (1987–1988), senator and min-
ister on several occasions, notably minister of institutional reforms in the Prodi and
D’Alema governments.
Chapter 3
1. Antonio Gramsci, Letteratura e vita nazionale (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1975), 88.
2. Gramsci, Letteratura e vita nazionale, 138.
3. Giorgio Rumi, “Povera Padania, triste storia la sua,” Liberal, October 1996.
4. See Silvio Lanaro, “Le élites settentrionali e la storia italiana,” Meridiana, no. 16, 1993.
5. The text was C. Cattaneo, Notizie naturali e civili su la Lombardia (1844), now Storia
della Lombardia (Milan: Rusconi, 1992).
6. La città considerata come principio ideale delle istorie d’Italia (1855), now Storia della
Lombardia.
7. G. Rumi, “Povera Padania, triste storia la sua,” Liberal, no. 19, October 1996.
8. Cattaneo, Notizie naturali e civili, 138.
9. Cattaneo, Notizie naturali e civili, 163. According to the calculations of Vera Zamagni,
in 1857 Lombardy produced a value corresponding to 238 lira per hectare, which was
slightly less than 1.5 times the production of Piedmont (169 lira), approximately twice
that of Tuscany (117 lira), 3 times that of the Kingdom of the Two Sicilies (81 lira), and
3.5 times that of the State of the Church (68 lira). Dalla periferia al centro. La seconda
rinascita economica dell’Italia (1861-1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 42.
10. Cattaneo, Notizie naturali e civili, 167.
11. Marco Meriggi, Breve storia dell’Italia settentrionale, dall’Ottocento ad oggi (Rome:
Donzelli, 1996), 152.
12. Fausto Fonzi, Crispi e lo Stato di Milano (Milan: Giuffrè, 1965). The “State of Milan”
was, according to Francesco Crispi’s polemical description, a coalition between Mila-
nese industry, the democrats, the Socialists, and a part of the Catholic world organized
against the Africa policy of the Sicilian prime minister. During hostile street demon-
strations organized in Milan during the Abyssinian War, people shouted slogans of
support for the Ethiopian Negus Menelik. Felice Cavallotti (1842–98) was a radical
politician, poet, and dramatic author.
13. Filippo Turati, “Proemio al programma comunale dei socialisti milanesi” Critica Soci-
ale, 20(9): 134–37, May 1, 1910.
Chapter 4
1. See Ernesto Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1998), 81.
2. This was in “Il carattere nazionale come storia e come invenzione,” published in 1976
in the first volume of La Storia d’Italia (Turin: Einaudi), and republished as a book
under the very similar title L’Italiano. Il carattere nazionale come storia e come invenzi-
one (Turin: Einaudi, 1983).
3. “Il carattere nazionale come storia e come invenzione,” 40.
4. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana, 130, 131.
5. The revolt known as “the Sicilian Vespers” was organized in Palermo by the Sicilian
nobility to “avenge” the Swabians, who had recently been vanquished by the Planta-
genets after the death of Frederick I Barbarossa. It was at the beginning of Spanish
222 NOTES
domination of the Aragonese and, some say, the birth of the Mafia. The revolt of the
Ciompi (wool workers) of Florence in 1378 was probably the revolt in which the class
characteristics of the protagonists were the clearest. Nonetheless, it also led to the
uprising of the “very slim people” under the impulse of a leader, Michele di Lando,
who did not hesitate to betray the Ciompi and pass over to the “Arti maggiori” (Major
Guilds) This revolt ended with the workers’ defeat and the definitive political crisis
of the Commune of Florence. Masaniello (1620–1647; his real name was Tommaso
Aniello), led the revolt of the Neapolitan commoners of 1647 against tax-collection
bureaus. Named “captain general of the most loyal people” by the viceroy of Naples,
he was later killed by his own partisans. Finally, Cola di Rienzo took advantage of the
vacancy in the pontifical seat in Rome in 1347 and was named “tribune of the peo-
ple” with the support of Clement VI, one of the Avignon popes. A victim of his own
ambition, he defied Emperor Charles IV, who imprisoned him. Returned to Rome, he
ended the anarchy of the city before being captured and killed by the populace.
6. Indro Montanelli and Roberto Gervaso, L’Italia dei secoli d’oro (Milan: Rizzoli, 1967),
135; Luigi Barzini, The Italians: A Full-Length Portrait Featuring Their Manners and
Morals (New York: Touchstone, 1996); Giuseppe Prezzolini, The Legacy of Italy (New
York: Vanni, 1948).
7. This image, which appeared in the Rümische Geschichte, was repeated by G. Prezzolini.
8. Johann Gottlieb Ficthe, Discours à la nation allemande (Addresses to the German
Nation), Paris: Imprimerie nationale, 1992), 54.
9. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana, 155.
10. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana, 131.
11. The phrase comes from Anne-Marie Thiesse, La création des identités nationales.
Europe XVIIIème-XXème siècle, Paris: Seuil, 1999, 161.
12. “Catonism,” according to the American sociologist Barrington Moore, is the “rhe-
torical glorification of the peasant as the backbone of society.” Barrington Moore, Jr.,
Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Lord and Peasant in the Making of the
Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1993), 491–96.
13. Tommaso Garzoni, Piazza universale di tutte le professioni del mondo, e nobili et ignobili
(Venice: Gio Battista Somascho, 1586); Giuseppe Baretti, An Account of the Manners
and Customs in Italy: With Observations on the Mistakes of Some Travelers, With Regard
to That Country (London: T. Davies, 1768).
14. Prezzolini, The Legacy of Italy, 220.
15. Quoted by Claudio Varese, “Teatro, prosa, poesia,” in Storia della Letteratura Italiana,
vol. V, ed. Emilio Cecchi and Natalino Sapegno (Milan: Garzanti, 1967), 736.
16. Vareses, “Teatro, prosa, poesia,” 58.
17. Paolo Greppi, La Rivoluzione francese nel carteggio di un osservatore italiano, vol. 1
(Milan: Hoepli, 1900–1904), 360. Greppi was the “finance minister” of the Cisalpine
Republic, of which Melzi d’Eril was vice president.
18. “Our revolution being a passive one, the only way it could prevail was by conquering
the opinion of the people,” wrote Cuoco in his famous Saggio storico sulla rivoluzione
napoletana del 1799. In order to return King Ferdinand IV to the throne, Cardinal Fab-
rizio Ruffo di Bagnara organized the Army of the Holy Faith (whose adherents were
thus referred to as Sanfedisti), led by famous and pitiless outlaws, but enjoying vast
support among the peasant masses of the kingdom.
NOTES 223
Chapter 5
24. Quoted by Elena Aga Rossi, Dal partito popolare alla democrazia cristiana (Bologna:
Cappelli, 1969), 22.
25. Giuseppe Mazzini, Dei doveri dell’uomo (Genoa: Giovanni Ricci Editore, 1922), 18.
26. Tullio De Mauro, Storia linguistica dell’Italia unita (Bari: Laterza, 1963), 43, 44.
Chapter 6
1. According to figures suggested by Raffaele Romanelli, the movement led to 257 deaths,
1,099 injuries, and 3,788 arrests. Rosario Romeo, L’Italia liberale (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1990), 156.
2. Giacomo Devoto, Il linguaggio d’Italia (Milan: Rizzoli, 1974), 306, 308.
3. T. de Mauro, Storia linguistica dell’Italia unita (Rome: Laterza, 1984), 16.
4. T. de Mauro, Storia linguistica dell’Italia unita, 92, 93. Examples of the structural inad-
equacy cover more than five pages of de Mauro’s text.
5. E. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1998), 107.
6. T. de Mauro, Storia linguistica dell’Italia unita, 46.
7. A thesis on dialectology written in 1968 was entirely devoted to the “differences, espe-
cially of a lexical character, between one zone of the city and another” of the town of
Asti. Maria Grazia Socco, “Per una topografia linguistica di Asti” (thesis, University of
Turin, 1967–68), 1, 2. Keep in mind that, when the research published in this thesis was
carried out, Asti had only some 75,000 inhabitants (76,151 in the 1971 census).
8. Antonio Gramsci, Gli intellettuali e la formazione della cultura (Turin: Einaudi, 1953),
23.
9. Among others, Luigi Settembrini, Edoardo Scarfoglio, Carlo Dossi, as well as the Tus-
cans Giosuè Carducci and Pietro Fanfani.
10. The data come from the ministerial survey of 1864–65; quoted by de Mauro, Storia
linguistica dell’Italia unita, 40.
11. This sociolinguistic distinction between the countryside and the cities was intro-
duced by Marcel Cohen in Pour une sociologie du language (Paris: Albin Michel, 1956),
139–40.
12. Matteo Giulio Bartoli, “I dialetti dell’Italia settentrionale,” in Piemonte, 5th ed. (Milan:
Touring Club Italiano, 1930), 83.
13. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 39.
14. Amadeo Bordiga, I fattori di razza e nazione nella teoria marxista (Milan: Iskra Edizioni,
1976), 80.
15. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 40.
16. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana, 123.
17. Galli della Loggia explains that “in France, in Spain and in Austria—which is to say in
all the other large Catholic countries—a religiously inspired political and ideological
perspective . . . was consciously assumed by the national monarchy” (L’identità, 127).
18. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 63.
19. G. Prezzolini, The Legacy of Italy (New York: Vanni, 1948), 237.
20. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 59, 60.
21. Eugene of Savoy-Carignan-Soisson (1663–1736) led the Austrian army in its victori-
ous campaigns against the Turks of Zenta in 1697 and again in Petrovaradin, in Temes-
var, and, especially, in Belgrade (1716–1717), and against the French during the War
of Spanish Succession. He was also governor of Milan and a diplomat (the peace of
Rastadt in 1709 and of Passarowitz in 1718).
22. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 60.
NOTES 225
23. Pasquale Villari, Di chi è la colpa? O sia La Pace e la guerra (Milan: Tipografia di Zanetti
Francesco, 1866), 31. Villari (1826–1917) was a famed historian. The “quadrilateral”
was a territory controlled by four Austrian fortresses that had allowed Vienna’s army—
during the wars of 1848, 1859, and 1866—to defend the western accesses to Venice
while also guarding communications avenues with the center of the empire via Tren-
tino and the Tirol.
24. A. Gramsci, Letteratura e vita nazionale (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1975), 86.
25. Manlio Graziano, “Le philosophe militant,” in L’Internationaliste no. 17–18, July–August
2001.
26. Melchiorre Cesarotti (1730–1808) was a teacher of rhetoric and ancient literature. The
text from which the quotation is taken is the Saggio sulla filosofia delle lingue applicata
alla lingua italiana (Padoua: Penada, 1785).
27. French became an official language of the Italian departments of the empire in 1809
(including, roughly speaking, the modern regions of Piedmont, Liguria, Tuscany, and
Latium), along with Italian.
28. Vittorio Alfieri, La vita Turin: Unione Tipografico Editrice Torinese, 1948, 168, 169.
29. Francesco de Sanctis, Storia della letteratura italiana (Milan: Bietti, 1963), 810, 811. De
Sanctis (1817–1883), the most important Italian literary critic of the nineteenth cen-
tury, took part in the revolution of 1848 in Naples. Later (1878–1882), he was minister
of education.
30. Quoted by T. de Mauro, Storia linguistica, 281.
31. Carlo Muscetta, “Niccolò Tommaseo,” in Storia della letteratura italiana, vol. VII, ed.
Emilio Cecchi and Natalino Sapegno (Milan: Garzanti, 1969), 750.
32. Edoardo Scarfoglio, Il libro di don Chisciotte (Naples: L’Editrice Italiana, 1919), 103,
104.
33. S. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 33.
34. Gramsci, Letteratura e vita nazionale, 252.
Chapter 7
1. Quoted by Gianfranco Lotti, L’avventurosa storia della lingua italiana (Milan: Bom-
piani, 2000), 121. Balbo’s text is Del naturale dei Piemontesi (Florence, 1855).
2. Quoted by Aurelio Lepre in Italia, addio? Unità e disunità dal 1860 a oggi (Milan: Mon-
dadori, 1994), 41.
3. E. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1998), 61.
4. See Gaston Tuaillon, “Le frontiere linguistiche (Il caso Piemonte),” in La frontiera da
Stato a nazione. Il caso Piemonte, ed. Carlo Ossola, Claude Raffestin, and Mario Ric-
ciardi (Rome: Bulzoni, 1987), 221.
5. The royal family’s entrance into the new capital of Turin took place on February 7,
1563. In October 1581, Montaigne wrote of Turin: “French is widely spoken here, and
all the people of the country seem quite affectionate toward France. The common
language has only Italian pronunciation but it is essentially composed of our own
expressions.” M. de Montaigne, Journal du voyage de Michel de Montaigne en Italie par
la Suisse & l’Allemagne en 1580 & 1581 (Paris: Chez Le Jay Librairie, 1774), 154.
6. Dante Alighieri, De vulgari eloquentia, vol. I, XV, 7
7. Quoted by T. de Mauro, Storia linguistica dell’Italia unita (Rome-Bari: Laterza, 1984),
287. After 1848 Costanza Arconati (1800–1871), born in Vienna, followed her hus-
band, the Milanese marquis Giuseppe, to Belgium and to Turin, where she held a polit-
ical and literary salon open to exiles of the other Italian states.
226 NOTES
Chapter 8
1. G. Leopardi, “Discorso sopra lo stato presente del costume degli Italiani” (1824), in Tutte
le opere, vol. 1 (Firenze: Sansoni, 1969), 971.
2. S. Cassese, Lo Stato introvabile. Modernità e arretratezza delle istituzioni italiane (Rome:
Donzelli, 1998), 53.
3. So said the deputy Niccola Marselli, quoted by Alberto Caracciolo, Stato e società civile.
Problemi dell’unificazione italiana (Turin: Einaudi, 1960), 69.
4. Open letter from Sicily to the former Prime Minister Massimo d’Azeglio, in August
1861. D’Azeglio had resolutely opposed the Roman solution starting in March 1861.
5. The phrase comes from the Milanese federalist Giuseppe Ferrari, quoted by Denis
Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia dal 1861 al 1997 (Rome: Laterza, 1997), 73.
6. A. Caracciolo, Stato e società civile, 28.
7. A. Caracciolo dated from the 1910s the beginning of this “anti-Roman polemic.” Roma
capitale. Dal Risorgimento alla crisi dello Stato liberale (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1999), 63.
Emilio Gianni notes that, in the first fifteen years of the twentieth century, the Latium
influence in governments doubled when compared to forty years earlier, reaching 6.1
percent of all ministers. E. Gianni, “Le influenze regionali nei poteri governativi,” in
Lotta comunista 1985, nn. 182, 183, 185.
8. Quoted by A. Caracciolo, Stato e società civile, 67.
9. G. Salvemini, L’Italia politica nel secolo XIX (1925), today in Scritti sul Risorgimento
(Milan: Feltrinelli, 1961), 433.
10. P. Gobetti, “Motivi di storia italiana. Socialismo di Stato,” La rivoluzione liberale no. 15,
May 22, 1923.
11. See A. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento (Turin: Einuadi, 1949), 69, 70.
NOTES 227
12. E. Gianni, “Le influenze regionali nei poteri governativi,” art. cit. One should keep in
mind that some of the men elected in regions other than Piedmont, such as the
Tuscan Ricasoli and the Emilians Minghetti and Farini, were considered “Piedmon-
tized,” having spent the majority of their political careers in Piedmont as exiles.
A particular case is that of Agostino Depretis, who had been elected to the Pied-
montese parliament starting in 1848 as a deputy of Stradella, a city in Piedmont
until 1859, when it was incorporated into the province of Pavia and, consequently,
“Lombardized.” It is thus not entirely accurate to consider Depretis, who headed
most of the thirteen ministerial teams during the Sinistra period (1876–91), as rep-
resenting Lombardy.
13. The data come from a study by Francesco Saverio Nitti, Il bilancio dello Stato dal 1862
al 1896–97 (Naples, 1900), cited by A. Caracciolo, Stato e società civile, 124.
14. E. Ragionieri, Politica e amministrazione nella storia dell’Italia unita (Rome: Editori
Riuniti, 1979), 136, 137. One must consider that the prefects who had been career
bureaucrats were but a minority in a corps dominated by men who had come directly
from political careers, leaving one to suppose—for want of specific data—that the
incidence of Piedmontese among prefects was much greater than what is cited above.
15. During World War I, the Lombards, for the first time, had a greater presence in Italian
government (15.2 percent of ministerial posts) than the Piedmontese (13.1 percent);
under fascism, the subalpine presence dropped further, to 6.1 percent.
Chapter 9
1. Note sent to Italian embassies abroad on August 24, 1861, quoted by S. Romano, His-
toire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 28.
2. G. Prezzolini, L’Italia finisce, ecco quel che resta (Milan: Rusconi, 1994), 210–22.
3. See G. Candeloro, Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. V, La costruzione dello Stato unitario,
1860–1871 (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1968), 47; Christopher Seton-Watson, L’Italia dal liber-
alismo al fascismo (Bari: Laterza, 1973), 31; V. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro (Bolo-
gna: Il Mulino, 1990), 37–39, 92; Denis Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia dal 1861 al 1997
(Rome-Bari: Laterza, 1997), 50.
4. Smith, Storia d’Italia, 52.
5. According to Romeo, the southern emigrants, who composed nearly the entirety of the
provisional government of the south (in the autumn of 1860) were “fierce adversar-
ies” of autonomy (R. Romeo, Dal Piemonte sabaudo all’Italia liberale [Rome: Laterza,
1974], 274), and they had “become almost strangers to the country” (G. Candeloro, La
costruzione dello Stato unitario [Milan: Feltrinelli, 1968], 127).
6. Out of hatred for France, Mazzini had described the Sanfedisti revolt of 1799 as “an
atrocious war, but a national one.” Franco Della Peruta, Politica e società nell’Italia
dell’Ottocento. Problemi, vicende e personaggi (Milan: Franco Angeli, 1999), 13.
7. Salvatore Lupo, “Mezzogiorno,” in Dizionario storico dell’Italia unita, ed. B. Bon-
giovanni and N. Tranfaglia (Rome: Laterza, 1997), 584.
8. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie, 27.
9. The quotations come from Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1998), 66, A. Lepre, Italia, addio? Unità e disunità dal 1860 a oggi (Milan: Mondadori,
1994), 4, and A. Caracciolo, Stato e società civile. Problemi dell’unificazione italiana
(Turin: Einaudi, 1960), 68); on the Garibaldians, A. Lepre, Storia del Mezzogiorno nel
Risorgimento (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1974), 283, and E. Ragionieri, Politica e ammin-
istrazione nella storia dell’Italia unita (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1979), 91.
228 NOTES
Chapter 10
1. Among the most important texts are the 1989 essay by Carlo Tullio-Altan, “Populismo
e trasformismo” and the article by Giovanni Sabbatucci, “La soluzione trasformista.
Appunti sulla vicenda del sistema politico italiano” in Il Mulino (March–April 1990),
which was the point of departure for the book Il trasformismo come sistema (Rome:
Laterza, 2003); Giampiero Carocci, Il trasformismo dall’unità ad oggi (Milan: Unicopli,
1992); Riccardo Nencini, Il trionfo del trasformismo (Firenze: Loggia de’ Lanzi, 1996);
Sandro Rogari, Le origini del trasformismo (Rome-: Laterza, 1998); and perhaps the
most complete, Luigi Musella, Il trasformismo (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2003). In addition
are essays such as that by Piero Melograni, “Trasformismo vizio italiano,” published in
Corriere della Sera (March 17, 1993), and that of Alfio Mastropaolo, “Innovation ou
transformisme? D’une classe politique à l’autre . . .” in Politique à l’italienne (Paris:
Presses Universitaires de France, 1997).
2. Raymond Grew, “Il trasformismo: ultimo stadio del Risorgimento,” in Il Risorgimento
e l’Europa, ed. Vittorio Frosini (Catania: Bonanno, 1969).
3. A. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento (Turin: Einaudi, 1949), 70. Musella’s book begins with the
first of these two quotations.
4. See E. Galli della Loggia, L’identità italiana (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1998), 99; L. Musella, Il
transformismo (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2003), 9, 173; G. Carocci, Storia d’Italia dall’Unità
ad oggi (Milan: Feltrinielli, 1975), 43.
5. Raffaele Romanelli, Il transformismo (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 212.
6. R. Grew, quoted in Romanelli, Il transformismo, 59.
7. For Gramsci, the transformist operation certainly weakened the influence of the aris-
tocracy and landowners in the life of the state, but “it is impossible to speak of the
substitution of one class for another.” Romanelli, Il Risorgimento, 57.
8. Speech by Chateaubriand in the French House of Lords, on the death of the Count of
Sèze (Moniteur, June 20, 1828), quoted by Rosario Romeo, Cavour e il suo tempo (Bari:
Laterza, 1969), 283.
9. Quoted by Giampiero Carocci, Agostino Depretis e la politica interna italiana: 1876–
1887 (Turin: Einaudi, 1956), 612. By “disorganization,” Spaventa means what today we
probably would call “disarticulation.”
10. S. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 72–74.
11. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 58.
12. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 58.
13. See Arturo Carlo Jemolo, Chiesa e Stato in Italia. Dall’unificazione ai giorni nostri
(Turin: Einaudi, 1974), 3, 44.
14. Stefano Jacini explores these themes in an 1879 text, I conservatori e l’evoluzione natu-
rale dei partiti politici in Italia. See Giorgio Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico in Italia
(Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1982), 178, and Gabriele de Rosa, I conservatori nazionali. Bio-
grafia di Carlo Cantucci (Brescia: Morcelliana, 1962), 32–43.
15. Edoardo Soderini, Il pontificato di Leone XIII, vol. II (Milan: Mondadori, 1932), 20.
16. See G. Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico in Italia (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1982), 178.
17. Benedetto Croce, History of contemporary Italy (1871–1915) (Paris: Payot, 1929), 26.
18. La Repubblica, July 2, 1988.
19. Gianfranco Pasquino, “Interprétations du système politique italien,” in L’Italie
aujourd’hui. Situation et perspectives après le séisme des années 90, ed. Manlio Graziano
(Paris: L’Harmattan, 2004), 52.
20. C. Seton-Watson, L’Italia dal liberalismo al fascismo 1870–1925 (Bari: Laterza, 1973),
109 (original edition: Methuen, 1967)
230 NOTES
21. The stability of power offered by Depretis, Romanelli states, lies in the “capacity to turn
the classic institution of the vote of confidence through an attentive management of
extra-parliamentary crises, of sudden resignations, followed by an immediate renewal.”
R. Romanelli, L’Italia liberale ((Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 210. Let us remember that all
51 governments from 1945 to 1992 revolved around the Christian Democratic Party, and
31 of them were led by only six prime ministers (De Gasperi, Fanfani, Moro, Andreotti,
Rumor, and Craxi). Sabino Cassese remarked that the length of service of many Italian
ministers was no less than that of their counterparts in France or in Great Britain in the
same period. “Histoires et caractéristiques de l’État italien,” in Portrait de l’Italie actuelle,
ed. Sabino Cassese (Paris: La Documentation Française, 201), 27.
22. V. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro. La seconda rinascita economica dell’Italia (1861–
1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 210, 211. Concerning the incidence of the public
debt on GDP, it was 45 percent in 1861, 95 percent in 1876, 116 percent in 1889, and
119 percent in 1896, its high point.
23. S. Cassese, “Introduction,” in Portrait de l’Italie actuelle (Paris: La documentation fran-
çaise, 2001), 13.
24. The statistics come from annual general records of the State Accounts Department.
Regarding the decrease, we have to consider that entire sections of the public adminis-
tration (post and telecommunications from 1993, the agency of national roads - ANAS
- from 1995, the railways, etc.) are removed from the statistical sheets once the process
of their privatization began.
25. Arrigo Cervetto, “La tendenza generale del capitalismo italiano,” in L’ineguale sviluppo
politico: 1968–1979 (Milan: Editore Lotta Comunista, 1991), 86.
26. The tax rate in Italy was 25.8 percent of GDP in 1960 and 31.0 percent in 1980 (an
increase of 20.1 percent in 20 years); it rose to 39.5 percent of GDP in 1990 (an increase
of 24.05 percent in 10 years).
27. S. Romano, L’Italia scappata di mano (Milan: TEA Storica, 1995), 11.
28. In 1992 the Christian Democrats and Italian Socialist Party won 43.3 percent of the
vote, in 1994 they received 13.3 percent, and in 1996 they received 6.8 percent.
29. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 139, 149.
Chapter 11
1. For Valerio Castronovo (Storia economica d’Italia [Turin: Einaudi, 1995], 49, 51) growth
was 1.44 percent from 1862 to 1878; for ISTAT, it was 2.0 percent (1861–1881); and for
Stefano Fenoaltea, it was 2.2 percent for the same period (quoted by V. Zamagni, Dalla
periferia al centro [Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990], 108).
2. Denis Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia (Rome: Laterza, 1995), 98.
3. After the signing of the convention on navigation and the treaty on commerce between
Italy and France in 1863, imports from France rose from 233 million lire in 1862 to
346 million in 1865 (an increase of 48.5 percent) and exports to France went from 189
million lire to 188 million. G. Candeloro, Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. V, La costru-
zione dello Stato unitario 1860–1871 (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1968), 242. A large part of the
public debt issuances (which rose from 21 percent of total public spending in 1861
to 31 percent in 1866 through 1870) were subscribed abroad, and notably in France.
Christopher Seton-Watson, L’Italia dal liberalismo al fascismo, 1870–1925 (Bari: Lat-
erza, 1980), 24. Moreover, for the period 1861 through 1870, 325 million of the 789
million lire of gross investment (or 41.2 percent) came from abroad. See. R. Romeo,
Risorgimento e capitalismo (Bari: Laterza, 1959), 106.
NOTES 231
Chapter 12
1. The estimate comes from Vera Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1990), 464.
2. Enrico Cuccia (1907–2000) went to work for the Banca d’Italia in 1932, for the IRI in
1934, and for the Banca Commerciale in 1938; he was cofounder (in 1946) and direc-
tor (from 1982 until his death, honorary chairman) of Mediobanca SpA, the largest
Italian merchant bank following the suppression of mixed banks in 1936.
3. Gianni Toniolo, Storia economica dell’Italia liberale, 1850–1918 (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1988), 104. Remember that in the modern sense, the “lender of last resort” is the cen-
tral bank.
4. When Bonaldo Stringher became its director-general in 1900 (a position he held until
1928, when he was named governor, a role he kept until his death in 1930), the Banca
d’Italia had a privileged clientele, in competition with other banks. This proves that its
transformation into an organ of “monetary power” was the result of a process and not
of a preestablished plan.
5. The banks in question were the Banca Nazionale, Banco di Napoli, Banca Nazionale
Toscana, Banco di Sicilia, and Banca Toscana di Credito. The Banca Nazionale played a
central role among all these issuing banks, with (as of December 31, 1873) 67.7 percent
of total capital.
6. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 182.
7. Alexander Gerschenkron, Il problema storico dell’arretratezza economica (Turin: Ein-
audi, 1965), 84; Guido Baglioni, L’ideologia della borghesia industriale nell’Italia liberale
(Turin: Einaudi, 1974), 120; Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 140–45.
8. Paolo Farneti, Sistema politico e società civile (Turin: Giappichelli, 1971), 171. For the
quote from De Ruggiero (1888–1948), see Renzo De Felice, Gli intellettuali di fronte
al fascismo (Rome: Bonacci, 1985), 50. We should point out the different conclusion
232 NOTES
reached by Silvio Lanaro, who, in L’Italia nuova. Identità e sviluppo, 1861–1988 (Turin:
Einaudi, 1988), states that, from the beginning of unitary history, “with the excep-
tion of a few modest Catholic groups, Italian nationalism was markedly industrialist”
(p. 161).
9. B. Croce, Histoire de l’Italie contemporaine (Paris: Payot, 1929), 62, 63.
10. C. Cavour, “Des chemins de fer en Italie par le comte Petitti, Conseiller d’État du Roy-
aume de Sardaigne,” quoted by G. Candeloro, Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. V, La
costruzione dello Stato unitario, 1860–1871 (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1968), 37, 38.
11. Among the major works projects linked to this hypothesis we should mention the
extension of rail service to Brindisi (completed in January 1865) and the construction
of the Fréjus tunnel, inaugurated in 1871.
12. In 1862 only 1.59 percent of global tonnage was steam powered, compared to 11.1 per-
cent of English tonnage and 9.71 percent of French; moreover, the average vessel was a
mere 69 tons, compared to 170 tons for both British and French ships (see Candeloro,
Storia dell’Italia moderna, 40, 41). Zamagni notes that “even in 1913, one-third of the
Italian merchant marine was wind-powered” (Dalla periferia al centro, 131).
13. In Genoa alone, the number of shipyards rose from eight in 1868 to nineteen in 1873,
and having built, from 1870 to 1875, a yearly average of 70,000 tons of capacity, all Ital-
ian shipyards combined produced only 14,000 tons in 1880 and 11,000 the year after.
14. R. Romanelli, L’Italia liberale (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1979), 236.
15. The former thesis is supported by Romanelli (L’Italia liberale, 164), the latter by
C. Seton-Watson (L’Italia dal liberalismo al fascismo (Bari: Laterza, 1980), 74).
16. Luciano Cafagna, Dualismo e sviluppo nella storia d’Italia (Venice: Marsilio, 1989), 269.
The same observation is made by G. Candeloro in Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. VI, Lo
sviluppo del capitalismo e del movimento operaio, 1871–1896 (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1970), 21.
17. The number of new deputies comes from Romanelli (L’Italia liberale, 144), although
Candeloro puts the number at 184 (Storia dell’Italia moderna, 387).
18. In describing the regional vote breakdown, we consider the south to be the provinces
of the former Kingdom of the Two Sicilies plus Sardinia, the center to be the regions of
the former Papal States plus the former Grand Duchy of Tuscany, and the north to be
the other provinces (Piedmont, Liguria, Lombardy, and Venice).
19. D. Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia (Rome: Laterza, 1995), 132.
Chapter 13
1990), 101. Among the indicators of this “indifference,” we should also include the
near-total absence of any migratory flow between the two parts of the country (see
Cafagna, Nord e Sud, 46).
5. See Pasquale Villani, Mezzogiorno tra riforme e rivoluzione (Bari: Laterza, 1973),
195–197.
6. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 37–39.
7. David Abulafia, Le due Italie. Relazioni economiche tra il Regno normanno di Sicilia e I
comuni settentrionali (Naples: Guida, 1977).
8. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 38.
9. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 60.
10. P. Bevilacqua, Breve storia dell’Italia meridionale (Rome: Donzelli, 2005).
11. See Valerio Castronovo, “Il Piemonte,” in Storia d’Italia. Le regioni dall’Unità a oggi
(Turin: Einaudi, 1977), 4, 5, 146, 149.
12. From 1871 to 1881, the migration balance (emigration minus immigration) was nega-
tive, by 34,000 people a year for the north and 2,000 for the south; from 1881 to 1901,
62,000 people left the north and 47,000 left the south every year; and from 1951 to 1967,
in total, some 2.6 million people left the northern countryside and 1.5 million left the
south. Paolo Sylos Labini, Problemi dello sviluppo economico (Bari: Laterza, 1974), 116.
13. S. Lupo, “Mezzogiorno,” in Dizionario storico dell’Italia unita, 591.
14. Gianfranco Viesti, Abolire il Mezzogiorno (Rome-Bari: Laterza, 2003), 7.
15. Paolo Macry, La società contemporanea. Una introduzione storica (Bologna: Il Mulino,
1992).
16. A. Schiavone, Italiani senza Italia. Storia e identità (Turin: Einaudi, 1998), 103.
17. This was the neighborhood built in the southwestern area of the city, at the feet of the
Sant’Elmo hill during the reign of Charles V, under Vice-King Pierre of Toledo. It was
the working-class neighborhood.
18. One of the paradoxes of national Italian mythology is that it promotes the anti-imperial
leagues of the communes to the rank of founders of a supposed national conscience
against the invader from the north, whereas these leagues played a fundamental role
in the struggle to prevent Ghibelline unification against the papacy. The defeat of the
emperors allowed the pope to remain as arbiter of a fierce struggle between the “thou-
sand bell towers” until the eve of unification of the peninsula, without, however, suc-
ceeding in spreading the communal system through the kingdom of the south.
19. Sylos Labini, Problemi dello sviluppo economico (Bari: Laterza, 1974), 111. Labini places
the beginning of this process in the Bourbon era.
20. Labini, Problemi dello sviluppo economico, 112.
21. Letter quoted by A. Lepre, Italia, addio? Unità e disunità dal 1860 a oggi (Milan: Mon-
dadori, 1994), 33.
22. Letter from Cavour to Nigra, ambassador to Paris, on March 4, 1861.
23. Luciano Cafagna, La grande slavina. L’Italia verso la crisi della democrazia (Venice:
Marsilio, 1993), 19, 20.
24. G. Carocci, Il trasformismo dall’Unità a oggi (Milan: Unicopli, 1992), 14.
25. S. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 77.
Between 1861 and 1882, 29.7 percent of the lawyers present in the chamber were of
the Destra and 37.5 percent were of the Sinistra (without counting the extreme left);
from 1882 to 1900, only 15 percent of lawyers in the chamber were of the Destra, com-
pared to 40 percent of the Sinistra. See Fulvio Cammarano, “Sinistra storica,” in ed.
Bongiovanni and Tranfaglia, Dizionario storico dell’Italia unita, 830, 831.
26. Data cited by A. Caracciolo, Stato e società civile. Problemi dell’unificazione italiana
(Turin: Einaudi, 1960), 119.
234 NOTES
27. Jean Meynaud, Rapporto sulla classe dirigente italiana (Milan: Giuffrè, 1966), 44. Mey-
naud refers to the post–World War II situation, when this phenomenon, qualitatively
comparable, was to undergo a powerful quantitative acceleration.
28. S. Lanaro, L’Italia nuova. Identità e sviluppo. 1861–1988 (Turin: Einaudi, 1988), 110.
29. The 1904 law on the southern region of Basilicata would mark a veritable resort to “spe-
cial legislation” until the war in 1915. See Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 218, 219.
30. At the time of the first African expeditions, the Milan newspaper Italia del popolo cal-
culated that the Milanese were paying 89.85 lira in taxes per inhabitant, while the
national average was only 47.95 lira. Quoted by Lepre, Italia, addio? 81.
31. Filippo Turati, in Critica Sociale, October 16, 1891. Quoted by Lepre, Italia, addio? 83.
Chapter 14
Intellettuali e Chiesa all’inizio dell’era moderna, in Storia d’Italia, vol. IV, Intellettuali e
potere (Turin: Einaudi, 1978), 195.
16. Enzo Pace, La nation italienne en crise (Paris: Bayard, 1998), 122, 123.
17. Quoted by Prosperi, Intellettuali e Chiesa all’inizio dell’era moderna, 181.
18. Guerri, Gli italiani sotto la Chiesa, 132.
19. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 34.
20. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali e la formazione della cultura (Turin: Einaudi, 1953), 39.
21. On this subject, read chapter 5 (The Means of Seduction) of the T. Jones book, The Dark
Heart of Italy (London: Faber & Faber, 2003), 109–30.
22. Gramsci, Gli intellettuali, 57.
23. We must exclude from this list a series of minor authors, like Daniello Bartoli
(1608–1685), a historian and apologist for the Society of Jesus; Emanuele Tesauro
(1592–1672), an ex-Jesuit and theoretician of baroque poetry; and Giovanni Botero
(1540–1617), an ex-Jesuit and a theoretician of “raison d’État.”
24. G. Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico in Italia (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1982), 13. Bene-
detto Croce, Storia d’Europa nel secolo decimonono (Milan: Adelphi, 2007), 36, also
discusses the temporary agreement between the Church and a part of the “vanquished
states and classes.”
25. Antonio Gramsci, Note sul Machiavelli, sulla politica e sullo Stato moderno (Rome: Edi-
tori Riuniti, 1971), 307.
26. Croce, Storia d’Europa nel secolo decimonono, 36.
27. Croce, Storia d’Europa nel secolo decimonono, 35.
28. C. Cattaneo, “Vita di Dante” di Cesare Balbo, quoted by E. Passerin d’Entreves, “Ide-
ologie del Risorgimento,” in Storia della letteratura italiana, vol. VII, ed. E. Cecchi and
N. Sapegno (Milan: Garzanti, 1969), 326.
29. See Roger Aubert, “L’Eglise catholique de la crise de 1848 à la Première Guerre mondiale,”
in Nouvelle Histoire de l’Eglise, vol. V, L’Église dans le monde moderne, ed. J. Danielou,
L.-J. Rogier, R. Aubert, and D. Knowles (Paris: Seuil, 1975), 32.
30. Ippolito Nievo, Opere (Naples: Riccardo Ricciardi Editore, 1952), 1079, 1080.
31. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 72.
32. Gramsci, Il Risorgimento, 146.
Chapter 15
7. See Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico, 344; Guerri, Gli italiani sotto la Chiesa, 250;
D. Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia dal 1861 al 1997 (Rome: Laterza, 1997), 325; Luigi Goglia
and Fabio Grassi, Il colonialismo italiano da Adua all’Impero (Bari: Laterza, 1981), 139,
140; E. Ragionieri, Italia giudicata 1861–1945, vol. II (Turin: Einaudi, 1976), 385; Pietro
Grifone, Il capitale finanziario in Italia. La politica economica del fascismo (Turin: Ein-
audi, 1971), 21; V. Castronovo, Storia economica d’Italia (Turin: Einaudi, 1995), 182.
8. Jemolo, Stato e Chiesa in Italia, 57, 63.
9. The phrase “first economic miracle” comes from Michèle Merger, Un siècle d’histoire
industrielle en Italie (1880–1970). Industrialisation et sociétés (Paris: Sedes, 1998), 37.
10. V. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro. La seconda rinascita economica dell’Italia (1861–
1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 210.
11. Quoted by L. Musella, Il trasformismo (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1998), 84.
12. Antonio Gramsci, “I cattolici italiani,” in Avanti!, ed. Piemontaise, December 22, 1918;
available in A. Gramsci, Scritti politici, vol. I (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1973), 225, 226.
13. Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico, 375.
14. The data are from Guerri, Gli italiani sotto la Chiesa, 256.
15. Gramsci, “I cattolici italiani,” 228.
16. Candeloro, Il movimento cattolico, 25.
Chapter 16
1. Gian Enrico Rusconi, “Religione civile e identità italiana,” in Il Mulino, no. 5 (2003):833.
2. F. de Sanctis, Storia della letteratura italiana (1870) (Milan: Bietti, 1963), 859.
3. E. Gentile, La Grande Italia. Il mito della nazione nel XX secolo (Rome: Laterza, 2006), 46.
4. Quoted by Giacomo Perticone, La politica estera italiana dal 1861 al 1914 (Turin: ERI,
1961), 154, 155.
5. Quoted by A. Lepre, Italia, addio? Unità e disunità dal 1860 a oggi (Milan: Mondadori,
1994), 74, 75.
6. Filippo Turati, “1° maggio 1911,” in Critica Sociale, April 16, 1911.
7. Quoted by G. Belardelli, “Una nazione ‘senza anima’: la critica democratica del Risorgi-
mento,” in Due nazioni. Legittimazione e delegittimazione nella storia dell’Italia contem-
poranea, ed. L. Di Nucci and E. Galli della Loggia (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2003), 49.
8. The Socialist Party went from representing 2.95 percent of votes cast in the election of
1897 (15 deputies) to 6.5 percent in 1900 (33 deputies), 8.7 percent (41 deputies) in
1909, and 17.7 percent (52 deputies) in 1913 (not to mention the 5.2 percent of votes
and the 27 deputies of the two other Socialist parties that took part for the first time
in this election). We should note that the elections of 1913 were the first involving
universal suffrage for men.
9. According to the Italian Statistical Institute (ISTAT), it rose by 51 percent between
1900 and 1911; A. Gerschenkron estimated that it rose by 74 percent during that same
period, while S. Fenoaltea reports a rise of 118 percent. M. Merger, Un siècle d’histoire
industrielle en Italie (1880–1970). Industrialisation et sociétés (Paris: Sedes, 1998), 145.
One also gains a better understanding of the industrial dynamism of the period from
energy production, which doubled between 1898 and 1913 (while production of elec-
trical energy soared by a factor of 20). See V. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro. La
seconda rinascita economica dell’Italia (1861–1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 125.
10. Merger, Un siècle d’histoire industrielle, 50. The period in question was 1895 through 1913.
11. See Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro, 89.
12. Merger, Un siècle d’histoire industrielle, 148.
NOTES 237
13. Merger, Un siècle d’histoire industrielle, 37. The percentages are based on cities of more
than 20,000 inhabitants.
14. On the crisis of 1907, see Merger, Un siècle d’histoire industrielle, 51; P. Grifone, Il capi-
tale finanziario in Italia. La politica economica del fascismo (Turin: Einaudi, 1971), 18;
Richard A. Webster, L’imperialismo industriale italiano. Studio sul prefascismo 1908–
1915 (Turin: Einaudi, 1974), 45.
15. Il Regno, May 22, 1904, quoted by E. Gentile, La Grande Italia, 70.
16. Francesco Saverio Nitti, Il Partito Radicale e la nuova democrazia industriale. Prime
linee di un programma di un Partito Radicale (Turin: Sten, 1907).
17. Giampiero Carocci, Giolitti e l’era giolittiana (Turin: Einaudi, 1971), 149.
18. E. Corradini, Principii di nazionalismo (1910), in Scritti e discorsi, ed. L. Strappini
(Turin: Einaudi, 1980), 173, 174.
19. Principii di nazionalismo, 174.
20. E. Corradini, Le nazioni proletarie e il nazionalismo in Scritti e discorsi, ed. L. Strappini,
Turin: Einaudi, 1980, 186, 187.
21. P. Gobetti, “Il nazionalismo italiano”, in La Rivoluzione Liberale, September 20, 1922, in
La Rivoluzione liberale. Saggio sulla lotta politica in Italia, Turin: Einaudi 1995, 116.
22. See Merger, Un siècle d’histoire industrielle, 50, 51; Grifone, Il capitale finanziario in
Italia, 18, 19.
23. See. E. Ragionieri, L’italia giudicata, 1861–1945, vol. II (Turin: Einaudi, 1976), 385.
24. On the Libyan War, see Angelo del Boca, Gli italiani in Libia (Rome: Laterza, 1986) and
Italiani, brava gente? (Venice: Neri Pozza, 2005).
25. G. Salvemini, “Alla ricerca di una formula,” in L’Unità, March 14, 1913, quoted by Gen-
tile, La Grande Italia, 88.
26. Gobetti, Il nazionalismo italiano, 117, 119.
Chapter 17
1. E. Pace talks about “the most coherent attempt” in La nation italienne en crise (Paris:
Bayard, 1998), 72, 73. As to the Fascist “secular religion,” see Emilio Gentile, Il culto del
littorio. La sacralizzazione della politica nell’Italia fascista (Rome-Bari: Laterza, 1993).
2. The military defeat of Fascist Italy seems “to disqualify forever the slightest reference
to the nation,” wrote Marc Lazar, who dealt with this subject in the essay “La gauche,
la République et la nation,” in I. Diamanti, A. Dieckhoff, M. Lazar, and D. Musiedlak,
L’Italie, une nation en suspens (Brussels: Editions Complexe, 1995), 66.
3. For the data, see V. Castronovo, Storia economica d’Italia (Turin: Einaudi, 1995), 174.
4. Luigi Salvatorelli, Nazional fascismo (Rome: Libero, 2004), 22, 25, 28.
5. Giovanni Ansaldo (1895–1969), a contributor to La Rivoluzione liberale, asserted, in a
debate with Salvatorelli, that fascism’s origins were not among petit-bourgeois intellectuals,
but among the productive petite bourgeoisie (“La piccola borghesia,” in Il Lavoro, Genoa,
June 3, 1923). Ansaldo later became one of the most important journalists of the Fascist era.
Adriano Tilgher (1887–1941), a philosopher and literary critic, in his essay “Piccoli borghesi
al bivio” (Il Tempo, December 7, 1919, then in La crisi mondiale e saggi di socialismo e marx-
ismo [Bologna: Zanichelli, 1921]), emphasized the hostility toward the working class.
6. Speech delivered in late May 1915, quoted by D. Mack Smith, Storia d’Italia dal 1861 al
1997 (Rome-Bari: Laterza, 1997), 354.
7. According to S. Romano, 470,000 emigrants returned to Italy in the first months of the
European conflict, including 150,000 from France. Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento
à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 163.
238 NOTES
material interest of the nuclear family.” E. Banfield, The Moral Basis of a Backward
Society, New York: The Free Press, 9-10.
24. See Renzo De Felice, Un totalitarisme a l’italienne? (Paris: Presses de la Fondation
Nationale des Sciences Politiques, 1988), 138–40.
25. P. Milza and S. Bernstein, Le fascisme italien. 1919–1945 (Paris: Seuil, 1980), 277.
26. R. De Felice, Intervista sul fascismo (Rome: Laterza, 1975), 60. It is interesting to note
that the Hungarian-British journalist George Mikes (1912–1987), in his book on the
Italians, published in 1956, offered the same observation as the great historian of fas-
cism. He added an almost banal further observation that seems to have escaped those
who have criticized the feeble patriotic enthusiasm of the Italians and their army on
the eve of the war of 1940: “One cannot expect an army to put all its soul into a battle
if it knows that the decision to fight, on one side or the other, was taken by the flip of
a coin.” G. Mikes, Italy for Beginners (London: Allan Wingate, 1956), 76.
27. P. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Con-
flict from 1500–2000 (New York: Random House, 1987), 383.
28. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers, 386, 426.
29. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers, 430.
30. Thus, for example, contended Corrado Alvaro in 1944: “A large part of Italy hoped for
defeat from the first day of the war.” C. Alvaro, L’Italia rinunzia? (Palermo: Sellerio,
1986), 34.
31. Giuseppe Bottai, Diario. 1935–1944 (Milan: Rizzoli, 1982), 193.
32. Ernesto Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria (Rome: Laterza, 1996), 95.
Chapter 18
12. Vittorio Foa, Il cavallo e la torre (Turin: Einaudi, 1991), 137. Vittorio Foa was a founder
of the Action Party and was one of the most important postwar Socialists, with the
CGIL, the union linked to the PCI.
13. Estimates range from around 100,000 active members “if one excludes the 11th-hour
converts,” a figure advanced by Paul Ginsborg (Storia dell’Italia contemporanea (Turin:
Einaudi, 1988), 90), to the 223,639 “fighting partisans” suggested by Gianni Oliva (I
vinti e I liberati [Milan: Mondadori, 1994], 590).
14. Pietro Secchia, Aldo dice 26 x 1. Cronistoria del 25 aprile (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1973), 155. Pietro
Secchia (1903–1973) was the no. 2 man in the Communist Party during the Resistance.
15. W. Barberis, Il bisogno di patria (Turin: Einaudi, 2004), 84.
16. E. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria, op. cit., p. 70. “Naturally,” Galli della Loggia
continued, “the Republic will always be obliged to deny, at least officially, this double
truth. In the official declamations, in solemn written documents, in school books, it
will always, and only, be anti-Fascist.”
17. Jürgen Habermas, “L’identité des Allemands, une fois encore.” in Ecrits politiques. Cul-
ture, droit, histoire (Paris: Editions du Cerf, 1986), 245–63.
18. S. Romano, Histoire de l’Italie du Risorgimento à nos jours (Paris: Seuil, 1977), 232–34.
19. E. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria, 61. Moreover, he describes it as “radically
and manifestly foreign to the national community” (p. 72).
20. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria, 128.
21. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria, 67.
22. Remember that the Mussolinian adventure had begun under the auspices (and with
the money) of the French government and of the SFIO, the French Socialist party,
before finishing its arc with its hands and feet tied to Germany. See P. Milza and S.
Bernstein, Le fascisme italien. 1919–1945 (Paris: Seuil, 1980), 93, among others.
23. The Action Party, founded in 1942 and dissolved in 1947, was a very heterogeneous mix-
ture of diverse tendencies, united in the attempt to federate the non-Stalinist anti-Fas-
cists, but irremediably divided at the moment it proposed a governmental action plan.
24. Quoted by S. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana (Venice: Marsilio, 1992), 160. Mon-
signor de Luca (1898–1962) was a close collaborator of Cardinal Gasparri in the 1930s,
then of Cardinal Montini (the future Paul VI) and John XXIII. He was a mediator in
the Vatican’s contacts with the Communist Party and the Soviet Union.
25. See Gianni De Michelis, La lunga ombra di Yalta (Venice: Marsilio, 2003), 21, 22.
26. Quoted by Giuseppe Boffa, Storia dell’Unione Sovietica. 1917–1941. Lenin e Stalin.
Dalla rivoluzione alla seconda guerra mondiale (Milan: Mondadori, 1976), 504.
27. Palmiro Togliatti, La via italiana al socialismo (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1972), 38.
28. Quoted by Antonio Pellicani, Il papa di tutti. La Chiesa cattolica, il fascismo e il razzismo.
1929–1945 (Milan: Sugar, 1964), 31.
29. A. C. Jemolo, Chiesa e Stato in Italia. Dalla unificazione ai giorni nostri (Turin: Einaudi,
1977), 270.
30. Jemolo, Chiesa e Stato in Italia, 313.
31. See Renato Moro, La formazione della classe dirigente cattolica (1929–1937) (Bologna:
Il Mulino, 1979).
32. The “official” government of Badoglio and of the king; the “Italian Social Republic”
of Mussolini; the National Liberation Committee; the German military governor; and
the Allies.
33. Federico Chabod, L’Italia contemporanea (1918–1948) (Turin: Einaudi, 1994), 125.
34. See A. C. Jemolo, Chiesa e Stato in Italia, 314, 315; Guido Verucci, La Chiesa nella soci-
età contemporanea. Dal primo dopoguerra al Concilio Vaticano II (Bari: Laterza, 1988),
231, 232.
NOTES 241
35. Alcide De Gasperi, 1946, quoted by Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, 103.
36. See Gianni Baget Bozzo, Il partito cristiano al potere. La DC di De Gasperi e di Dossetti
(1945–1954), vol. I (Florence: Vallecchi, 1974), 255. Giuseppe Dossetti (1913–1996), a
university professor and resistance militant, was vice secretary of the Christian Demo-
cratic Party in 1945. A deputy since the Constituent Assembly, he abandoned political
life in 1958 to become a priest. He took part in the work leading up to the Second Vatican
Council and was a patron of Romano Prodi’s candidacy for prime minister in 1996.
37. For De Gasperi, as Andreotti writes, the defense of the currency was “the best guarantee
for savers, for employees, for the little people.” Andreotti, Intervista su De Gasperi, 106.
38. According to an ex-minister of the Communist Party, De Gasperi said, during a min-
isterial meeting in April 1947: “Experience has taught me that it is impossible today to
govern Italy without drawing into the new government, in one form or another, the
representatives of this fourth party, of the party of those who have the money and the
economic power.” Quoted by P. Ginsborg, Storia dell’Italia contemporanea, 100, 101.
39. Emilio Gianni, “La DC nasce come partito nordista,” in Lotta Comunista no. 149, Janu-
ary 1983.
40. Andreotti, Intervista su De Gasperi, 103. In the elections of 1948, the Christian Demo-
crats obtained 48.5 percent of the votes cast and won 305 of the 507 seats in the Cham-
ber of Deputies.
41. Manlio Graziano, “Trois idées sur les mutations de la vie politique italienne,” in L’Italie
aujourd’hui. Situation et perspectives après le séisme des années 90, ed. M. Graziano
(Paris: L’Harmattan, 2004), 17.
42. Andreotti, Intervista su De Gasperi, 33.
Chapter 19
7. Thus said the famous literary critic Luigi Russo in 1953, quoted in Nemici per la pelle.
Sogno americano e mito sovietico nell’Italia contemporanea, ed. Pier Paolo D’Attore
(Milan: Franco Angeli, 1991).
8. Pina Nuzzo, Congressi dal 1944 al 1968. Available at www.udinazionale.org, Archivio
centrale – Memoria.
9. Franco Paparo, “Pubblicazioni sulle questioni sessuali,” in Gioventù Nuova no. 11–12
(November–December 1950). In the review Sexual Digest, translated from the French,
one finds articles by Jacques Prévert, Francis Carco, and Roland Dorgelès, and in the
Italian version, pieces by Giovanni Papni, Luigi Barzini, Jr., and even texts by father
Agostino Gemelli and Pius XII.
10. Quoted by S. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana (Venice: Marsilio, 1992), 207. In
1950, according to Marta Boneschi, only 72 of 104 films obtained the censor’s stamp
of approval. Boneshi, Poveri ma belli. I nostri anni cinquanta (Milan: Mondadori,
1995), 287.
11. Carli, Cinquant’anni di vita italiana, 3, 4. It is noteworthy that Carli uses the phrase
“animal spirits” here in a sense opposite to that used by Keynes, to the extent that,
for the latter, the phrase referred to irrational behaviors when private investment is
left to itself.
12. Carli, Cinquant’anni di vita italiana, 3, 4.
13. Quoted by Lucio Villari, Il capitalismo italiano del Novecento (Bari: Laterza, 1972), 484,
522.
14. G. Carli, Intervista sul capitalismo italiano (Rome: Laterza, 1977), 89
15. V. Zamagni calculates that the number of farmers dropped from 8.6 million to 2 mil-
lion from the end of the war to the 1990s, and their share in the creation of GDP fell
from 23 percent to 5 percent. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro. La seconda rinascita
economica dell’Italia (1861–1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 442.
16. The law “for the defense of the consumer” was signed by the Christian Democrat
Giuseppe Togni in 1950, laying out a series of rules intended to block the rise of big
retailers.
17. The data were reported by Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, 183; Paolo Sylos
Labini, Saggio sulle classi sociali (Bari: Laterza, 1975), 49, 158; and Ginsborg, Storia
dell’Italia dal dopoguerra a oggi, 186, 187, 323.
18. Jacques Nobécourt, L’Italie à vif (Paris: Seuil, 1970), 45–48. The figure quoted comes
from a 1967 study. According to the government, Nobécourt says, they numbered
2,000; those who wanted to cut into this forest, he concludes, were never able even to
“carry out a count of the trees.”
19. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, 183.
20. L. Musella, Il trasformismo (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2003), 155, 156. For the functioning
of the commissions, see Nobécourt, L’Italie à vif, 56. On the nearly regular contribu-
tion of the PCI to the majority, see L. Cafagna, La grande slavina. L’Italia verso la crisi
della democrazia (Venice: Marsilio, 1993), 40; Carli, Cinquant’anni di vita italiana, 17;
and R. Cartocci, “L’Italia di tangentopoli e la crisi del sistema partitico,” in La coscienza
civile degli italiani. Valori e disvalori nella storia nazionale, ed. C. Tullio-Altan (Udine:
Gaspari Editore, 1997), 225.
21. Giuseppe Maranini, Storia del potere in Italia 1848–1967 (Milan: Corbaccio, 1995), 511.
22. Stephen Gundle, “L’americanizzaione del quotidiano. Televisione e consumismo
nell’Italia degli anni Cinquanta,” Quaderni Storici no. 62 (August 1986):561–94.
23. C. Alvaro, L’Italia rinunzia? (Milan: Bompiani, 1945), 33.
24. The data come from Ginsborg, Storia d’Italia dal dopoguerra ad oggi, 102, 103; Mis-
sione Americana per l’ERP in Italia, Divisione Informazioni, June 1951; George
NOTES 243
Chapter 20
1. The most complete text on this subject is that of Goffredo Fofi, L’immigrazione meridi-
onale a Torino (Milan: Feltrinelli, 1964).
2. S. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana (Venice: Marsilio, 1992), 290. This lack was also
underlined by E. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria (Rome: Laterza, 1996), 136.
3. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, 241.
4. See V. Zamagni, Dalla periferia al centro. La seconda rinascita economica dell’Italia
(1861–1990) (Bologna: Il Mulino, 1990), 17 for the period that preceded World War I;
Adriana Castagnoli and Emanuela Scarpellini, Storia degli imprenditori italiani (Turin:
Einaudi, 2003), 154–160, on the history of Italian businessmen abroad; and Richard
A. Webster, L’imperialismo industriale italiano. Studio sul prefascismo 1908–1915
(Turin: Einaudi, 1974), 357–74, on Italian economic expansion in the Balkans and in
Eastern Europe before 1914.
5. Telegram from A. Lessona, November 11, 1937, quoted by Fabienne Le Houerou,
L’épopée des soldats de Mussolini en Abyssinie, 1936–1938 (Paris: L’Harmattan, 1994),
156. Coffee exports fell from 15,822 tons in 1935 to 200 tons in 1939, and pelts from
4,984 tons in 1936 to 48 tons in 1939. While the commercial balance with Ethiopia was
active in 1935 (28.497 billion lira in imports and 21.508 billion lira in exports), in 1937
Italy was obliged to send merchandise to its colony worth 86.998 billion lira, and in
1939 it imported goods worth only 480 million lira. Richard Pankhurst, “A charter in
Ethiopian commercial history: Developments during the Fascist occupation, 1936–1941,”
in Ethiopia Observer vol. XIV (1971).
6. P. Sylos Labini, Problemi dello sviluppo economico (Rome: Laterza, 1974), 156.
7. Among the foreign entrepreneurs who “emigrated” to Italy, we should mention Gior-
gio Enrico Falck, Heinrich Mylius, Pietro Krumm, Giulio Richard, Roberto Lepetit,
Ulrico Hoepli, Otto Joel, and Federico Weil. From 1880 to 1890, foreigners held about
15 percent of industrial capital, a figure that had declined to 8 percent by 1913. The
foreign presence was more evident in the credit sector. The Banca Commerciale was
formed with 99 percent foreign capital, and the Credito Italiano owed its creation to
the capital of two German banks and one Italian bank. See Zamagni, Dalla periferia
244 NOTES
23. For the data on the PCI, see Marc Lazar, Maisons rouges. Les partis communistes français
et italien de la Libération à nos jours (Paris: Aubier, 1992), 397, 398.
24. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana, 363.
25. Edition of February 2, 1969, quoted by Smith, Cento anni di storia italiana, 546.
26. According to the Association of Victims of Terrorism, the political violence of the left
caused, between 1970 and 1989, the deaths of 118 people, including 18 between 1969
and 1977, 90 between 1978 and 1982, and 10 between 1983 and 1989 (see www.vittim-
eterrorismo.it). In the same years, the five attacks of the Questura on Milan (Decem-
ber 12, 1969, and May 17, 1973), Brescia (May 28, 1974), the Rome–Brenner train
(August 4, 1974), and the Boulogne station (August 2, 1980), which can certainly not
be blamed on leftist terrorism, claimed a total of 125 victims.
Chapter 21
1. On the reform of the public sanitary service, see P. Ginsborg, Storia d’Italia dal dopogu-
erra ad oggi. Società e politica, 1943–1988 (Turin: Einaudi, 1988), 528.
2. At the beginning of the 1980s, in the manufacturing sector, 90.6 percent of companies
had fewer than fifty employees (and, according to 1998 data, nearly 75 percent of these
had fewer than fifteen employees).
3. La Stampa, July 24, 1977.
4. Quoted by A. Cervetto, “Nuovi aspetti del riciclaggio sociale” (February 1989), in Cervetto,
Forze e forme del mutamento italiano (Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista, 1997), 209.
5. “I gioiellieri guadagnano meno dei maestri,” in Corriere della Sera, October. 14, 2006.
6. See Tullio De Mauro, “La culture et la langue,” in Portrait de l’Italie actuelle, ed.
S. Cassese (Paris: La Documentation Française, 2001), 136–43, and Storia linguistica
dell’Italia unita (Bari: Laterza, 1963), 120–26.
7. Created in 1956 by the union of a small liberal group and a group of intellectuals
linked to the weekly Il Mondo (notably its celebrated editor, Mario Pannunzio), the
Radical Party enjoyed some media success thanks to its battles first for the right to
divorce and later for abortion rights.
8. Massimo Livi Bacci, “La population italienne,” in Cassese, Portrait de l’Italie actuelle,
100–105. See also Stefano Molina, L’equazione demografica italiana: variabili e costanti
(Turin: Fondazione Giovanni Agnelli, 2004).
9. Paul Ginsborg, L’Italia del tempo presente. Famiglia, società civile, Stato. 1980–1996
(Turin: Einaudi, 1998), 139.
10. “The Church of tomorrow [ . . . ] will be a Church of a minority” (Salt of the Earth: The
Church at the End of the Millennium. An Interview With Peter Seewald, San Francisco:
Ignatius Press, 1997, 265.
11. Ratzinger, Salt of the Earth, 16.
12. Quoted by Guido La Barbera, Crisi di internazionalizzazione. L’Italia degli anni Nov-
anta (Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista, 2000), 58.
13. La Barbera, Crisi di internazionalizzazione, 58.
14. Giovanni Sartori, “Ma quanto è laico, Eminenza! È un uomo di Chiesa a dare una lezione
ai ministri dello Stato sul problema immigrati,” in L’Espresso, September 29, 2000.
246 NOTES
Chapter 22
1. The Cassa per il Mezzogiorno reimbursed 20 percent of initial investments and financed
70 percent of this through a 4 percent loan reimbursable over fifteen years. In his 1970
text, Nobécourt cited the case of industrialists who, having received financing to create
businesses in the south, closed them not long afterward and brought back to the north
the machines purchased with the state’s money. J. Nobécourt, L’Italie a vif (Paris: Seuil,
1970), 213.
2. V. Castronovo, Storia economica d’Italia (Turin: Einaudi, 1995), 495, 496.
3. The statute of the GEPI (Gestioni e partecipazioni industriali) is quoted by Luciano
Barca, Dizionario di politica economica (Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1979), 164. It is inter-
esting to note that, in chronological order, the IMI (in 1939), the IRI (1933), and the
EFIM (1947) were created at different moments with the same objective, but wound
up becoming state holding companies.
4. S. Lanaro, Storia dell’Italia repubblicana (Venice: Marsilio, 1992), 439. Between 1977
and 1982, the number of the workers of the state-owned factories grew 31.9 percent.
5. The comment by Jacques Chirac, in September 1996, that “the devaluation of the lira
has done a lot of harm to a certain number of European countries, and in particu-
lar France” (see www.elysee.fr) was followed by near-general indignation in Italy, led
by Deputy Prime Minister Walter Veltroni. Two governors of Banca d’Italia, Paolo
Baffi, in 1979 (see G. Carli, Cinquant’anni di vita italiana [Rome: Laterza, 1996], 350),
and Carlo Azeglio Ciampi, in 1980 (Il Sole 24 Ore, October 27, 1985), had already
denounced the risks of a recovery “doped” by the continual depreciations of the lira.
6. Gianni Agnelli, interview with Eugenio Scalfari, L’Espresso, November 19, 1972.
7. Enrico Berlinguer, Austerità, occasione per trasformare l’Italia (Rome: Editori Riuniti,
1977), 13.
8. Interview with Eugenio Scalfari, Repubblica, January 24, 1978. Luciano Lama’s line was
approved by the Congress of the CGIL in February 1978.
9. P. Ginsborg, Storia d’Italia dal dopoguerra a oggi. Società e politica, 1943–1988 (Turin:
Einaudi, 1988), 601.
10. In 1976 the PCI obtained 34.37 percent of all votes cast; in 1979 this fell to 30.38 per-
cent; in 1983 to 29.89 percent; and in 1987 to 26.57 percent. In 1992 the two parties
born of its dissolution won a total of 21.73 percent.
11. E. Galli della Loggia, La morte della patria (Rome: Laterza, 1996), 84.
12. E. Pace, La nation italienne en crise (Paris: Bayard, 1998), 107.
13. Mariella Gramaglia in La questione socialista. Per una possibile reinvenzione della sinis-
tra, ed. Gaetano Arfé, Vittorio Foa and Antonio Giolitti (Turin: Einaudi, 1987)
14. Quoted by A. Cervetto, L’ineguale sviluppo politico. 1968–1979 (Milan: Edizioni Lotta
Comunista, 1991), 216.
15. La Stampa, January 7, 1996. The OECD estimate comes from October 1995.
16. Carli, Cinquant’anni di vita italiana, 5.
17. Ciampi, Il Sole 24 ore, October 27, 1985.
18. Giangiacomo Nardozzi, Miracolo e declino. L’Italia tra concorrenza e protezione (Rome-
Bari: Laterza, 2004), 68.
19. Nardozzi, Miracolo e declino, 69.
20. Romano, Guida alla politica estera italiana, 192.
21. Francesco Cossiga, “Perché contiamo poco,” interview with Lucio Caracciolo, Limes,
May 1995. Cossiga (1928) was the Christian Democratic interior minister when Aldo
Moro was abducted. He was president of the republic from 1985 to 1992.
22. S. Romano, L’Italia scappata di mano (Milan: TEA Storica, 1995), 120, 121.
NOTES 247
23. On “Mediterranean Atlanticism,” see also Arrigo Cervetto, Forze e forme del muta-
mento italiano (Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista, 1997), 147, who coined the phrase;
Romano, Guida alla politica estera italiana, 85, 86, and L’Italia scappata di mano, 120,
121; L. Caracciolo, Terra incognita. Le radici geopolitiche della crisi italiana (Rome: Lat-
erza, 2001), 14, 15. In English, see Manlio Graziano, “The Rise and Fall of the ‘Medi-
terranean Atlanticism’ in the Italian Foreign Policy: the Case of the Near-East,” Modern
Italy, vol. 12, no. 3 (November 2007).
24. Thus said the president and director-general of Toro Assicurazioni (Fiat Group), Anto-
nio Mosconi, before an assembly of northern entrepreneurs in January 1979. Quoted
by Sergio Motosi, Scritti. Indagine scientifica e passione rivoluzionaria (Milan: Edizioni
Lotta Comunista, 2003), 469.
Chapter 23
Conclusion
1. Giulio Tremonti, Il futuro del fisco, in F. Galgano, S. Cassese, G. Tremonti, T. Treu, Ric-
chezza senza nazioni. Nazioni senza ricchezza, Bologna: Il Mulino, 1993.
2. Mario Draghi, Considerazioni finali per l’anno 2006, general meeting of the Banca
d’Italia, exercise CXIII, Rome, May 31, 2007, p. 8.
3. Data from ISTAT, July 11 and 12, 2006.
4. Unicredit was created through the progressive merger, begun in 1998, of Credito Ital-
iano, Credito Romagnoolo, Cassa di Risparmio di Verona, Vicenza Belluno e Ancona,
Cassa di Risparmio di Torino, Cassamarca (Cassa di Risparmio della Marca Trivi-
giana), Cassa di Risparmio di Trento e Rovereto, and Cassa di Risparmio di Trieste.
5. Banca Intesa is the result of the merger, between 1998 and 2001, of Cassa di Rispar-
mio delle Provincie Lombarde (Cariplo), Banco Ambroveneto (in turn created by the
merger of Banco Ambrosiano and Banca Cattolica del Veneto), and Banca Commer-
ciale Italiana.
6. Luigi La Spina, “Prime prove di megalopoli,” La Stampa, August 25, 2006.
7. For a more complete analysis of this subject, allow me to refer the reader to my own
Identité catholique et identité italienne: L’Italie laboratoire de l’Église (Paris: L’Harmattan,
2007).
References
History of Italy
Banfield, E. 1958. The moral basis of a backward society. Glencoe, IL: Free Press [Italian ed.,
Le basi morali di una società arretrata. Bologna: Il Mulino, 1976].
Barberis, W. 2004. Il bisogno di patria. Turin: Einaudi.
Barzini, L. 1996 [1964]. The Italians: A full-length portrait featuring their manners and mor-
als. New York: Touchstone.
Becchi, A. 1995. La questione meridionale. In La politica italiana. Dizionario critico 1945–95,
ed. G. Pasquino. Rome: Laterza.
Bevilacqua, Piero. 2005. Breve storia dell’Italia meridionale. Rome: Donzelli.
Biffi, G. 1999. Risorgimento, Stato laico e identità nazionale. Casale Monferrato: Piemme.
Bobbio, N. 1969. Profilo ideologico del Novecento. In Storia della letteratura italiana, vol. IX,
eds. E. Cecchi and N. Sapegno. Milan: Garzanti.
Bocca, G. 1962. Miracolo all’italiana. Milan: Edizioni Avanti!
Bollati, G. 1983. L’Italiano. Il carattere nazionale come storia e come invenzione. Turin:
Einaudi.
Cafagna, L. 1989. Dualismo e sviluppo nella storia d’Italia. Venice: Marsilio.
———. 1994. Nord e Sud. Non fare a pezzi l’unità d’Italia. Venice: Marsilio.
———. 2003. Legittimazione e delegittimazione nella storia politica italiana. In Due nazioni.
Legittimazione e delegittimazione nella storia dell’Italia contemporanea, eds. L. Di Nucci
and E. Galli della Loggia. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Candeloro, G. 1982. Il movimento cattolico in Italia. Rome: Editori Riuniti.
Caracciolo, A. 1994. Roma capitale sta in fondo allo Stivale. Limes 4.
Carocci, G. 1975. Storia d’Italia dall’Unità ad oggi. Milan: Feltrinelli.
———. 1992. Il trasformismo dall’unità ad oggi. Milan: Unicopli.
Cassese, S. 1998. Lo Stato introvabile. Rome: Donzelli.
———. 2001. Histoire et caractéristiques de l’État italien. In Portrait de l’Italie actuelle, ed.
S. Cassese. Paris: La Documentation Française.
Castronovo, V. 1977. Il Piemonte. In Storia d’Italia. Le regioni dall’Unità a oggi, ed. V. Cas-
tronova. Turin: Einaudi.
Cattaneo, C. 1957. Scritti. Florence: Sansoni.
Ciuffoletti, Z. 1993. Stato senza nazione. Disegno di storia del Risorgimento e dell’Unità
d’Italia Naples: Morano Editore.
Diamanti, I., A. Dieckhoff, M. Lazar, and D. Musiedlak. 1995. L’Italie, une nation en suspens.
Brussels: Editions Complexe.
Galli della Loggia, E. 1998. L’identità italiana Bologna: Il Mulino.
Gentile, E. 2006. La Grande Italia. Il mito della nazione nel XX secolo. Rome: Laterza.
Gianni, E. 1985. Le influenze regionali nei poteri governativi. Lotta Comunista, 182–84.
Goglia, L., and F. Grassi. 1981. Il colonialismo italiano da Adua all’Impero. Rome: Laterza.
250 REFERENCES
Abulafia, D. 1977. The two Italies: Economic relations between the Norman kingdom of Sic-
ily and the northern communes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press [Italian ed., Le
due Italie. Relazioni economiche tra il Regno normanno di Sicilia e i comuni settentrionali.
Naples: Guida, 1977].
Aymard, M. 1978. La transizione dal feudalesimo al capitalismo. In Storia d’Italia, vol. I, Dal
feudalesimo al capitalismo, eds. Ruggiero Romano e Corrado Vivanti. Turin: Einaudi.
Braudel, F. 1974. Due secoli e tre Italie. In Storia d’Italia, vol. II, 1476–1700: Politica, società,
religione, eds. Ruggiero Romano e Corrado Vivanti. Turin: Einaudi.
Cantimori, D. 1967. Le idee religiose del Cinquecento. La storiografia. In Storia della lettera-
tura italiana, vol. V, Il Seicento, eds. E. Cecchi and N. Sapegno. Milan: Garzanti,
Guicciardini, F. 1983 [1519]. Considerazioni intorno ai Discorsi del Machiavelli. In Discorsi
sopra la prima deca di Tito Livio, ed. C. Vivanti. Turin: Einaudi.
Luzzatto, G. 1958. Breve storia economica dell’Italia medievale. Turin: Einaudi.
Machiavelli, N. 1983 [1513]. Discorsi sopra la prima deca di Tito Livio, ed. C. Vivanti. Turin:
Einaudi.
Misson, M. 1702. Nouveau Voyage d’Italie, avec un Mémoire contenant des avis utiles à ceux
qui voudront faire le mesme voyage. La Haye: Chez Henry Van Bulderen.
Montaigne, M. de. 1774. Journal du voyage en Italie par la Suisse & l’Allemagne en 1580 &
1581. Paris: Chez Le Jay Librairie.
Montanelli, I., and R. Gervaso. 1967. L’Italia dei secoli d’oro. Milan: Rizzoli.
Prosperi, A. 1981. Intellettuali e Chiesa all’inizio dell’era moderna. In Storia d’Italia, vol. IV,
Intellettuali e potere, eds. R. Romano and C. Vivanti. Turin: Einaudi.
Quazza, G. 1957. Le riforme in Piemonte nella prima metà del Settecento. Modena: STEM.
Raffestin, C. 1987. L’evoluzione del sistema delle frontiere del Piemonte dal XVI al XIX secolo.
In La frontiera da Stato a nazione. Il caso Piemonte, eds. C. Ossola, C. Raffestin, and
M. Ricciardi. Rome: Bulzoni.
Recuperati, G. 1987. Cultura di frontiera e identità italiana nelle vicende del Piemonte sette-
centesco. In La frontiera da Stato a nazione. Il caso Piemonte, eds. C. Ossola, C. Raffestin,
and M Ricciardi. Rome: Bulzoni.
The Risorgimento
Belardelli, G. 2003. Una nazione “senza anima”: La critica democratica del Risorgimento. In
Due nazioni. Legittimazione e delegittimazione nella storia dell’Italia contemporanea, eds.
L. Di Nucci and E. Galli della Loggia. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Candeloro, G. 1958. Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. II, Dalla Restaurazione alla rivoluzione
nazionale, 1815–1846. Milan: Feltrinelli.
———. 1964. Storia dell’Italia moderna, vol. IV, Dalla rivoluzione nazionale all’Unità 1849–
1860. Milan: Feltrinelli.
252 REFERENCES
Carpi, U. 1981. Egemonia moderata e intellettuali nel Risorgimento. In Storia d’Italia, vol. IV,
Intellettuali e potere, eds. R. Romano and C. Vivanti. Turin: Einaudi.
Casella, R. 1984. 1863: I primi passi dello scontro tra protezionisti e liberoscambisti in Italia.
Lotta Comunista September.
Cattaneo, C. 1968 [1849]. L’insurrezione di Milano nel 1848 e la successiva Guerra. Turin:
Loescher.
Della Peruta, F. 1973. Democrazia e socialismo nel Risorgimento. Rome: Editori Riuniti.
———. 1999. Politica e società nell’Italia dell’Ottocento. Problemi, vicende e personaggi.
Milan: Franco Angeli.
Duriez, É. 1905. Les principes de l’annexion dans les Traités de 1815. Paris: Henri Jouve.
Ferrero, G. 1996. Talleyrand à Vienne (1814–1815). Paris: Éditions de Fallois.
Gianni, E. 2006. Liberali e democratici alle origini del movimento operaio italiano. I congressi
delle società operaie italiane (1853–1893). Milan: Edizioni Pantarei.
Gioberti, V. 1861. Del Primato morale e civile degli Italiani. Naples: Stamperia del Vaglio.
Gobetti, P. 1926. Risorgimento senza eroi. Turin: Edizioni del Baretti.
Gramsci, A. 1949. Il Risorgimento. Turin: Einaudi.
Greppi, P. 1900–1904. La Rivoluzione francese nel carteggio di un osservatore italiano (Paolo
Greppi). Milan: Hoepli.
Lepre, A. 1974. Storia del Mezzogiorno nel Risorgimento. Rome: Editori Riuniti.
Mack Smith, D. 1967. Italy. In The New Cambridge Modern History, vol. 10, The Zenith
of European Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press [Italian ed., Italia, Milan:
Garzanti, 1972].
———. 1969. Il Risorgimento italiano. Storia e testi. Rome: Laterza.
———. 1994. Vittorio Emanuele II. Milan: Mondadori.
Marcelli, U. 1970. Interpretazioni del Risorgimento. Bologna: Patron.
Marx, K., and F. Engels. 1959. Sul Risorgimento italiano. Rome: Editori Riuniti.
Mazzini, G. 1922 [1860]. Dei doveri dell’uomo. Genoa: Giovanni Ricci Editore.
Montanelli, I. 1972. L’Italia del Risorgimento. Milan: Rizzoli.
Nievo, I. 1952. Opere. Naples: Riccardo Ricciardi Editore.
Nobili, M., and S. Camerani, eds. 1945. Carteggi di Bettino Ricasoli. Rome: Istituto Storico
Italiano per l’età Moderna e Contemporanea.
Pedio, T. 1987. Brigantaggio meridionale (1806–1863). Lecce: Capone Editore.
Romeo, R. 1969. Cavour e il suo tempo. Rome: Laterza.
———. 1998 [1959]. Risorgimento e capitalismo. Rome: Laterza.
Rosselli, N. 1967. Mazzini e Bakunin: Dodici anni dimovimento operaio in Italia (1860–
1872). Turin: Einaudi.
Russo, V. 1999. Pensieri politici e altri scritti. Naples: Generoso Procaccini.
Salvemini, G. 1961. L’Italia politica nel secolo XIX. In Scritti sul Risorgimento, eds. P. Pieri,
C. Pischedda. (Milan: Feltrinelli.
1861–1922
Caracciolo, A. 1960. Stato e società civile. Problemi dell’unificazione italiana. Turin: Einaudi.
———. 1999 [1956]. Roma capitale. Dal Risorgimento alla crisi dello Stato liberale. Rome:
Editori Riuniti.
Carocci, G. 1956. Agostino Depretis e la politica interna italiana 1876–1887. Turin: Einaudi.
———. 1971 [1961]. Giolitti e l’età giolittiana. Turin: Einaudi.
Chabod, F. 1951. Storia della politica estera italiana dal 1860 al 1896. Rome: Laterza.
Corradini, E. 1980. Scritti e discorsi. 1901–1914. Turin: Einaudi.
Croce, B. 1955. Cultura e vita morale. Intermezzi polemici. Bari: Laterza.
———. 2004 [1928]. Storia d’Italia dal 1871 al 1915. Milan: Adelphi.
———. 2007 [1932]. Storia d’Europa nel secolo decimonono. Milan: Adelphi.
Fonzi, F. 1965. Crispi e lo Stato di Milan. Milan: Giuffrè.
Grew, R. 1969. Il trasformismo: Ultimo stadio del Risorgimento. In Il Risorgimento e l’Europa,
ed. V. Frosini. Catania: Bonanno.
Isnenghi, M. 2007. Garibaldi fu ferito. Storia e mito di un rivoluzionario disciplinato. Rome:
Donzelli.
Martini, F. 1928. Confessioni e ricordi. 1859–1892. Milan: Treves.
Nitti, F. S. 1907. Il Partito Radicale e la nuova democrazia industriale. Prime linee di un pro-
gramma di un Partito Radicale. Turin: Sten.
Passerin d’Entrèves, E. 1969. Ideologie del Risorgimento. In Storia della letteratura italiana,
vol. VII, eds. E. Cecchi and N. Sapegno. Milan: Garzanti.
Roberts, J. M. 1965. Italy. In The new Cambridge modern history, vol. 9, War and peace in an
age of upheaval 1793–1830. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Romeo, R. 1974. Dal Piemonte sabaudo all’Italia liberale. Rome: Laterza.
Seton-Watson, C. 1973. L’Italia dal liberalismo al fascismo 1870–1925. Rome: Laterza.
Soderini, E. 1932. Il pontificato di Leone XIII. Milan: Mondadori.
Spadolini, G. 1972. Gli uomini che fecero l’Italia. Milan: Longanesi.
———. 1974. Giolitti e i cattolici (1911–1914). Milan: Mondadori.
Villari, P. 1866. Di chi è la colpa? O sia La Pace e la guerra Milan: Tipografia di Zanetti
Francesco.
1922–1945
Milza, P., and S. Bernstein. 1980. Le fascisme italien. 1919–1945. Paris: Seuil.
Oliva, G. 1994. I vinti e i liberati. Milan: Mondadori.
Pankhurst, R. 1971. A charter in Ethiopian commercial history: Developments during the fas-
cist occupation 1936–1941. Ethiopia Observer 15 (1).
Pellicani, A. 1964. Il papa di tutti. La Chiesa cattolica, il fascismo e il razzismo. 1929–1945.
Milan: Sugar.
Rocca, G. 1993. Avanti Savoia! Miti e disfatte che fecero l’Italia 1848–1866. Milan: Mondadori.
Salvatorelli, L. 2004 [1923]. Nazional fascismo. Rome: Libero.
Secchia, P. 1973. Aldo dice 26 x 1. Cronistoria del 25 aprile. Milan: Feltrinelli.
Tilgher, A. 1921. La crisi mondiale e saggi di socialismo e marxismo. Bologna: Zanichelli.
Treves, A. 1976. Le migrazioni interne nell’Italia fascista. Turin: Einaudi.
1945–1992
Aga Rossi, E. 1969. Dal Partito popolare alla Democrazia cristiana. Bologna: Cappelli.
Ajello, N. 1979. Intellettuali e PCI. 1944–1958. Rome: Laterza.
Andreotti, G. 1977. Intervista su De Gasperi. Rome: Laterza.
Baget Bozzo, G. 1974. Il partito cristiano al potere. La Dc di De Gasperi e di Dossetti (1945–
1954). Florence: Vallecchi.
Berlinguer, E. 1977. Austerità, occasione per trasformare l’Italia. Rome: Editori Riuniti.
Boneschi, M. 1995. Poveri ma belli. I nostri anni cinquanta. Milan: Mondadori.
Calise, M., and R. Mannheimer. 1982. Governanti in Italia. Un trentennio repubblicano.
1946–1976. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Casella, R. 1989. La crisi sindacale degli anni ottanta. Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista.
Cassese, S. 1980. Esiste un governo in Italia? Rome: Officina Edizioni.
Cervetto, A. 1991. L’ineguale sviluppo politico. 1968–1979. Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista.
———. 1997. Forze e forme del mutamento italiano. Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista.
Crainz, G. Storia del miracolo italiano. Culture, identità, trasformazioni fra anni cinquanta e
sessanta. Rome: Donzelli.
Farneti, P. 1971. Sistema politico e società civile. Turin: Giappichelli.
Franzinelli, M. 2006. L’amnistia Togliatti. 22 giugno 1946: Colpo di spugna sui crimini fascisti.
Milan: Mondadori.
Galli, G. 1966. Il bipartitismo imperfetto. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Galli della Loggia, E. 1996. La morte della patria. Rome: Laterza.
Gianni, E. 1983. La DC nasce come partito nordista. Lotta comunista, 149.
Ginsborg, P. 1988. Storia d’Italia dal dopoguerra ad oggi. Società e politica, 1943–1988. Turin:
Einaudi.
———. 1998. L’Italia del tempo presente. Famiglia, società civile, Stato. 1980–1996. Turin:
Einaudi.
Gundle, S. 1986. L’americanizzazione del quotidiano. Televisione e consumismo nell’Italia
degli anni Cinquanta. Quaderni Storici, 21(2).
La Malfa, U. 1977. Intervista sul non-governo. Bari: Laterza.
Lanaro, S. 1992. Storia dell’Italia repubblicana. Venice: Marsilio.
Lazar, M. 1992. Maisons rouges. Les partis communistes français et italien de la Libération à
nos jours. Paris: Aubier.
Lupo, S. 2004. Partito e antipartito. Una storia politica della prima Repubblica (1946–1978).
Rome: Donzelli.
Motosi, S. 2003. Scritti. Indagine scientifica e passione rivoluzionaria. Milan: Edizioni Lotta
Comunista.
REFERENCES 255
1992–2007
Caracciolo, L. 2001. Terra incognita. Le radici geopolitiche della crisi italiana. Rome: Laterza.
Cossiga, F. 1995. Perché contiamo poco, intervista con L. Caracciolo. Limes, 3.
De Michelis, G. 2003. La lunga ombra di Yalta. Venice: Marsilio.
Graziano, M. 2007. The rise and fall of “Mediterranean Atlanticism” in Italian foreign policy:
The case of the Near East. Modern Italy 12 (3): 287–308.
Jean, C. 1994. La nostra sicurezza nel mondo balcanizzato. Linee-guida per una politica estera
e di difesa coerente. Limes, 4.
Mammarella, G., and P. Cacace. 2006. La politica estera dell’Italia. Dallo Stato unitario ai
giorni nostri. Rome: Laterza.
Perticone, G. 1961. La politica estera italiana dal 1861 al 1914. Turin: ERI.
Quaroni, P. 1965. Il mondo di un ambasciatore. Milan: Ferro Edizioni.
Romano, S. 1993. Guida alla politica estera italiana. Dal crollo del fascismo al crollo del comu-
nismo. Milan: Rizzoli.
Vigezzi, B. 1997. L’Italia unita e le sfide della politica estera. Milan: Unicopli.
Other Texts
Agnelli, G., and A. Cabiati. 1986. Federazione europea o Lega delle nazioni. Pordenone: Stu-
dio Tesi.
Boffa, G. 1976. Storia dell’Unione Sovietica. 1917–1941. Lenin e Stalin. Dalla rivoluzione alla
seconda guerra mondiale. Milan: Mondadori.
Bordiga, A. 1976. I fattori di razza e nazione nella teoria marxista. Milan: Iskra Edizioni.
Cohen, M. 1956. Pour une sociologie du langage. Paris: Albin Michel.
De Martino, E. 2001. Sud e magia. Milan: Feltrinelli.
Di Nola, A. 2001. Gli aspetti magico-religiosi di una cultura subalterna italiana. Turin: Bollati
Boringhieri.
Fichte, J. G. 1992 [1808]. Discours à la nation allemande. Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.
Gil, J. 1980. Nazione. In Enciclopedia, vol. IX, ed. R. Romano. Turin: Einaudi.
Graziano, M. 2007. The Catholic Church and the ‘others’: A universalist strategy. Geopolitical
Affairs, 2.
Habermas, J. 1986. Écrits politiques. Culture, droit, histoire. Paris: Editions du Cerf.
Hobsbawm, E. J., and T. Ranger. 1983. The invention of tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press [Italian ed., L’invenzione della tradizione, Turin: Einaudi, 1987].
Hogan, M. 1989. The Marshall Plan: America, Britain, and the reconstruction of Western
Europe, 1947–1952. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
258 REFERENCES
Kennedy, P. 1987. The rise and fall of the Great Powers: Economic change and military conflict
from 1500–2000. New York: Random House.
La Barbera, G. 2006. L’Europa e lo Stato. Milan: Edizioni Lotta Comunista.
Marx, K. 1975a. Il Capitale. Critica dell’economia politica. Turin: Einaudi.
———. 1975b. Opere. Lotta politica e conquista del potere, ed. G. M. Bravo. Rome: Newton
& Compton.
Moore, B., Jr. 1993. Social origins of dictatorship and democracy. Lord and peasant in the mak-
ing of the modern world. Boston: Beacon Press.
Ratzinger, J. 1997. Il sale della terra. Cristianesimo e Chiesa cattolica nella svolta del millennio.
Cinisello Balsamo: Edizioni San Paolo.
Sieyès, E.-J. 1994 [1789]. Écrits politiques. Paris: Édition des Archives Contemporaines.
Thiesse, A.-M. 1999. La création des identités nationales. Europe XVIIIème-XXème siècle.
Paris: Seuil.
Tremonti, G. 1993. Il futuro del fisco. In Ricchezza senza nazioni. Nazioni senza ricchezza, eds.
F. Galgagno, S. Cassese, G. Tremonti, and T. Treu. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Index