FULLTEXT01
FULLTEXT01
FULLTEXT01
Television Broadcasting
in Smaller Countries
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen (eds.)
NORDICOM
Nordicom’s activities are based on broad and extensive network of contacts and collaboration
with members of the research community, media companies, politicians, regulators, teachers,
librarians, and so forth, around the world. The activities at Nordicom are characterized by three
main working areas.
www.nordicom.gu.se
Small among Giants
Small among Giants
Television Broadcasting in Smaller Countries
NORDICOM
Small among Giants
Television Broadcasting in Smaller Countries
ISBN 978-91-86523-16-9
Published by:
Nordicom
University of Gothenburg
Box 713
SE 405 30 Göteborg
Sweden
Robert G. Picard
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size 43
John D. Jackson
with Yon Hsu (on Taiwan), Geoffrey Lealand (on New Zealand), Brian
O’Neill & Michael Foley (on Ireland) & Christian Steininger (on Austria)
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets 89
Josef Trappel
Structure and Dynamics.
The Television Broadcasting Industry in Smaller Countries 109
Chris Hanretty
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries 161
Bibliography 2__
Preface
7
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
expectations for media regulation and strategising to small countries with small
populations, markets and languages? When conditions differ, best solutions
will differ in turn.
The need for clarification is urgent because broadcasters and policymakers
are increasingly stipulating that how things are organised and handled in the
biggest media markets provide generalisable models for all markets. This carries
the risk of false comfort by those seeking to devise some template with which
to steer decision-making, both among broadcasters struggling with uncertainty
in turbulent markets and regulators who want to reduce the arduous demands
for adjudicating complaints about PSB causing market distortion. Although
their pursuit is understandable, it risks false comfort because it relies mainly
on an untested belief that broadcasting is broadcasting – that ‘one size fits all’.
8
Preface
governs this book – or at least not directly, although there is room for potential
indirect effects, as some authors note.
Despite caveats, the body of research reported here does confirm the de-
terminant importance of size in both population and economy in affecting the
structure and health of television markets. We should expect a wealthy small
country like Luxembourg to have a lot more going on than a poor small coun-
try like Moldavia. The complexity becomes still greater as one moves beyond
exclusively market-oriented criteria to consider those political and cultural
factors that inscribe the character of a media system in a particular socially and
historically situated context. This is especially evident in comparing western
and eastern Europe, but also northern and southern Europe – tasks that various
authors undertake in this volume.
In the east commercial broadcasting wasn’t even possible until after 1989,
and then was embraced with such enthusiasm that in many cases there was
a complete failure to exercise due diligence regarding regulations and licens-
ing. Public broadcasting was not easily accommodated due to its association,
or perhaps better to say disassociation, with state broadcasting. As a result,
corporate transnationalisation in media industries had a field day. In compari-
son, northern Europe with its heritage rooted in the Nordic welfare state and
strong protestant roots, has typically organised and funded the most dominant
PSB systems anywhere in the world. Southern Europe, on the other hand, has
been poorer and less convinced of this approach. In three of these countries a
history of dictatorship (Greece, Portugal and Spain) has encouraged perspec-
tives more akin to those in eastern Europe.
Language is another significant factor that must be factored in for analyses.
Its affects can be beneficial or a liability, and in many case one finds some
combination of the two. The relative strength of the television business in
the Scandinavian countries is arguably explained to a large extent by the fact
that they share a similar language, making it easier to cooperate for instance
in exchanging television programmes and participating in joint development
projects. Other examples are not as benign, however, as evident in the inter-
relation between neighbouring small and big countries that share a language,
as is the case with Austria-Germany, Belgium-France, Ireland-UK, and Canada-
USA – or Switzerland with France-Italy-Germany.
Finally, as hinted earlier, it should be noted that the operations of wealthy
transnational media corporations affect media markets everywhere, and can’t
be usefully assessed only by looking at the population or market size of their
home countries. One of the biggest and most successful companies in the format
trade, Endemol, is legally of Dutch origin. This ‘home address’ allows it to be
considered as a company based in a small country. But in fact Mediaset, the
Italian conglomerate, owns Endemol today, which obviously changes the picture.
Transnational media corporations require analysis beyond country size, which
9
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
may be of only minor importance of its self but is keenly relevant when smaller
countries can be bundled to create a regional or global market for these firms.
This more complex and nuanced treatment of size can be regarded as refuting
our general hypothesis that country size is of general importance for devising
appropriate media policies. As a matter of fact several chapters in this volume
highlight variables that indicate the way television broadcasting is regulated is
not primarily size-related. The ‘maturity’ of a country’s political culture and its
overall economic wealth are certainly crucial factors in categorising European
countries in north-south as well as east-west comparisons.
On the other hand this more complex treatment confirms our warrant for
counselling policymakers and media managers that trying to adopt templates
from bigger countries may not only be unsuitable, but can be damaging. There
is quite a lot that deserves deeper consideration when crafting domestic media
policies, especially when the objective is to ensure not only that mandates
are doable but also appropriate. The gloss often put on these matters when
mandates are decided does an injustice to many. At the least one ought to dig
into the evidence to ascertain the extent to which common assumptions that
ground trends in media policy and corporate strategy are legitimate.
No one in this volume is arguing that policymakers or broadcast manag-
ers shouldn’t look abroad for inspiration. They should, and very often must.
In today’s increasingly globalised media industries and cultures not doing so
would be another variant of failing to exercise due diligence. But the research
and analyses reported in this volume suggests there are many good reasons to
interrogate whether it is reasonable to assume that any country can conform
to dynamics that do not characterise its own internal conditions. This seems a
sore spot among EU policymakers, and sometimes also domestic policymakers.
Of course it is difficult to craft policies that accommodate diversity, complex-
ity and variance. A key problem is that the outliers – the few comparatively
big, rich and powerful countries – are seen as the preferred models precisely
because they are big, rich and powerful. In scientific terms, however, they are
in fact atypical – they are the aberrant cases and exceptions to the rule, rather
than the norm. In that light seizing on these cases as exemplars can certainly
distort the picture and skew analyses. One really has to wonder why there
should be such evident surprise when whatever was being modelled on such a
basis ends in failure? That is rather inevitable when “the differences that make
a difference” are too often not understood – or actually even considered (to
use a phrase popularised by the sociologist Gregory Bateson).
What’s needed is analyses of empirical evidence that tries to answer a variety
of questions that are obviously consequential for drafting policy and crafting
strategy. How does the scale and scope of national economies influence opera-
tional conditions? How does the size and composition of a population establish
parameters for audience formation? What are the practical effects on a smaller
10
Preface
media market when there are competitive pressures from media situated in a
larger neighbouring country, especially when the smaller country shares the
language (or a close dialect) and even some cultural heritage? Are media markets
in smaller countries impacted disproportionately by international media firms
and contents, financial conditions and systemic requirements, or cost structures?
How does the comparatively limited capacity of in-house production play
out on TV screens in smaller markets compared with bigger markets? In what
ways and to what extent do programme profiles in smaller market companies
differ from larger market broadcasters? Are there generalisable characteristics
concerning relations with governments and audiences when comparing smaller
to bigger countries? Of course we can’t hope to answer all of these questions
in a single volume, and probably only a few with high certainty. But these
are the kinds of questions we are trying to interrogate, to the extent possible
within our own limitations.
While not wanting to downplay the usefulness of studying how things are
handled among market leaders, especially given the state of flux and general
uncertainty characteristic of media industries today, the research documented
in this book strongly suggests that caution is warranted. A model is only valid
to the extent that the conditions accounting for its construction are compara-
tively similar in those other contexts where it is to be applied. In broadcasting,
such applicability is very often not the case. It is therefore highly problematic
to assume that conditions and dynamics characterising countries with bigger
populations and wealthier media markets are inherently appropriate patterns
for countries with smaller populations and less wealthy media markets.
Sizing up size
Conceptually one can distinguish between various facets of size. Facets
that are typically important include territorial mass1, industry size2, military
strength and/or presence, population size and/or density, market size and
economy size3. Omitting the military4 facet, most of the others can be argued
1. Territory can be measured as square miles or kilometers, but also or in combination with population density.
Both have principle effect on the media system due to infrastructure requirements.
2. This is more problematic than at first glance because there are actually several media markets (radio, TV,
web, content production, newspapers, magazines, etc), which in some ways overlap, or can be handled as
an aggregate for analytical purposes, but in many respects can be discrete. We think the general point made
in the paragraph is valid, however.
3. Economy can be measured in different ways, as well. The usual way is gross domestic product (GDP). But
it is also measured in per-capita income and productivity, and sometimes according to household dispos-
able income. It can also be adjusted for parity, as in the chapter by Robert G. Picard in this volume. Our
purpose is not to discuss economic theory or dig into the nuances of measurement, although some of that
is handled in the book to enhance clarity.
4. This is not to indicate that a military cannot influence the media – in many cases they are strongly influential.
Rather our point is to argue that continuous effects on media are relatively limited to a few most widespread
and typically fundamental national characteristics.
11
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
12
Preface
being treated by the respective author/s. When that makes the most sense for
analysis and meaning, we of course approved the choice.
Caveats
Although seemingly self-explanatory due to everyone’s familiarity with radio
and television, a recurrent complication in discussions about broadcasting is
that each observer mainly understands what that is, and explains what it means,
on the basis of lived experience in one or a very limited number of societies.
This is of course pertinent for the researchers and editors of this book, as well.
Throughout the project the editors and authors have taken pains to remind
each other of the idiosyncratic nature of our perceptions, and worked to remain
self-critical. Of course some of our various dispositions are apparent, especially
in treating public sector broadcasting. Most of our contributors have been in-
volved with PSB in one way or another, sometimes for decades. Most are also
from smaller countries and see the world from this vantage point. Both factors
must colour our perspectives. On the other hand, considering that the book is
mainly written in the European context and for an audience familiar with the
role of public service broadcasting, and given the typical size and importance
of PSB in many of our case countries, we could expect readers to take this
into account when sifting through the results and considering the implications.
We have chosen to focus mainly on television. We acknowledge the vital
role that radio plays in daily life for millions. Indeed, one editor and some
contributors ‘cut their teeth’ in radio at the start of their careers. The issue was
debated, and we agreed it is best here to focus on television because that is
the locus of policy attention and thus the most pertinent area of study for this
project. We concluded that radio deserves its own treatment and could not be
fairly handled in a book of this size. Similarly, we have not focused primarily
on so-called ‘new media’, which hasn’t been new for quite some time, and
again because broadcast television is a far more dominant factor in electronic
media markets both in economic terms and as the focal point for policy and
regulation. That said, our contributors were not ‘forbidden’ to discuss radio or
the internet whenever these media were important for their respective analyses
or argumentation.
Although the inspiration for the book grew out of discussions among various
members of our research team in response to the BBC conference highlighted
at the beginning, another important editorial decision was to expand the focus
of analysis to both incorporate and juxtapose the two sectors that comprise
the European dual television market. Thirty odd years after the dissolution of
public monopoly in European television it is no longer useful to analyse, and
is impossible to understand, what’s happening in either the public service or
13
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
the private commercial sectors without looking at their interaction. That is the
essential dynamic governing developments in European broadcasting.
14
Preface
readers will come away with a firmer grasp of the issues and better possibilities
for arriving at useful answers.
This book demonstrates a shared interest to support deliberations in media
policy and strategic planning. Our effort has been focused on generating in-
sights on the basis of evidence rather than making arguments on the basis of
normative ideals. There is nothing wrong with normative ideals, indeed such
are essential to properly consider the role and functions of media – i.e., their
‘remit’. But that is not what this book sets out to be mainly about. For this
reason we do not stipulate what media policy ought to be. Deciding that is a
normative exercise best left to those responsible for directing and managing
broadcast operations in each society. We think, however, that the contents of
this book will be helpful to improved understanding of some practical reasons
why and how size matters to broadcasting policy, for proposing and declin-
ing options in systemic modelling, and in considering options for operational
development in every society grappling with these issues. Our collective goal
is to make some useful contribution to the thinking that grounds policymaking
and steers strategic planning among responsible agents working in each context
to create a broadcasting system that is optimal for its distinctive conditions,
while also recognising diverse needs and intentions.
Although many of our contributors, and the editors as well, have a shared
history of involvement in PSB, we want to avoid taking any partisan stand. This
book is neither for nor against PSB or commercial broadcasting; it does not
promote a specific arrangement. The contents present evidence and pertinent
discussion about what television broadcasting is, how it works as a function
of its nature as a medium and variables keyed to size-related dimensions, and
why that matters for those who must deliberate on the normative dimensions
that are outside the focus of our investigations.
The editors and authors support all good faith efforts to craft the very best
broadcasting system for each country’s respective goals and needs, and rec-
ognise that what that means must be decided by those who are entrusted to
make these decisions. Our work succeeds to the extent that readers come away
agreeing that size must be accommodated in deliberations about how things are
done, and with greater caution in presuming how they are done in one context
may be suitable for modelling in other contexts. Of course resource limitations
bound every decision and every responsible agent must legitimate how scarce
resources will be used, and why in a particular configuration. We hope this
book is helpful in efforts to manage that well by contributing to greater clarify
about what is essential in media regulation today. This is especially important
as a great deal of attention in this volume is devoted to explaining why some
form of intervention in broadcasting is typical rather than exceptional. This is
primarily because TV is a public good and has never only been about content;
it has always been at least as much about context. This book works to establish
15
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
more clearly than before why and how size matters for policy-making and in
strategic planning. Content might be king; but context is the kingdom.
Chapter summaries
In the introductory chapter, Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy by Gregory
Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg and Christian S. Nissen, the authors set
the scene by relating the perspective of this volume to earlier studies on small
countries in varied social science disciplines. The special features of media
markets are underscored, especially for television, both as a field of study
and as an area for business strategy and regulation. The core variables (size
of population, general economic conditions, and the character of television
markets) are clarified and related to other important factors variously treated
elsewhere in the book. These include, for example, the maturity of political
systems, more general cultural value systems, and issues related to degrees of
vulnerability and dependency. The chapter argues that size certainly matters
in television broadcasting, but acknowledges good reasons to take other vari-
ables into account when looking at specific markets and working to explain
the policies of particular actors.
In chapter two, Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country
Size, Robert G. Picard explores how country size and the economics of broad-
casting are related. He shows why scale issues create different conditions for
broadcasters and how these affect structures, operations, and costs. He stud-
ies 31 European nations to demonstrate how size, financial resources, market
structures and services, and content provision are related, and in consequence
strengthening the conviction that for television broadcasting operations, size
really matters.
In chapter three, titled Sizing Up Size on TV Markets: Why David would Lose
to Goliath, Christian Edelvold Berg argues that every size of television market
has characteristic dynamics that are more or less applicable everywhere, and
that the explanation of key difference lies in “relative market leverage”, concep-
tualised as an expression of a market’s inability to allocate resources efficiently.
He shows how this is the case due to conditions of imperfect competition and
high potential for market failure in media goods. Quantitative analysis clarifies
the availability of revenues in European television markets and investigates the
relationship between population size and economy size to demonstrate how
size influences market volume. He examines the relationship between size and
the level of investment in originated TV content programming, and concludes
with discussion about the importance of size to how TV markets are structured
and how TV systems work.
Chapter four is a group effort steered by John D. Jackson with contributions
from Yon Hsu, Geoffrey Lealand, Brian O’Neill, Michael Foley and Christian
16
Preface
17
Gregory Ferrell Lowe & Christian S. Nissen
demonstrates tight links between the de jure (legal) independence that pub-
lic broadcasters have, and de facto independence they enjoy. Hanretty finds
that smallness is unrelated to either de jure or de facto independence. Rather,
smallness affects the potential sources of attacks upon independence – and the
experiences broadcasters can draw upon to defend themselves.
In chapter eight, Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries, Tom
Moring and Sebastian Godenhjelm conduct analysis around the idea that media
production is shaped by society’s general culture. In this chapter we find that
media products not only have informational and ‘consolidational’ functions, but
also confirm in each case some relatively peculiar and variable social and cultural
order – a society’s so-called general culture – where production practices are
carried out. The authors present their findings under the rubric of a ‘restitutional’
function for TV broadcasting. Understanding the import of social and cultural
order is among the biggest challenges that policy makers must face today.
In our final chapter, Big Formats, Small Nations: Does Size Matter?, Annette
Hill and Jeanette Steemers combine political economy with audience analysis
to generate insights about production in and between broadcast markets of
varying size. The results deepen understanding of the relationship between
media production and reception in bigger and smaller nations. The analysis
indicates small countries are limited by the size of their domestic markets, the
lack of sufficient resources to sustain more expensive entertainment shows,
and the cheapness of overseas products such as reality entertainment formats
(e.g. X Factor and the Got Talent franchise). Even for those successful small
producers, consolidation and integration within a globalised marketplace as
part of a ‘big country company’ seems to be the destiny for the few who break
out internationally.
Acknowledgements
The editors would like to thank the authors for their patience in working on
what has often been a moving target. Despite a clear orientation and agreed
objectives from the beginning, the development of this book has been organic
by necessity. As various chapters have gotten closer to completion we’ve needed
to go back to earlier chapters and request further revision or reorientation. The
authors have done good work and we deeply appreciate their commitment to
the quality of results. We have also enjoyed this collaboration.
Editors and authors alike wish to thank the Media Management and Trans-
formation Centre at the Jönköping International Business School for the funding
and support that made the project possible. We especially thank Barbara Eklöf
and Danielle Tarnhamn for handling the arrangements for our international
meetings.
18
Preface
19
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
As discussed in the preface, we consider country size a key determinant for any
explanation of how television broadcasting is organised and works in compara-
tive contexts. In this introduction we offer more detail to understand why we
hold this view. This discussion has implications for media policy and company
strategy. We begin with an overview of ‘small state’ theory, which grew to promi-
nence during the Cold War. We then elaborate important features of particular
relevance to the media environment, which need to be accounted for any useful
articulation of policy pertaining to broadcasting systems. This chapter offers a
close focus on elements of research reported in this volume found most important
for defining “smallness” as having a decisive bearing on television broadcasting.
21
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
began to also take account a country’s capability to apply its resources. The
variable influences of proximate as well as historic cultural and social relations
became increasingly pertinent, as well. Deepening understanding encouraged
differentiation on the basis of weaker and stronger states as it was evident that
size is relative, not absolute. As Rothstein observed (1968: 21):
The question then is what characterises small powers as unique entities, as
something other than merely weaker states? The answer, one presumes, must
rest on an analysis of patterns of behaviour which remain the same for small
powers, despite basic shifts in the international system.
His articulation was a fresh point of departure. The study of small states diver-
sified into a broad range of variables and behavioural characteristics reported
in a burgeoning collection of studies on international politics (Koehane 1969;
Dosenrode 1993 &1997), political economy (Katzenstein 1985; Pedersen and
Campbell 2006) and economics (Robinson 1960; Alesina and Spolaore 2003).
Fast-forwarding to the present day, we are by now faced with so many per-
tinent variables that the sheer complexity makes it difficult to achieve a man-
ageable solution, and manageability is certainly necessary for achieve anything
useful in comparative research. The Cold War ended long before the challenges
inherent in settling this matter. Deciding the key variables is a work of on-going
refinement and remains an enormous conceptual challenge, certainly one this
book can’t hope to resolve. Candidate variables especially include size of popula-
tion, economic wealth measured in GNP or GDP, and territorial size. These must
be weighted against less easily quantifiable factors, especially political culture,
language, domestic social relations, and international influences.
Moreover, the structural context within which small states operate still has
considerable influence on their relative status. That was evident earlier in military
alliances such as NATO and the Warsw Pact, and equally today in economic
systems that are pivotal in regulating trade such as the WTO and the EU Com-
petition Authority. Small states aligning with larger ‘powers’ can gain a degree of
influence or affluence disproportionate to their objective characteristics in isola-
tion. Of course the opposite is also possible, and could be said about less highly
developed countries in former colonies. The interrelations and permutations
characterise one important school of developmental studies that conceptualise
relations as a matter of “centre–periphery” dependencies. For example, Amin
(1970) and Emmanuel (1972) argued that relatively small European countries
continued to dominate most former colonies due to structural dependencies
despite the fact that these countries often have larger geographical territories,
bigger populations and more natural resources.
Thus any effort to categorise countries as small and large is devilishly dif-
ficult. The path taken is mainly determined by the focus of study. That is the
case here, as well.
22
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
23
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
service media [PSM] because the cost per inhabitant is higher than in countries
with bigger populations, at least for comparatively wealthy member states.
Even in the United States, the largest and wealthiest commercial media market,
there is renewed debate about subsidising the newspaper industry in light of
economic difficulties keyed to the recent recession (Downie & Schudson 2009).
Smaller European countries are especially important because they react dis-
tinctively to economic change, using flexible adjustment policies for industrial
development that combine a general preference for liberalisation with a ten-
dency to provide compensation. Christian Berg discusses this at some length in
his chapter. Sometimes referred to as the ‘Nordic model’, but actually indicative
of other countries to varying degrees as well, the objective is on the one hand
to avoid protectionist policies (that often characterise policy in large liberal
countries) and, on the other, to encourage structural transformation of statist
traditions. This distributes market dependencies widely instead of focusing such
on discrete markets. Rather than going full sail in one go, the smaller countries
of Europe evidence a political will to preserve continuity through incremental
adjustment to wider trends via ad hoc measures, improvisation and intervention.
This is not done to constrain liberalisation, which on the contrary is generally
preferred today as it is understood to be an essential pre-condition for rising
prosperity. Rather the reason is to govern dynamics inherent in liberalisation,
which needs to accommodate variable needs under local conditions.
In his work on the political economy of nations, Peter J. Katzenstein sug-
gested that country size affects both degrees of economic openness and the
character of political administration. Systematic differences should be expected
when comparing bigger and smaller countries. But even among smaller coun-
tries, Katzenstein identified comparative differences between ‘liberal corpo-
ratism’ in Switzerland, Belgium and the Netherlands and ‘social corporatism’
in Austria, Norway and Denmark. In his analysis, Sweden represented some
combination of the two (and we could probably add Finland, as well)1. At heart,
the difference is reflected in where and how small European states adapt to
economic change. His contrast hinged on the global adaptation and private
compensation of liberal corporatism, compared with the national adaption and
public compensation characteristic of social corporatism. Katzenstein (1985:
134-135) concluded:
Flexible industrial adjustments are not a uni-dimensional response to chang-
ing market conditions or political pressures. Instead, as I have shown,
democratic corporatism has two variants, one liberal and the other social.
Both variants respond to the economic as well as the political requirements
of adjustment. Liberal corporatism accepts market-driven change but makes
political gestures necessary to keep disadvantaged industry segments, firms,
1. For a useful introduction to Katzenstein’s thinking on liberal corporatism and social corporatism, see http://
www.tidsskrift.dk/visning.jsp?markup=&print=no&id=95546. See also Katzenstein 1985: 105.
24
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
25
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
underway in Norway and Portugal (EBU 2009). At any rate, the historic pat-
tern makes sense when remembering that some countries in the west (Spain,
Portugal and Greece) have recent histories of state broadcasting associated
with dictatorships, as typically also the case in much of Eastern Europe. In
such contexts the private sector has been viewed as an antidote to oppressive
legacies in broadcasting.
Meanwhile, the financial situation for public broadcasting in some Western
European countries that depend on license fee revenue has become increas-
ingly uncertain. Political complications have ended, for now at least, efforts
to pass a proposed change from a TV-based fee to a more comprehensive
media-based fee in Finland, for example (for a useful overview see Ala-Fossi
& Hujanen 2010). Recent reports indicate the BBC was forced to compromise
its financial situation to protect income generated by the fee from viewers age
75+. To keep that share of income the government is requiring the BBC to take
added financial responsibilities for the World Service as well as S4C in Wales,
and to achieve reductions amounting to about 16% of their budget over the
next four years (Martinson 2010). Moreover, the growing popularity of various
mechanisms for regulating PSB is, in affect, hobbling efforts to develop these
companies into PSM firms, as evident in the drive for ex ante mechanisms (e.g.
the 2005 Public Value Test in the UK and the 2008 Three-Step Model in Ger-
many). Demands for similar procedures are percolating in an increasing number
of EU member states. Instability in European TV broadcasting is evident in the
financial status of broadcasters in the private commercial sector, as well. In this
sector margins have declined as a result of over-leveraging during the boom
years, and since 2008 to under performing advertising markets as companies
drew down in the face of declining sales and growing deficits.
Protective measures for domestic markets have not only been taken in smaller
countries; many bigger European countries have similarly acted to protect
or nurture (depending on one’s perspective) domestic production. That has
been characteristic in France where language and culture are always the stuff
of politics. But in fact most states have made varying arrangements to cope
with the impact of deregulation, convergence, consolidation and digitalisation,
which are together fuelling globalization in media industries. It is important to
understand that as markets, all states are not equal. The degree of competition
varies, and also the degree of attractiveness for investment. The main point
argued here is that size has policy implications as a relative feature for most
countries, at least in Europe, as a function of being larger and/or smaller in
comparative terms. Commercial broadcasting can’t accommodate the ample
provision of some desired services, and this is what legitimates state interven-
tion3. This is the generalisable conclusion of two influential reports, as important
3. There is a theoretical line of argument concerning this based on the attributes of programmes as public
goods and merit goods.
26
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
27
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
is not yet, and never well be, enough spectrum space for everyone to have
a personal TV channel. This is the central reason that a licence is required to
have a TV channel, and why television operators have typically been mandated
with more obligations than newspapers. That example suffices to illustrate the
technological dimension. Regarding financial parameters, the digitalisation of
broadcasting technology requires a scale of investment that accounts for many
countries deciding the costs must be at least partly covered by the state or by
telecom operators, and in quite a few European countries for stipulations that
PSB operators are obligated to make significant investments.
One should also consider the relationship between content and finance.
All programmes feature some format structure. The rights to use a successful
format are expensive in today’s highly competitive markets. Moreover, different
genres have distinctive cost structures and production process requirements.
Producing news programmes is different from producing drama programmes,
even though both are expensive. It is easier, however, to offset the cost of
successful drama production than daily news production because there is
only the most limited after-market for news while drama products can enjoy
long shelf lives and benefit from windowing strategies. The means of fund-
ing the two types of content also vary, and more or less in the same ways
in most countries. Co-production is increasingly characteristic to spread the
risk and maintain quality as costs rise, and importing formats that have been
successful elsewhere is common practice today – another way of reducing
risk, as well as cost (see the chapter by Annette Hill and Jeanette Steemers).
Most news organisations, however, bear high internal costs for coverage and
it is more difficult to co-produce, although collaboration and content shar-
ing agreements are on the increase – again, mainly for economic reasons.
Despite differences, all genres of television programming have comparatively
high degrees of demand uncertainty. This means broadcasters can’t know for
certain how successful anything they offer will be in a competitive market,
and moreover that something which is popular today may not be popular
tomorrow (DeFillippi 2009).
General similarities in the medium as such should not blur crucial distinc-
tions. How broadcasting is organised, funded and mandated is quite varied for
both practical and intentional reasons, a point recognised by the Amsterdam
Protocol for PSB, but really applicable more generally to the regulation and
operation of broadcasting systems. To use an obvious example, the structure of
broadcasting in the United States and Europe feature fundamental differences
both in ideas about media and in the intentions that are considered essential.
The American market is an overwhelmingly commercialised system that is, for
the most part, privately owned, locally licensed and highly networked. Public
broadcasting came to the USA only in the 1960s. Contrast this with Europe
where a TV ‘market’ was non-existent (except in Luxembourg) until quite re-
28
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
cently. Until the mid to late 1980s broadcasting (also in radio) was organised
as a PSB monopoly in most of Western Europe and as state broadcasting in
the former Soviet countries – as well as those under dictatorships in the West.
Today, the European media system is a competitive market featuring a dual
structure, and in that alone still provides a stark contrast with the rest of the
world. How media markets are organised, managed, mandated and operated
differs in ways that are fundamental (for example license fee funding versus
advertising revenue) and proportionate (for example how many channels can
be funded by the available resource base). To assume that one policy fits all,
or one model is suitable everywhere, is simple minded.
Contextual history must also be kept in mind when discussing what broad-
casting means and how it is organised in different countries. In the early
days of radio no one was sure how to regard its potential (Barnouw 1966).
Economic and social conditions in Europe encouraged a public service orien-
tation and television was built on the foundation earlier laid in radio. In just
the same way American TV was built on the foundation laid in radio there,
and with very different systemic properties. The expense later involved with
launching TV in Europe accounts in part for early development in European
commercial broadcasting (in the UK and Finland in the mid-1950s). This is
not to imply that developing television was easy even for the companies that
were experienced in radio. It required significant investments in new technol-
ogy and building bigger and more complex facilities, developing new skills
and talents (for example set design and lighting), and the reorganisation of
company structures and routines. But television everywhere enjoyed a ‘path
dependency’ in that it was mainly built on the chassis of existent systems in
terms of production (companies), reception (audiences) and in methods for
its financing.
Similarly, and more or less everywhere in the early days, governments were
unsure how to regard the potential of radio. There was great interest in its
potential social impact and effects, for good and ill. Contextual factors played
a significant role in channelling regulatory and systemic preferences – in de-
termining the path that would account for dependencies. The rise of fascism
in the West and communism in the East, both of which featured imperial de-
signs, encouraged European policy-makers to consider radio broadcasting too
influential to treat as an ordinary consumer good. Americans essentially agreed
that radio had an extraordinary capacity for shaping social life and percep-
tions, but given characteristic distrust for government control they thought it
better to assign radio to the private sector. Thus, contradictory trends account
for different orientations, but indicate as well that social, political and cultural
tensions everywhere played a decisive role in the determination of systems,
arrangements and relations. Decisions taken have never only been practical,
but always also ideological (see the chapter by Jackson et al).
29
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
30
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
Finally, everyone agrees that wherever television has a commercial role and
its programming functions as a commodity. This is determinant in establishing
the way programmes are conceptualised, prioritised, produced, distributed and
consumed, as a factor of how programming is financed (Lowe 2009). The cost
of producing and distributing a programme is independent of the number of
viewers that watch it. Holding geography constant, this means that it costs as
much to broadcast to five million, five thousand or five. But of course the size
of viewership has a direct bearing on per capita costs, and thus on systemic
potential. There is less revenue available from five people than five million. The
number of viewers establishes market parameters that are decisive for calculating
the profit potential of programmes as commodities, which in turn has a decisive
bearing on what is produced, and how much (see the chapter by Trappel).
These features collectively challenge the ambitions of smaller countries in
producing domestic programming. Taken together with the historic argument
of market failure for public goods, it’s clear why states intervene in media
markets – especially smaller states. Not doing so results in forms of distortion
that are less often recognised and discussed than market distortion today. It is
arguably the case that smaller states must take approaches to regulating and
legislating TV markets that are quite different from their larger counterparts –
even in some ways oppositional to how things are done in bigger countries or
wealthier economies (see the chapter by Christian Berg).
31
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
two factors of particular importance with regard to the subject of this book are
vulnerability and dependency because these relate directly to market size and
resource limitations (Trappel & Meier 1992; Puppis 2009).
We have some problems with the semantic implications because both of
these terms have a negative orientation in the sense that few today would
consider being vulnerable a positive thing, and dependence is associated with
addictions. We debated using other terms, for example ‘permeability’ and ‘ac-
commodation’. In the end we decided to continue with the commonly used
for the sake of clarity as a function of familiarity and because these terms are
used by the authors.
Smaller countries have smaller markets but, as mentioned earlier, the costs
for operation and programming tend to be as high as in bigger countries (less
the number of operators, obviously, and also depending on the volume of origi-
nal versus imported programming). There are less people to pay for broadcast
services and so the cost per capita can only be higher. This condition poses a
unique dilemma for smaller countries. On the one hand smaller countries must
be more flexible and adapt to international conditions, while on the other they
must be more steadfast in the will to support domestic production.
Smaller markets only rarely determine the tide of affairs. They are most of-
ten on the ‘receiving end’ of international pressures. So they must adapt even
while resisting pressures to adopt. They are compelled to tailor responses to
supranational trends in policy or transitional forms of incorporation, especially
conglomeration. Accommodation very often requires striking a balance between
competitive fairness to address international requirements and operational neces-
sities to contextualise for domestic conditions. If a smaller country isn’t able to
adjust to broad trends it risks undermining its own international competitiveness,
but if rendered unable to support domestic interests it risks much more than that.
Large markets are better able to withstand international pressures, indeed
they are positioned in many cases to have direct influence on what becomes an
international pressure in the first place. They are not invulnerable, but certainly
far less vulnerable to external pressures and shocks (Katzenstein 1985; Jensen
& Campbell 2006). Bigger countries with large markets are more often the
source rather than the recipient of international content in media. It has long
been noted that American television and radio channels feature small amounts
of programming originating elsewhere, and that what is broadcast from abroad
is mainly from other English-speaking countries. It will be interesting to see if
growth in programming from Latin America may change the pattern given the
growing Spanish-language minority that is positioned to become a majority in
the future (Reshaping Politics 2010).
The twin characteristics of higher vulnerability and dependency can be traced
to 1) lack of self-sufficiency in media content provision and 2) adherence to
an open economy. The same does not apply in smaller countries with closed
32
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
33
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
dated, the practice is as true today; if anything the cost differential can be even
higher as a function of rising prices due to increasing scarcity of content given
growth in the number of channels and hours of broadcasting to be filled. The
point, however, is that the cost to produce a programme or series is all in the
first copy. The revenues from international sales is “new money” on top of
whatever is generated in the domestic market, and often used to finance new
production. But for a Scandinavian series produced in the national language
of one home market, international sales are obviously very limited and even
when possible would only cover a fraction of the costs.
Because audiovisual products are not only economic goods but also cultural
products, their export market varies considerably. Smaller countries suffer much
higher limitations on average, with the exception of those that have been able
to successfully specialise in formats where the concept is sold for reproduction
with versioning to fit the local context (e.g. Endemol). Bigger countries enjoy
a two-fold advantage: they have the capacity to produce a higher volume of
original production, and they have a larger market in which to sell it – in many
cases also enormous, even global, secondary international markets. All of this
explains why it is important to accommodate differences in public expenditure on
broadcast media as a function of size in view of available revenue. Purism in free
market philosophy does neither science nor society fair service in these matters.
Smaller countries tend to be smaller markets and cannot support as many
companies. This accounts for higher concentration in smaller markets, which
can again legitimate increased levels of regulatory intervention. Without that
it can easily be the case that conglomerated companies with broader markets,
deeper pockets, and greater inventory could inundate a small country market.
Of course high quality programming is costly wherever it is produced,
and by whichever company. And guarantees of quality are no guarantee of
profitability. Bigger market companies nonetheless have greater opportunities
to spread costs, lower risks, and increase revenue streams. This happens in
part internally when a company can produce more products and expect that
at least one will be a hit, and also because foreign direct investment is more
likely for bigger market firms. This is not to imply that business is easier for
bigger market firms. Although market size might be larger and total resource
availability higher, this typically also entails more competitors fighting for share.
Business is not necessarily easier, but it is different – and that is the central
point we are driving at here.
Implications of language
As briefly noted, smaller markets have lower potential to attract commercial
funding than bigger markets, especially when broadcasting in smaller countries
accommodates a distinctive national language. Production of programming for
34
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
5. A similar wording is also in the draft for the 2009 Communication on Broadcasting in Article 42: “The Com-
mission will also take into account the difficulty some smaller Member States may have to collect the neces-
sary funds, if costs per inhabitant of the public service are, ceteris paribus, higher while equally considering
potential concerns of other media in these Member States”. The addition of the later clause is a significant
acknowledgement of the economic interests of commercial operators.
35
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
36
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
37
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
38
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
Competitiveness in TV Lower
Competition Higher markets and potential for (Higher industry concentra-
profitable niche channels, tion and greater difficulty in
especially in pay-TV. overcoming entry barriers.
More often keenly targeted
by foreign channels as part
of some regional market for
them (e.g. the Scandinavian
market).
not only have the capacity to produce far more, they also have greater pos-
sibilities that the commercial market will produce informational and cultural
programmes even for minority audiences because those are sizeable in abso-
lute terms when compared with the audience available for such products and
services in smaller market countries. Because TV has a voracious appetite this
39
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
40
Gregory Ferrell Lowe, Christian Edelvold Berg & Christian S. Nissen
stated in many cases given that domestic cultures in general show a strength
and depth that flies in the face of this. But it is certainly not overstated with
regard to weakening domestic audiovisual culture, which is today an essential
dimension of any shared social condition.
On the whole and overall, we have concluded that the differences between
television broadcasting in bigger and smaller countries are significant. That is
evident when assessing general market conditions, the operational environment
of television systems, that status of other media corporations in their strategic
designs and operations, policies preferred by governments and regulators in
markets of varying size, and in the supply characteristics of programme content
on TV screens. At the same time, it should clear that investigation reveals a fas-
cinating picture of true complexity and great diversity in comparisons of bigger
and smaller countries, as well as between smaller countries and across diverse
regions. It is not possible to draw any clean, crisp lines. That is precisely why
policy makers are needed in the first place. If it could all be handled on some
automated basis there would be no need for human judgment. We hope the
contents of this volume suggest dimensions of essential importance for making
wise judgments, the quality of which will be seen in policy designs. This book
will have done useful service if readers concur in the end that size matters for
TV broadcasting policy because one size does not fit all cases.
41
Size Matters for TV Broadcasting Policy
Appendix 1.
Three categories of countries listed by their populations in millions
Note: The numbers of population size should be qualified/updated for instance by checking in the CIA World Fact-
book, see: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/rankorder/2119rank.html listing 237 countries.
42
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale,
and Country Size
Robert G. Picard
This chapter explores the relationship between country size and the econom-
ics of broadcasting. It reveals why issues of scale create different conditions
for broadcasters and how these affect the structures, operations, and costs
of broadcasting. Based on a study of 31 European countries, it demonstrates
how a variety of factors are connected, and why size influences the type of
broadcasting system and content available in a given country. These factors
include: population size, financial resources, market structures, and content
and services provision.
The very term ‘broadcasting’ integrates the concept of size with the idea
of communicating to a large (broad) audience. It is by nature a mass medium
designed to reach aggregated audiences on a mass scale. Because it does not
involve distribution of a physical product the cost structures of broadcasting
– that is, the costs incurred and their significance to overall operations in a
firm or industry (see Picard 2010) – produce savings that are not possible for
other media such as newspapers, magazines, books, CDs, and DVDs. The cost
structures of broadcasting create efficiencies that are directly related to scale
This book is concerned with differences that broadcasters encounter as a
function of size in two aspects: 1) the total audience available in sheer numbers
at the nation-state level, and 2) the size of a country’s economy. This signals
the importance of studying broadcasting economics as a fundamental determi-
nant of systems and their characteristic dynamics. This chapter addresses that.
The conceptual foundation of broadcasting as a mass medium with advan-
tages cost structures and a unique economic basis, and the operational require-
ments for effective broadcasting, are central issues and raise important questions
about whether there are threshold requirements to realise certain benefits from
broadcasting. This chapter seeks to provide useful answers by focusing empiri-
cal investigation to determine whether there are significant differences between
smaller and larger countries that affect the kinds of broadcasting services they
provide and the scope and nature of those services.
43
Robert G. Picard
We begin with the premise that the size of the “mass” that broadcasting can
serve matters to the possibilities for broadcasting as a system. If the mass is
large then the per capita costs for providing services will be lower than if the
mass is small. This is why scale is so important to establishing the medium
in operational and systemic terms. Broadcasters in large countries are able to
achieve economies of scale in broadcast operations that aren’t possible for
smaller countries because they have more people, and hence bigger audiences
overall. They often also have more financial resources (e.g. Germany and the UK
in Europe). Smaller countries can’t typically support as many domestic public
service or commercial broadcast channels (both in radio and television), usually
have less local and regional broadcasting stations, fewer television producers,
and less domestic programming. Country size is the central issue treated in this
book because of presumed effects of scale on the content of broadcasting, and
in determining the structures and financial resource availability for broadcasting.
44
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
because a nation’s size can be measured in many ways, three of which are
most common – geographical area, population volume, or economic activity.
Geographic size
What constitutes a small country in geographic terms is in fact disputed. Coun-
tries range in size from the Vatican City at 0.2 square miles to Russia at 6.6
million square miles. In statistical analyses, some geographers consider small
to be any country falling below the median while others prefer to classify a
country as small if it is at least one standard deviation below the mean. In
general, countries are considered microstates if their geographic area is less
than 200 square miles.
Although complicated and actually rather fascinating, in considering issues
related to broadcasting services geographic area can’t be treated as a primary
indicator because it is not related to the critical mass needed to support
broadcasting enterprises. Australia, for instance, is geographically much larger
than Germany (slightly less than the size of the America’s ‘Lower 48’ states
combined), but supports far fewer broadcasting enterprises. Within Europe,
countries such as Sweden and Finland are relatively large in terms of surface
area but their broadcasting industries are constrained by population sizes.
Large countries in geographic terms, such as France, Germany, and Spain,
have large broadcasting industries with many operators that provide nation-
wide service and many others providing more discrete services for specific
regions and municipalities.
Of course geographic area does have effects on broadcasting. The territory
affects costs via the size and complexity of the necessary transmission infra-
structure to serve the country as a whole and in respective localities, however
defined. Moreover, geography also affects costs because it is more difficult and
expensive to serve highly mountainous territories than relatively flat territories
because more transmitters and repeaters are necessary maintain signal integrity
that is easily blocked by natural obstructions (mountains, peaks and ridges).
Finally, services to large territories with low population density certainly increase
the cost per viewer. It is cheaper to serve urban audiences because population
density creates advantages cost thresholds. This is everywhere evident in the
fact that there are far more channels in big cities and conurbation areas than
in rural areas or the ‘outback’ of a large territory.
Population size
The ability of countries (as well as regions and municipalities) to support
broadcasting industries is related to population because the costs of service and
economies of scale provide advantages to countries with larger populations.
45
Robert G. Picard
Economic size
Because media require financial resources, countries with larger economies
should be able to support more media operators and channels. This factor
has a determinant role in the financing of broadcasting and affects the scope
of resources available for both public service and commercial broadcasting.
The traditional measure of economic output is gross domestic product [GDP].
Worldwide and calculated in U.S. dollars, this figure ranges from $10 million in
Tuvalu (an island in Pacific Polynesia) to $14 trillion in the United States (United
States Central Intelligence Agency 2008). Most use the mean as the dividing line
between large and small countries. When making direct comparisons among
countries, economists typically prefer to use either GDP per capita or GDP
per capita adjusted for purchasing power parity (especially when comparing
countries with widely disparate economies). In 2008 the GDP per capita in
the 27 countries comprising the European Union was €23,500 (Eurostat 2008
Yearbook). For analysis within the EU, we can thus consider those below that
average as having lower GDP and those above as having higher GDP.
All things being equal one would expect wealthier nations to have more
resources to devote to providing and acquiring broadcasting services. However,
because population is a factor in domestic production, one would expect that
46
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
small countries, even wealthy ones, would face constraints on services produced.
Thus it was clear from the outset that analyses for this book would need to use
both population and wealth for assessing the impact of size on TV broadcasting.
47
Robert G. Picard
cable and satellite channels). This was not at all characteristic in the early days
of broadcasting when spectrum was a scarcity. The amount that could be used
for TV broadcasting was limited by both technological capability, but was also
restricted by governments who needed spectrum for other important functions
(especially defence applications). Before development and advances in alterna-
tive distribution systems there was no realistic possibility for the volume and
range of channels media consumers enjoy today.
In terms of hours of programming provided, by now no individual in any
competitive, mature media market can view all the hours provided by all the
operators – and increasingly not even a fraction of the total. The sheer volume
provided to choose from far exceeds the finite natural limit of 24-hours in a
day. Of course much of this additional programming is not original but rather
is syndicated, of foreign origination, and many channels feature a lot of repeat
programmes (especially themed channels).
Broadcasting is relatively unique because of non-rivalry in consumption. This
means that content use by one media consumer does not preclude its use by
others. There is also wide variance in the amount of consumption by day and
time of day. Individuals also vary in the amount of radio to which they listen
and the amount of television they view. All of these factors create unique cost
realities for broadcasters. Because costs for facilities, equipment, and operations
are relatively fixed, economies of scale in service are related to audience size.
The average cost for serving viewers (that is, cost per viewer) decreases as audi-
ence size rises and, crucially for this book, vice versa: costs per viewer increase
as population size decreases. An advantage for size occurs because there is no
marginal cost – that is, no additional extra cost per person – for serving a larger
number of viewers. Consequently, the cost is more or less the same whether
the programme is viewed by 1 million or by 1 viewer. The fixed and variable
costs remain essentially the same, thus making larger audiences more efficient.
As the number of broadcasters (and cable/satellite channels) increase, audi-
ences fragment and the average financial resources available to each broadcaster
in the market are reduced. This forces managers of broadcast enterprises to
control other costs. The three most controllable costs involve the number of
broadcast hours (total hours of broadcasting operations), the hours of pro-
gramme production (how much of the volume is originated content, which is
more expensive than importation), and genres of production (the costs vary for
different types of programmes, e.g. news versus drama). These understandably
become the focus of cost control and create incentives for broadcasters to rely
on externally syndicated production for much of their programming.
The consequences of these factors are 1) that a typical threshold level of
costs must be borne by the operator, whether broadcasters are serving smaller
or larger countries, and this is significant for operators in smaller countries be-
cause there are fewer potential listeners or viewers available; and 2) the average
48
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
cost for serving audiences will be higher in smaller than larger countries. Thus,
in terms of provision one should expect that countries with smaller popula-
tions or less financial resource availability will – on average – be expected to
broadcast fewer hours, produce less original programming, avoid expensive
genres, and acquire more syndicated programming from external producers.
As the number of broadcasters increase in a country, the average resources
available for programming each additional channel will decline, leading again
to reduced production of original programming by each operator and the
acquisition of more syndicated programming from other producers, as well as
the avoidance of expensive genres.
Because of these underlying economic and cost characteristics, managers of
broadcasting companies tend pursue strategies to maximise their audience in
terms of programme share at peak hours and in average daily share. Whenever
advertising revenue must be secured by broadcasters, whether commercial or
public service, there is need not only to maximise audience by day part but also
to maximise average income per viewer and average income per programme.
This encourages making programme choices that privilege serving those de-
mographic segments that are most attractive to advertisers. These strategies are
important because as audience size diminishes the benefits of scale diminishes
with it, and the average cost per viewer rises.
That is why one crucial benefit of licence fees and channel subscriptions is
the provision of relatively stable incomes that permit better financial planning
and programme cost allocation: the overall average income per viewer is fixed.
49
Robert G. Picard
50
Table 1. Co-relation results
GDP Ad Expend. Aud. Share # Public # Private PSB Com. TV Hours % Domestic Licence
Population /capita /capita 4 Channels Channels Channels Revenues Revenues Programming Production Fee
Population 1
Advertising
Expenditures per
Capita 0,114842461 0,899522993 1
Audience Share
for top 4 Channels -0,205288707 -0,306009546 -0,325947279 1
# Nationwide Public
Terrestrial Channels 0,525137141 0,343198953 0,456876394 -0,143983379 1
# Nationwide Private
TV channels 0,625845423 0,179266543 0,160981273 -0,063805231 0,697049367 1
Commercial TV
Operating Revenues 0,961597558 0,358152633 0,28451157 -0,265521622 0,681214693 0,65985289 0,953835649 1
Hours of programming
Broadcast 0,698508463 -0,375268113 -0,294446206 0,117769943 0,409064356 0,362292832 0,665428557 0,58829243 1
% Domestic Production 0,790374305 -0,548961677 -0,646232574 0,326016583 0,275789603 0,510187263 0,567716847 0,697386908 0,731962044 1
Licence Fee -0,1312261 0,711603386 0,809565638 0,011833391 0,232300759 -0,052526868 0,188355128 0,114213874 -0,283060454 -0,52015074 1
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
51
Robert G. Picard
Size findings
Four findings relating to population size were found important in the research.
Population has a very highly positive co-relation (revealing a very dependable
relationship) with operating revenues of PSB radio and television and with
commercial television operating revenues. Population has a highly positive
co-relation (showing a marked relationship) with the percentage of domesti-
cally produced feature films, TV films, short films, series, soaps and animation
programmes. Finally, population has a moderate positive co-relation (indicating
a substantial relationship) with the number of nationwide public and private
terrestrial channels.
These findings indicate that broadcasters in smaller states have fewer chan-
nels, lower revenues for both public and private broadcasters, and broadcast a
lower percentage of domestic programming than larger countries. These findings
meet our theoretical expectations based on broadcast economics relative to size.
When wealth is used as a size indicator, three significant findings are im-
portant. GDP per capita has a very highly positive co-relation (showing a very
dependable relationship) with advertising expenditures per capita, and a highly
positive co-relation (indicating a marked relationship) with higher licence
fees. Second, GDP per capita has a moderate negative co-relation (revealing a
substantial relationship) with the percentage of domestically produced feature
films, TV films, short films, series, soaps and animation programming.
These findings indicate that broadcasters in smaller economies (evidenced
by lower GDP per capita) have lower advertising expenditures per capita and
lower license fee levels than wealthier countries, and that they broadcast a
higher percentage of domestic programming than wealthier countries. The first
two findings confirm our theoretical expectations. The finding that countries
with lower GDP per capita produce a higher percentage of domestic entertain-
ment programming is interesting because it defies expectations. One would
normally expect that countries with lower financial resources would produce
less original programming in order to reduce costs. The reason for the finding
is unclear but it may be that broadcasters in these countries choose not to use
their resources to purchase inexpensive programming from abroad but prefer
to make more inexpensive programmes domestically.
52
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
53
Robert G. Picard
programming are typical. These findings are in line with theoretical expecta-
tions in broadcast economics.
54
Broadcast Economics, Challenges of Scale, and Country Size
Conclusions
This study of uses co-relation analysis for empirical investigation of variables
related to size in terms of both population and wealth. Clear relationships are
revealed between size (in population and GDP/capita) and the number of
broadcasting stations, volume of available resources, and scale of domestic
production. Caution is warranted because co-relation does not reveal causation
in any identified relationships. As demonstrated, however, the relationships
we’ve uncovered meet most of the theoretical expectations keyed to issues of
scale in broadcast economics. The exception is the finding that higher domestic
content provision is associated with smaller countries in terms of wealth. It is
nevertheless quite clear that size matters to revenues, services available and
domestic production (Table 2).
* Unexpected finding
The unforeseen finding that countries with lower licence fees, lower GDP, and
lower revenue for public and private broadcasting nonetheless provide a larger
percentage of domestic productions is particularly interesting. Although it can-
not be proven from the data and analysis used here, a good possibility is that
because there are fewer channels domestic content is emphasised. It would be
logical to expect that as the number of commercial channels increase there is
a tendency to see more imported syndicated programming as a consequence
of cost savings measures.
The findings also make it clear that strength of financial resources is directly
related to industry structure and performance (Table 3).
55
Robert G. Picard
Greater financial resources produce more public and private broadcast channels
Greater financial resources and industry revenues increase number of hours broadcast and
greater domestic production
This chapter has shown that from the economic standpoint, size certainly does
matter. It is highly relevant as an influence on resources, capabilities, economic
viability and the capacity for national broadcast provision. This being the case,
one cannot have the same expectations for broadcasting in smaller countries as
in larger countries and one must recognize that similar policies will not equally
viable or effective in countries of different size.
The implication is that media policy makers should be wary when looking
to larger countries as exemplars of desirable broadcast systems at home, or as
appropriate templates for guidance on domestic policy development. Instead,
optimal broadcasting policies are those that are developed to account for the
specificities of domestic economic, structural, and resource conditions.
The results also indicate that standard indicators of top-4 (and top-8) firms
used in analysis of consolidation and concentration are not particularly germane
to media markets because there is a natural concentration due to economic
conditions that typically produces less major firms in both smaller and larger
countries. This would seem to indicate that more media-specific policy rather
than general competition policy is likely warranted in the broadcasting sector.
Thus, it is clear in this analysis of empirical data from 31 European countries
that broadcasting in the EU (at least) is definitely not the same across countries.
The size of the country, both in population and wealth, is a key factor, in ad-
dition to historical, political, and cultural factors. In short, size matters because
it has a determinant bearing on the possibilities and potential outcomes for
every broadcasting system.
56
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Why David would Lose to Goliath
This chapter1 argues that every size of television market has characteristic dy-
namics that are more or less applicable everywhere, and that the explanation
of key difference lies in relative market leverage2. This can be conceptualised
as an expression of the market’s inability to allocate resources efficiently, which
is the case generally in media markets due to conditions of imperfect compe-
tition and higher potential for market failure in media goods. In this chapter
I assume that size matters for both performance and policy in TV markets,
and focus attention on how it influences market conditions. I approach the
task by examining difference in market volume and domestic programming
between smaller and larger markets. In line with the book’s premise, I utilise
both population size and economy size. Interest is especially focused on the
interaction between types of size.
We begin with quantitative analysis to clarify available revenues in respec-
tive television markets. This establishes TV market volume and is the result of
combining the three primary streams of funding for television: public subsidy,
advertising and subscription. I rely on statistical regression to investigate the
relationship between population size and economy size to see how size influ-
ences market volume. The findings are substantiated by descriptive statistics.
Secondly, I study whether size influences the level of investment in do-
mestic TV content. That is handled by investigating the volume of originated
programming, defined as all programming that is commissioned by domestic
operators rather than acquired from the international market. This is useful for
1. This chapter is a significantly reduced version of a section in my forthcoming doctoral thesis at the Copenha-
gen Business School. When published, readers will find more detailed descriptions and analysis there.
2. The definition of size applied in the regression analysis is not categorised but scaled, the reason being that
return to scale should respectively increase and decrease relative to population and economy size. The larger
the market the more efficiently it should be able to provision services. This points to a linear relationship,
with an important exception. When assessing public subsidy it becomes more a question of political choice
regarding the scale and scope of market intervention rather than size per se. Large markets, however, have
the potential to provide higher levels of subsidy, although there is no guarantee this will be utilised. When
using the term categorised size, we apply a relevant definition for large market and large Economy via GDP
PPP pr. Capita 24.216,8 US $, all other instances being considered small.
57
Christian Edelvold Berg
identifying the relationship between the two primary size variables (population
and economy) on the expenditure for originated content. The same statistical
techniques are applied.
Thirdly, I substantiate the claim that size of population and size of economy
interact. This is useful for establishing how size influences TV market volume
and expenditure on originated content both individually and through interac-
tion. Both the size of the population and the economy are important because
they influence the critical mass of the market. The larger the market the more
revenue should be available on the one hand, and the more that cost can be
spread on the other. I argue that the provisioning of domestic content is in-
fluenced by size due to the logic of collective funding and increasing returns
to scale.
The chapter begins with the essential argument, followed by three sections
where the relationships of interest are investigated. The first of those sections
focuses on why there should be a difference. That is followed by empirical
evidence about TV market volume, which shows differences in co-relation
with the size variables. The evidence for difference based on expenditure on
originated content is demonstrated in both statistical and descriptive forms.
This leads to the presentation and testing of four varieties of size. The chapter
concludes with discussion about the importance of size to how TV markets
are structured and how TV systems work.
3. Efficient scale in small markets requires relatively high levels of market share, evident in high degrees of
market concentration. Especially in the situation where advertising and subscription revenue are garnered
by international owners or investors, the distinctly domestic aspects of a TV market are correspondingly
weakened. When taking into consideration digitization, this problem may actually worsen – if not in terms
of channel supply or overall content supply, then at least in the level of domestic content supply.
58
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
4. Even in cases of subscription funding, if lacking the critical mass to facilitate production there can be no
guarantee of sufficient revenue to secure the content necessary to satisfy either consumer or public interests.
The greater the number of subscribers the further cost is spread due to the intrinsic character of broadcast
properties as non-rivalry goods.
5. Public subsidy is therefore a viable way to secure the level of provisioning desired in media content by a
particular market. But this does not necessarily mean size will determine the level of public subsidy because
that is inherently a political decision and always hinges, to a high degree, on the agreed legitimacy of market
intervention.
59
Christian Edelvold Berg
+ IRS ↓
High MES level ↓
We expect small media markets to be more vulnerable and dependent than large markets
due to increased difficulty in establishing a commercially viable domestic market as a conse-
quence of market failures ↓
Small TV market volume is less than Large TV market volume ↓
Small TV markets have less expenditure on originated content than Large TV markets ↓
Small and large markets share general characteristics caused by TV as a medium, but mana-
ging with the entailed dynamics is more challenging for small TV markets in provisioning original
domestic media content due to less market volume and lower commercial incentive. ↓
The level of Population and Economy therefore influence the relative market leverage of
volume and provisioning, both individually and through interaction.
6. I argue that domestic content while potentially non-excludable, is for the primary market audience. We can
argue that culture and language almost by definition will act as excluding factors which influence what and
where the firm can acquire productions for domestic audiences.
60
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Smaller and larger media markets certainly share challenges that are inherent for
broadcasting, and other forms of mass media (especially newspapers) for that
matter. These create considerable difficulties in ensuring adequacy in the public
service dimensions of media, long accepted as being of essential importance in
the EU and other mature democracies (at least) because media are necessary
for serving the democratic, cultural and social needs of respective societies. It
has also long been accepted that smaller countries share relatively unique chal-
lenges in being subject to significantly higher degrees of vulnerability to and
dependency on foreign-originated content. This legitimates varying amounts of
policy intervention that are intended to correct deficiencies. This is a familiar
premise in numerous reports (see for example Peacock 1986; the Amsterdam
Protocol of 1997; UNESCO 2005). This is also in line with provisions in the Com-
munication on Broadcasting issued by the European Commission regarding the
application of State aid rules to public service broadcasting (2009, no.42), where
it is explicitly noted that smaller member states face real limitations in being
able to finance public services in media due to the higher cost per inhabitant.
The market in and of its self cannot be expected to provision the full vari-
ety of desired programmes, especially in smaller countries with their reduced
volumes of domestic resources. To this we can add the even greater problems
in doing so with regard to informational and educational programmes that are
not typically profitable for commercial business. In practice this means that
while the relative costs for a one-hour production are relatively the same in
Germany and Denmark, for example, the main difference lies in the number of
people available to co-finance production, as well as the relative wealth of the
respective societies (an issue that becomes especially pointed, for instance, in
certain countries in Eastern and Central Europe today). As a function of popu-
lation size alone, Danes must pay more per capita than Germans if they want
to enjoy the full range of media goods that are typically considered necessary
for democracy, society and culture.
The background to this discussion hinges on the notion of a public interest
in providing specific media goods and services to society as a whole, and which
are inherently beyond the more particular tastes of an individual consumer
(McQuail 1992). This implies the importance of accounting for differences in
the volume of public expenditure on media as a factor of available revenue.
Of course the commercial sector has an understandable interest in establishing
common markets and promoting free trade. The potential of export markets
does significantly increase business opportunity. But it is equally understandable
that in smaller markets policymakers have an interest that is quite reasonable to
ensure the viability of domestic audiovisual production in all the varied genres
of content and media products necessary to the well-being of the societies for
which they are responsible, and to which they must be accountable. The fact
that it is understandable on both sides accounts for continuing disagreement
61
Christian Edelvold Berg
between the EU and US over policy in television trade (among other things).
The US claims that the EU violated GATT agreement in formulating policies
that require some percentage of European originated works in the totality of
programme output in member states (e.g. in the Television without Frontiers
directive from 1989 that was recently amended in 2007 as the Audiovisual Media
Services directive). For more about all these policy concerns see the chapter
by Erik Nordahl Svendsen.
EU legislation since the mid-1980s has facilitated the establishment of the
dual system of public and private broadcasting sectors competing in Europe,
and facilitating a strong commercial media sector that is now able to compete
in scale and scope across Europe. This has undeniably benefitted diversity in
content and pluralism in provision. Although under fierce attack today, public
subsidy has factually been essential to ensuring that competition is robust for
markets where it would otherwise collapse due to problems inherent with
economies of scale inside and across European media markets. Ironically,
however, EU policy is today limiting the competence of state policy to handle
media matters, matters that have undeniable importance for both historical and
cultural interests as well as efficacy in the performance of competition. The
evidence points to very different conclusion than the noisy contrary claims
about public subsidy creating ‘unfairness’ in conditions of competition.
Here we are dealing with material limitations and necessities caused by
differing levels of market leverage potential in variously sized markets, which
affect abilities to provision domestic public services in media. Despite claims of
market distortion and the desire for some universally applicable template to fairly
steer media policy in respective member states, variability in market conditions
means that what might counts as distortion in one country could not be fairly
be considered as such in another country. There is no universal best practice.
Rather, policy in each member state must take account of all the particularities
and traits of each respective television market, even if the medium as a technol-
ogy has inherent characteristics that create commonly shared challenges – as
noted earlier. There is a case to be made that in the struggle between com-
mercial and cultural interests, which is certainly evident in EU media policies,
what has been taking shape in recent years appears tailored more for catering
to the interests of the large member states with their inherent advantages than
for the small member states with their inherent disadvantages. Complexity in
markets is not, apparently, something the EU is all that competent to deal with.
62
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
not be included for analysis due to lack of comparability in the kinds of data
collected, and how it is collated in different countries and regions. There are
especially severe limitations regarding the expenditure on originated content.
The markets I have been able to include are presented in the Table 1.
POPCAT
Small Large
N 22 13
Bulgaria, Croatia, Estonia, Poland, Romania,
Small 12
Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Turkey, Ukraine
TV market Slovakia, Portugal Australia, Canada,
ECONCAT
volume Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Czech France, Germany,
Republic, Denmark, Finland, Italy, Japan, Spain,
Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, UK
Large 23
New Zealand, Norway, Slove-
nia, Sweden, Switzerland
POPCAT
N Small Large
19 17
Bulgaria, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Romania
Small 9 Latvia, Lithuania, Slovakia,
Expenditure
Portugal
on originated ECONCAT
Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, France, Germany,
content
Czech Republic, Denmark, Italy, Spain, UK
Large 17 Finland, Greece, Ireland,
Netherlands, Norway, Slovenia,
Sweden
7. For public revenue the decision has been to include radio revenue in the figure because this is inseparable
in the data for most markets where all PSB is handled by a single company. For markets such as Sweden
and Romania where the figures are divided I had to therefore aggregate them to achieve comparable figures
necessary for analysis.
63
Christian Edelvold Berg
64
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Coefficient (OLS) 154,459 *** 0,006 *** 281,356 *** 0,009 ***
SE 14,885 0,000 15,741 0,000
t-statistic 10,377 25,074 17,874 37,896
Constant -308,935 -138,690 -2962,525
SE 561,130 243,926 992,351 -136,410
t-statistic -0,551 -0,569 -2,985 -2,952
Observations 34 34 35 35
*** (**) [*] denote significance at p < 0.01, (p < 0.05), [p < 0.1].
1. This needs further analysis on the hypothesized relationship between POP, ECO and TV MV can be written like this:
Regression: Y = + βX + , equal to TV MV = + βPOP + & equal to TV MV = + βECO +
Where = The constant term (the MS with a population or economy of zero), β = The effect of increased PS or ES in
terms of 1mn on MS in mn. Euro (the coefficient of the independent variable), = The error function, that other factors
influence MS (non-observed/non-observable factors).
2. Using the method of stepwise forward in the regression analysis led to the omitting of population, therefore I have
performed two separate analysis of these, in short economy appear as the variable explaining most of the variance.
3. The t-test being 107,67 and 628,690 is different from Zero. Beta coefficients refers to the change in the slope of the
line, meaning the change in market size based on change in population (under the function of MS = + βP).
4. Furthermore, we can reject that the data is auto correlated as the values are within the range of 1,5-2.5 and thus
assume independence of observations.
65
Figure 1. TV market volume by type of revenue in millions of euros € ordered by largest volume1
66
84,9 43668,6 51229,8 1. USA
3911,6 12379,9 9015,3 2. Japan
5135,9 4743,3 6333,2 3. UK
7249,9 4240,3 2636,1 4. Germany
2368,9 4306 3634,5 5. France
1588 4646,2 2130,4 6. Italy
673,3 2285,8 4333,8 7. Canada
436,9 3373 1644,2 8. Spain
620,6 1995,8 1199,2 9. Australia
605,3 829,4 1119,7 10. Netherlands
476,3 1123,5 577,7 11. Belgium
156 1413,6 428 12. Hungary
196,9 846 943,8 13. Poland
657 473,5 753,9 14. Sweden
676,5 576,4 582,6 15. Switzerland
471,9 759,2 562,3 16. Norway
PS
321,5 934,6 436,7 17. Turkey
450,9 353,3 582,6 18. Denmark AD
241 503,6 576,1 19. Portugal
473 569,9 264,4 20. Austria SU
182,3 925,6 163,1 21. Czech Republic
323,8 716,2 176,9 22. Greece
41,2 954 108,6 23. Slovakia
215,5 261 449,6 24. Romania
387,2 253,9 262,6 25. Finland
Christian Edelvold Berg
1. The table has been constructed using data from the following sources, for advertisement revenue a combination of World association of Newspapers annual publication in combination with the Euromonitor database for
exchange rates and corrections, the figure representing the method of calculating this in the individual markets. The subscription revenue is from the Screen Digest Television intelligence database representing the individual
domestic market figures. The public revenue is from a combination of sources where annual reports of financial figures in combination with Screen Digest and controlled using EBU figures. Furthermore, in markets where public radio
companies are independent, their public subsidy has been included in the calculations to ensure comparability, the only market where this is not the case is the US – this is not to been perceived as a major skewing, but rather a
relatively small bias. The inclusion of public radio revenue was to secure that the markets with separate companies did not fall below the level of similar markets, where television and radio are combined. Separate ranking tables
of the individual revenue types are in available in appendix 1A-1D.
Source: Screen Digest, WAN and GMID
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
UK followed by Germany, France and Italy. The middle markets are largely
comprised of Nordic states along with Switzerland and Austria, but there are
large population markets with weak economies such as Poland. It is interest-
ing to observe the diversity of revenue levels across markets. It’s clear that
respective individual markets rely on different proportions for funding from
the three revenue streams.
In fact, analysis reveals that most markets apply public subsidy to some
degree. But the level is quite different for several smaller population markets,
which apply public subsidy to a higher degree in order to reach a higher mar-
ket volume. Moreover, this is done mainly via PSB. Public subsidisation and
subscription revenue play major roles in some markets, as well. But what seems
of greatest importance to media companies is that the diversity of revenue has
varying risk reduction potential in relation to wider fluctuations of domestic
and regional economies. European markets in general have small populations
in comparative terms, and thus even in large economy markets like Germany
and the UK public subsidy plays a strong role in supporting domestic audio-
visual production. We should also observe that the markets with the largest
advertising revenue are among those with the strongest private commercial
media companies. It is fair to say that most markets are small in comparison
with giants like the USA and Japan.
1. Due to the US effect, the tables below will include data with and without the numbers from the US. First we will look
into total revenue and then revenue per capita.
There is a lot of variance between the figures, even without the USA included.
The average for advertising revenue in large population markets is €3.362 bil-
lion, while average subscription is €2.740 billion and public funding averages
€1.894 billion. That adds up to a total of €7.996 billion on average. In small
population markets the averages are much smaller: €537 million for advertis-
ing, €319 million for subscription, €261 million for public revenue, for a total
67
Christian Edelvold Berg
68
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
10. It is important to remember that subscription also functions as a club good because there are packages
(tiers) instead of free channel choice.
11. The difficulty is that the services are not available. If all available content is imported and there is no domestic
content, then the market must be evaluated differently.
12. In principle small markets could subsidise more than large, but it would of course represent a higher per-
centage of their GDP to do so.
69
Christian Edelvold Berg
*** (**) [*] denote significance at p < 0.01, (p < 0.05), [p < 0.1].
1. Using a multiple regression analysis is not viable, as applying the method of stepwise forward in the regression ana-
lysis led to the omitting of population, therefore I have performed two separate analysis of these, in short economy
appear as the variable explaining most of the variance.
70
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
larger the market, the more able it is to provision such goods. We assume that
size influences the level of expenditure on originated content. This requires
analysis of the hypothesised relationship between size regressed on expendi-
ture for originated content.
The regression confirms our expectation: Every additional one million in
either population or economy sizes influences the level of expenditure on
originated content. The figures indicate that size in a European context has
convincing explanatory strength13. The larger these variables, the more market
leverage and, consequently, the higher the level of expenditure on originated
content. The findings verify our hypothesis on the relationship between size
and originated content, and are precisely as expected in economic theory.
Population and economy size help establish the framework conditions for
market volume, as earlier indicated in this analysis, and thus secure conditions
for commercial broadcast activity in allowing utilisation of economies of scale.
It is especially important to understand that private commercial companies
are able to utilise economies of scale across markets, while public broadcast-
ers are confined to function in the home domestic market, thereby necessarily
limiting their capabilities to utilise proximate economies of scale. This makes
sense, given the general scarcity of talent and resources that correspondingly
limit the scope of what is possible in domestic production. Very often, as well,
a considerable portion of available resources must be invested in news and
current affairs programmes because these are so highly relevant to the public
service mandate, but for such programming the export potential is extremely
low in smaller markets with unique languages. Large market conditions estab-
lish more viable frames for commercial activity even here because it becomes
more feasible to achieve economies of scale also because their languages tend
to be spoken abroad. Smaller markets thus function as subsidiaries where the
larger production companies find it attractive to gain market entry or to set up
ventures that allow them to better utilise economies of scale largely already
achieved elsewhere. In general it is fair to say that smaller states can only real-
istically counter some of these challenges by relying on PSB, i.e. by investing
public revenue in public media. Obviously this will not counter everything, nor
should it in the interests of pluralism. Moreover, even when more successful
than on average it can’t produce perfect competitive conditions. On the other
hand, no media system anywhere under any conditions has yet produced
perfect competition.
There is a surprise when studying the affects of size on expenditure on
originated content [EOC], however. We expected to find less revenue was
spent on new domestic content in large markets on a per capita basis. This
was not the case.
13. Population regressed on EOC give an adj. r(26) = .810, p < .001 and where economy regressed on EOC give
an adj. r(26) = .936, p < .001.
71
Christian Edelvold Berg
POPCAT ECOCAT
Total in € mn € per Capita1 Total in € mn € per Capita
1. The per capita calculations are based on population per 1st of January 2007
72
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Latvia 11
Lithuania 13
Estonia 14
Cypros 17
Slovenia 43
Slovakia 68
Bulgaria 73
Hungary 119
Romania 125
Czech Republic 167
Finland 262
Greece 269
Ireland 278
Austria 279
Portugal 310
Poland 334
Sweden 343
Norway 360
Belgium 413
Denmark 469
Netherlands 605
Spain 1346
Italy 1669
France 2524
UK 4140
Germany 4512
73
Christian Edelvold Berg
Lithuania 3,8
Latvia 4,8
Romania 5,8
Poland 8,8
Bulgaria 9,6
Estonia 10,4
Hungary 11,8
Slovakia 12,6
Czech Republic 16,2
Cypros 19,9
Slovenia 21,4
Greece 24,1
Italy 28,3
Portugal 29,2
Spain 30,3
Austria 33,6
Netherlands 37
Sweden 37,6
Belgium 39,1
France 41,1
Finland 49,6
Germany 54,8
Ireland 64,7
UK 68,2
Norway 77,1
Denmark 86,1
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Source: Oliver & Ohlbaum performance, own calculations based on national statistics on population collected by
Euromonitor.
The evidence is conclusive: market size does impact the level of provisioning
for originated content. However, there are differences among the small states
and markets in their ability to provision, with the main difference reflected in
per capita figures. The result is not always purely a matter of market econom-
ics, but rather indicates the importance of political choices via the affordance
of subsidy.
74
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Economy
Population Small Large
In Table 7 we are utilising the four types of size devised for analysis in this
chapter. Each type has different degrees of market leverage. We can concep-
tualise the challenges posed by size based on similarity and difference in the
markets.
• Type 1 markets have smaller populations and poorer economy condi-
tions (-,-). This market type has the lowest potential leverage because the
population is relatively small, which limits potential for spreading costs,
and it has low economy potential due to smaller market volume, which
typically results in less originated content.
• Type 2 markets have smaller populations but richer economy conditions
(-,+). This market type has the same small ‘club’ characteristics as Type 1
markets, but the commercial market potential is greater due to wealthier
economic conditions overall. This condition also enables greater latitude
for political intervention in the provision of subsidy. The economic con-
ditions enhance the potential for originated content.
• Type 3 markets have larger populations with poorer economy conditions
(+,-). This market type has a big ‘club’ to draw on, which enhances po-
tential for commercial investment and public subsidy despite relatively
75
Christian Edelvold Berg
76
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Conclusion
Size has been overlooked, even ignored, as a significant factor for addressing
the challenges that face television markets in Europe (at least, and probably
also beyond). This is a grave oversight in the construction of media policies,
77
Christian Edelvold Berg
78
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
public subsidisation. This is especially evident for the UK and Germany, and
differs quite a lot from markets such as Poland and Romania.
Analysis also revealed the influence of size on the basis of relative impor-
tance as this depends on size variety. We found statistically significant effects
for the categorised size variables on both TV market volume and expenditure
on originated content, and moreover the interaction between the categorised
size variables supported the validity of the proposed model. This suggests
that the most appropriate perspective reckons with distinctive challenges that
respective markets face, in combination with variability in political interest as
expressed by public subsidy and regulatory measures, as well as more general
historic and cultural traditions in these markets. As argued in the introductory
chapter, one size of policy doesn’t fit all size of markets.
Of course TWF (and presumably now also AVMSD) has helped establish
European broadcasting as an integrated market, and this has benefitted the
development of many companies that are able to utilise economies of scale
to function more efficiently. But this has also certainly challenged particular
market types with a level of competition they cannot easily withstand, and in
fact can only cope with adequately by erecting certain barriers of entry. We are
not intending to imply that current European media legislation doesn’t allow
for consideration of distinctive needs of different member state markets. This
is possible for instance under Article 107(3) (d) of the Treaty, which allows
state aid on the basis of cultural considerations, as for instance to promote
cultural diversity. But most often this is not applied to media per se, especially
mass media, which are treated more along the lines of traditional manufactur-
ing and service industries. Taking this into account, then, EU policy has both
merits and de-merits, so to say, which reveals a peculiar kind of schizophrenia
as suggested earlier.
The short conclusion of this chapter is that size matters in defining the
level of market volume and originated content. The tested relationships have
been verified as statistically significant, confirming our hypotheses. We have
also established the importance of subsidised and regulated television markets
for the competitive interests of states faced with significant competition from
external sources. Further, we have substantiated that the four varieties of size
are significant in identifying differences in the interaction of the categorised
size variables. This indicates that when one discusses size he or she should
take into account not only the relative level or population but also the level of
economic development vis a vis per capita purchasing power. Also notable is
that the level of political intervention in media markets clearly impacts the level
of TV market volume and expenditure on originated content through public
subsidy, and that this is especially the case in the economically strong markets.
The model has policy implications for media market regulation. Policymak-
ers should take into account the differences that size make on system param-
79
Christian Edelvold Berg
80
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
evolve policies that are appropriate for application that properly address
the respective interests of every size of member state.
2. Media companies in bigger states that are able to utilise large market
scale benefits are reaping the benefits of EU policies today, while those
in smaller states are mainly facing keener challenges, especially their PSB
operators. These can’t enjoy the same scale advantages because they are
limited to domestic markets and entrusted with the specific purpose of
securing domestic production.
3. Currently EU media policy mainly benefits member states that have both
large population and economy markets, while member states with small
population and economy markets suffer the most adverse effects of vari-
ous trends, including deregulation and stricter governance on matters of
subsidy.
4. No one-size-fits-all policy is a best option for Europe as a whole because
in matters of media, it is not (and might never be) exclusively a single
market. In media, at least, Europe is a union of numerous single markets,
each with their own distinctive conditions, needs and interests. There
can’t be unity without accommodating diversity.
5. EU media policy that is oriented to benefit the interests of media industry
in larger and wealthier member states will likely have detrimental impact
by limiting the options for smaller state policy responses.
6. Political intervention through public subsidy is of cornerstone importance
for securing domestic production throughout Europe.
7. PSB operators are the best instruments currently available for securing
adequate domestic production in both small and large domestic markets.
There is nothing so far to suggest that PSB is replaceable or substitutable.
8. Key differences between small and large markets are accounted for by
the public media sector because it does the best job of offsetting scarcity.
The question raised in this analysis is whether the media should be treated as
an ‘ordinary business’, no different from industries that toasters or pencils? If the
answer acknowledges there are significant differences, then a one-size policy
is not appropriate for a multi-sized Europe. Personally, the analysis leads me
to conclude that it is far from any ordinary business, despite having business
interests and an important role in business generally. Media are distinctive in
that both market and content good characteristics create imperfect conditions
for competition, and limit investment in original production as a result of un-
certainty of profitability. This is clearly, especially the case in smaller markets.
Political intervention in the European television market is an important remedy
81
Christian Edelvold Berg
82
Appendix 1A. Public subsidy in millions of euros €
Appendix 1A: Public subsidy in millions of euros € Appendix
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
83
84
Estonia
Appendix 1B.
Latvia
Lithuania
Slovenia
Cyprus
Bulgaria
Ukraine
Croatia
New Zealand
Ireland
Finland
Romania
Slovakia
Greece
Czech Republic
Advertisement revenue in millions of euros €
Austria
Appendix 1B: Advertisement revenue in millions of euros €
Portugal
Denmark
Turkey
Norway
Switzerland
Sweden
Poland
Hungary
Belgium
Netherlands
Australia
Spain
Canada
Italy
France
Germany
UK
Japan
USA
Christian Edelvold Berg
Appendix 1C. Subscription revenue in million €
Appendix 1C: Subscription revenue in million €
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
85
Appendix 1D. Total TV market revenue in million €
86
Appendix 1D: Total TV market revenue in million €
Christian Edelvold Berg
Appendix 2C. General linear model Multivariate tests of the relationship between the independent and dependent variables
Intercept Pillai's Trace ,837 53,864 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,837 107,728 1,000
Wilks' Lambda ,163 53,864 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,837 107,728 1,000
Hotelling's Trace 5,130 53,864 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,837 107,728 1,000
Roy's Largest Root 5,130 53,864 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,837 107,728 1,000
POPCAT Pillai's Trace ,677 22,041 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,677 43,081 1,000
Wilks' Lambda ,323 22,041 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,677 43,081 1,000
Hotelling's Trace 2,099 22,041 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,677 43,081 1,000
Roy's Largest Root 2,099 22,041 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,677 43,081 1,000
a
ECOCAT Pillai's Trace ,652 19,650 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,652 39,300 1,000
Wilks' Lambda ,348 19,650 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,652 39,300 1,000
Hotelling's Trace 1,871 19,650 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,652 39,300 1,000
Roy's Largest Root 1,871 19,650 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,652 39,300 1,000
POPCAT
* ECOCAT Pillai's Trace ,590 15,111 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,590 30,222 ,997
Sizing Up Size on TV Markets
Wilks' Lambda ,410 15,111 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,590 30,222 ,997
Hotelling's Trace 1,439 15,111 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,590 30,222 ,997
Roy's Largest Root 1,439 15,111 a 2,000 21,000 ,000 ,590 30,222 ,997
87
Appendix 2D. General linear model Tests of Between-Subjects Effects
88
Dependent Type III Sum Partial Eta Noncent. Obs.
Source Variable of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Squared1 Parameter Power2
Total TV MV 5,669E8 26
Christian Edelvold Berg
EOC 5,004E7 26
1. The partial eta square is a nonlinear similar to the R-square in the regressions above
2. Computed using alpha = ,05
The Socio-Cultural Context
of Broadcasting Markets
John D. Jackson
with
Yon Hsu (on Taiwan), Geoffrey Lealand (on New Zealand),
Brian O’Neill & Michael Foley (on Ireland) & Christian Steininger
(on Austria)
Markets as social institutions vary considerably across national boundaries in
response to the particular historical and socio-cultural contexts in which they
are located. In this respect media markets in relatively small countries may well
develop in response to the dominant social, cultural and economic links with
their larger, more powerful neighbours in addition to local conditions. In the
process public services rest uneasily beside commodity markets such that public
services too are rapidly converted into commodities. Furthermore, broadcast-
ing systems, which are preoccupied with the divergence between market and
non-market goods, are likely to be implicated in negotiations between national
identity and economic imperatives.
Accordingly, broadcasting in small countries, neither more nor less than in
large ones, requires an appreciation of the properties of media as subsystems
within the larger social system of which they are a part. To understand media
systems and their market components in relation to a broader social, political
and cultural framework requires a set of conceptual tools that can capture market
structures and practices as interacting elements within media subsystems, on
the one hand, and in relation to the larger social system on the other. Figure
1 portrays this complexity.
A media subsystem and its composite interacting elements (creators, pro-
viders, markets and receivers) is shaped by and shapes existing political and
legal institutions (the state), socio-cultural and political values (ideology),
and methods of exchange and ways of deploying labour and matériel (the
economy). For example, television and press decisions to select, broadcast and
print certain events over others may strongly influence or be influenced by
political action and public values. However, the representation of broadcasting
organisations as a system can be taken only so far. Implied is the presence of
some system that is established, orderly and predictable. And so it is, but only
in a very limited way. Disorder accompanies order; the urge to rearrange the
relations inherent in the parts and to institute totally new relations is always
89
John D. Jackson
Creators: Receivers:
Journalists, Audience as
Writers, Commodity;
Performers Audience as
citizen
• POLITICAL • SOCIO-
VALUES CULTURAL
VALUES
90
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
economic processes varies from country to country, although the literature does
suggest the possible presence of commonalities among smaller countries in a
variety of size indicators: population, density, geography, or global economic
and political power (Puppis, d’Haenens, Steinmaurer and Künzler 2009).
Addressing the issue of size is the first task. Next we will consider some ty-
pologies used in the literature to examine the political-economy of broadcasting.
This, in turn, provides a baseline for the construction of a model incorporating
the state, the economy and political and social values on the one hand and
selected broadcasting parameters on the other. This produces a heuristic device
that is useful for examining broadcasting systems in five selected states. Table
1 lists the selected states by population size and density. Note the dramatic
differences, but also consider the key similarity among these five states: each
borders a powerful state and each shares a major language with that neighbour.
1. The 3.4 individuals per square kilometer cover a vast territory. The Northern regions cover 39% of the area of Ca-
nada but include only 0.3% of the population. The vast majority of Canadians live within 100 kilometers of the United
States border. Canada’s 33 metropolitan census areas, all close to the U.S. border, when combined yield a popula-
tion density of 238 per square kilometer.
In part this selection was made to move beyond the European Union, the set-
ting toward which most studies of small states have, of late, been addressed.
However, the selection was principally influenced by a shared language and
location rather than size per se. The selection was based on the fact that each
faces a large and powerful neighbour, with whom it more or less shares a
common language. Relative rather than absolute size holds when we contrast
Canada to the United States, New Zealand to Australia, Ireland to the United
Kingdom, Austria to Germany and Taiwan to China.
91
John D. Jackson
Steinmaurer opts for relative regional and global political power (Austria vs.
Germany), common language and relative size; Germany is “roughly 10 times
larger” (2009: 78). Grisold compared newspaper markets in Ireland and Aus-
tria and defined small states as those with a “big more powerful neighbour”
where the same language is spoken (1996: 485). In a collection of conference
papers published during the revival of the small states problematique in the
mid-eighties under the title, Small States in Europe and Dependence, numerical
definitions of size were for the most part avoided but the implied definition
points to the significance of dependence (Höll 1983). Steinmaurer (2009) incor-
porates dependence and a common language in his definition of “smallness”.
Thus and apart from sheer size itself, two conditions stand out in the litera-
ture: dependence (economic and/or political) and sharing a language with a
more powerful neighbour (in effect, cultural dependence insofar as language
carries a speaker’s worldview). Our selections for analysis in the present study
(Austria, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand and Taiwan) are all situated in close
proximity to powerful neighbours that share a common language, and each
is at least somewhat economically dependent on that neighbour. The reader
should note that neither Canada nor Taiwan meet the “20 million” threshold
referred to in the introduction to this work. Nevertheless, both, as well as the
remaining three, are small states relative to their immediate neighbour with
whom they share varying but important cultural as well as economic depend-
ence. So even though the numerical threshold is not met in all of our case
study sites, the dynamics and principles for analysis hold for the purposes of
the research reported in this volume.
In search of a model
Keeping in mind that markets are complex social institutions linked to state
bureaucracies and the political and socio-cultural life of societies, models that
take into account – or at least imply – an awareness of such connections are
of keen interest. Colin Leys proposed four elements to assess the politics of
the marketplace: (1) the role of the State; (2) the power of industry associa-
tions and lobbyists; (3) structural power (e.g. the ability of one industry or
cluster of industries to dominate a market); and (4) networks of elites or the
“social embeddedness of the market” in question (2001: 86). Although his
model features no specific reference to small states or broadcasting, it points
to a set of dimensions that reveal key nodes and connections between the
state and economic, political and socio-cultural elements. Three dimensions
of note emerge from this typology: (1) the political, in the sense of the mode
of governance; (2) the economic, in the sense of corporate control of markets;
and (3) the social, in the sense of interlocking elites.
92
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
Three other works employ models for media analyses in which economic
and political dimensions are brought into play. Picard (1985: 6) used a model
to organise observations on the economics of the press. The five-point model
he proposed focuses on “patterns of intervention [which] presumably reveal
underlying political and economic policies”. In their analysis of non-western
media, Curran and Park (2000:12-13) posed the following questions: “(1) how
do media relate to the power structure of society; (2) what influences the media
and where does control…lie; (3) how has the media influenced society; [and] (4)
what effect has media globalization and new media had…?” To usefully respond
to these questions they constructed a typology keyed to political systems (demo-
cratic or authoritarian) and economic systems (neoliberal or regulated). Hallin
and Mancini (2004: 30-31) proposed an influential heuristic in their comparative
analysis of media systems, suggesting three “models of media systems” that in-
corporate political and economic elements along with methods of governance.
A model proposed
We are inclined to select value orientations that, among other structural elements
of social systems, suggest the presence of a shared symbolic system. This can
be understood as a device for the articulation of general cultural, social and
political traditions with media subsystems (following Parsons 1951: 12). Society-
wide or general value orientations also provide a reference point from which
various parameters of subsystems may be ascertained (Parsons 1961: 38-39;
see also Luhmann 1995: 317-319). Curran and Park (2000) and Picard (1985)
referred to above adopt, in one way or another, political and economic value
orientations as reference points for their analyses. Succinctly put, values lead
to “preferences in choosing between alternatives for action” (Friedrichs 1968:
113; Luhmann 1995: 577). Returning to Figure 1, we require a model that will
permit us to link value orientations at the system level with the parameters of
broadcasting at the subsystem level.
We begin this quest by noting that states have two major functions. First,
the state legitimates society as a whole in the eyes of its population – the com-
posite of its social, cultural, and economic properties as a system. Second, in
capitalist societies the state buttresses markets and capital accumulation with
sector subsidies, bailouts, negotiating trade opportunities, and the like. Public
services, such as health care, transportation and public broadcasting, serve in
turn to help legitimate the state. Negotiating trade pacts, subsidising media
industries and providing a regulatory regime favourable to private broadcast-
ers promote capital accumulation. In any particular country it is a question of
emphasis regarding the relative priorities, and states are challenged with the
need to maintain some balance (often delicate) between the two functions. But
93
John D. Jackson
it is certainly true that states do shift emphasis over time and in response to
changing contexts. From a market perspective such a shift may move a society
away from privileging pubic goods and services towards favouring private
goods and services, or vice versa. Private goods and services are relatively
exclusive in the sense that price and disposable income determine access to
a high degree, while public goods and services are relatively inclusive, even
encouraging access for all.
It should be added that legitimation practices indirectly support capital ac-
cumulation. A public health care plan reduces corporate labour costs. American
automotive companies have readily relocated in Canada because, among other
things, these costs are significantly less of a burden under a public system.
And of course actions designed to support capital accumulation may indirectly
contribute to the legitimation function, as well. Private broadcasters that pro-
vide local news and information programming and current affairs talk shows
certainly contribute to the legitimation of their existence and the state.
Following Macpherson (1962) it is useful to note, then, that within a socio-
cultural domain normative emphases may underscore either a possessive indi-
vidualism at the core of accumulation, or a sense of collective responsibility
(stewardship) at the core of societal legitimation. Possessive individualism
highlights the principals of self-reliance, independence and consumption.
Collective responsibility and stewardship flips the coin, placing emphasis on
interdependence, community, and the common weal. Of course, private goods/
public goods and individualism/stewardship are neither polar opposites nor
a dualism. The relation is properly dialectical with the interactive elements
constantly seeking but never reaching any final synthesis.
With all of this in mind, we suggest two types of value orientations, combin-
ing political, economic and social elements:
A Classical Liberal or Neo-conservative orientation in which political values
emphasise capital accumulation; economic emphasis is on private goods
and services with a competitive marketplace economy, and socio-cultural
emphasis is on possessive individualism with a comparatively low value
placed on stewardship.
A Contemporary Liberal or Welfare State orientation in which political values
emphasise legitimation functions; economic emphasis is on public non-market
services and on intervention as an act of stewardship, and socio-cultural em-
phasis is on collective responsibility and a high level of stewardship.
Each type points to an emphasis and should not be understood as an either/
or schema. Moreover, insofar as each type is the antithesis of the other, one
would expect that at any selected time movement would be in one direction
or the other, from one or the other position, straining towards a synthesis –
which will not be finally achieved.
94
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
Over the last few years Canada, Austria, Ireland and New Zealand show
evidence of moving from an earlier emphasis on a contemporary liberal orien-
tation toward a neo-conservative orientation. In contrast, Taiwan has remained
at the neo-conservative end of the spectrum without evidence of much move-
ment. Taiwan has maintained its social and political distance from China and
consciously opposed socialism along with China’s position on Taiwan’s national
integrity. This demonstrates that the emphasis is never only economic, however
important or bedrock that is to a particular system (such as the USA and the
EU), but always also strongly political and socio-cultural.
The next step is to isolate certain defining characteristics or parameters
of broadcasting to permit linkage between values orientations at the general
systems level and broadcasting at the media subsystem level. The following
are relevant to this inquiry:
•The significance of national identity
•The extent of public funding
•The extent of private or commercial funding
•Regulatory regime bias
Drawing on this, Table 2 points to a set of hypotheses as possible links, and
intended to set a framework in place for evaluating broadcasting in the five
selected countries. In the next section we assess each of the five selected cases
using this framework.
Austria
In Austria, the mass media are generally subject to a dual regime – a mixture
of economic and constitutional elements – under which the public service
sector is subject to greater traditional, legal regulations and the private sector
95
John D. Jackson
96
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
Canada
Broadcasting began in Canada, as in the United States, as a commercial en-
terprise during the 1920’s. During the late 20’s and into the depression of the
30’s, Canadian political circles increasingly placed a high value on creating
and maintaining a strong national identity relative to the United States – and
the UK. To combat what was becoming an overwhelming onslaught from U.S.
broadcasters, Canadian public broadcasting was established at the local level
in Edmonton and Winnipeg and in a string of local production units across
the country that were owned and operated by the Canadian National Railways
(CNR), a Crown corporation operating stations in Halifax, Montreal, Winnipeg
and Vancouver. The purpose was to provide entertainment and news for their
transcontinental passengers. The CNR operated competitively along-side the
Canadian Pacific Railway, a privately owned corporation. This points to a
characteristic feature of the Canadian social system: there has always been a
private / public mix inscribing “National Policy” since the country’s Confedera-
tion in 1867. Public or Crown Corporations were common in transportation,
communications and resource extraction.
Political values embedded in the National Policy stressed legitimation func-
tions as Canada acted to define its self as a distinctive nation vis-à-vis the large
neighbour influences of the United States. Simultaneously national policies in
transportation, financial services, communications and immigration acted to
link resources mainly situated in the western provinces with manufacturing
mainly located in eastern provinces in lieu of powerful north/south economic
97
John D. Jackson
ties with the United States. As for broadcasting, private and public broadcasting
continue to exist side by side in a state of constant tension.
The Canadian Radio/Television Commission [CRTC] is the regulatory agency,
and is ultimately responsible to Parliament. Broadcasting regulations have
assumed that frequencies are public property, and that controls should be
applied to public and private broadcasters alike. Regulations have intended
to incorporate private broadcasters in the national identity project assigned to
broadcasting overall, and especially the public provider. Thus, regulations also
encourage Canadian production and dissemination.
Between 1930-1932 the formation of a national public broadcaster created
tension between regional and national interests. A newly chartered Canadian
Broadcasting Company [CBC] absorbed the former CNR local stations along
with established provincial public broadcasters in western Canada. This tension
has persisted as CBC policy constantly shifted interests away from and then
back to regional broadcasting. Private broadcasters have tended to occupy
the regional vacuum, although this is becoming more problematic in a current
battle for control between cable, satellite and over-air broadcasters. Another
tension, common to any Canada-wide project was between Québec (French
language dominant) and the rest of Canada (English language dominant). This
tension was resolved early on with the creation of two language services: the
CBC (English) and the Société Radio Canada (SRC), each one broadcasting
across the country.
More recently three provincial public broadcasters have entered the scene:
Télé-Québec, TV Ontario and The Knowledge Network (British Columbia).
All three feature a mixed funding model, being supported by Provincial gov-
ernment financing, direct public support and some discreet advertising. The
CBC/SRC is a Crown corporation reporting to Parliament and supported by
Federal funds and advertising. During the 2008-2009 year the parliamentary
appropriations amounted to 60% of revenues and advertising accounted for
20%. The remaining 20% came from a variety of other services. The advertising
revenue budget was down considerably as a result of the 2007-2008 recession
that has led to severe cost cutting and the insertion of more American prime
time programs in the TV line-up.1
Canada’s 33.4 million people are mainly located along the border with the
United States with a population of 309.2 million. Of course the two countries
share a common language (with the exception of Québec where its language
affords some protection for both media and cultural agencies). The USA is
the largest producer of media products in English and Canadians have always
had ready access to most of that – and for which they have tended to show
some preference. Public broadcasting, along with other national projects in
film and music, were created to slow the pace of what was considered an
1. See, www.cbc.radio-canada/annualreports/2008-2009 accessed 14 June 2010.
98
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
Ireland
Ireland’s small nation status has been a major factor in the development of its
media system. Its size and relatively open society character, however, does not
mean that Ireland’s media organisation is defined only through dependence
on larger, more dominant structures. A number of counter strategies illustrate
patterns of integration at a transnational level that cut across the traditional
notion of dominance and dependence.
Historically, Ireland is overshadowed by United Kingdom, its big neighbour
with a population of 61.3 million. Six of the 32 counties on the island of Ireland
are within the United Kingdom, and have a devolved government and a differ-
ent legal and regulatory environment for media compared with the Republic of
Ireland. The official language is Irish, or Gaeilge. However, the country is practi-
cally, predominantly English-speaking. English is the language of all mainstream
media and daily affairs and Irish is only spoken as an everyday language by
a small number of communities along the west coast. Government-supported
initiatives have led to an increase in support for the language in education,
in government, and in the media, and a number of important national media
services are now available in the Irish language.
Despite proximity to the United Kingdom with its large, complex and mature
media environment, arguably ranking second globally after the USA, Ireland re-
tains a prosperous and (for its size) diverse media market. Ireland’s public service
99
John D. Jackson
100
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
cial radio and television. The new authority is responsible for all broadcasting,
including RTÉ. It will license independent, commercial broadcasters, examine
ownership issues, and manage a complaints procedure. However it is its role
in public service broadcasting that has caused the most controversy. There is
concern that the new Authority, heir to a previous regulator that never had a
public service remit of any kind, has now assumed such control over the sector
as a whole. There are fears of a far more constrained role for public broadcasting.
New Zealand
The short history of this small South Pacific nation has generated a highly
complex situation in media industries, broadcasting in particular. What has
happened here is both an echo of wider trends and a prefiguring of shifts and
re-alignments in other parts of the world. It has also been keen on develop-
ing strategies and structures that can rightly be considered as local solutions
to local problems.
In the nineteenth century New Zealand was widely regarded as ‘the social
laboratory of the world’ at the vanguard of policy (social welfare) and emanci-
pation. New Zealand is famously the first country to give women the vote. In
the late twentieth century and into the twenty-first century, New Zealand can
no longer be regarded as such a shining example of social progressiveness,
although some exception is perhaps in order for its anti-nuclear and immigra-
tion policies. But New Zealand has embraced with enthusiasm an ideology of
change many would regard as anti-progressive.
This shift is particularly visible with respect to the ownership and purpose
of media in this society. The deregulation and over-heated free market ideol-
ogy of the 1990s accelerated a situation where the New Zealand broadcasting
environment was declared “the most deregulated in the world…extremely per-
missive by world standards”.2 In fact a primary characteristic of New Zealand
broadcasting is regular and relentless change. Indeed, such inconstancy can
be regarded as a constant.
Unfortunately poor decision-making has also been a constant. In 1998, for
example, Television New Zealand sold its Natural History production house
to Twentieth Century Fox, a subsidiary of the News Corp global empire. In
the ensuing years, Natural History New Zealand has grown into a globally-
oriented and highly profitable enterprise with annual profits exceeding those
of Television New Zealand [TVNZ] in 2009.This was not a rare example of
poor decision-making; there have been many others in the past twenty years
as broadcasting (television, in particular) has lurched between the poles of
unabashed commercialism and an older public service ethos.
2. A New Broadcasting Policy for New Zealand. A discussion paper published by the Screen Producers and
Directors Association. Wellington, July 1966, 6.
101
John D. Jackson
Despite inconstancy, there has always been a case for mixed television in
New Zealand. From the earliest days of New Zealand television (the 50th an-
niversary of the first official transmission was June 2010), one finds a balancing
act between a fee-based funding model (annual license fee) and a commer-
cial model (advertising) characteristic of the system. In subsequent decades
funding of television increasingly gravitated towards commercial imperatives
with TVNZ now receiving over 90% of its revenue from advertising, and thus
competing for this income with private, commercial free-to-air [FTA] channels
and the dominant pay-TV Sky service.
In 2010 New Zealand has a particular and quite peculiar mix of television
structures. There are residual elements of public broadcasting objectives in
the state-owned TVNZ with its two channels, but because it is also desig-
nated a Crown-Owned Company [CROC], it is obliged to return a healthy
annual dividend to the government. The three-term Labour administration
(1999-2009) attempted to shift the company back to clearer public service
objectives, which included introducing the TVNZ Charter. But with the return
of a right-leaning National/ACT/Maori Party coalition in November 2009 the
Charter was abandoned and commercial imperatives again hold sway. As
Peter Thompson explains, “as TVNZ’s failure to deliver its public Charter
outcomes while depending on commercial revenue for 90% of its income
demonstrates, commercial broadcasters operate under significant constraints
that make the delivery of quality content and public service largely impos-
sible” (Thompson 2010).
Sky Network Television, the dominant pay-TV provider, now reaches 46%
of New Zealand households, with up to a quarter share of the total audience.
There is another connection to News Corp in that it owns 44% of the majority
shareholder, Independent News Limited. And so it owns rights to premium
sports events (rugby, in particular) and has extended its hold on the New
Zealand mediascape through the acquisition of the FTA channel called Prime.
Other FTA channels have been bought and sold by overseas interests, with G.R.
Holdings from the UK acquiring a majority ownership in TV3 and C4 recently.
This mix of channels (Sky provides more than 80 pay channels) struggles for
audience in a population of just over four million New Zealanders, and in a
market where advertising revenue is in a slump due to the combined effects
of a global recession and competition from other media.
That’s the bad news. The good news is that the decline in television viewing
for FTA channels has flattened and, in some cases, viewing has increased. The
two-channel FTA Maori Television Service, which might properly be called a
public service provider, is funded by the state with a modicum of advertising.
It continues to attract respectable audience shares and critical approval for in-
novative programming and language support. Locally produced drama series
such as Outrageous Fortune (also sold as a format to the USA and the UK), and
102
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
serial dramas such as Shortland Street, together with news and current affairs,
continue to dominate ratings for FTA television.
The two Freeview channels, TVNZ6 and TVNZ7, continue to attract dis-
criminating audiences with their mix of locally produced content and overseas
documentaries, although there is uncertainty about their state-derived fund-
ing beyond 2012. The funding agency New Zealand On Air continues to play
a critical role in funding vulnerable genres (children’s, special interest, and
documentaries) for the local market, receiving $NZ127 million in 2008-2009,
and allocating 64% of this to television productions. On a smaller scale another
funding agency, Te Mangai Paho, allocates up to $NZ20 million annually spe-
cifically for Maori language or Maori interest programming.
These agencies and interventions can be regarded as attempts to ameliorate
the real or perceived shortcomings of a totally commercial television system.
New Zealand On Air is a residual safeguard put in place at a time when de-
regulation of broadcasting hit its stride. The others are more recent additions
to the mediascape and largely put in place during the period when there was
a more public service-friendly government. But given that every new govern-
ment has chosen to reshape broadcasting according to its own philosophy (or
ideology), with TVNZ usually being the sacrificial victim, television in New
Zealand faces more changes. The current government has declared that TVNZ
will not be sold off in the current term (until November 2012), but has been
noticeably silent about what might happen if they get elected for another term.
Taiwan
Taiwan is located close to the People’s Republic of China, one of the largest
countries in the world, and shares Mandarin as the official language. Under the
“one China policy” Taiwan is not recognised as a fully-fledged independent
nation-state, nor does it have a seat in the United Nations. Being positioned
by the Chinese government as a renegade province, Taiwan is constantly mar-
ginalised in diplomacy. Its peripheral status further singles out its ‘smallness’
in international politics.
Taiwan is nevertheless an island that heavily depends on international trade
and has established itself as one of the newly industrialised, semi-peripheral
countries. In addition, Taiwanese investors have profited from the geographical,
cultural and linguistic proximity to China and have played a key role in leading
China into the world of capitalism. Nonetheless, although financial, human, and
technological resources are being transferred from Taiwan to China, Taiwan
fears that China threatens its competitive edge in the global economy. Finally,
and importantly, as long as China does not relinquish its policy of invading Tai-
wan as a final solution to political division, it must remain a military threat and
considered as a potential enemy. It was only in 2008 that direct links for postal
103
John D. Jackson
104
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
broadcasting history in the 1960s. Lee Chin Chuan (2004) argued that there
existed a strong bureaucratic-commercial complex characterised by entertain-
ment programming for profit, and by media discourse control, language use
and ideology was established for maintaining the status quo of the authoritarian
regime and state-capitalist development. Twenty-five years of democratic struggle
helped to free broadcasting channels, however, and various television and radio
stations are now more inclined towards different political parties and views.
But over the past two decades an excessive neo-conservatism has also
marked the Taiwanese broadcasting system. Public broadcasting is margin-
alised in Taiwan. Since its establishment in 1999 the TPS has received only a
very limited budget of less than $50 million USD to serve a population of 23
million. In contrast, the Canadian public broadcasting budget is $540 million
USD to serve a population of 30 million Canadians. A recent regrouping of
public broadcasting channels combined the original TPS, Taiwan Indigenous
TV [TITV], Hakka TV, Taiwan Mac, and CTS. While the TPS continues to re-
ceive $50 million USD per year, the TITV, Hakka, and Taiwan Mac receive a
total budget of $76 million USD. Legislators in Taiwan do not support budget
increases or license fees to maintain the public broadcasting system. While be-
ing underfunded, government agencies are responsible for indigenous, Hakka
and overseas Chinese affairs.
Conclusion
We set out to demonstrate that broadcasting markets in relatively small and
dependent states develop their systemic properties not only with regard to
local conditions, but also in response to the social, cultural and economic ties
they have with larger, more powerful neighbours as a feature of these condi-
tions. Size was defined in terms of dependency in three dimensions, political,
economic and cultural. We took markets to be one element in a complex of
interacting elements within media subsystems. Our decision to use depend-
ency as a selective device was not investigated as a variable but rather as a
way to examine certain properties within and between selected small coun-
tries – Austria, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand and Taiwan, each of which has
been shown to be more or less dependent upon a proximate, more powerful
neighbour with whom they share a common language.
Austria, Ireland and New Zealand are small by any definition; Canada and
Taiwan are larger but all five are clearly dependent states. All are struggling
with the public/private broadcasting balance in situations where public broad-
casting acquires a national identity function relative to powerful neighbours.
Private broadcasting does assume public service and identity functions, but in
the main it acts as a major carrier of programming from each state’s powerful
105
John D. Jackson
neighbour. This is the case with Austria, Canada and Ireland. New Zealanders do
not appear to rely as heavily on their closest foreign broadcaster for information
and entertainment. However, similar to the others, New Zealand broadcasting
continues to respond to global socio-economic forces. Taiwan too is responding
to global forces, but contrary to the other four cases its antagonistic/dependent
relation with mainly China has yielded a highly protective system.
Our story is one of states struggling to offset the heavy media hand of their
immediate neighbours, as well as global political and economic forces. Media
organisation in Austria responded to the national socialist movement and later
Allied occupation during the 40’s; Canada responded to its divorce from British
influence at the end of World War I and its subsequent quest to differentiate
itself from the United States; Ireland responded to its long history of conflict
with Britain; New Zealand is constantly in the shadow of Australia, the UK
and the United States; and Taiwan’s situation indicates a complicated set of
factors that on the one hand leads to an attempt to distance itself from China’s
socialism to seek universal recognition as a sovereign, independent nation,
while at the same time the importance of trade, culture and political relations
with China create considerable complexity.
We began our analysis with an elaboration of the proposition that broadcast-
ing in small and large countries alike requires an appreciation of the organisation
of media as subsystems within a larger social system of which they are a part.
Providers, creators, receivers and markets are subject to interactive elements
of media subsystems. In turn, media subsystems interact with the state, the
economy, and political and socio-cultural values as determinant elements in a
comprehensive social system. With this in mind we advanced two types of value
orientations – the classical liberal or neo-conservative set and the contemporary
liberal or welfare state set – to summarise and capture the elements of larger
social systems. The next step was to propose a set of broadcasting parameters
as a way of capturing media subsystems. This yielded a cross-classification of
value orientations and broadcasting parameters, generating a set of hypotheses
designed to explore changes in broadcasting as a consequence of changes in
overall social systems.
Regarding value orientations, Canada and Austria, the former under the
influence of the NAFTA and the latter under the influence of the EU, show a
decided move toward neo-conservative value orientations. Ireland, also within
the European Union, demonstrates a similar trend, even more pronounced.
New Zealand exhibits a pattern of see sawing back and forth, but tends overall
toward the neo-conservative. Taiwan is solidly located in the neo-conservative
paradigm.
International trade pacts moved Canada, Austria and Ireland toward neo-
conservative positions such that these three not only respond to powerful
neighbours, but to global economic and political forces as well. International in-
106
The Socio-Cultural Context of Broadcasting Markets
National identity
Within the framework of neo-conservative value orientations, commercial
broadcasting may be viewed as economic activity in the “national interest”.
But this must be also understood in contrast to broadcasting as a mechanism
for creating and enhancing particular national cultures where policy decisions
may well run contrary to commercial interests. The definition of broadcasting
as a “heritage institution”, as part of the creative activity of a people, is more
likely to occur under contemporary liberal orientations. We see this at work
at several levels among our selected countries. Both Ireland and Austria find
themselves immersed in controversies with the EU over a conflict of defini-
tions: is broadcasting a commercial enterprise or a national cultural institution?
Canada as a NAFTA member finds itself in a similar position.
This drift toward broadcasting as solely a commercial activity is not entirely
due to outside pressures. Internal changes in orientations are evident in each
of the selected states and that supports drifting toward the commercial impera-
tive. The tension between national identity and commercial objectives is in fact
a constant in all five selections. Internal changes in value orientations since
the 1990’s have led to a shift away from national, cultural objectives toward
commercial objectives in four of the five selections. Taiwan is the exception.
Moreover, Austria, Canada, and Ireland experienced heavy use of channels
originating from big neighbours across their respective borders, further weak-
ening national identity objectives. New Zealand broadcasting, though less
impacted by its neighbour, defined its broadcasting industry as an instrument
for national cultural identity. The degree to which that has been maintained
is open to debate. Taiwan is an interesting exception. The hostile relations
between Taiwan and China have acted as the major force shaping broadcasting
policy, combined with a marginalisation of public broadcasting.
Private/public funding
Advertising has always been the major source of revenue for commercial
broadcasters, and is now becoming an important source for public broadcasters.
107
John D. Jackson
This is a significant change; one that began in earnest during the 1990’s and
has continued into the present with increasing emphasis. Governments began
reducing their support of public broadcasting as the shift from contemporary
liberal to neo-conservative values gained momentum. The significance of the
shift is readily observed in changes in audience perception. The reliance on
ratings as the primary basis for determining both policy and programming
changes the perceptions of audiences from that of citizen to that of commodity.
Concluding comment
The selected countries all exhibited commonalities arising from their economic
and cultural dependence on larger neighbours and/or transnational trends
in policy or industry. Each responded with a regulatory regime designed to
maintain control and reinforce national identity. In these cases broadcasting
regulations are relational; that is, in addition to responding to local political/
cultural/social value orientations, they were designed to address cultural in-
trusion from their neighbours. Broadcasting in relatively small and dependent
countries is responding to at least two, and in some cases three, larger systems:
their proximate larger and more powerful neighbour just across the border (all
five selections in varying degrees); international trade pacts (Austria, Canada
and Ireland); and internal shifts in value orientations. From the perspective
of broadcasting policy design, all three lines of dependency deserve deeper
consideration and need to be addressed.
108
Structure and Dynamics
The Television Broadcasting Industry
in Smaller Countries
Josef Trappel
109
Josef Trappel
110
Structure and Dynamics
Belgium 10.8 VRT Eén VTM Ketnet > 25; i.a. Prime, TV
RTBF La Une RTL-TVI RTBF La Deux Brussel, Tele Bruxel-
les, VT4, regional
channels
Bulgaria 7.6 BNT 1 bTV BNT Sat, regional > 25; i.a. TV 3, TV 7,
Nova TV public service regional channels
channels
Nether- 16.5 Ned 1 RTL 4, SBS 6 Ned 2, Ned 3; 12 > 25; i.a. NET5, RTL7,
lands digital special- RTL5, Veronica,
interest channels Misdaated
Portugal 10.6 RTP 1 TVI, SIC RTP 2, RTP N, RTP > 25; i.a. Sport TV,
internacional TV1 24, SIC Noticias
Slovak 5.4 STV 1 TV Markiza, STV 2, STV 3 > 25; i.a. TA3, Joj
Republic TV Joj Plus, regional
channels
Slovenia 2.0 TVS 1 Pop TV, i.a. regional public > 25; i.a. TV 3, Info
Kanal A service channels TV, PeTV, Pop TV,
regional channels
Sweden 9.3 SVT 1, SVT 2 TV 4 SVT Extra, SVT HD, > 25; i.a. TV3, TV6,
SVT World, SVTB Kanal 5, Canal+
(pay)
111
Josef Trappel
Table 1. Cont.
Germany 82.2 ARD, ZDF RTL, Sat 1, regional public > 25;
ProSieben service channels i.a. VOX, n-TV, N24,
Sky (pay)
Italy 60.0 RAI Uno, RAI Canale 5 Raitalia, RAI 4, RAI > 25;
Due, RAI Tre Italia 1, Storia, RAI Scuola Sky Italia (pay),
Rete 4 La 7
Poland 38.1 TVP1, TVP2 TVN, Polsat i.a. TVP Sport, TVP > 25;
HD, TVP Info i.a. Canal+ Polska,
Polsat
Romania 21.5 none Pro TV TVR 1, TVR 2, TVR > 25; i.a. Antena 1,
Info Acasa TV, Realita-
tea TV
United 61.6 BBC 1 ITV 1, Sky i.a. BBC 2, BBC 3, > 25; i.a. ITV 2, ITV3,
Kingdom Channel 4 (pay) BBC 4, BBC News ITV 4, Discovery
24, BBC HD, BBC Channel, Disney,
regional ESPN, Five, Gold,
Nickelodeon
* Main channels = channels with a market shares of 10% or above; Secondary channels = channels with a market
share lower than 10%.
In bold font = the leading channel in the audience market.
Source: Author’s compilation based on the MAVICE database of the European Audiovisual Observatory (with mar-
ket share classification based on data from 2008).
and via cable) enable more broadcasters to distribute programming than ever
before. What digital technology cannot change, however, are the structural
constraints embedded in industry specificities. Viewed from a purely economic
perspective, the following are among the most important structural constraints:
• Availability of resources
• Economies of scale and scope
• First copy cost
• Public good characteristics
These generalisable characteristics of media markets are well described in the
literature (see the chapter by Christian Berg in this volume; furthermore see
also Albarran 2002 and 2010; Doyle 2002a; Owers et al. 2004; Picard 1989).
112
Structure and Dynamics
113
Josef Trappel
114
Structure and Dynamics
115
Josef Trappel
116
Structure and Dynamics
dependent on total market size. All of the larger European countries have a
broad spectrum of special interest television channels, typically including news,
business, sports, music, and channels for children. These broadcasters have
generally been able to successfully locate themselves within a market niche
that is wide enough to support the running costs for the channel at a profit.
Some such operations are explicitly intended to cross borders, including for
example Euronews, Eurosport and BBC World – as well as signals originating
from further afield, such as BloombergTV from the USA. Moreover, many of
these channels are delivered at an international scale in a variety of languages
(e.g. Euronews and Eurosport). Others are more national in market orienta-
tion, such as the news channel N24 in Germany or Sky Sports in the United
Kingdom.
There are fewer examples of special interest television channels offering
genuine domestic content that references national current affairs in smaller
countries. Low budget television channels are far more active in these more
local or regional areas. There are fewer business opportunities for national (or
international) special interest channels. In Switzerland, for example, several
attempts have been undertaken to establish a business television channel.
One might think this should stand a fair chance of success given the country’s
prominence in international banking. But all of these investments have failed
economically either in the planning stage or collapsed mere months after
launching operations. A good example is the European Business Channel in
1990 (Meier and Saxer 1992: 234). Another example is from Denmark where a
national sports pay-TV channel was launched without success in 1997, closing
shop later in the same year (Mortensen 2004: 46).
The switchover to digital television distribution since 2005 to 2007 (ap-
proximate because switchover schedules vary widely in Europe), together with
new legal rules, have enabled broadcasters in smaller countries to set up new
channels. As a rule these do not carry so much domestic content, however, or
as much news and current affairs programming. Instead they tend to establish
small market niches and offer low cost programmes, very often imported. Fin-
land and Flanders are good examples for this recent boom in niche television
channels (see de Bens 2007: 77; Jyrkiäinen 2007: 103). Their economic viability
and sustainability has been severely tested during the recent economic crisis
that hit advertising spending hard in 2009 and 2010.
Apart from the obvious reason of having too few people watching special
interest programs in smaller countries to convince the local advertising industry
to make use of these channels for getting the attention of audiences, the high
fixed cost for running a decent newsroom during large parts of the day have
typically been considered to be high barriers to market entry. Aukse Balĉytienė
confirms this in her assessment of the Baltic states where she argues that “for
smaller markets, a particular concern is the availability of resources to support
117
Josef Trappel
118
Structure and Dynamics
119
Josef Trappel
120
Structure and Dynamics
barriers to market entry are simply too high to surmount in smaller countries
with smaller markets.
121
Josef Trappel
7. Exposure to take-over
National corporations in concentrated markets are critically exposed to take-
overs by potential investors. This characteristic of highly concentrated media
markets is a result of general industry and competition dynamics. Monopolies
(or duopolies) represent valuable business opportunities for investors. While
such duopolies can be found in both smaller and larger states, the cost for any
take-over is much less in smaller states while expected margins are often at
least as attractive as in larger states. Therefore, highly concentrated television
markets where there is only one private commercial corporation presents an
attractive acquisition target for investors, especially today among international
conglomerates. While such business operations are risky in larger countries,
122
Structure and Dynamics
123
Josef Trappel
is welcome for growing programme diversity, but is less desirable with regard
to sovereignty and culture.
Thirdly, smaller countries with far less comparative resources are con-
stantly vulnerable to take-overs by wealthy foreign companies, thus reducing
sovereignty in decision-making for the smaller country as well. As illustrated
above, decisions about television programming and structures in many of the
countries in Central and Eastern Europe have been taken over by corporations
established outside these countries. Todd Chambers (2003: 45) used the term
“absentee owners” to describe the pattern (although in a different television
context). Such owners are absent from the social, economic and political reali-
ties of domestic populations, and are inclined to pursue different priorities and
to employ different decision motifs than those who are personally exposed to
the social consequences of their decisions. Such absentee-owners make the
television industry in smaller countries still more vulnerable.
Moreover, decisions on how the television industry in smaller countries is
organised are to a large extend taken over by outside actors and local authorities
have quite limited options for influencing decisions. Probably the most impor-
tant decision concerns the internal (domestic) market order. As demonstrated
earlier, smaller countries cannot afford to sustain a no-holds-barred market
model based on pure competition rules. Scarce resources simply do not allow
this option. Nonetheless, smaller countries today increasingly find themselves
vulnerable to the supranational regulations on television industry structure that
are applied to larger countries with much bigger, and often wealthier, markets.
This imbalance and the dependence it creates has become increasingly
evident in comparisons between smaller and larger countries. Let’s remember
that the number of main television channels (market share of 10% or above) is
considerably fewer in smaller countries. Market competition with its promises for
internal checks and balances can’t be achieved in the TV industries of smaller
countries. Instead of Adam Smith’s heralded invisible hand, the hand of the
market in smaller countries is highly visible: dominant market players control
commercial television activities in highly concentrated markets, generally with
only one company commissioned to set the standards – namely the public
service provider. Of course the UK complicates the picture with its incorpora-
tion of commercial PSB companies (Channels 4 and 5), but recent economic
problems suggest that the degree to which these hybrids will be held to public
service standards is in decline.
Although there are no convincing arguments that competitive television
markets in larger countries provide the best achievable quality and the most
relevant contents, there is no doubt that in smaller markets an entirely market-
based approach has so far failed to deliver the goods. Smaller countries delib-
erately and with good reason insist on measures to prevent market deficiencies
and market failure. Today, however, such measures can only be applied only
124
Structure and Dynamics
to the extent that the relevant supranational framework permits this, such as
the rules established by the European Union. Smaller states are hardly ever
able to influence such fundamental decisions, as demonstrated in this volume
by the chapter from Erik Nordahl Svendsen. At least their capacity for influ-
ence is meagre compared to the negotiating power wielded by large states.
Consequently, smaller states depend on rules designed to suit the preferences
of larger states. This doesn’t always or necessarily imply a disadvantage for
smaller states, but it certainly reduces self-determination in the television field.
EU competition policy rules that are applied to television, for example, do
not – and following the institutional setting actually cannot – take into account
the specificities of smaller markets where competition doesn’t work the same
way or to the same extent due to smaller size characteristics. Despite this it has
become evident that smaller television markets are under permanent scrutiny
by the European Commission regarding state aid rules, and mainly due to an
endless series of complaints filed by commercial media operators for their own
self-interested reasons. It is only very recently that the EC acknowledged that
smaller states might actually be different. In its Broadcasting Communication
2009 the Commission suggested with regard to state aid rules and public fi-
nances of public service media that “the Commission will also take into account
the difficulty some smaller Member States may have to collect the necessary
funds, if costs per inhabitant of the public service are, ceteris paribus, higher…”
(European Commission 2009: para. 42).
The question arises, then, whether smaller states require different rules in
order to provide their populations with the best possible television service –
with services that are appropriate to their distinctive comparative needs. Factors
keyed to size, resource abundance, vulnerability and dependency for doing
television in smaller states together suggest that an approach to governance is
needed that would accommodate adequate tailoring (or versioning) to respect
the legitimate needs and distinctive comparative interests of smaller member
states. This ought to be taken on as a developmental frontier for governance
rules explicitly addressed to television broadcasting in smaller states by supra-
national authorities.
Denis McQuail has suggested using the term governance “to describe the
overall set of laws, regulations, rules and conventions which serve the purpose
of control in the general interest, including that of media industries” (2005: 234).
He distinguishes formal from informal, and internal from external, elements
in media governance. In the context of television governance in smaller states
McQuail’s systematic order is helpful to address fields where action is merited:
First and foremost, formal and external governance is required to deal with
the conflict of interest between the requirements of market and competition on
the one hand and high levels of media ownership concentration and market
failure on the other. Domestic regulation cannot change market conditions
125
Josef Trappel
in smaller states. But formal and external rules could be applied that would
make all television operators, public and private, accountable to a shared set
of goals at some general standard for society, e.g. with democratic principles
and diversity requirements. Such rules would not only define acceptable levels
of media concentration (including cross-media concentration), but also formal
and internal governance rules. All television broadcasters would thereby
necessarily adhere to a set of obligations for internal conduct, for standards of
programming, in staff recruitment, in guidelines for programme acquisition, for
principles of collaboration with national programme producers, for ensuring
the independence of newsrooms from undue influence (internal and external),
etc. All of this is supremely relevant for and in smaller states with necessarily
higher concentrated television markets.
Another aspect of formal and external governance concerns the role and
performance of public service television broadcasters in smaller states. These
broadcasters are essential to balancing between the commercial interests of
private television and the public interests of civil society. In smaller states the
relative importance of public service broadcasters is higher due to the small
number of relevant competitors. Formal and internal governance rules should
clearly define the obligations and the remit for public service television. In return,
revenue sources should be defined and assured for a suitable period of time.
A third aspect of formal and external governance lies in the importance
of a clear separation of power between television broadcasters, government
agencies, and economic forces. Due to the smaller size of their societies, the
necessary and essential distance between television and those wielding power
in both government and markets deserves consideration. Temptations to il-
legitimately influence television coverage can be more likely in smaller states
with stronger corporate ties between political, industrial and media actors than
in larger states. Empirical research is uncertain here, as the chapter by Chris
Hanretty demonstrates. More is needed to confirm or disprove this assumption.
Informal and external governance refers to the continuous public debate
about television in smaller states, and that mainly means discourse about threats
to and opportunities for its development. This debate is essential for arriving at
a shared understanding of the roles and functions of television broadcasting in
contemporary societies. Again, this debate is of more relevance in smaller states
because of the scarcity that is characteristic of television supply. Television’s
role in society should be defined by a public debate rather than by vested
interests. The scale of available resources in small markets simply does not
permit fair and robust services for minorities if handled on a purely competi-
tive basis. This is another pressing reason that public debate about television
broadcasting and its roles is essential.
Finally, informal and internal governance refers to conduct within television
organisations. This field is least accessible for, and least exposed to, public
126
Structure and Dynamics
control. But that is essential for ensuring adequacy and fairness in television
system performance. Television programming is the result of collective efforts
by a large variety of people engaged with many aspects of its production and
distribution. The better and clearer the informal and internal codes of conduct,
and the more rigorously observed, the better the programme output that can
be expected. This factor obviously applies equally to small and large states.
Conclusions
The television industry in smaller countries is in a delicate position. Vulnerable
and dependent on external decisions, its point of reference remains the civil
society requirements of the national population. Television can still be con-
sidered what James Curran calls “core media” for society (2007: 39). As such,
television “should sustain a culture of ‘civil democracy’ designed to promote
conciliation and compromise. (…) Core media should also promote conciliation
by supporting the rituals and procedures of the democratic system” (ibid.: 40).
Television in smaller countries can live up to this requirement only if structural
conditions are accommodated and structural requirements are met. These
include a high level of accountability for industrial television actors – public
and private – a sufficient level of financial resources, and a set of governance
rules that respect the distinctions of smaller states. Rules governing markets
and competition alone will not fully comply with these requirements because
market failure and deficiencies continue to threaten the capacity of this core
media sector to be a well-functioning structure. Achieving that requires an
adequate set of appropriate media policy measures.
127
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Media Policy in Small European Countries
129
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
Historical sketch
The general history of Europe certainly affected the organisation of radio
broadcasting in the 1920s, which conditioned arrangements for the develop-
ment of television. Arguably the greatest legacy from the Golden Age of Radio
in Europe is the concept and approach generally characterised as ‘public ser-
vice broadcasting’ [PSB]. This approach defined the structure and objectives of
broadcasting in Western Europe (gradually, of course). The political division of
Europe after the Second World War deeply affected the organisation of televi-
sion. In Western Europe public TV became a cultural element of the welfare
state and liberal democracy, while in Eastern Europe broadcasting became part
of the state apparatus controlled by the Communist party.
The year 1950 was significant in this regard. Two organisations were launched
that year: the EBU in the West and OIRT in the East. There was considerable
130
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
diversity even in the West among EBU members, however. Not every country
that was accepted as a member practiced democracy. Dictatorships prevailed
in Portugal and Spain, and Greece was under military rule. The PSB approach
was imposed, to an important degree, on West Germany by the Allied pow-
ers – especially Britain and with America’s blessing. Television in the west was
not generally organised or operated as a private enterprise, although in some
countries noted here it wouldn’t qualify as genuine public service broadcast-
ing either.
The general pattern and the variance both serve to demonstrate that struc-
turing television was almost entirely a domestic affair for governments of
respective nation-states to decide. It was also that for technical reasons: TV
signals did not travel very far. As with radio before it, television was positioned
as a tool for nation building in a continent devastated by war, and especially
understood as a means for uniting rural and urban populations, as well as di-
verse provinces. During the 1980s this began to change with the introduction
of satellite broadcasting. In market terms, the European Economic Community
(forerunner of the EU) was growing in this period, incorporating the new de-
mocracies in southern Europe as they shook off post-war dictatorships. With
the Single European Act that was agreed in 1986, the era of closed national
television systems ended. The TWF directive in 1989 mandated the free recep-
tion of signals on minimal conditions. There were rules limiting the amount
of advertising, requiring that at least 50 % of content on any channel must be
European works [EW], and provisions for the protection of minors. The objec-
tives were to create a common advertising market and stimulate a common
European audiovisual market to compete with American media industry. At
best it was hoped that pan-European TV would facilitate some shared sense
of European identity. This aspiration was naïve from the start (Schlesinger
1993: 6-17). As we shall see, the net result did not hinder growth of American
content but in fact helped facilitate an escalation of that1 – especially in small
markets. In 1991 the Euromedia Research group did a content analysis of 53
channels and concluded:
It is undoubtedly in the cultural interest of European nations, as well as of
Europe as a whole, to recognize that the dominant economic and industrial
logics that motivated commercialization of television and the rapid develop-
ment of new communication technologies in the 1980’s have had the cultural
consequence of supporting neither nationally based production nor Euro-
pean production, but rather, of massively supporting Hollywood. Because of
1. “It is possible to argue that EU media policy is bringing about the opposite of what it states it is trying to
achieve. Rather than promoting Europeanness, the strategy of liberalization is creating more commercial chan-
nels, which are dependent on American programming. Americanization may be the unintended consequence
of Television without frontiers in Europe” (Kevin Williams, quoted in Terzis, 2007, p. 454). I will add it is
even more so if the TWF-directive is not respected by big member states, regulating channels broadcasting
to small states, as we shall see later.
131
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
This perspective grounds our approach in this chapter, and particularly in light
of our interest in the smaller country context. The year 1989 was thus a turning
point for television in Western Europe, and moreover for television in Eastern
Europe after the Berlin Wall came down in November. In the early 1990s Eastern
Europe abandoned the communist model and (re-)introduced capitalism and
democracy (of varying kinds and to different degrees, of course). This happened
peacefully everywhere except in the former Yugoslavia. By 2005 most former
Soviet countries were members of the Council of Europe (and its European
Convention on Transfrontier Television) and then or later of the European Union.
In their national transformations television underwent two parallel changes. Pri-
vately owned and commercially financed stations were allowed, and the former
state television companies were redefined as public service broadcasters. This
latter change was often the most difficult, with persistent political interference
reported.3 As part of this process, former OIRT-members joined the EBU in 1993.
132
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
This may position them as being closer to the “transition countries” of Eastern
Europe as described by Karol Jakubowicz.5 Transition countries lack any real
history with PSB and Jakubowicz thinks that is unlikely to be mended. At the
same time, and in many cases instead, the introduction of private television
was done quickly and without critical thought.
Politically/economi-
Population > 1 million cally developed Transition countries
+= (partly) sharing language with big neighbours,* = sharing language with small neighbours
This categorisation is parsimonious and will ground the research questions that
steer the rest of the chapter. The objective is to ascertain whether the devel-
opment and conditions of TV in these countries feature similarity in patterns
that are determined more by the size of the country or by political-economic
traditions. We will develop answers by looking to find if Small West and Small
East are more closely related because they are smaller than Big West and Big
East, or if instead Small West is closer to Big West and Small East to Big East
because they share democratic traditions and are at some parallel level of
economic status. Moreover, if Small West is different from Small East, we will
look for evidence that Small West may not be the same as Big West primarily
because of size. The countries included in each category are not presumed
to be homogenous. The point is to facilitate analytical comparisons that can
answer the research objective. We shall begin analysis by looking to see when
the various countries included in the typology launched the two types of tele
5. The term ”transition country” indicates a transition to democracy after an authoritarian or totalitarian system,
see: Karol Jakubowicz (2007) p. 17.
133
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
6. The analysis is limited to nationwide terrestrial channels because this is the most significant and top level of
media politics, and because the number and functions of local/regional channels or cable channels vary even
more between European countries. Satellite channels from other countries are left out in this first analysis,
since they are not decided by the country itself. We come back to these important channels later in other
analysis.
134
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Table 2. Launch years for public and private TV, with number of public channels
established before the introduction of private TV
No of No of
public public
channels channels
Start of before Start of Start of before Start of
public TV private start private TV public TV private start private TV
135
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
136
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
137
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
here, and in Greece where public service was new and fragile, the balance
in a sense became quickly imbalanced, tipping very strongly in favour of the
private sector. These channels have not normally had programme obligations,
and the little that was initially mandated is largely abandoned by now. As we
shall later see, these countries today have the weakest public TV of all.
138
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Sweden and Denmark under the balancing approach due to their use of hybrid
models in the introduction of private television, Sweden consolidated PSB early
when SVT was given the second channel (1969) and Denmark kept its hybrid
TV 2 in public ownership even if outside its traditional PSB company, DR.
In the Small East, Czechoslovakia had two public channels, and continued
with them after the country was divided. Slovenia and Croatia had consolidated
public TV with two channels each, as well. Not surprisingly, these four Small
East countries are the only ones with a public share of viewing over 20% today
(Table 3 below).
The consolidation strategy has proven effective for national television un-
der different circumstances: Germany, the Netherlands, parts of Scandinavia,
transborder competition countries (e.g. Austria and Ireland) and small transi-
tion countries (e.g. Czech Republic and Slovenia) all introduced second and
even third public channels before private television. The reason is keyed to the
operational possibilities for developing more advanced programming strategies
via profiling than is possible with only one mainstream channel. The small
countries who instead chose to balance the broadcasting system by introduc-
ing the second channel as a private station had no chance in the short term
of launching a second public channel, or of controlling private competitors
through soft public service mandates. This lesson was learned the hard way.
When small countries want to use television to achieve national cultural aims,
the results of this analysis clearly support the view that the strategy of consoli-
dation is the better choice.
139
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
12. EAO Yearbook 2008 Vol. 1. Revenue proportion calculated from table T.1.Country.1 and/or T.1.Country.2,
It means the summarised operating revenues of the TV companies, even if the channels are established in a
different country. It also means no distinctions between commercial income and public income from license
fee etc. The net-revenue of German advertising windows to Switzerland (174 million CHF, against 365 mil-
lion CHF of advertising on SRG) and Austria (183 million Euro, against 351 million Euro of advertising on
ORF) are included in the markets of the small countries (Source: mediareports prognosis 2009). The total
revenue may be to high, since some companies like British Sky also encompass distribution services. The
EAO Yearbook 2008 Vol. 2 p. 148 presents the public stations’ relation between audience share and share
of public funding. It shows no clear correlation.
140
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Table 3. PSB’s slice of audience share and total revenue (license fee funding plus
advertising)
1. In Sweden the PSB (SVT) is only TV. If SR (the radio PSB) is included, the PSB share of revenue is 38 %.
2. Denmark is an odd case: TV2 is a public station, completely financed by advertising. The station gets no state aid,
but is still owned by the state as long as several EU-court cases are pending, and therefore this station (5½ channels)
with a share of viewing of 40 % and 27 % of total revenue is categorized as public. It explains the extreme position
of Denmark in all the tables.
sector in television broadcasting. The Small West countries reserve more of their
proportionate revenue for the public stations and this seems to work rather
well in terms of securing audience share.
Defensive strategies vary partly as a function of language in transborder
television. The presence of German private channels, some with commercial
windows, has encouraged Switzerland not to open nationwide, private television
yet. Even a PSB operator as well financed as SRG has a viewing share of only
34% as a result of transborder competition from German operators. Caught in
the same dilemma Austria was rather forced by the European courts to allow (a
so far meagre) private TV presence. The viewing share for ORF is much better,
however, and still 44%. In the Nordic countries private TV was introduced both
by the state via licensing hybrid stations and by satellite transmission. The general
wealth of these small countries seems sufficient to sustain both sectors, and their
broadcasting markets are more protected due to non-international languages.
But in many Small West countries private sector competition originates out-
side the country and comes as “spill over” keyed to a shared language. Private
channels may also amount to local branches of big international conglomerates.
141
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
In all three situations the private stations only contribute modestly to production
of domestic programmes. Greece is the outlier because there private television
has been strongly favoured and PSB only got a second channel very late in the
game (as discussed earlier).
The Small East countries devote about the same proportion of revenue to
public television as the Big West and Big East countries, but which is much
less than in the Small West countries. Even though the proportion is similar, the
actual quantity varies as a function of comparative economic conditions. Audi-
ence shares are rather poor, with most having less than a 20% share. Croatia
is the exception with a share of 49% and largely because it consolidated PSB
before introducing private sector competition (see Table 1). The explanation for
poor results in PSB viewing in Small East countries may be related to problems
of quality in both programming and management, although the small income
in absolute terms is certainly a major factor. One really can’t make attractive
television on a shoestring budget these days. But a company can important
polished and popular programming from abroad on the cheap.
This analysis deepens understanding of the practical implications of the
TV strategies earlier considered, and again demonstrates that political and
historic factors are very important for explaining the organisation of television
in small countries – certainly more explanatory than small market size alone
can account for.
Turning attention now to private and foreign-origination television, it’s
certainly true that fulfilling the wishes of people in any domestic setting today
can’t be done only with national PSB channels. Audiences want to have choices
between kinds of channels and types of programmes. How are countries coping?
First we must analyse the strategies of small countries in this field. By focusing
on the regulatory options taken by each country we can discern patterns of
competition as the share of viewing in three parts:13
1. Share for publicly owned, national channels
2. Share for private terrestrial or satellite stations established in the country
3. Share for foreign stations (spill-over or satellite).
By legislative force the state can regulate terrestrial broadcasting, and determine
the balance between PSB and private stations. The state can’t do this regard-
ing the influx of foreign channels. Put differently, a state can either keep the
private stations in the country by licensing domestic operators with favourable
conditions, or it must accept that such provision will come from other countries
offering better conditions.
13. Source for public share is EAO Yearbook 2008, vol. 2, p. 147. The next cells are from the national chapters
in vol. 1 and less precise, because the table often ends in a group with “other channel”, which maybe should
be placed in other categories. The main picture is not disturbed.
142
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
143
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
The third strategy for handling private TV among Small West countries can
be deemed a “keep them out” stance because the state gives (almost) no or
only very late access for private stations, and almost all private sector view-
ing is for foreign channels. This describes the situation in Ireland, French
Belgium, Austria, Denmark and Switzerland. Excepting Denmark,14 these are
small countries with one or more dominant neighbours sharing a language.
In Ireland the British channels arrive both as spill over and by satellite, for
Switzerland and Austria the source is Germany (which also competes for adver-
tising revenue in the market by selling advertising in “windows” as mentioned
above). For French speaking Belgium, spill over competition is from France
and Luxembourg, and to such a degree that there’s been no great interest in
starting private channels.
These Small West countries have the same basic conditions: They are small
wealthy countries with mature democracies and deeply rooted traditions in
PSB. But their specific conditions vary greatly, as especially evident in language
cultures, which has a decisive impact on their strategic stance regarding the
private sector in broadcasting. This produces different policies, here character-
ised as trying to keep them in, keep them out, or getting them back.
Finally, we note that the Small East countries all opened investment markets
for private companies during the 1990s, a strategy that more or less combines
“keeping them in” with what I’ll call “inviting them in”. Among the leading
companies with stations established in several Small East countries are CME
from the USA, RTL from Luxembourg/Germany, Pro Sieben/SBS from Germany,
and MTG from Sweden.15 Thus it should be clear that how private television
is handled is also only partly a matter of market size. The big rich countries
mainly feature domestic private television while the smaller countries – both
richer and poorer – evidence different strategies depending as much or more
on other factors. Some of this is related to cultural protectionism, when the
small country is rich enough to afford that, and in other cases to efforts to grow
a market and economic prosperity in the first place. In each case, however,
politics makes the real difference in determining the basic conditions.
144
Chart 1. Strategic stance regarding private television operators
Share of viewing within the typology for public, national private and foreign channels (2007)
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
10
IT
FI
SI
IE
LT
PT
ES
TR
SE
PL
EE
FR
AT
LV
NL
DE
HR
CZ
DK
HU
GB
BG
RO
GR
NO
BE fr
BE vl
CH it
CH fr
CH ty
Type B
Type A
Type D
Type C
”Be our guest” ”Keep them in” ”Get them back” ”Keep them out” ”Invite them in”
145
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
While the freedom to establish and transmit across borders is strictly enforced, this
‘demand’ for works of European origination is so elastic as to be practically com-
promised from the start: “where practicable”, when “appropriate” and “progres-
sively” on the basis of whatever can be construed as “suitable” decision-making
criteria. According to an official study conducted for the European Commission,
using “where practicable” in national regulation is not the decisive factor for how
much European works one finds on a channel; the market size seems to be more
important16. At any rate, the quota for EW was a political compromise from the
start, brought forward by France, and the Commission made it quite clear that
failure to comply would not be sufficient grounds for bringing a member state
to court.17 A judgement later issued by the European Court of Justice ruled that
Article 4 (EW) and Article 5 (Independent works) has no weight:
A television broadcaster comes under the jurisdiction of the Member State
in which it is established. The origin of programmes broadcast by the televi-
sion broadcaster or their conformity with Articles 4 and 5 of the Directive
are irrelevant in determining the Member State having jurisdiction over such
a broadcaster […] a Member State may not oppose the retransmission on its
territory of broadcasts of a television broadcaster over which another Mem-
ber State has jurisdiction when those broadcasts do not conform with the
requirements of Articles 4 and 5 of the Directive (C -14/96).
146
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Difference,
From (country) To (country) “balance of
”export” ”import” trade”: Relative
Number of channels (to Europe) (from Europe) Surplus or deficit? difference
Source: EAO: Mavise database. Excluding channels to own country or to countries outside Europe
147
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
Re-flagged channels
Now we return to our discussion about the quota for European works, which
is set at 50%. In a sense that is supposed to be the price that imported chan-
nels are expected to pay in return for the opportunity to do business in the
country of reception. If a channel does not fulfil the quota and instead uses
programmes originating elsewhere, and that usually means America, then it
should by rights be construed as engaging in unfair competition. It is certainly
unfair for exclusively domestic public service channels, which as a rule adhere
to the law and always feature over 50% in European works. Little or nothing is
mentioned about this in discussions about PSB distorting markets and creating
an unfair playing field, which rather smacks of hypocrisy.
When a channel does not comply with Article 4 (about EW), the member
state (country of origin) is asked to explain the reason for this to the European
Commission competition authority. The Commission categorises explanations
under eight headings that are listed below19.
1. Programme orientation and special-interest nature of the channel
2. Higher costs of European programmes
3. Subsidiaries of non-EU companies
4. Groups of channels belonging to the same broadcaster achieve the re-
quired proportions when taken together, but not individually
19. Commission of the European Union (2008), pp. 15-17. The next report (2010) confirms the reasons.
148
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
20. The 342 channels include channels to Britain only, with 380 channels in Table 4 above only for export. The
explanation is the growth of channels during the three years from 2006 to 2009 For 2008 Ofcom reported
about 417 channels of which 225 channels (54 %) did not comply. So the situation has worsened, not im-
proved.
149
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
21. The interest here is to study the small countries as ”victims” of the big countries due to lack of rigour in
regulation, therefore we ignore the cases where (small) countries ignore the non-compliance of their own
national channels. Details for instance on Denmark can be found in Commission of the European Union
(2008).
150
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Table 5. Some channels not complying to the 50% European Works, their market
share in the receiving country and the explanation given to the Commis-
sion
share of
Country viewing EW %
Country of reception Channel of origin 2007 2006 Explanation
151
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
have very high degrees of EW (78%), while subscription channels offer about
33% – again far below the 50% requirement.22
152
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
153
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
decision on the size of the market.29 This restraint is critical because PSB plays
a relatively much greater role in the Small West countries than in Big West or
all East countries – as demonstrated earlier in this chapter.
It is also important to observe that all cases about state aid have so far
only been registered about PSB in the Big West and Small West countries. No
complaints have been registered against PSB in any size Eastern state. The
complaints have been lodged by private TV companies, usually in collabora-
tion with their Association of Commercial Television in Europe (ACT). They
don’t have any need to complain about PSB in the eastern countries because
it is so weak to begin with, and there the conditions for private television are
extremely liberal. But for the Small West countries where PSB is relatively big
and more popular, limiting its development potential is their best opportunity
to grow market share quickly and cheaply – i.e. by rolling back the incumbent,
which in these countries are mainly PSB operators. The ramifications can be
quite serious for these countries, and not only for their PSB providers – certainly
more serious than for big countries where market volume offers ample resource
for both PSB and private media companies. Ironically, however, the complaints
against state aid for the public media sector most often come from the private
“re-flagged” companies based in big countries like the UK and Germany – the
very companies that do not themselves comply with quota requirements for
European works. The whiff of hypocrisy is pungent here. Their strategy is
self-serving and has nothing actually to do with anything other than profits: If
they can break PSB in the big countries then PSB in the small countries is far
more vulnerable and with less room to maneuver because they have far less
influence and resources to lobby with in the first place.
When the Commission issued the new Communication on Broadcasting in
July 2009,30 there was suddenly much activity around the article about small
countries – now Article 42. A new clause was added (emphasised in italics):
“The Commission will also take into account the difficulty some smaller Member
States may have to collect the necessary funds, if costs per inhabitant of the
public service are, ceteris paribus, higher, while equally considering potential
concerns of other media in these Member States”. The new sentence has an
interesting history. In the first draft presented in November 2008 this Article
(then number 62) was absent. In the next draft from April 2009 it was back,
but without the clause. The concerns of private commercial media were not
incorporated with the quoted clause until the final version in July 2009 (now
Article 42). What happened?
The answer becomes clear when reviewing the response of private media
organisations to the April draft. ACT wrote: “First, that much is made by pub-
154
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
31. The contributions to the consultation (7.04-8.05.2009) are available at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/
consultations/2009_broadcasting_review/index.html.
155
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
of using its enormous size and brand power to overwhelm private operators
there.32 PVT has two assessment components: 1) a public value assessment
(will this serve democratic, social or cultural needs?), and 2) a market impact
assessment (will the negative effect on competition outweigh potential public
benefits?).
The Communication demands that member states develop some similar and
systematic process for value assessment with public consultations (Article 84)
and a market impact assessment (Article 88). It is doubtful whether the Com-
mission has the right to demand this from the member states, as by Treaty law
states have the competence to decide on the domestic public service remit.
But efforts to comply are already underway, and we can expect that putting
this kind of system in place will be an added burden on already stressed ad-
ministrative resources in most small countries. The cost of a single PVT test
in Britain has been in the double-digit millions of pounds. Aware of this, the
Commission has accepted that tests may be conducted with less exhaustive
rigour in some smaller countries, like Belgium and Ireland.33
While the first state aid cases were raised by private companies complaining
about subsidies, the recent trend is for complaints about the activities of PSB
on the internet and in other new media (e.g. mobile). So it is really an effort
to exclude PSB from any realistic potential to become PSM. Now newspaper
publishers are getting more involved because much in their development strate-
gies relies increasingly on harnessing opportunity in new media to offset loses
in the old one. They are keen on PVT because it offers an already accepted
route to curtail the drive for PSM that may hinder their self-interested objectives.
And they tend to focus directly on the smaller member states, as well, because
newspapers are still more domestic than international. So although the general
competition policy of the EU does not take market size into account, it clearly
is a factor in assessing which lobbies are involved with which complaints in
which countries, and for which essential reasons. The clause about small mar-
kets in the Broadcasting Communication has not been used, and may never
be. Even so, it was recently watered down when referring to “other media” at
the initiative of private sector publishers. That can only increase the dangers of
vulnerability for small countries, especially where PSB is of great importance
not only in broadcasting but, moreover, in the development of public services
online. The sheer burden of proof in responding to these cases and, in the
future, implementing PVT is a challenge of formidable dimensions.
156
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
Conclusion
European history with PSB is indigenous and differs across regions. Western
and Eastern countries have different historical experiences and, correspond-
ingly, different levels of resources and perspectives on values. It is no surprise
they feature different media policies in turn. Similarly, southern Europe is quite
different in many ways compared with northern Europe, and unsurprising that
media policies differ as a result. Obviously size matters for how broadcasting
is organised and mandated in a country. Big countries and companies have
more resources and powers than small ones. Despite the differences, we have
noted important similarities among small countries. In the endeavour to nourish
vulnerable national cultures these countries share a common interest that is in
many ways oppositional when compared with big countries, which are often
neighbours and may be part of the problem from a small country perspective.
That is especially clear when treating the impact of company size, for example.
The small countries try to defend their national cultures, more or less against
the odds, which is a central justification for PSB in those countries.
But this chapter makes it quite clear that size is not the only factor, and may
not even be the most important with regard to policy and the dynamics involved
in making that. There are important differences between small countries, as
well, and not only between big and small. Small Western countries have had
as strong a PSB structure as the Big Western countries because they’ve been
able to afford it (so far, at least) and they’ve had political traditions that enabled
it. The Small Eastern or transition countries have been in a different situation
and have invited private stations to develop their audiovisual and advertising
markets. The internal, national policies for media development in the small
countries of Europe tend to be more different than similar, on the whole. That is
an important observation that may counsel against efforts to ‘harmonise’ media
policy across states. When histories are different, resource bases are different,
languages are different, value structures are different, and internal relations
are different, why, exactly, would media policies seeking to ignore – even to
erase – differences be expected to succeed?
The common interest among small states became clear when we introduced
the transnational perspective with foreign television. Foreign TV is not relevant
for big countries but is clearly decisive for small ones. As demonstrated, Small
Western countries react with different strategies in efforts to keep the foreign
presence in their audiovisual space, and culture, within some reasonable limits.
Sometimes this involves keeping them out, and sometimes bringing them back
under domestic control. The path taken depends on various factors, includ-
ing nationality of neighbours and the behaviour of private companies, as well
as general historical preferences rooted in value structures and also resource
parameters. The Small Eastern or transition countries have less room for ma-
157
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
158
From Sovereignty to Liberalisation
159
Erik Nordahl Svendsen
160
The Governance of Broadcasters
in Small Countries
Chris Hanretty
161
Chris Hanretty
that differs between big and small countries (as defined for this project). I give
reasons why we should expect broadcasters in smaller countries to differ in
key aspects of their governance. Ultimately, however, I find that key govern-
ance features differ little between countries, regardless of size. In broad terms,
public broadcasters have the same distance from government in small countries
as in big countries, whether one considers the formal legislation that governs
these broadcasters or how that formal legislation is translated into practice. The
ownership structure of private broadcasters also looks similar in small and big
countries. These are ‘negative findings’ only in the clinical or academic sense.
Whether the findings are negative or positive for society is a different issue. The
finding, for example, that the level of public broadcasters’ formal and actual
independence from government does not vary significantly between small and
big countries undercuts a common argument in many classic works of political
science that smaller countries are more virtuous (assuming of course that PSB
independence is a virtue). Viewed differently, this finding suggests that small-
ness does not condemn any country to a particular pattern of governance, and
that there is therefore room for careful institutional engineering.
162
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
that the Italian public broadcaster, Rai, is often described as the ‘televisione
di stato’, or state television in Italy. But public broadcasters normally operate
in a murky zone that is neither part of the government proper, nor of civil
society, nor of the market.The term ‘governance’ is therefore very appropriate
for this context.
Borrowing from RAW Rhodes, we can describe the ‘governance’ of public
broadcasters as encompassing the interdependent and repeated interactions
between the state and the broadcaster, each understood as autonomous within
its own sphere. These interactions have both their formal and ‘real’ elements.
The formal elements are concentrated in the legal texts which established the
broadcaster, which guarantee its continued operation, and stipulate, for example,
what the state is obliged to provide the broadcaster, and what the broadcaster
is obliged to provide in return. Although these elements have become less
legalistic in recent years (Coppens and Saeys 2006), an undue concentration
on the black-letter provisions of these laws is ultimately extremely stultifying
for everyone except lawyers. Indeed, this is part of the reason why the term
‘governance’ has become so popular: it draws attention to how these provisions
are cashed out in terms of interactions between the state and the broadcaster.
One way of examining the governance of public broadcasters in small and
large countries would be to run through a set of interactions – say, all those
interactions concerning the licence fee, all those concerning new operations,
all parliamentary hearings and committee meetings, and so on. Indeed, later in
this chapter I look at one aspect of governance in particular, namely whether
national legislatures are involved in appointing members of the public broad-
caster’s board. I would suggest, however, that it is more helpful to consider all
of these aspects as part of the broadcaster’s independence from politics. The
independence of public broadcasters from politics is one of the two classic
issues in public broadcasting.1 It is a classic issue because of perpetual ten-
sion between politicians’ desire to secure better coverage from the broadcaster
(which often enjoys a considerable influence on the reporting of current af-
fairs), and the role those politicians play in granting the broadcaster the funds
and the institutional support needed to continue operating. It’s an issue that
benefits from analysis through the lens of governance precisely because it has
both formal and real elements.
We can describe the independence of the broadcaster in real, or de facto
terms, as concerning “the degree to which PSB employees take day-to-day
decisions about their output or the output of subordinates, without receiv-
ing and acting on the basis of instructions, threats, or other inducement from
politicians, or the anticipation thereof; or considering whether the interests
of those politicians would be harmed by particular choices about output”
(Hanretty 2010). If politicians are constantly ringing up news-desk editors to
1. The other is the degree to which public broadcasters crowd out free market activity.
163
Chris Hanretty
have running orders changed, then the broadcaster is not at all independent.
Correspondingly, we can describe the formal or de jure independence as the
degree to which the law or laws governing the broadcaster give politicians
the formal means to sanction or reward the by appointing or dismissing board
members, altering the broadcaster’s funding, or scheduling extra committee
hearings on the broadcaster’s work.
The relationship between these two aspects of independence is by no
means straightforward. Some organisations maintain a high degree of de facto
independence despite laws that, in appearance, would permit politicians any
number of opportunities to interfere in the broadcaster’s work. Conversely,
some organisations have low degrees of de facto independence despite laws
that would seem to give the broadcaster a number of guarantees against politi-
cal interference. As a result, we need to check whether smallness affects either,
both, or neither of these aspects of independence.
164
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
service broadcasters are embedded in the polities they must serve. Conse-
quently, characteristics of the polity – high trust, or high factionalism – should
be expected in those relationships that govern the broadcaster. If small coun-
tries are virtuous democracies populated by civic-minded individuals, and if
an independent media is a civic virtue displayed by such societies, then we
should expect that public broadcasters in smaller countries are more independ-
ent of politics, both in formal terms and in terms of their day-to-day activities.
Conversely, if small countries are subject to capture by motivated factions, then
we could expect public broadcasters to be captured by those factions as well,
and consequently less independent of politics. This link might not be straight-
forward, however. Politics structures a lot of the work of public broadcasters,
but it does not explain everything. There are of course other structural features
to consider: the state of the media market in each country, the cultural base
in the country, general economic conditions, and so on. Equally, we cannot
ignore the role of agency – many public broadcasters owe their current rude
health to charismatic chief executives who have moulded the broadcaster in
their image, or at least moulded the broadcaster so as to follow their precepts.
I will return to such factors towards the end.
165
Chris Hanretty
When these scores are plotted against country population we find almost no
relationship between the smallness of a country and the formal independence
granted to its public broadcaster. This is true whether one looks at the popula-
tion of the country as is or taking the log of the population which helps remove
the distorting effect of countries with much larger populations (see Figure 1).
Figure 1.
1.0
CHE
NOR
FIN AUS DEU
IRLDNK
BEL AUT
CHL GBR
JPN
SWE CAN
EST ITA
0.8 BELNZL ISR
LVA POL USA
FRA
SVN
De facto independence
CZE ROM
0.6 ZAF
BGR PRT ESP
LTU
ITA
0.4 SVK
HUN
BGR
0.2
0.0
50000
100000
150000
200000
250000
300000
Population (thousands)
Countries with a bigger population grant their public broadcasters slightly less
formal independence than countries with smaller populations, which would
tally with our view of small countries being more virtuous and more content
to devolve true authority. However the relationship is substantively negligible,
and in any case is not statistically significant. Put differently, if we were to plot
the population of each country against the degree of formal independence it
gives its broadcaster, and then draw a line of best fit between all the points,
we would be faced with a flat line. It’s difficult to make a strong case that the
governance of public broadcasters differs between small and big countries –
166
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
167
Chris Hanretty
average of these two figures one can arrive at a reasonable proxy for measur-
ing how much de facto independence each public broadcaster has. Broad-
casters with high de facto independence include the BBC, ZDF, and the Swiss
broadcaster SRG-SSR. Broadcasters with low de facto independence include
Italian broadcaster Rai, the Hungarian broadcaster MTV, and the Slovakian
broadcaster RTV-SLO.
Here too, however, there is little evidence that the size of a country affects
the degree of independence that the public broadcaster there has (see Figure 2).
Figure 2.
1.0
CHL
0.8 BEL
SWE
SVN DNK
CHL GBRDEU
PRT
POL
De jure independence
BGR FRA
0.2
0.0
50000
100000
150000
200000
250000
300000
Population (thousands)
168
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
ers have, and found no real relationship at all. It might be the case that there
is a relationship out there complicated by confounding factors. In the original
research which produced these measures of de facto and de jure independence
I tried to model de facto independence and included two other explanatory
factors (or covariates) alongside the degree of de jure independence: the size
of the market for news, measured in terms of per capita circulation of news-
papers, and whether or not the country had formerly been under Communist
rule earlier. The size of the market for news is, in turn, a shorthand way of
referring to two other developments that gain speed as the market for news
increases: journalists’ professionalisation project and the development of press
agencies. Both are powerful factors in establishing norms about journalistic
content, how it is produced, and how it is not produced (i.e., without the
input of politicians).
All of these developments happen to have a marked geographic distribution:
countries in southern Europe tend to have smaller markets for news just as
they also have fewer major and long-established press agencies and journal-
ists’ associations. Although it is not the very fact of being in the north or south
that explains this pattern, these factors do cluster geographically to give us a
baseline expectation of how independent the public broadcaster will be. This
baseline may subsequently be improved upon or made worse, depending on
the degree of de jure independence possessed by the broadcaster.
This model explains about half of the variation in de facto independence.
When we add the size of a country to our model, however, we don’t explain
any more variation and the effect of population is not statistically significant.
So even with the best model of de facto independence available at this time,
the size of a country doesn’t offer any explanation about the degree of inde-
pendence for a public broadcaster.
Of course these are statistical findings and may not always be convincing.
It is open to us to say that whilst there is no overall effect of population on a
broadcaster’s independence, the history of broadcasting in a particular small
country shows us that there, at least, size did have an effect, even if it has no
effect elsewhere. Or we might suppose that size has quite opposite effects in
very large countries and very small countries, which cancel each other out.
Finally, it might be that whilst the size of a country has no direct effect, it does
affect other factors that in turn affect independence. I examine this possibility
in the last section of this chapter.
169
Chris Hanretty
caster in that country, perhaps there are links between the size of a country and
particular aspects of the governance of the public broadcaster? One particularly
intriguing aspect of the governance of the public broadcaster is the method
by which the top ranks of managers are appointed, and in particular whether
organs like the board of the public broadcaster are appointed by the executive
or the legislature branches of democratic governments. In my index of de jure
independence I assumed that appointment by both the legislature and the execu-
tive should be scored more highly (i.e., more ’independently’) than appoint by
the legislature alone; and further assumed that appointment by the legislature
alone should be scored more highly than appointment by the executive only.
This ordering comes directly from the literature on central bank independ-
ence and is questionable. There are good reasons to suppose that appointment
methods which involve both the executive and the legislature will result in
more independence for the broadcaster based on the assumption that where
multiple actors must agree to appoint an individual, that individual will, in all
likelihood, be less beholden to any particular actor. There are, however, few
good reasons for supposing that appointment by the legislature would result
in more independence than appointment by the executive branch. Each ap-
pointment method involves a different source of interference, but in many
European countries the same sets of political parties would be involved. One
may even make an argument that appointment by the legislature, being more
public, makes it more difficult for non-political individuals to be appointed
since they are unlikely to excite party or group politicians enough to lobby on
their behalf. Consequently groups of politically well-connected appointees may
be nominated as part of a package deal (see Hanretty 2009: 71-95).
Even if appointment methods are unrelated to independence, they might
still be important. Consider two PSB companies with the same degree of (de
facto) independence from politics. One of these has a board appointed by
the government; the other has a board appointed by the legislature. In the
first case we presume that threats to the broadcaster’s independence are more
likely to come from the government, whilst threats to the second broadcaster’s
independence will come from parliamentary committees and/or influential
backbenchers. Thus, even if the organ by which board members are appointed
has no overall effect on independence, it might nevertheless be indicative of
the source of political pressure on the broadcaster. Public broadcasters whose
boards are appointed by parliament may choose to spend more time assuaging
the concerns of influential legislators rather than ministers or ministerial aides.
We can use data gathered by Steven Fish and Matthew Kroenig to look at
parliamentary power and parliamentary involvement in appointment. Fish and
Kroenig (2009) collected data on the concrete powers enjoyed by legislatures
around the world, including the power to appoint directors of public media
companies. They also calculated the overall power of each legislature. Once
170
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
again, the empirical evidence reveals no real link between the population
of a country and the governance structure of its public broadcaster. Smaller
countries are not more likely to involve parliament in appointing the boards of
their public broadcasters. This is true irrespective of whether we focus on all
of the 158 countries covered by Fish and Kroenig, or only focus on the same
36 countries used in my analyses reported above.
At the same time, however, there is a modicum of evidence to suggest that,
considering just the 36 countries used in my analysis, parliament tends to be
more important the smaller the population of a country. Consequently, public
broadcasters in smaller countries who wish to remain independent might have
to spend more time dealing with potential threats to their independence from
influential committee members instead of potential threats from junior ministers.
171
Chris Hanretty
172
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
173
Chris Hanretty
174
The Governance of Broadcasters in Small Countries
Conclusion
Smallness in the narrow sense used here as country size in terms of popula-
tion seems to have little to do with the governance of either public or private
broadcasters. Smaller countries are not more likely to give their public broad-
casters greater independence, in either de jure or de facto terms, and this is
true whether or not one controls for other relevant factors. There is slight
evidence to suggest that broadcasters in smaller countries are more likely to
be appointed by legislatures rather than the executive branch, which would
suggest that public broadcasting managers in these countries should try to
spend more time on managing their relationship with influential legislators than
junior ministers. There is no evidence to suggest that private media companies
in smaller markets have a more concentrated ownership structure of the kind
that might facilitate political influence.
There are, however, reasons to think that small countries might be better
placed to learn lessons from their neighbours than larger countries. In these
kinds of relationships other aspects of smallness – the smallness of a language
community or a media market – do tend to play a role. Consequently, broadcast-
ers in small but well-connected countries may enjoy a comparative advantage
in governance not held by broadcasters in larger countries.
175
Broadcasting for Minorities
in Big and Small Countries
177
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
outset that such differences are irrespective of the size of the hosting country.1
Both policy and practice condone different levels of service for minority lan-
guage groups; there are no standardised, mandatory rules about this.
Although this area of research is keenly important given concerns about the
dynamics of globalisation, the body of literature on minority language media
is still relatively thin (see Moring & Dunbar 2008). It is clear, however, that
the totality of media supply in most countries tends to undermine rather than
strengthen the position of language minorities. The dominance of media in
the majority language, and the growing trend to import channels as well as
content from international media markets where the predominant language is
English, account for increasing difficulty in maintaining a competitive supply
in minority languages. The situation has encouraged the notion that broad-
casting for small language communities has a ‘restitutionary’ function (Dunbar
& Moring 2008; see also Kymlicka 1995); here the purpose of broadcasting
is to compensate minority cultures for loss in the media domain and to sup-
port minority languages in the context of daily life where this is contested
by supranational and national competition. This chapter presents examples
that predominantly – but to various degrees – are based on public service
broadcasting.
Attuned to the focus of the book, we investigate whether the size of the
country determines how states provision broadcasting for minorities residing
in their territories. Does the size of a minority population determine the level
of service that is offered, or is this more a matter of political choice irrespec-
tive of size? How do bigger countries and smaller countries serve cross-border
minorities in situations where new media technologies have been introduced,
especially digital television? Has this changed the conditions under which
transborder flows emerge and are accessible to minorities in neighbouring
countries? We are interested in the consequences of introducing digital broad-
casting. Has it increased services for minority language populations, or has it
caused new problems through encryption of signals that stop service delivery
at the borders of a country?
In our discussion about policy obligations for handling broadcasting at the
intersection of market and country size, the service provisions for regional
audiences within countries form a special case that we also address. There
are some international instruments that regulate this field in Europe, although
only a few and not always validated by state governments. Maintained by the
Council of Europe, the United Nations, and the Organisation for Security and
Co-operation in Europe, these instruments are particularly aimed at encouraging
appropriate minority language broadcasting services in national and regional
settings. Although some countries have chosen to adhere to these instruments,
1. We follow the terminology described in the introductory chapter, referring to country as the general term
whereas using the terms nation or state in references to policies and related agreements.
178
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
many have not; and those that have vary quite a lot regarding the level of
services they offer minority audiences. Thus, one finds a great variety of solu-
tions for the 50 million or so speakers of national minority languages within
EU member-states. In addition, there is a multitude of migrant minorities that
are not covered by international agreements in this field.
The cases considered in this chapter were chosen with the typology char-
acterising between bigger and smaller countries formulated by Christian Berg
in chapter three. We look at eight cases in seven countries, four of which are
comparatively big (Italy, Spain UK and Germany) and three of which are rela-
tively small (Finland2 Denmark, and the Netherlands). Across these countries
broadcasting in minority languages is provided in different ways, as we will
see. In three cases (German in Italy, Swedish in Ostrobothnian Finland and
Danish in Germany) the minority language populations can access spill-over
programming in their respective language from channels that cross the borders
between kin-states (or kinship-states), meaning states sharing a border where
the language of transition is a minority language on one side but the dominant
language on the other side. In three cases there are no bordering kin-states
(Catalan in Spain; Welsh in UK and Frisian in the Netherlands). In two cases,
there are limited kin-state services available, though not free to air (Swedish
in Southern Finland3 and German in Denmark).
All the minorities treated in this chapter are, through various arrangements,
covered by radio and television in their respective mother languages. Thus,
it needs to be clear that the situations assessed are not representative of the
general situation in Europe where most of the approximately 50 traditionally
spoken minority languages do not have access to a television channel in their
mother language, and where a multitude of migrant languages must depend
on global satellite channels and, perhaps, some programmes on local radio.
Of course some have no broadcasting services at all. This chapter takes a
benchmarking approach. We are looking at a relatively privileged group of
minorities to study how the availability of public broadcasting service varies
across countries as a function of investment in services particularly targeted to
language minorities, and where pertinent also how the existence of services
from kin-states affect the situation.
2. It should be noted that Swedish in Finland is not a minority language but one of two national languages, by
constitutional law. Swedish speakers do, however, constitute a minority of the population as they constitute
less than 6 percent of the population.
3. Ostrobothnia on the Finnish west coast and Uusimaa in Southern Finland can be distinguished in this re-
gard. Ostrobothnia by tradition has had access to spill-over broadcasting from Sweden, later maintained and
reinforced by special arrangements, whereas Southern Finland has not had such access but has received
a compilation of programmes domestically produced by the public service broadcaster SVT from Sweden.
Today, at a cost, broadcasting from Sweden is available also in Southern Finland on some cable networks,
and the compilation of domestic public service programmes is available on air for those who purchase a
decoding card. This arrangement has, however, not encouraged wide viewing of television from Sweden in
Southern Finland.
179
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
Supranational obligations
regarding media production for their minorities
The current regulatory regime for minority issues in the European Union dates
back to problems arising from the First World War. In the post-war division
of Europe into a variety of new nation states an obvious problem was that
not all distinct groups were large, compact or strong enough to be granted
an independent state of their own. As the Yiddish linguist Max Weinreich is
reputedly said, “a language is a dialect with an army and navy”. Also, in many
cases state borders divided areas where the population is some mixture of two
nations, creating bilingual areas on either or both sides of the new border.
These situations produced the phenomenon here referred to as minorities with
kinship-states.
Immediately after the war there were efforts to form a regulatory regime
for minority populations, but it only came to fruition in the last decades of
the 20th century (Kymlicka 1995), and even then only with international rules
pertaining to what is often referred to as autochthonous (or national) minori-
ties – meaning minorities with a traditional presence in the region where they
live. In the broader picture of the formation of integrated Europe, this limita-
tion is of course problematic as Europe has been moulded and remoulded
throughout its conflicted history by population movements for various reasons.
This movement continues within EU and its member states today, in fact (see
Cormack & Hourigan 2007; Salovaara-Moring & Moring 2010).
Today there are international instruments to help ensure the beneficial treat-
ment of minorities in the European Union, including also access to broadcasting
services in minority languages. Moreover, a body of ‘soft law’ has gradually
formed that has encouraged a great many European states to ratify pertinent
international conventions. Minorities in states that have not ratified such
conventions, and also in cases where more recent mobility have also created
new minorities, these instruments are taken as international benchmarks. The
contents of the main instruments in this field are briefly summarised in Box
1 below.
The European Union as such has not agreed on formal regulations with
regard to broadcasting for minority audiences within member states. Regula-
tions pertaining to national minorities and minority languages are mainly in
the principles of non-discrimination and respect for cultural, religious and
linguistic diversity, both established in the Charter of Fundamental Rights of
the European Union, Articles 21 and 22. The EU’s non-involvement in this field
is based on the principle of subsidiarity, which is applied to minority policies
in general. The sentiments expressed in the Audiovisual Media Services Di-
rective are positively disposed to trans-frontier exchange (formerly known as
Television without Frontiers). Whilst the directive introduced basic principles
180
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
United Nations
UN approved a Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples 2007. This declaration grants
rights to culture and media for indigenous people. However, it has the status of a recommenda-
tion and is not monitored.
Council of Europe
The Council of Europe has two instruments that specifically require services to minority groups
or in regional or minority languages.
The Framework Convention for the Protection of National Minorities is in force in more than 40
states. Its article 9 includes provisions for the right of national minorities to their own media.
The European Charter for Regional or Minority Languages is in force in 25 states. Its article 11 in-
cludes a menu of provisions regarding radio and television broadcasting. In states that carry out
a public service mission, the undertakings range from ensuring the creation of at least one radio
station and one television channel in the regional or minority language to making adequate
provision so that all broadcasters offer programmes in the regional or minority languages. Simi-
lar undertakings are proposed also regarding commercial broadcasting. The Charter aims at
guaranteeing freedom of direct reception of radio and television broadcasts from neighboring
countries in minority languages, and requires states not to oppose the retransmission of such ra-
dio and television broadcasts. Furthermore, the Charter encourages production and distribution
of audio and audiovisual works in the regional or minority languages.
181
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
in different EU member states are, given the lack of effective sanctions, rela-
tively much weaker yet. Whilst policy documents that relate to broadcasting
for minorities do provide an internationally established normative framework
within which states may chose to operate, states may also chose not to adhere
to any of these principles in the field of broadcasting, which characterises
the situation in France and Greece, and many of the former Soviet states (see
Grin et al. 2003).
A observation of generalisable importance is that media markets in Europe
do not provide broadcasting services to minorities in the absence of public
service broadcasting, except in the rare case where the minority language au-
dience is sufficiently large to comprise an attractive market in its own right.4
The only case where this potential could exist that we find inside the EU is
Catalonia with more than four million speakers of Catalan. In certain cases,
as TV Breizh in France, the argument of serving the minority has been used
to solicit approval for a license to broadcast, but in practice the transmissions
have been predominantly for other purposes (Guyot 2007: 39).
182
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
183
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
The role of new technologies in helping resolve this tangle is still ambiguous.
It is evident that the Internet (both stationary and mobile platforms) will have a
huge impact eventually, but of what kind/s and in which condition/s is unclear
for now. It is safe to say, however, that these platforms are obviously different
from broadcasting media and it is not very likely that they will substitute for
broadcasting; quite the opposite, we see cross-media effects emerging where
for example patterns in the use of television apparently transfer to patterns of
use for the Internet.6
Aspects of demand
In assessing demand for broadcasting services within minority audiences, it is
critical to understand the importance of a rich and varied supply. The demand
for broadcasting among any audience group includes not only daily news in
the mother language and about its self-interested community, but also other
programme genres offered in all the various media, such as youth programmes
and different types of popular content like drama and comedy (Moring & Dun-
bar 2008). This wider range of needed services is rarely met for minority audi-
ences, however, particularly where domestic production is not complemented
by access to kin-state supply. Thus, part of the demand for broadcasting tends
to be fulfilled through the use of contents in the majority language.
From a demands perspective, a language would always require the support
of full and comprehensive media services on all platforms and genres. From
a practical perspective, international standards allow for adjustment to lower
levels of supply to accommodate various constraints mainly related to required
investment to facilitate fulfilment (ibid). That said, it is certainly arguable that
states should do all they are able to do to make the most effective use of all
the means available to support minorities and their languages, including ar-
rangements involving offerings available in neighbouring countries. As argued
above, such arrangements would be of an important, though complementary,
character.
It is natural that minority audiences, even when being well served in their
mother languages, will turn to other outlets for some things in varying propor-
tions – either in the majority language or other languages offered in today’s
increasingly global media environment. But wherever reasonable demands are
met in regard to broadcast quantity, quality and generic diversity, audiences
would be expected to show a marked preference for the use of media in their
own language. If this condition (the strict preference condition, as discussed
by Grin et al. 2003) is not met, or only weakly met, it will be of little use to
make further investments in services to a minority. However, only in very few
6. This observation has been presented by Laszlo Vincze in his ongoing research, as presented with permission
in Moring and Godenhjelm (2010) and also on Moring et al. (forthcoming).
184
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
Aspects of use
Where media services include a complete array of media platforms (e.g.
newspapers, radio, television, the web) and genres (programmes for older
and younger people, with news and information as well as entertainment
programmes) the prerequisite for functional completeness is met. But even in
situations where broadcasting supply in a minority language is institutionally
complete, or next to complete (such as we find in Catalonia for Catalan, in
South Tyrol for German, in Wales for Welsh, or in Finland for Swedish) it would
be normal to find bilingual speakers using a large proportion of media in the
majority language. This is not a problem in itself, and on the contrary can be
understood as beneficial in the potential for fostering good relations between
groups within and between societies. In those situations where a language
coexists in a positive relation with other languages it can be considered quite
normal that bilingual or multilingual speakers use media across a spectrum of
languages. It does, however, become a problem where the use of media in
the majority language is caused by a lack of quality minority language media
due, for example, to a lack of resources.
Linguists use terms related to domain loss and domain expansion, which refer
to the domains in people’s lives where a language is normally used (Laurén et
al. 2008). In this context the lack of attractive programmes directed for a young
audience in the minority language, for example, would foster a domain loss
in use of the language through media among them. On the other hand, it has
been shown (Grin et al. 2003) that an investment in, for example, youth format
radio in a minority language can bring back a lost audience generation, thus
compensating for the influx of global formats that tend to promote uniform
media behaviour among young people. In such cases, there is a potential for a
domain expansion, or domain re-conquest, reversing earlier patterns of domain
loss for the language.
Aspects of space
The provision of media services to minority audiences is dependent on aspects
of their territorial organisation (Patten 2003: 299-305). All types of market-
based media services may emerge in minority languages within federal states
or territorial divisions where the minority locally forms a viable market that
185
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
186
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
Variables
Danish in Germany 50 000/82 milj. 50 000/3 milj. Limited availability No official status
0.06 % 1.6 % (Bilateral
in Germany in Schleswig-Holstein agreement)
Catalan in Spain 4.3 milj./46 milj. 2.4 milj./7.3 milj. Not available Co-official language
9.3 % 33 %
in Spain in Catalonia
Welsh in the UK 588 000/61 milj. 588 000/2.9 milj. Not available Official language in
1% 20 % Wales
in the UK in Wales
German in Denmark 12-15 000/5.5 milj. 12-15 000/260 000 Free No official status
0.01-0.02 % 5-6 % (Bilateral agre-
in Denmark in Sønderjylland ement)
Frisian in the Nether- 474 000/16.5 milj. 474 000/643 000 milj. Not available Second official
lands 2.9% 74 % language
in the Netherlands in Friesland
1.
Source: Befolkningsregistercentralen, 2010.
2.
Source: Kommunförbundet, 2010.
3.
Functionally it is equivalent to free viewing although a small fee is required to cover costs for technical transmission.
To clarify the geographic locations for our eight cases, we drafted a map
(Figure 1). The cases we have selected for analysis are found in different
parts of Europe, representing different contexts in terms of media landscape
and political cultures. However, most of these cases (all within the EU) fea-
ture a minority served by domestically produced daily television services. In
addition to those cases that we have studied here, television services in the
form of a separate channel can be found, for example, also in the Basque
country in Spain, in Ireland for Irish, and in Scotland for Gaelic. As situations
vary, strict comparisons are not meaningful. However, the cases provide a
basis for benchmarking and furnish examples of practices to inform policies
in this field.
187
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
Figure 1.
The map portrays the location – in white – of the eight regions with minority language broadcasting
that are discussed in this chapter: In big countries South Tyrol in Italy, Wales in the UK and Catalonia
in Spain, in small countries Ostrothnia and Uusimaa in Finland, Friesland in the Netherlands and Aa-
benraa in Southern Denmark
188
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
functional perspective. This minority has access to several TV and radio chan-
nels, as well as printed and internet-based media.
The German-speaking population has a particular status in this autonomous
province. The language enjoys strong policy backing from regional authorities.
The most significant TV broadcasting comes from a local PSB television station,
RAI Sender Bozen, and from cross-border TV broadcasting by Rundfunkt-An-
stalt-Südtyrol RAS. The RAI channel broadcasts two to three hours of German
language programmes per day, and its most popular day show (Tagesschau)
features coverage of local news and events. The programme attracts a signifi-
cant portion of all viewers every day, even though they have access to a wide
variety of other channels.
The publicly owned company, RAS, enables border-crossing media from
the neighbouring German speaking countries. The technical solutions and a
quite particular arrangement regarding copyright issues enable RAS to provide
access to a multitude of different TV and radio channels to the province free
of charge. The arrangements are based on a special agreement to include
broadcasts for South Tyrol in copyright agreements within the neighbouring
countries. This arrangement excludes retransmission of major sports events,
however, the copyright issues of which have not been resolved.
ORF1
ORF2
ZDF
ARD
SF1
Italian language channels
RAI1
RAI2
RAI3
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
189
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
190
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
from terrestrial digital broadcasting. Access to the public service broadcasts via
satellite provided by Danmarks Radio [DR] is restricted by encryption due to
problems associated with copyright protection. The government of Schleswig-
Holstein has offered a terrestrial channel to Denmark for relay-broadcasting,
but DR has not accepted the offer due to copyright problems. Cable networks
operating with analogue technique carry the DR channels, but this issue has
not been solved for digital cable networks.
Many Danish speakers in the region therefore receive a limited supply of
TV-programmes from Denmark, and the situation has deteriorated with the
introduction of digital television. This case illustrates problems associated with
language minorities living in big countries at the border of small kin-states,
especially how broadcasting from a small country is associated with more
problems than broadcasting from a big country.
191
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
number of Catalan speakers is also big enough to attract some private com-
mercial broadcasting.
Figure 3. Use of media in Catalan and Castilian language among speakers of the
two languages in Catalonia (reach, %)
74
45
Catalan language
55
22
Consumption in the Castillian language 48
49
36
31
14
Castillan language
80
43
Consumption in the Castillian language 52
47
38
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Television Radio Internet Weekly Daily
newspaper newspaper
192
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
Figure 4. Media use and social participation in Welsh among people with different
levels of language skills (%)
Watched welsh TV
0 20 40 60 80 100%
193
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
the Rugby Union. Due to its size and broadcasting with a Welsh commentary,
S4C can buy broadcasting rights at a lower price and thus enjoys a favourable
competitive advantage compared with larger TV stations. This feature helps the
channel reach an audience that would otherwise not be interested in Welsh
programming because sporting events gather a significant amount of viewers
among the majority language speakers even though the commentary is in Welsh.
In international comparison, the television supply in the Welsh language
enjoys a uniquely high level of funding. It can be concluded that the level
of funding has, indeed, proven its worth in terms of a high level of reach
particularly for Welsh television among viewers with different levels of lan-
guage skills (Figure 4). The present media landscape in Wales thus illustrates
the potential benefits that public service provision has not only for minority
language speakers but for majority language speakers as well. It also indicates
that media usage is guided by content quality rather than quantity. The Welsh
language TV station has recently been faced with the threat of major cutbacks
in funding which might lead to future changes in its operations (Guardian
20.10.2010)7. As it stands now, the case of Welsh language media in the UK
illustrates how minority language media can operate without support from a
kin-state. It also illustrates how essential public media provision can be for a
small minority language to survive; and it further provides a case where a big
country can decide to share out considerable resources to support a relatively
small minority, this not being the case in many other big countries in Europe
such as France and Germany.
194
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
and a dedicated TV channel (FST5) with daily broadcasts covering the entire
prime time. Whilst Swedish is a national language in Finland, due to its mar-
ginal proportion of the total population it is de facto in a minority position. The
Swedish language has a kin-state (Sweden), but the extent to which the Swedish
culture in Finland leans on the kin-state relation differs considerably between
the predominantly bilingual south (Uusimaa) and the western coast (Ostroboth-
nia) where there are much closer relations with Sweden, and in earlier years a
traditional presence of analogue spillover broadcasting on radio and television.
In Ostrobothnia relay stations increasing the coverage for television pro-
grammes from Sweden were set up during the era of analogue broadcasting
(before August 2007). Arrangements allowing distribution of the full contents
of all major television channels from Sweden are continued in the digital era.
A relay station network for direct on-the-air access was set up at low cost for
this audience. This arrangement was made possible by a special agreement with
broadcasters in Sweden. In Uusimaa a compilation of programmes produced
by the public service broadcaster in Sweden (SVT) was available free to air
until the digital switchover, but is now only available for monthly subscription8
that requires a decryption card.
Among Swedish-speaking Finns, the weekly reach of FST5 is around 60-
70 percent (Finnpanel 2009). This domestically produced Swedish-language
channel produced by YLE (FST5) has proven to be the crucial medium for the
language minority to reach the majority population, as well: a recent survey
among Finnish-language speakers shows that almost 70 percent sometimes fol-
low Swedish media via FST5. Television is the most important medium among
the population; 56 percent say they follow FST5 and 6 percent say they follow
television channels from Sweden (TNS-Gallup 2009, N=1142). Thus, for the
Finnish population the contact to Swedish language television almost exclusively
occurs through the domestic public service channel.
In contrast, among Swedish speakers in Ostrobothnia programmes from
Sweden dominate viewing while in southern Uusimaa the more limited service
has never attracted much interest among predominantly bilingual speakers.
Thus, in terms of functional completeness in broadcasting, we see two quite
different landscapes in Finland (Figure 5). Interestingly, the preferences for
language do not differ dramatically between southern Finland and Ostroboth-
nia, whereas the actual behaviour does. This signals that also in predominantly
bilingual southern Finland, the strict preference condition is met. The problem
relates to supply, and the actual media use would look different if full access
to kin-state broadcasting from Sweden was available.
A second interesting observation is that the viewing of the domestic televi-
sion channel FST5 is almost equally popular in Uusimaa and Ostrobothnia. The
difference in viewing pattern emerges mainly from a different choice of com-
8. In the Capital Region cable television network the cost was circa 14 Euro per month in 2010.
195
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
Figure 5. Preferences for television language and actual language use among
Swedish speakers in Southern Finland (Uusimaa) and the West Coast
(Ostrobothnia). (N=703) (%)
4
8
20
43
66 28
Mostly in Finnish
67
Equally in both languages
Mostly in Swedish
53 52
23
25
11
196
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
these speakers vary, but it can be estimated at something between 12.000 and
15.000, representing well under one percent of the total Danish population.
The regional weight of this minority is estimated at something between 5-6
percent. The German language in Denmark is regarded as a minority language
guided by the previously mentioned bilateral agreement between the two states.
In contrast to the situated presented earlier regarding Danish-language
television supply in Germany, German-language television in Denmark is not
encrypted. This allows for relatively free access to German television program-
ming. This case provides a useful example, paralleling South Tyrol, of how
minorities close to big kin-states suffer less from copyright restrictions than
minorities related to small kin-states. Whilst the transborder access to German
media is large, the media landscape can, however, be regarded as incomplete
from both institutional and functional perspectives.
There is a regional daily newspaper in German and small scale internet and
radio media services produced in the region. But there is almost no locally
produced broadcasting supply for this minority. In this situation, and with a
growing supply of Danish and also English-language television, the German
audience has to a significant extent abandoned German language television
and is partly in a process of assimilating into the Danish majority (see Moring
and Godenhjelm 2010). Thus, this case provides an example of how lack of
locally produced broadcasting supply, even in the presence of extensive kin-
state supply from a big country, may contribute to a negative development of
the minority and its related culture.
197
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
Conclusions
In this chapter, we have studied examples of broadcasting services for minori-
ties in select European countries, and across a rather good range of regional
locations. Our main question, following the theme of this book, relates to how
size affects broadcasting. In this case the focus has led us to investigate numer-
ous minorities in both larger and smaller countries. Moreover, the topic of this
chapter has encouraged focusing not only on the size of the country that hosts
the minority, but also on the size of a relevant neighbour, here called kin-state.
The similarities and differences we identified may not be entirely expected.
Regarding the size of the hosting country, we know from the literature that
many big countries do not cater for broadcasting to minorities. But we did find
that one of the big countries (UK) has equipped one of its minorities (Welsh)
with a particularly well-funded television channel that has made a difference
for this minority, not only in how it reaches Welsh-speakers but also in how it
is able to cross the language barrier between populations. For the policy maker
this points to the essential fact that money matters in this field as in all others,
and that only funded policies are likely to produce desired results.
In another big country, Italy, we found that domestically produced broad-
casting wins over even very rich kin-state broadcasting. In South Tyrol it is
the regionally produced German-language channel that engages the audience
most strongly, whilst the transborder supply from surrounding countries serve
to enrich the German media landscape further and make it functionally com-
plete for this audience.
We have also presented examples from small countries that support their
minorities with less costly yet effective broadcasting services. The Frisian speak-
ers in the Netherlands are among the few European minorities that are served
by a daily domestically produced broadcasting service. For this language,
198
Broadcasting for Minorities in Big and Small Countries
radio and television broadcasting are essential mass medium in support of the
language’s daily use
For Swedish-speaking Finns, broadcasting services vary – demonstrating
important nuances and variation even within a single country. In Uusimaa the
services resemble those of a country without a kin-state while in Ostrobothnia
the transborder influx from Sweden is considerable. This case allowed us to
study differences in preference and use patterns. We found that preferences
are quite stable. Whilst the south is predominantly bilingual and Ostrobothnia
more unilingually Swedish, it is nonetheless clear that preferences for television
services in Swedish are almost identical in both regions. The unhindered access
in Ostrobothnia to kin-state broadcasting from Sweden has led to a function-
ally complete media use in this region, whereas the use is complementary in
southern Finland. Based on this example, the policymaker may consider the
fact that also predominantly bilingual minorities may fulfil what we here have
called the strict preference condition: if relevant services with competitive
quality are available, the minority will prefer to use them. The Finnish case
also, in the context of a small country, shows how a domestically produced
television channel may involve the interest from the minority and at the same
time bridge between language groups, something of considerable importance
for prosperity and peace.
In cases where there are no domestically produced broadcasting services
available in minority languages, the supply across borders is particularly crucial.
Two minorities on either side of a shared border between Germany and Den-
mark provide examples of how the size of the neighbouring country matters.
In Denmark access to German language broadcasting is good. Germany, as a
big country and market, has a broadcasting policy that allows for transmitting
contents more widely, and especially regionally, without encryption. In con-
trast, adherence to variable copyright regulations often means that small states
must encrypt their signals – and thus are at a comparative disadvantage. In the
digital age this has introduced a sharper border between these countries as
many Danish speakers in Germany are not willing to pay for access to chan-
nels they earlier viewed without surcharge.
In South Tyrol in Italy and in Ostrobothnia in Finland, copyright related
problems have been solved through special agreements between the countries
with their broadcasters. Policymakers would likely benefit from study of such
arrangements in cases where transborder services to minorities have been hin-
dered rather than improved by digitisation. We also see this as one particularly
relevant policy field where the EU could helpfully secure common policies to
benefit more members in member states.
A final reflection is that irrespective of country size or the size of a language
minority, in all cases we have studied PSB operators are key players in securing
an adequacy of services for minorities and regional cultures. This is factually
199
Tom Moring & Sebastian Godenhjelm
the case even in Catalonia where the minority is of a population size that ex-
ceeds many of the smaller European countries. Even in an institutionally rich
media landscape offering a good supply of contents in the Catalan language,
we find effects caused by asymmetry that typically reflect negatively on the
position of a minority: Catalan speakers use Spanish media more than vice
versa. And there is a general acceptance that regional PSB broadcasting, such
as in the Catalan language and contrary to national broadcasters, should have
the right to broadcast advertisements in order not to lose competitiveness in
a increased competitive market. Thus, issues related to the appropriateness of
different approaches and mixtures of funding require a more nuanced treat-
ment than seems to be preferred among many policymakers today, given the
trends in ex ante legislation.
Does size matter in the aspects being treated in this chapter? Yes, it absolutely
matters. But it is vital to understand that policy matters more. In bigger and
smaller countries, and for bigger and smaller minorities, broadcasting services
vary more according to the will and activity of policy makers in establishing
principles and solving problems related to size, among much else, than only in
terms of any mechanical relationship to size. If our effort to cultivate a deeper
appreciation of the richness of practice in broadcast provision for all the varied
and lively populations that comprise the people of Europe has been grasped,
this chapter has done a fair service. If the substance encourages efforts to craft
solutions that are appropriate in varying contexts with differing circumstances,
this chapter will have achieved its greater purpose.
Acknowledgements
This chapter partly relies on data collected as part of a project financed by Magma, the
Swedish think tank in Finland (Moring and Godenhjelm 2010), and has been written as part
of the project Bilingualism, Identity and the Media in Inter- and Intra-cultural Comparisons
(BIM). This project has benefitted from financing provided by the Academy of Finland. The
authors also thank Professor Eva Pons, Doctor Cristina Cullell March, and researcher Laszlo
Vincze for their assistance with data gathering in Catalonia and South Tyrol.
200
Big Formats, Small Nations
Does Size Matter?
It is not that the small countries follow on from the big countries. Everyone
wants to start. But the biggest are the key springers of the business. (Gary
Carter, FremantleMedia)
201
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
exported globally between 2006 and 2008 (Frapa 2009: 21), in Europe they
accounted for 64% of spending on formats – e.g. Pop Idol and Deal or No Deal
(Attentional 2009: 60). This chapter investigates the extent to which players in
small nations can function as key actors in the global format business.
Second, this chapter considers audiences and reality entertainment formats
by investigating why programmes like X Factor (Syco) are so successful across
large and small nations worldwide. The case study of FremantleMedia is useful
for exploring two themes: 1) risk management in the format business and 2)
the idea of international formats as made to measure for small nations. Given
the case and industry issues of key focus, we confine analysis to Europe. Com-
bining political economy and audience analysis, the chapter generates insights
about production in and between broadcast markets of varying size. In this we
aim to deepen understanding of the relationship between media production
and reception in big and small nations.
Format trade
One outstanding feature of television programme trade in recent years has been
the growth in formats as producers and broadcasters seek the cost benefits of
global production and distribution. According to a report by industry analysts
Oliver and Ohlbaum (2007: 3), global TV formats accounted for 10-15% of peak
time schedules across Europe in 2007, and 20% (€3bn) of all non-news content
spend. International formats were expected to take as much as a 40% share of
peak time schedules in the future (ibid: 5). Moreover, according to the format
trade body, Frapa (2009: 8), the global value of the production volume gener-
ated by traded formats grew from €6.4bn in 2006 to €9.3bn in 2008. Of course
this trade in formats is not new and can be traced back to the earliest days of
television, and even before that to radio. Yet one notable characteristic of this
trend since the 1990s has been the extent to which some smaller nations have
emerged as players and exporters alongside players based in larger countries.
Historically the United States has dominated global trade in finished program-
ming. Indeed, broadcasters in most European territories have a trade deficit
with the US because they acquire substantial amounts of American feature films
and television series which are available at low cost and thus efficient for fill-
ing round-the-clock channel schedules (Attentional et al. 2009: 148; Steemers
2004; EAO 2002). According to the Television Research Partnership (2008: 20),
the US accounted for 76% of the global trade in finished programmes in 2007
(59,600 hours), followed by Britain with a 7% share.
But in the format trade business American dominance is not nearly as strong.
The same study by Oliver and Ohlbaum (2007: 19) found the US in second
place with a 13% share of global formats by source, ahead of the Netherlands
202
Big Formats, Small Nations
(9%) by a fair margin but trailing far behind the UK’s impressive 43% share.1
But it’s certainly important to observe that the Netherlands was the third larg-
est exporter of formats in 2009 in number of formats, hours of adaptations,
and exported episodes (Frapa 2009: 13-15). Sweden is an emerging player,
although Britain exports more formats than Sweden, Norway, Denmark, the
Netherlands and Germany combined (ibid: 101). It is worth noting that while
some smaller, richer countries export a few formats, as with Sweden, they are in
fact net importers (Waller 2006a). According to Frapa, between 2006 and 2008
the Netherlands (64 imports; 35 exports) and Sweden (39 imports; 22 exports)
imported more formats than they exported. Compare this with the UK which
imported 37 formats but exported 146 (Frapa 2009: 11). In fact four countries
accounted for over 75% of exported episodes (Frapa, 2009: 14): the UK (15,981
hours), the USA (13,485), the Netherlands (9,364) and Argentina (6,877).
It is perhaps encouraging to note that small European countries with minor-
ity languages (the Netherlands and Sweden) have managed to break into the
international marketplace as originators of formats (Waisbord 2004: 361). Indeed
some small countries do rather better at exporting formats than exporting more
dramas which are more culturally-specific. But to what extent is market size a
key factor in determining success? It is true that larger transnational corporations
like UK-based FremantleMedia are keen to secure shows from ‘emerging ter-
ritories’ outside Britain and America (Rushton 2010). According to Tony Cohen,
FremantleMedia Chief Executive “The prejudices about where things come from
are all melting away. ‘Is it good or is it not good?’ is the only question [now],
not ‘Where did it come from?’” (cited in Rushton 2010). Indeed investment in
format ideas can be lower than for more complex drama projects, and it does
not really matter where a format idea originates. Creatives in small countries
come up with ideas too. However a key factor is global implementation, which
does, as we shall see later, tend to imply consolidation in order to compete on
the global stage. As Waisbord suggested, in the long term the cards are stacked
against smaller countries and smaller producers: “Although the pool of global
exporters has expanded beyond traditional Hollywood studios as industries
matured, companies based in big and wealthy countries have better chances to
become global exporters” (2004: 362) simply because they have more resources
to translate their hit shows globally.
Format exports by some small countries do run counter to an oversimplified
view of media imperialism because smaller countries do occasionally achieve
international success, even in America which is one of the most culturally
resistant yet commercially lucrative overseas markets. The most notable of
these is the Dutch company Endemol, originator of Big Brother, Deal or No
1. A similar study by the Television Research Partnership gave the UK a 53% share of format airtime and 52%
of titles in 2007. The Netherlands accounted for 18% of format hours and 9% of titles; and the US accounted
for 14% of format air time and 19% of titles (2008: 28)
203
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
Deal, and Wipeout). To be fair, however, one should note that the Spanish
company, Telefonica, owned the majority shares until 2007 and today Endemol
is co-owned by Berlusconi’s Mediaset, America’s Goldman-Sachs and founder
John de Mol (Ashton 2010). So even when a company from a smaller country
is successful, that doesn’t mean it will remain a small country company. We
will come back to this later.
Some of the success that various players enjoy in format trade seems to
be a factor of cultural proximity between different countries – what Sinclair,
Jacka and Cunningham (1996) called ‘geolinguistic regions’. They concluded
that countries are more likely to exchange programmes if they share cultural,
linguistic and historical ties. Thus Britain tends to get preferential access to
the American market because of a shared language (Collins 1989). Within
Scandinavia there is cultural proximity, a geolinguistic region, and a tradition
of working co-operatively that provides a platform for exchanging formats
there. This has allowed companies to strengthen their expertise in adapting
shows to take account of different cultural values and traditions (Frapa 2009:
91; Attentional et al. 2009: 148).
Shifting focus from exports to imports one could argue that formats help to
reinforce the idea that smaller countries are ‘producing’ home-grown content
to satisfy cultural and political objectives even if the formats are acquired from
transnational corporations based in larger countries (Moran 1998: 22-3). For
smaller countries formats can reduce the financial pressures of development,
as more of the risk is taken on by independent producers which are compen-
sated by the retention of secondary, overseas and ancillary rights (Oliver and
Ohlbaum 2007: 25). Even with relatively ‘closed adaptations’ there is still some
scope for “omission, inclusion, substitution or permutation” (Moran 2009a: 46).
The adaptations help to satisfy local preferences and cultural sensibilities and
therefore maintain audience attention (Njus 2009: 125). These changes may
focus on the obvious, such as the choice of host or question topics, but can
also extend to the vibrancy of colours on screen, the length of the show, and
slight adaptations to game rules, programme structure or set design to match
the prevailing television culture of each country (ibid).
This works as long as the overall integrity of the brand is not damaged be-
cause “the ideal format has to be global, but it has to look local” (Jarvis 2010).
The general assumption is that given a choice most people prefer whatever
seems like home grown entertainment (see Morley and Robins 1989; O’Regan
1993; Sinclair, Jacka and Cunningham 1996; Larkey 2009). In this respect Straub-
haar suggested the issue is ‘cultural proximity’, the idea that audiences prefer
programming and content that “is closest or most proximate to their own cul-
ture” (2000: 202). Similarly from an economic perspective, Hoskins and Mirus
suggested the notion of ‘cultural discount’, the idea that cultural differences
relating to style, values, belief, institutions and behavioural patterns will limit
204
Big Formats, Small Nations
the appeal of foreign programmes (1988). Formats have the potential to over-
come this cultural discount and achieve cultural proximity precisely because
they are adapted to local preferences (Lantsch et al 2009).
The “glocalisation” (Robertson 1995) of formats, involving globalising, re-
gionalising and localising forces, is “a commercial strategy to maximise profit”
(Waisbord and Jalfin 2009: 57). In this sense formats are also one outcome of
globalising tendencies where transnational companies customise their formats,
channels and products to appeal to differentiated local markets and maximise
revenues. At the same time formats allow local media producers in smaller
countries to “draw on the codes and conventions...of the global popular to stamp
their own product, channel, distribution network as professional, competitive
and attractive to [domestic] audiences and, more importantly, to advertisers
who sell transnational products” (Boyd-Barrett 1997: 16; see also Waisbord
and Jalfin 2009: 57-58).
One can argue that country size is but one factor in the global format business,
and that is certainly true. There is a strong case for the argument that “media
policies, funding, market competition and broadcast history…shape local pro-
duction” as much as “national social cultural particularities” (Jensen 2009: 165).
Increasing demand for formats with an established track record elsewhere is
keyed to the fact that such content is less risk-laden and less costly than original
programming (Waller 2006a; Oliver and Ohlbaum 2007: 3). Broadcasters like
entertainment formats because they are less risky than other kinds of content,
especially important in an economically unstable environment. Growth has been
driven by the rise of multi-channel television. In this sense smaller countries
function as testing grounds for new ideas. Risk-averse US networks, for example,
can outsource much of their risk-taking to producers and networks in Britain,
the Netherlands, Scandinavia, Japan and New Zealand, using performance in
these territories as a basis for making their own decisions for launch (Oliver
and Ohlbaum 2007: 16; TBI 2010a: 10)
This begs the question: why are some countries more prepared to take risks?
Both Britain and the Netherlands, the first a larger country and the second a
smaller one, have been significant exporters of formats while larger European
territories such as Germany, France, Italy and Spain have been among the
greatest importers (Oliver and Ohlbaum 2007; Frapa 2009). This would suggest
they are more risk averse. One way to pinpoint the factors determining export
205
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
206
Big Formats, Small Nations
adapted for overseas markets. In the case of formats this means the ability to
generate and develop many ideas quickly for the international marketplace. It
also depends on generating the expertise necessary to translate these ideas to
other settings (Moran 2009: 44).
Thus, being small is not a disadvantage for countries like the Netherlands
and Sweden because of these success factors. Clearly, then, format trade is
not only down to size. Like Britain, a larger competitor, the Netherlands and
Sweden have a number of key independent producers who have access to
a sufficient number of domestic outlets that are willing to experiment with
new ideas. There is a history of developing formats for different parts of the
schedule, resulting in a depth of expertise about how to translate these to other
territories. Importantly, in both countries there has been demand from public
service media as well as commercial outlets. In contrast, many of the smaller
markets in Europe are “still reliant on tried and tested formats from the larger
nations and, with very little overall export activity, have little incentive to drive
growth in formats that could potentially be sold in the international market”
(Attentional 2009: 317). Under such conditions smaller nations have been far
more active in the import rather than the export trade.
This transferability underpins the strategy of those major companies that have
built their success on cornerstone properties such as Pop Idol (19/Fremantle-
Media) Big Brother (Endemol), Test the Nation (Eyeworks) and Dancing with
the Stars/Strictly Come Dancing (BBC Worldwide). The largest, most successful
properties mainly come from large international producers, usually in Britain
207
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
and America, with the expertise and resources to roll out a format quickly and
efficiently across many countries.
Where the format business was once focused on small companies licensing
properties to third parties, the business has now consolidated into more “verti-
cally integrated giants with production arms in multiple territories” (C21 2010a).
These companies are intent on retaining their intellectual property, “controlling
the brand” (Jarvis 2010) and using established formats to open new markets
that secure the overseas revenues necessary for growth at scale (C21 2010b;
Oliver and Ohlbaum 2007: 3). This has also impacted smaller countries because
it is characterised by a rise in consolidation and acquisitions.
In the Netherlands the top six independent producer groups already ac-
counted for 75% of the independent production sector in 2007 (Oliver and
Ohlbaum 2007: 12). In recent years, however, foreign rivals from large countries
have acquired key players. So, for example, Endemol has been owned by an
investment group since 2007, led by Goldman Sachs, Mediacinco and Cyrte. It
has also expanded its operations beyond the Netherlands through subsidiaries
and co-ventures around the world, including Latin America and the Middle
East. With a population of only 16.5 million the Netherlands is also home to
other leading format players. Several of these were similarly acquired by larger
transnational companies: 2waytraffic (acquired by Sony Pictures Entertainment
in 2008), IDTV (acquired by UK-based All3Media in 2003), and Blue Circle
(owned by FremantleMedia).
Similarly Sweden with a population of only 9 million has punched above
its weight, producing 78 international versions of 40 original formats between
2006 and 2008 (Frapa 2009: 85). These included The Farm and The Bar, origi-
nated by Strix, part of Sweden’s Modern Times Group. Strix was the company
that licensed the first production of Survivor (Planet 24, now Castaway), which
became Expedition Robinson in Scandinavia. Like the Netherlands, the inde-
pendent production sector in Scandinavia was already highly consolidated with
four producers (Strix, Zodiak, Metronome, and Nordisk) accounting for 60%
of all TV productions in 2006 (Waller 2006b). The market has since become
still more consolidated with the acquisition of Blu in Denmark by the UK’s
FremantleMedia in 2005. Dutch-based Eyeworks (Test the Nation) has acquired
companies in Denmark (Easy Film) and Sweden (ProduktionsBolaget and Nova
TV). Silverback in Sweden was acquired in 2008 by the UK’s ITV. Metronome
Film and Television was incorporated into the UK-based Shine Group in 2009.
Agostini, which is based in Italy, acquired Zodiak Entertainment in 2008. For
larger transnational companies the Scandinavian market offers an opportunity to
expand the scope of their global content and test new ideas ahead of a launch
in the bigger, costlier markets – especially the UK or the USA (C21 2009). This
in itself raises a set of questions about the home base of local companies that
are acquired by companies located in larger countries.
208
Big Formats, Small Nations
209
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
Risk evaluation
One reason for the success of entertainment formats is related to risk. The rise
of reality TV coincided with the rise of a ‘risk society’, to use a framework
popularised by Ulrich Beck (1992). According to this German sociologist,
people live with real and symbolic risks to health and life expectancy. These
risks are associated with modernisation. The perception of risk becomes key
to understanding how people manage different types of threats, such as the
perception of risks from car travel as opposed to aeroplanes. It is often noted
that the public is far more worried about flying than driving despite the fact
that they are statistically at far higher risk when driving. In the sociology of
risk researchers have identified strategies for risk evaluation and management
(see Palmlund 1992). This can include the management of visible risks such as
dangers to health, or livelihood, and the less visible such as moral risk.
Reality TV is a feral genre (Hill 2007). The genre is like a nature experiment
gone wild, where the introduction of a new species takes over a habitat and is
resistant to re-containment. Many cultural commentators have criticised reality
TV for being a moral risk – trash TV for the masses. It has also been perceived
as a cultural risk, contaminating local production with imported formats. This
perception of reality TV as a real and symbolic threat to quality TV and national
values is one way of evaluating a feral genre. But it’s also important to under-
stand that television is a risky business and reality TV is a way of managing
risk through the introduction of a strong and virulent genre. In this way we can
see negative and positive perceptions of reality TV as economic and cultural
risks. Different ways of evaluating risk become significant to understanding
the phenomenon of formats. International producers in the format trade can
be cultural risk producers, as some critics suggest, or from the point of view
of broadcasters they can be risk takers in the development of formats, and at
the same time risk containers, strategically evaluating and managing cultural
and economic risks in media environments.
From an industry perspective reality entertainment formats are a necessary
risk in an economically challenging market – necessary because audiences like
them. It’s a style of television that mixes different genres to create hybrids, such
as a variety show with singing and dancing and a game show with competi-
tion and voting. Reality TV reinvents itself on a rolling basis. At the same time
this is a genre that attracts audiences who want to see themselves as cultural
risk takers – trying out one new show, dropping another. This makes for an
unstable audience that like to watch a constantly changing genre. To make a
successful reality format means a production company has to be a both a risk
taker and a controller of risk. There will be failures. Rob Clark, President of
Worldwide Entertainment at Fremantle pointed out: “These shows are thought
through. They are finely tuned. They are not written down on the back of an
envelope” (2010). From the failures a finely tuned format may emerge; that is
210
Big Formats, Small Nations
the format that circulates worldwide as a low risk product in a high risk industry
with products aimed at a fickle audience.
In this sense, the risk factor certainly relates to matters of size. The players
willing to take risks have changed over the past decade as the business has
evolved. A common explanation for the success of reality TV in the 1990s was
that shows like Airport (BBC) were cheap to make compared to drama and,
as importantly, they rated highly with audiences. Even at then this was an
easy explanation for a complex phenomenon (see Hill 2005 amongst others).
Nevertheless, the relatively lower economic risks of reality TV (as opposed
to soap opera, for example), combined with independent production quotas,
meant that smaller producers and smaller nations could garner success from
big reality series. We saw in the previous section how the Netherlands and
Sweden have both performed well in the format trade. As the trend in reality
shows shifted from lifestyle experiment to talent, however, the opportunities
for smaller players reduced as the scale and expense of these live-event shows
increased. At present, the statistics indicate English language countries are
dominating. As the roll out of these formats continues apace, the key players
become the cultural and economic risk managers that other companies and
countries trust to produce hit shows.
The rollout of an entertainment format to different regions and countries
follows a discernable pattern, as mentioned previously. This geographic pattern
is not only about geo-linguistic regions and cultural proximity, but also about
the perception of risk. According to Rob Clark (2010) “there is a minimisation
of risk at a regional level”. If a format works well in Britain and America that
doesn’t mean it will work in Asia. Other countries need to trust that a format
can work in a similar culture or region. For example, the reality dating format,
Farmer Wants a Wife, (Fremantle and Associated Press) had a rollout that
worked across a large, a medium and a small European nation first. Clark (2010)
explains: “There were three things which happened to make it a success. It
went to Britain and had a great launch. It was formatted in Belgium. By giving
it a structure it minimised the risk because all of a sudden there was a pattern
to follow. And it went to Holland and was a huge hit”.
The perception of risk was further reduced as Farmer Wants a Wife was
transformed into a reality format and rolled out across Western Europe, then
to Southern and Eastern Europe, before breaking out to Australia. Thus, for-
mats are not only about selling but also about understanding how to evaluate
and manage cultural risks. Freemantle certainly understands this. Douglas
Wood (2010) comments: “The rest of the world looks to the UK and US as
a source of formats. This has changed over the past five years. If a format
launches on a Sunday night in the UK I know by Monday morning I will get
calls from France, Spain, and Italy for example, saying send us the ratings
for this format now”.
211
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
When a format launches successfully in the UK the risks are attenuated for
other broadcasters and smaller nations. Gary Carter (2010) notes: “TV is expen-
sive in the first series. Once you have done it once, you understand how to
make it leanly and that is the other benefit to the licensing broadcaster. They
buy on the basis of comfort and justification because of track record. They can
see it very clearly. They don’t have to imagine it”.
What broadcasters in other big and small nations look for is not only the
finely-tuned format but also risk management in action.
Made to Measure
Another reason for the success of entertainment formats is that shows like X
Factor are formats that adjust to local environments. In Albert Moran’s research
on the format trade he called this flexibility in production “open versus closed
formats” (2009). An open format is customised to suit a specific international
region or country. An analogy with fashion is useful, however, as a format like
X Factor is not so much open or closed as made to measure for a broadcaster
and their audience. The format is like a designer suit – you pay for their expert
eye, knowledge of cloth and form, and their instinctive sense of how a good
suit feels just right. The suit is made to measure in the way small adjustments
make it fit better. But the design, what you are paying for, remains the same.
As in fashion there are only a handful of producers that make it to the top
in the format industry. Clark (2010) comments on the clustering of production
talent for formats: “In theory anyone can join. In practice there are lots of bar-
riers, and it is better to hook up with a Big Daddy company who will promote
and market and give it love and attention and put the money behind it to go
international.” These Big Daddy companies manage real and perceived threats
associated with formats with regard to legal matters, production, marketing and
distribution issues within the format chain. They also offer needed skills in how
to make a quality format designed for mass audiences and publics worldwide.
As Clark (2010) says, “It is not the pony end of independent production. You
must have systems to roll out formats as quickly as you can without compro-
mising on the quality. We make it look easy, but it isn’t”. In the same way
that fashion lovers can tell one designer suit from another, from an industry
perspective there are shows that have the look and feel of one of the format
houses. For Clark (2010) it is important that “you always know a Fremantle
programme, there is a certain sheen and gloss and quality to it”.
A successful made to measure format from Fremantle is first and foremost
one that sticks with its original design. Other broadcasters from smaller produc-
tion environments are buying the look and feel of a specific format that already
has a gloss to it. Clark’s job at Fremantle is to make sure that local producers
know the format is a made to measure product: “The worst producer in the
212
Big Formats, Small Nations
world is one that knows better than the format. You don’t want that person. If
something is successful all over the world why would you want to change it?
Ninety nine times out of a hundred it won’t make it any better”.
When Fremantle sells a format to other regions and nations they sell a show
that can fit any broadcaster, with minor alterations. Vasha Wallace (2010), Senior
Vice President of Format Acquisitions Worldwide, noted that “the way we market
the format is always the same. It is always the essence of the show. Lets Dance
(Whizz Kidd) is about celebrity iconic dances. Hole in the Wall (Fuiji) is about
people falling in the water. Keep to the essence, what makes it a success”.
Fremantle has flying producers who work with local broadcasters and re-
gional production companies to ensure a format has a good chance of success.
From a production perspective, the scale of a local production environment is
not about the size of the nation and its population but rather the wealth of a
production culture and its knowledge base. The previous section noted how
Scandinavian countries were perceived within the industry as having good
production bases with skilled workers and access to sophisticated technology.
Eastern European countries must work harder to acquire such knowledge and
skills, usually with much less money. When a flying producer goes to Serbia
with Got Talent, the system at Fremantle ensures it looks the same as America’s
Got Talent – including the graphics, title, and music. The format system means
Serbia’s Got Talent immediately “associates itself with the biggest show on earth,
it brands it that way and gives it class” (Clark 2010). The system of the ‘format
bible’ puts in place the foundation stones – the set, auditions, casting, judges
– and the flying producers back this up with workshops where they pass on
knowledge from one production culture to another. Research on Norwegian
Idol, for example, showed precisely this balancing act of conserving the bible
whilst incorporating small variations in the local scripts (Njus 2009).
This made to measure approach can be seen in the way Got Talent works
in Sweden. Blu is a Scandinavian production company that is owned by Fre-
mantle. The Managing Director of Blu Sweden is Claus Leinstedt, former Head
of Production for Strix and responsible for reality formats such The Farm and
The Bar. The broadcaster of Sweden Talang (TV4) have bought the format
and the production skills and talent of Blu and its Big Daddy company. Got
Talent is a format that suits Sweden and needs few local alterations. According
to Leinstedt (2010) Swedish audiences tend to like British shows because of a
cultural affinity between these nations. He explains:
Got Talent should have the same look as the UK version because we think it
is perfect. … We have a smaller crew, smaller set design. We have less editing
hours, we do casting in another way. It is impossible for us to have a couple
of thousand people in the audience, so we use smaller venues... We are used
to this way of working in Sweden. We know how to make things work for
213
Annette Hill & Jeanette Steemers
less. It is hard to get the quality of the UK show, so we have to find smart
ways and use creative producers who make it look as good for less money.
Leinstedt (2010) understands “what is good about a format is that you can watch
the idea” and see how it will work with some adjustment in another culture
and production environment.
To summarise, the question of why entertainment formats are so successful
with audiences raises several issues. Broadcasters like entertainment formats
because they are perceived as low risk products in an economically unstable
media environment. These formats mainly come from large international pro-
ducers who know how to manage the perception of risk in a cultural industry.
They produce a finely tuned format that broadcasters and local producers can
see in action at a launch, usually in Britain or America, and subsequent roll out
to other regions and countries. The visible reduction of cultural and economic
risks through the successful launch of a format leads to increased trust in a small
group of international producers. The format is made to suit other production
cultures through minor alterations. This made to measure approach ensures
broadcasters buy a well-designed format that local producers can adjust with
few major problems. The relationship between the format producer and local
producer is explicitly handled through formal structures and systems, such as
the use of a bible and flying producers, and it is also implicitly handled through
knowledge of how a format works for local audiences. The combination of risk
management and flexible format production make Big Daddy companies like
Fremantle “key springers”, as Gary Carter put it, in the global entertainment race.
Conclusion
In the case of formats certainly size matters, but how and why reveals nuances
and complexities that are changing and merit better understanding. Ten to
fifteen years ago the size of a country was less important because good ideas
can come from anywhere. Yet as the format industry has grown into big busi-
ness, size has become paramount. The format industry has been successful in
some small, rich countries like the Netherlands and Sweden (Attentional 2009:
62). Although they have languages not widely spoken elsewhere, they have
managed to break into international markets. In 2008 in terms of exported
formats per million inhabitants, episodes exported per million of population,
and the amount of production costs generated per million of population, the
Netherlands and Sweden were reasonably successful on the global stage (Frapa
2009). Global presence, however, has only been maintained by consolidation
into larger transnational concerns, capable of rolling out programmes quickly
on an international stage. What is also noticeable is that in the main the larger
214
Big Formats, Small Nations
more expensive prime-time ‘shiny floor’ shows, which are more commercially
rewarding, tend to originate with transnational companies in larger countries
like the UK. Such countries have the resources to experiment with more costly
formats (TBI 2010b), and can extend that expertise to the all-important US
market as well (White 2010: 36-39). Size does matter in relation to companies
and the type of large-scale format they are promoting. The research reported
here demonstrates that although size may not have always mattered as much
in the past, it has become increasingly significant in the past ten years – and
should be expected to be at least as important in the years ahead.
In the end, small countries are limited by the smallness of their domestic
markets, the lack of sufficient resources to sustain more expensive entertainment
shows, and the cheapness of overseas products, including reality entertainment
formats, which serve as bankers for larger ‘superindies’. As small countries
they continue to be limited by a restricted range of producers, fewer viewers /
consumers, and less advertising or licence fee revenues; all of that even while
the costs of production remain high, whatever the size of the market. Even
for those few that break out internationally from small countries of origin, the
trends suggest that ultimately consolidation and integration within a globalised
marketplace will make them part of big country companies.
Acknowledgements
Our thanks goes to Ute Biernat, Chairman of Frapa, and Chief Executive Officer of Grundy
Light Entertainment Germany; Gary Carter, Chief Operating Officer, FremantleMedia and Chief
Creative Officer, FMX; Rob Clark, President of Worldwide Entertainment FremantleMedia,;
Julie Donovan Senior Vice President International Development at FremantleMedia; Colin
Jarvis, Director of International Format Production BBC Worldwide; Claes Leinstedt, Managing
Director of BLU, Sweden; Elin Thomas, VP of Format Sales for EMEA, BBC Worldwide; Vasha
Wallace, Senior Vice President Format Acquisitions Worldwide, FremantleMedia; Douglas
Wood, Head of Research FremantleMedia UK.
215
Bibliography
217
Bibliography
218
Bibliography
219
Bibliography
Guidelines on the Use of Minority Languages in the Broadcast Media. (2003) OSCE High Commis-
sioner on National Minorities (HCNM), October.
Guyot, J. (2007) Minority language media and the public sphere. In Cormack, M. and Hourigan,
N. (eds.) Minority Language Media: Concepts, Critiques and Case Studies. Clevedon: Multi-
lingual Matters Ltd, pp.34-51.
Hallin, D.C. and Mancini, P. (2004) Comparing Media Systems: Three Models of Media and Politics.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hamilton, A., Madison, J., and Jay, J. (2003) The Federalist Papers. London: Penguin Classics.
Handel, M. (1981) Weak States in the International System. Totowa, NJ: Frank Cass.
Hanf, K. and Soetendorp, B. (1997) Small states and the Europeanization of public policy. In
Adapting to European Integration: Small States and the European Union, NY: Longman.
Hanf, K. and Soetendorp, B. (1997) The nature of national adaption to European integration. In
Adapting to European Integration: Small States and the European Union, NY: Longman.
Hanretty, C. (2009) The Political Independence of Public Broadcasters. PhD dissertation, Fiesole,
Italy: European University Institute.
Hanretty, C. (2010) Explaining the de facto independence of public broadcasters. British Journal
of Political Science, 40(01).
Hill, A. (2005) Reality TV: Audiences and Popular Factual Television. London: Routledge.
Hirsch, M. and Petersen, V.G. (1992) Regulation of media at the European level. In Siune, K. and
Treetzschle, W. (eds.) Dynamics of Media Politics. London: Sage.
Hoskins, C. and Mirus, R. (1988) Reasons for the US dominance of the international trade in televi-
sion programmes. Media, Culture and Society, 10(4).
Hourigan, N. (2007) Minority language media studies: Key themes for future scholarship. In Cor-
mack, M. and Hourigan, N. (eds.) Minority Language Media: Concepts, Critiques and Case
Studies. Clevedon: Multilingual Matters Ltd.
Hutchison, D. (1999) Media Policy. UK: Blackwell Publishers.
Höll, O. (ed.) (1983) The Laxenburg Papers: Small States in Europe and Dependence. Boulder,
CO: Westview Press.
Jakubowicz, K. (2007) Systemic parallelism. IRIS Special: The Public Service Broadcasting Culture.
Strasbourg: European Audiovisual Observatory.
Jensen, P.M. (2009) How national media systems shape the localization of formats: A transnational
case study in The Block and Nerds FC in Australia and Denmark. In Moran, A. (ed.) TV For-
mats Worldwide. Bristol, UK: Intellect.
Jyrkiäinen, J. (2007) The Finnish media landscape. In Terzis, G. (ed.) European Media Governance:
National and Regional Dimensions. Chicago: Intellect.
Katzenstein, P.J. (1985) Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.
Keohane, R.O. (1969) Review: Lilliputians’ dilemmas – small states in international politics. Inter-
national Organization, 23(2).
Kesner, I., Victor, B., and Lamont, B. (1986) Board composition and the commission of illegal
acts: An investigation of Fortune 500 companies. Academy of Management Journal, 29(4).
Knee, J.A., Greewald, B.C. and Seave, A. (2009) The Curse of the Media Mogul: What’s Wrong with
the World’s Leading Media Companies. London: Portfolio.
Kommunförbundet (2010) Allmän statistik regionvis. Available: http://hosted.kuntaliitto.fi/skriptit/
tilastot/aluetietopankkiElevSv.asp.
Kymlicka, W. (1995) Multicultural Citizenship: A Liberal Theory of Minority Rights. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Laurén, C., Myking, J. and Picht, H. (2008) Language and domains: A proposal for a domain
dynamics taxonomy. LSP and Professional Communication, 2(2). Available: http://cjas.dk/
index.php/LSP/article/viewFile/1959/1961.
Lantsch, K., Altmeppen, K-D., and Will, A. (2009) Trading in TV entertainment: An analysis. In
Moran, A. (ed.) TV Formats Worldwide. Bristol, UK: Intellect.
Larkey, E. (2009) Transcultural localization strategies of global TV formats: The Office and Stromb-
erg. In Moran, A. (ed.) TV Formats Worldwide. Bristol, UK: Intellect.
220
Bibliography
Leys, C. (2001) Market Driven Politics: Neoliberal Democracy and the Public Interest. London: Verso.
Linz, J.J. and de Miguel, A.(1966) Within nation differences and comparisons: The eight Spains. In
Merrit, R. and Rokkan, S. (eds.) Comparing Nations: The Use of Quantitative Data in Cross
National Research. USA: Yale University Press.
Lonergan, E. (2009) Money. Durham, UK: Acumen Publishing Limited.
Lowe, G.F. (2009) The Meaning of Money: Modes & Implications for Funding PSM. Paper presented at
the annual conference of the European Media Management Association [EMMA] in Paris, France.
Luhmann, N. (1995) Social Systems. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Macpherson, C.B. (1962) The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: Hobbes to Locke. Oxford:
Clarendon.
Martinson, J. (2010) BBC ‘close to meltdown’ before last-minute license fee deal. Guardian.co.uk,
25 October. Avaliable at www.guardian.co.uk/media/2010/oct/25/bbc-license-fee-mark-
thompson. Downloaded 26 October.
McChesney, R.W. (2008) The Political Economy of Media: Enduring Issues, Emerging Dilemmas.
NY: Monthly Review Press.
McQuail, D. (2005) McQuail’s Mass Communication Theory, 5th Edition. London: Sage.
Mediareports prognosis (2009) Fernsehen 2013. Basel.
Meier, W.A. (2007) National and transnational media ownership concentration in Europe: A burden
for democracy?. In Meier, W.A. and Trappel, J. (eds.) Power, Performance and Politics: Media
Policy in Europe. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Meier, W.A. and Saxer, U. (1992) Switzerland. In Ostergaard, B.S. (ed.) The Media in Western
Europe: The Euromedia Handbook. London: Sage.
Meier, W.A. and Trappel, J. (1992) Small states in the shade of giants. In Siune, K. and Truetzschler,
W. (eds.) Dynamics of Media Politics: Broadcast and Electronic Media in Western Europe.
London: Sage.
Moran, A. (1998) Copycat TV. Luton, UK: University of Luton Press.
Moran, A. (2005) Configurations of the new television landscape. In Wasko, J. (ed.) A Companion
to Television. London: Blackwell.
Moran, A. (2009a) When TV formats are translated. In Moran, A (ed.) TV Formats Worldwide.
Bristol, UK: Intellect.
Moran, A. (2009b) Reasserting the national? Programme formats, international television and do-
mestic culture. In Turner, G, and Tay, J. (eds.) Television Studies After TV. London: Routledge.
Morgenthau, H.J. (1967) Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace. NY: Alfred
A. Knopf.
Moring, T. (2007) Functional completeness in minority language media. In Cormack, M. and Hou-
rigan, N. (eds.) Minority Language Media: Concepts, Critiques and Case Studies. Clevedon:
Multilingual Matters Ltd.
Moring, T. and Dunbar, R. (2008) The European Charter for regional or minority languages and
the media. Regional or Minority Languages, No. 6. Strasbourg: Council of Europe.
Moring, T. and Godenhjelm, S. (2010) Det sammanhållande kittet. En studie av minoritetsmedier
i Europa. (A study of minority media in Europe). Magma Studie 3, 2010 (monograph). Hel-
sinki: Magma-publikationer.
Moring, T. and Husband, C. (2007) The contribution of Swedish-language media in Finland to
linguistic vitality. International Journal of the Sociology of Language 187/188.
Moring, T. and Husband, C. (2009) Ethnolinguistic vitality, the media and language retention in
multiethnic societies. In Jasinskaja-Lahti, I. and Mähönen, T.A. (eds.) Identities, Intergroup Rela-
tions and Acculturation – The Cornerstones of Intercultural Encounters. Helsinki: Gaudeamus.
Moring, T. and Salmi, J. (1998) Public service radio programming for minority language audience(s)
in a competitive market: The case of the Swedish-speaking minority in Finland. Gazette, 60(4).
Moring, T., Husband, C., Lojander-Visapää, C., Vincze, L., Fomina, J. and Mänty, N. (forthcoming)
Media use and ethnolinguistic vitality in bilingual communities. Journal of Multilingual and
Multicultural Development.
Morley, K., and Robins, K. (1989) Spaces of identity: Communications, technologies and the re-
configuration of Europe. Screen, 30(4).
221
Bibliography
Mortensen, F. (2004) Denmark. In Kelly, M., Mazzoleni, G. and McQuail, D. (eds.) The Media in
Europe: The Euromedia Handbook. London: Sage.
Njus, Y. (2009) Collaborative reproduction of attraction and performance: The case of the reality
show Idol’. In Moran, A. (ed.) TV Formats Worldwide. Bristol, UK: Intellect.
Noll, R.G., Peck, M. and McGowan, J.J. (1973) Economic Aspects of Television Regulation. Wash-
ington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Oliver and Ohlbaum (2007) Prospects for the European TV Content Sector to 2012. London.
O’Regan, T. (1993) New and declining audiences: Contemporary transformations in Hollywood’s
international market. In Jacka, E. (ed.) Continental Shift. Sydney: Local Consumption Pub-
lications.
Oslo Recommendations regarding the Linguistic Rights of National Minorities & Explanatory Note.
(1998) OSCE High Commissioner on National Minorities (HCNM), February.
Ostrom, E. (1990 Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Ott, D. (2000) Small is Democratic: An Examination of State Size and Democratic Development.
NY: Garland Pub.
Owen, B.M., Beebe, J.H., and Manning Jr., W.G. (1974) Television Economics. Lexington, Mass:
D.C. Heath.
Owen, B.M. and Wildman, S.S. (1992) Video Economics. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Owers, J., Carveth, R., and Alexander, A. (2004) An Introduction to media economics theory and
practice. In Alexander, A., Owers, J., Carveth, R., Hollifield, A.C. and Greco, A.N. (eds.) Media
Economics: Theory and Practice, 3rd Edition. Mahwah NJ: Erlbaumn Associates.
Palmlund, I. (1992) Social drama and risk evaluation. In Krimsky, S. and Golding, D. (eds.) Social
Theories of Risk. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Parsons, T. (1951) The Social System. Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press.
Parsons, T. (1961) Shills, E., Naegele, K. and Pitts, J. (eds.) Theories of Society. NY: The Free Press
of Glencoe, Inc.
Patten, A. (2003) What kind of bilingualism? In Kymlicka, W. and Patten, A. (eds.) Language Rights
and Political Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Peacock, A. (1986) Report on the Committee on Financing the BBC. London: HMSO.
Pedersen, O.K., Campbell, J.L. and Hall, J.A. (2006) National Identity and Varieties of Capitalism:
The Danish Experience. Montreal: McGill-Queens University Press. Copenhagen: Jurist- og
Økonomiforbundets Forlag.
Pedersen, T. and Thomsen, S. (1997) European patterns of corporate ownership: A twelve-country
study. Journal of International Business Studies, 28(4).
Picard, R.G. (1985) Patterns of state intervention in Western press economics. Journalism Quar-
terly, Spring.
Picard, R.G. (1989) Media Economics: Concepts and Issues. Newbury Park, CA: SAGE.
Picard, R.G. (2002) Assessing the audience performance of public service broadcasters. European
Journal of Communication, 17(2).
Picard, R.G. (2010) The Economics and Financing of Media Companies, 2nd ed. New York: Ford-
ham University Press.
Plato (1926) The Laws. Loeb Classical Library. London: Heinemann.
Porter, M.E. (1998) Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. NY:
Free Press.
Puppis, M. (2009) Introduction: Media regulation in small states. The International Communica-
tion Gazette, 71(1-2).
Puppis, M., d’Haenens, L., Steinmaurer, T. and Künzler, M. (2009) The European and global dimen-
sion: Taking small media systems research to the next level. The International Communication
Gazette, 71(1-2), pp. 105-112.
Reshaping politics (2010) The Economist, January 8. Accessed June 18. Available at http://www.
economist.com/node/15213252.
Robertson, R. (1995) Glocalisation: Time-space and homogeneity-heterogeneity. In Featherstone,
M., Lash, S. and Robertson, R. (eds.) Global Modernities. London: Sage.
222
Bibliography
Robinson, E.A.G. (1960) Economic Consequences of the Size of Nations, International Economic
Association, 2nd Edition. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Rothstein, R.L. (1968) Alliances and Small Powers. NY: Columbia University Press.
Rushton, K. (2010) Fremantle widens format net. Broadcast, 12 April. Avaliable at http://www.broad-
castnow.co.uk/news/international/fremantle-widens-format-net/5012627.article?sm=5012627.
Salovaara-Moring, I. and Moring, T. (2010) Cultural Ecology of Cit(y)zenship: Changing the per-
spective on space and mobility. In Broddason, T., Kivikuru, U., Tufte, B., Weibull, L. and
Østbye, H. (eds.) The Nordic Countries and the World: Perspectives from research on media
and communication. A book for Ulla Carlsson. Gothenburg: Göteborgs universitet.
Saxer, U. (2005) Zur Institutionsgeschichte des öffentlichen Rundfunks. In Ridder, C-M, Langenbu-
cher, W.R., Saxer, U. and Steininger, C. (eds.) Bausteine einer Theorie des öffentlich-rechtlichen
Rundfunks. Festschrift für Marie Luise Kiefer. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.
Schlesinger, P. (1993) Wishful Thinking: Cultural Politics, Media, and Collective Identities in Europe.
Journal of Communication, 43(2).
Schumpeter, J. (1976) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 5th Edition. London: Allen and Unwin.
Siegert, G. (2006) The role of small countries in media competition in Europe. In Heinrich, J. and
Kopper, G.G. (eds.) Media Economics in Europe. Berlin: Vistas.
Sinclair, J., Jacka, E., and Cunningham, S. (1996) New Patterns in Global Television: Peripheral
Vision. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Spaink, H. and Meuleman, T. (2004) The Ox Report: Review of Licensing of Radio Services in Ire-
land. A Study for the Department of Communication, Marine and Natural Resources. Dublin.
Steemers, J. (2004) Selling Television: British Television in the Global Marketplace. London: British
Film Institute.
Steininger, C. and Woelke, J. (eds.) (2007) Fernsehen in Österreich 2007. Constance: UVK.
Steininger, C. and Woelke, J. (2008) Separating TV ads from TV programming. What we can learn
about programme-integrated advertising from economic theory and research on media use.
Communications. 33(4).
Steinmaurer, T. (2009) Diversity through delay? The Austrian case. The International Communica-
tion Gazette, 71(1-2).
Straubhaar, J. (2000) Culture, language and social class in the globalization of television. In Wang,
G., Servaes, J. and Goonasekera, A. (eds.) The New Communications Landscape. London:
Routledge, pp.199-224.
Study on the application of measures concerning the promotion of the distribution and produc-
tion of European works in audiovisual media services (i.e. including television programmes
and non linear services) (2009) – SMART 2007/0001, Final study report. Available at: http://
ec.europa.eu/avpolicy/info_centre/library/studies/index_en.htm#finalised
Television Across Europe: More Channels, Less Independence, Follow-Up Reports (2009) Budapest:
Open Society Institute.
Television Across Europe: Regulation, Policy, and Independence (2005) Budapest: Open Society
Institute.
[TBI] Television Business International (2010a) In Development. Oct/Nov.
[TBI] Television Business International (2010b) Shiny Floors. Oct/Nov, p.14.
Television Research Partnership (2008) Rights of Passage, 2007. London.
Terzis, G. (ed.) (2007) European Media Governance: National and Regional Dimensions. Bristol:
Intellect.
Thompson, P.A. (2010) Joining the Dots on Nat’s Broadcasting Policies. Avaliable at http://www.
scoop.co.nz/stories/HL1002/S001142.htm, accessed 10 Feb 2010.
Thorhallsson, B. (2000) The Role of Small States in the European Union. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate
Publishing Company.
Trappel, J. (1991) Born losers or flexible adjustment? The media policy dilemma of small states.
European Journal of Communication, 6(3), pp.355-371.
Tunstal, J. (2007) Cultural and media nationalism in Europe. In Meier, W.A. and Trappel, J. (eds.)
Power, Performance and Politics: Media Policy in Europe. Baden-baden: Nomos.
Turner, G. and Tay, J. (2009) Television Studies After TV. London: Routledge.
223
Bibliography
TWF Directive (1989) Television without Frontiers, directive 89/552/EEC. Avaliable http://europa.
eu/legislation_summaries/audiovisual_and_media/l24101_en.htm.
United Nations (2005) World Population Prospects.
United Nations Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples (2007) Adopted by General As-
sembly Resolution 61/295 on 13 September.
United States Central Intelligence Agency (2009) CIA World Factbook.
Waisbord S. and Jalfin S. (2009) Imagining the national: Gatekeepers and the adaptation of global
franchises in Argentina. In Moran, A. (ed.) TV Formats Worldwide. Bristol: Intellect.
Waisbord, S. (2004) McTV: Understanding the global popularity of television formats. Television
and New Media, 5.
WARC (2009) World Advertising Trends 2009. Henly-on-Thames, UK: World Advertising Research
Centre.
Waller, E. (2006a) Indies look to global format growth, C21, 14 September. Available at: http://
www.c21media.net/features/detail.asp?area=2&article=32140.
Waller, E. (2006b) Norse code. C21, 16 May. Available at: http://www.c21media.net/features/detail.
asp?area=2&article=30475
Waller, E. (2006c) The new empire builders. C21, 18 April. Available at: http://www.c21media.
net/features/detail.asp?area=2&article=30014.
Waller, E. (2007) UK’s Got Talent – but it’s not the only one. C21, 21 August. Available at: http://
www.c21media.net/features/detail.asp?area=2&article=37134
White, P. (2010) A Latin reality. Television Business International. Dec-Jan.
Whitehead, J. (2010) France halts plans to ban remaining ads on public TV. Advertising Age, 6
October.
Österlund-Karinkanta, M. (2004) Finland. In Kelly, M., Mazzoleni, G. and McQuail, D. (eds.) The
Media in Europe: The Euromedia Handbook. London: Sage.
224
NORDICOM
Nordic Information Centre for Media and Communication Research
NORDICOM is an Institution within
the Nordic Council of Ministers
Director: Ulla Carlsson Administration and Sales: Technical Editing and Webmaster:
Telephone: +46 31 786 12 19 Anne Claesson Per Nilsson
Fax: +46 31 786 46 55 Telephone: +46 31 786 12 16 Telephone: +46 31 786 46 54
[email protected] Fax: +46 31 786 46 55 Fax: +46 31 786 46 55
[email protected] [email protected]
Field of Activities
National Centres
www.nordicom.gu.se
Staffan Sundin
Telephone: +46 36 16 45 82
[email protected]