Practical DECISION THEORY
Practical DECISION THEORY
Practical DECISION THEORY
S1 S2 S3 Row minimum
A1 4 16 12 4
A2 5 6 10 5*maximum
A3 -1 4 15 -1
A2 will be chosen.
2. MAXIMAX
This approach is the opposite of the previous one: The best payoff for each alternative
is identified, and the alternative with the maximum of these is the designated
decision.
For the previous problem:
S1 S2 S3 Row Maximum
A1 4 16 12 16*maximum
A2 5 6 10 10
A3 -1 4 15 15
A1 will be chosen.
3. MINIMAX REGRET
Both the maximax and maximin strategies can be criticized because they focus only
on a single, extreme payoff and exclude the other payoffs. Thus, the maximax
strategy ignores the possibility that an alternative with a slightly smaller payoff might
offer a better overall choice. For example, consider this payoff table:
S1 S2 S3 Row Max.
A1 -5 16 -10 16*max
A2 15 15 15 15
A3 15 15 15 15
a similar example could be constructed to demonstrate comparable weaknesses of the
maximin criterion, which is also due to the failure to consider all payoffs.
An approach that does take all payoffs in to consideration is Minimax regret. In order
to use this approach, it is necessary to develop an opportunity loss table. The
opportunity loss reflects the difference between each payoff and the best possible
payoff in a column (i.e., given a state of nature). Hence, opportunity loss amounts are
found by identifying the best payoff in a column and, then, subtracting each of the
other values in the column from that payoff.
EXAMPLE
S1 S2 S3
A1 4 16 12
A2 5 6 10
A3 -1 4 15
opportunity loss table:
S1 S2 S3
A1 5-4=1 16-16=0 15-12=3
A2 5-5=0 16-6=10 15-10=5
A3 5-(-1)=6 16-4=12 15-15=0
The values in an opportunity loss table can be viewed as potential “regrets” that might
be suffered as the result of choosing various alternatives. A decision maker could
select an alternative in such a way as to minimize the maximum possible regret. This
requires identifying the maximum opportunity loss in each row and, then, choosing
the alternative that would yield the best (minimum) of those regrets.
S1 S2 S3 Max. Loss
A1 5-4=1 16-16=0 15-12=3 3*minimum
A2 5-5=0 16-6=10 15-10=5 10
A3 5-(-1)=6 16-4=12 15-15=0 12
A1 will be chosen.
Although this approach makes use of more information than either Maximin or
Maximax, it still ignores some information, and, therefore, can lead to a poor decision.
EXAMPLE
Opportunity loss table
S1 S2 S3 S4 Max. Loss
A1 0 0 0 24 24
A2 15 15 15 0 15*minimum
A3 15 15 15 0 15*minimum
4. PRINCIPLE OF INSUFFICIENT REASON
The Minimax regret criterion weakness is the inability to factor row differences.
Hence, sometimes the minimax regret strategy will lead to a poor decision because it
ignores certain information.
The principle of insufficient reason offers a method that incorporates more of the
information. It treats the states of nature as if each were equally likely, and it focuses on
the average payoff for each row, selecting the alternative that has the highest row
average.
EXAMPLE
S1 S2 S3 S4 S5 Row Average
A1 28 28 28 28 4 23.2*maximum
A2 5 5 5 5 28 9.6
A3 5 5 5 5 28 9.6
the basis for the criterion of insufficient reason is that under complete uncertainty, the
decision maker should not focus on either high or low payoffs, but should treat all
payoffs (actually, all states of nature), as if they were equally likely. Averaging row
payoffs accomplishes this.
DECISION MAKING UNDER RISK
The term risk is often used in conjunction with partial uncertainty, presence of
probabilities for the occurrence of various states of nature. The probabilities may be
subjective estimates from managers or from experts in a particular field, or they may
reflect historical frequencies. If they are reasonably correct, they provide the decision
maker with additional information that can dramatically improve the decision making
process.
*the sum of the probabilities for all states of nature must be 1.
EXPECTED MONETARY VALUE (EMV)
The EMV approach provides the decision maker with a value which represents an
average payoff for each alternative. The best alternative is, then, the one that has the
highest EMV. The average or expected payoff of each alternative is a weighted average:
EMVi = k
Σ Pj.Vij
i=1
Where:
EMVi = the EMV for the ith alternative
Pi = the probability of the ith state of nature
Vij = the estimated payoff for alternative i under state of nature j.
EXAMPLE