Leec 204
Leec 204
Leec 204
The Theor
Theoryy of the Firm
Firm
under Per
Per fect Competition
erfect
Reprint 2024-25
for the large numbers of firms to exist. If entry was difficult, or restricted, then
the number of firms in the market could be small. Perfect information implies
that all buyers and all sellers are completely informed about the price, quality
and other relevant details about the product, as well as the market.
These features result in the single most distinguishing characteristic of perfect
competition: price taking behaviour. From the viewpoint of a firm, what does
price-taking entail? A price-taking firm believes that if it sets a price above the
market price, it will be unable to sell any quantity of the good that it produces.
On the other hand, should the set price be less than or equal to the market price,
the firm can sell as many units of the good as it wants to sell. From the viewpoint
of a buyer, what does price-taking entail? A buyer would obviously like to buy
the good at the lowest possible price. However, a price-taking buyer believes that
if she asks for a price below the market price, no firm will be willing to sell to her.
On the other hand, should the price asked be greater than or equal to the market
price, the buyer can obtain as many units of the good as she desires to buy.
Price-taking is often thought to be a reasonable assumption when the market
has many firms and buyers have perfect information about the price prevailing
in the market. Why? Let us start with a situation where each firm in the market
charges the same (market) price. Suppose, now, that a certain firm raises its
price above the market price. Observe that since all firms produce the same good
and all buyers are aware of the market price, the firm in question loses all its
buyers. Furthermore, as these buyers switch their purchases to other firms, no
“adjustment” problems arise; their demand is readily accommodated when there
are so many other firms in the market. Recall, now, that an individual firm’s
inability to sell any amount of the good at a price exceeding the market price is
precisely what the price-taking assumption stipulates.
4.2 REVENUE
We have indicated that in a perfectly competitive market, a firm believes that it
54 can sell as many units of the good as it wants by setting a price less than or equal
to the market price. But, if this is the case, surely there is no reason to set a price
Microeconomics
Introductory
lower than the market price. In other words, should the firm desire to sell some
amount of the good, the price that it sets is exactly equal to the market price.
A firm earns revenue by selling the good that it produces in the market. Let
the market price of a unit of the good be p. Let q be the quantity of the good
produced, and therefore sold, by the firm at price p. Then, total revenue (TR) of
the firm is defined as the market price of the good (p) multiplied by the firm’s
output (q). Hence,
TR = p × q
To make matters concrete, consider the following numerical example. Let the
market for candles be perfectly competitive and let the market price of a box of
candles be Rs 10. For a candle manufacturer, Table 4.1: Total Revenue
Table 4.1 shows how total revenue is related to
output. Notice that when no box is sold, Boxes sold TR (in Rs)
TR is equal to zero; if one box of candles is sold, 0 0
TR is equal to 1×Rs 10= Rs 10; if two boxes of 1 10
candles are produced, TR is equal to 2 × Rs 10 2 20
= Rs 20; and so on. 3 30
We can depict how the total revenue changes 4 40
as the quantity sold changes through a Total 5 50
Revenue Curve. A total revenue curve plots
Reprint 2024-25
the quantity sold or output on the
Revenue
X-axis and the Revenue earned on
the Y-axis. Figure 4.1 shows the
total revenue curve of a firm. Three TR
observations are relevant here.
First, when the output is zero, the
total revenue of the firm is also
zero. Therefore, the TR curve A
passes through point O. Second,
the total revenue increases as the
output goes up. Moreover, the
equation ‘TR = p × q’ is that of a O q1 Output
straight line because p is constant. Fig. 4.1
This means that the TR curve is
an upward rising straight line. Total Revenue curve. The total revenue curve of
a firm shows the relationship between the total
Third, consider the slope of this revenue that the firm earns and the output level of
straight line. When the output is the firm. The slope of the curve, Aq1/Oq1, is the
one unit (horizontal distance Oq1 market price.
in Figure 4.1), the total revenue
(vertical height Aq1 in Figure 4.1)
is p × 1 = p. Therefore, the slope of
Price
the straight line is Aq1/Oq1 = p.
The average revenue ( AR ) of
a firm is defined as total revenue
per unit of output. Recall that if a
firm’s output is q and the market p
Price Line
price is p, then TR equals p × q.
Hence
TR p ×q
AR = q = q =p
55
In other words, for a price-taking
Reprint 2024-25
Is it a coincidence that this is the same as the price? Actually it is not. Consider
the situation when the firm’s output changes from q1 to q2. Given the market
price p,
MR = (pq2 –pq1)/ (q2 –q1)
= [p (q2 –q1)]/ (q2 –q1)
=p
Thus, for the perfectly competitive firm, MR=AR=p
In other words, for a price-taking firm, marginal revenue equals the market
price.
Setting the algebra aside, the intuition for this result is quite simple. When a
firm increases its output by one unit, this extra unit is sold at the market price.
Hence, the firm’s increase in total revenue from the one-unit output expansion –
that is, MR – is precisely the market price.
4.3.1 Condition 1
Profits are the difference between total revenue and total cost. Both total revenue
and total cost increase as output increases. Notice that as long as the change in
total revenue is greater than the change in total cost, profits will continue to
increase. Recall that change in total revenue per unit increase in output is the
marginal revenue; and the change in total cost per unit increase in output is the
marginal cost. Therefore, we can conclude that as long as marginal revenue is
greater than marginal cost, profits are increasing. By the same logic, as long as
marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, profits will fall. It follows that for
profits to be maximum, marginal revenue should equal marginal cost.
In other words, profits are maximum at the level of output (which we have
called q0) for which MR = MC
For the perfectly competitive firm, we have established that the MR = P. So the
firm’s profit maximizing output becomes the level of output at which P=MC.
4.3.2 Condition 2
Consider the second condition that must hold when the profit-maximising output
level is positive. Why is it the case that the marginal cost curve cannot slope
1
It is a convention in economics to denote profit with the Greek letter π.
Reprint 2024-25
downwards at the profit-
maximising output level? To
answer this question, refer once
again to Figure 4.3. Note that at
output levels q 1 and q 4, the
market price is equal to the
marginal cost. However, at the
output level q1, the marginal
cost curve is downward sloping.
We claim that q1 cannot be a
profit-maximising output level.
Why?
Observe that for all output
levels slightly to the left of q 1,
the market price is lower than Conditions 1 and 2 for profit maximisation.
the marginal cost. But, the The figure is used to demonstrate that when the
market price is p, the output level of a profit-
argument outlined in section
maximising firm cannot be q1 (marginal cost curve,
4.3.1 immediately implies that MC, is downward sloping), q2 and q3 (market price
the firm’s profit at an output exceeds marginal cost), or q5 and q6 (marginal cost
level slightly smaller than q 1 exceeds market price).
exceeds that corresponding to
the output level q 1. This being the case, q 1 cannot be a profit-maximising
output level.
4.3.3 Condition 3
Consider the third condition that Price,
SMC
costs
must hold when the profit-
maximising output level is
positive. Notice that the third SAC
condition has two parts: one part AVC
applies in the short run while the 57
Reprint 2024-25
Similarly, the firm’s total variable cost at q1 is as follows
TVC = Average variable cost × Quantity
= Vertical height OE × Width Oq1
= The area of rectangle OEBq1
Now recall that the firm’s profit at q1 is TR – (TVC + TFC); that is, [the area of
rectangle OpAq1] – [the area of rectangle OEBq1] – TFC. What happens if the firm
produces zero output? Since output is zero, TR and TVC are zero as well. Hence,
the firm’s profit at zero output is equal to – TFC. But, the area of rectangle OpAq1
is strictly less than the area of rectangle OEBq1. Hence, the firm’s profit at q1 is
[(area EBAp)-TFC], which is strictly less than what it obtains by not producing at
all. So, the firm will choose not to
produce at all, and exit from the Price, LRMC
market. costs
Reprint 2024-25
maximisation problem in the short run. Consider Figure 4.6. Notice that the
market price is p. Equating the market price with the (short run) marginal
cost, we obtain the output level q0. At q0, observe that SMC slopes upwards
and p exceeds AVC. Since the three conditions discussed in sections 3.1-3.3
are satisfied at q0, we maintain that the profit-maximising output level of the
firm is q0.
What happens at q0? The total revenue of the firm at q0 is the area of
rectangle OpAq0 (the product of price and quantity) while the total cost at q0 is
the area of rectangle OEBq0 (the product of short run average cost and quantity).
So, at q0, the firm earns a profit equal to the area of the rectangle EpAB.
Reprint 2024-25
condition 3 in section 3) that if a Price,
profit-maximising firm produces Supply
costs
Curve
a positive output in the short run, (SMC)
then the market price, p2, must be
SAC
greater than or equal to the AVC
at that output level. But notice AVC
from Figure 4.7 that for all positive
output levels, AVC strictly exceeds
p2. In other words, it cannot be the
case that the firm supplies a
positive output. So, if the market
O Output
price is p2, the firm produces zero
output. Fig. 4.8
Combining cases 1 and 2, we
The Short Run Supply Curve of a Firm. The
reach an important conclusion. A short run supply curve of a firm, which is based
firm’s short run supply curve is on its short run marginal cost curve (SMC) and
the rising part of the SMC curve average variable cost curve (AVC), is represented
from and above the minimum AVC by the bold line.
together with zero output for all prices strictly less than the minimum AVC. In
figure 4.8, the bold line represents the short run supply curve of the firm.
Reprint 2024-25
argued (see condition 3 in section Supply Curve(LRMC)
Price,
3) that if a profit-maximising firm costs
produces a positive output in the
long run, the market price, p2, LRAC
must be greater than or equal to
the LRAC at that output level. But
notice from Figure 4.9 that for all
positive output levels, LRAC
strictly exceeds p2. In other words,
it cannot be the case that the firm
supplies a positive output. So,
when the market price is p2, the O Output
firm produces zero output. Fig. 4.10
Combining cases 1 and 2, we
The Long Run Supply Curve of a Firm. The
reach an important conclusion. A long run supply curve of a firm, which is based on
firm’s long run supply curve is the its long run marginal cost curve (LRMC) and long
rising part of the LRMC curve from run average cost curve (LRAC), is represented by
and above the minimum LRAC the bold line.
together with zero output for all
prices less than the minimum LRAC. In Figure 4.10, the bold line represents the
long run supply curve of the firm.
Opportunity cost
In economics, one often encounters the concept of opportunity cost.
Opportunity cost of some activity is the gain foregone from the second best
activity. Suppose you have Rs 1,000 which you decide to invest in your family
business. What is the opportunity cost of your action? If you do not invest
Reprint 2024-25
this money, you can either keep it in the house-safe which will give you zero
return or you can deposit it in either bank-1 or bank-2 in which case you get
an interest at the rate of 10 per cent or 5 per cent respectively. So the maximum
benefit that you may get from other alternative activities is the interest from
the bank-1. But this opportunity will no longer be there once you invest the
money in your family business. The opportunity cost of investing the money
in your family business is therefore the amount of forgone interest from the
bank-1.
Reprint 2024-25
Recall that the long run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the
LRMC curve from and above the minimum LRAC together with zero output
for all prices less than the minimum LRAC. Using this observation in Figure
4.12, it is immediate that S0 and S1 are, respectively, the long run supply
curve of the firm before and after the imposition of the unit tax. Notice that
the unit tax shifts the firm’s long run supply curve to the left: at any given
market price, the firm now supplies fewer units of output.
LRMC1 Price S1 S0
Costs
LRAC1
LRMC0
LRAC0
0
p +t
p0 + t
t
p0
0
p
O O q0 Output
q0 Output
Fig. 4.11 Fig. 4.12
Cost Curves and the Unit Tax. LRAC0 Supply Curves and Unit Tax. S0 is the
and LRMC0 are, respectively, the long run supply curve of a firm before a unit tax
average cost curve and the long run is imposed. After a unit tax of Rs t is
marginal cost curve of a firm before a unit imposed, S1 represents the supply curve
tax is imposed. LRAC1 and LRMC1 are, of the firm.
respectively, the long run average cost
curve and the long run marginal cost curve
of a firm after a unit tax of Rs t is imposed.
Reprint 2024-25
price greater than or equal to p1 but strictly less than p 2 , only firm 1 will produce
a positive amount of the good. Therefore, in this range, the market supply curve
coincides with the supply curve of firm 1. For a market price greater than or
equal to p 2 , both firms will have positive output levels. For example, consider a
situation wherein the market price assumes the value p3 (observe that p3
exceeds p 2 ). Given p3, firm 1 supplies q3 units of output while firm 2 supplies q4
units of output. So, the market supply at price p3 is q5, where q5 = q3 + q4. Notice
how the market supply curve, Sm, in panel (c) is being constructed: we obtain Sm
by taking a horizontal summation of the supply curves of the two firms in the
market, S1 and S2.
Price
S1 S2
Sm
p3
p2
p1
O q3 O q4 O q5 Output
(a) (b) (c)
Fig. 4.13
The Market Supply Curve Panel. (a) shows the supply curve of firm 1. Panel (b) shows the
supply curve of firm 2. Panel (c) shows the market supply curve, which is obtained by taking
a horizontal summation of the supply curves of the two firms.
It should be noted that the market supply curve has been derived for a fixed
64 number of firms in the market. As the number of firms changes, the market
supply curve shifts as well. Specifically, if the number of firms in the market
Introductory
Microeconomics
increases (decreases), the market supply curve shifts to the right (left).
We now supplement the graphical analysis given above with a related
numerical example. Consider a market with two firms: firm 1 and firm 2. Let the
supply curve of firm 1 be as follows
0 : p < 10
S1(p) = p – 10 : p ≥ 10
Notice that S1(p) indicates that (1) firm 1 produces an output of 0 if the market
price, p, is strictly less than 10, and (2) firm 1 produces an output of (p – 10) if
the market price, p, is greater than or equal to 10. Let the supply curve of firm 2
be as follows
0 : p < 15
S2(p) = p – 15 : p ≥ 15
The interpretation of S2(p) is identical to that of S1(p), and is, hence, omitted.
Now, the market supply curve, Sm(p), simply sums up the supply curves of the
two firms; in other words
Sm(p) = S1(p) + S2(p)
Reprint 2024-25
But, this means that Sm(p) is as follows
0 : p < 10
Sm(p) = p – 10 : p ≥ 10 and p < 15
( p – 10) + ( p – 15) = 2 p – 25 : p ≥ 15
∆Q
× 100
Q ∆Q P
= = ×
∆P Q ∆P
× 100
P
Where ∆Q is the change in quantity of the good supplied to the market as market
price changes by ∆P .
To make matters concrete, consider the following numerical example. Suppose
the market for cricket balls is perfectly competitive. When the price of a cricket ball
is Rs10, let us assume that 200 cricket balls are produced in aggregate by the firms
in the market. When the price of a cricket ball rises to Rs 30, let us assume that 1,000
cricket balls are produced in aggregate by the firms in the market.
The percentage change in quantity supplied and market price can be estimated
using the information summarised in the table below:
65
Price of Cricket balls (P) Quantity of Cricket balls
∆Q
Percentage change in quantity supplied= Q × 100
1
Q 2 − Q1
= × 100
Q1
1000 − 200
= × 100
200
= 400
∆P
Percentage change in market price = P × 100
1
Reprint 2024-25
P2 − P1
= × 100
P1
30 − 10
= × 100
10
= 200
400
Therefore, price elasticity of supply, eS = =2
200
When the supply curve is vertical, supply is completely insensitive to price
and the elasticity of supply is zero. In other cases, when supply curve is
positively sloped, with a rise in price, supply rises and hence, the elasticity of
supply is positive. Like the price elasticity of demand, the price elasticity of
supply is also independent of units.
S S S
p0 p0 p0
O M q0
M O q0 Output O q0 Output Output
Price Elasticity Associated with Straight Line Supply Curves. In panel (a), price elasticity
(eS ) at S is greater than 1. In panel (b), price elasticity (eS) at S is equal to 1. In panel (c), price
elasticity (eS) at S is less than 1.
Reprint 2024-25
• In a perfectly competitive market, firms are price-takers.
Summary
• The total revenue of a firm is the market price of the good multiplied by the firm’s
output of the good.
• For a price-taking firm, average revenue is equal to market price.
• For a price-taking firm, marginal revenue is equal to market price.
• The demand curve that a firm faces in a perfectly competitive market is perfectly
elastic; it is a horizontal straight line at the market price.
• The profit of a firm is the difference between total revenue earned and total cost
incurred.
• If there is a positive level of output at which a firm’s profit is maximised in the
short run, three conditions must hold at that output level
(i) p = SMC
(ii) SMC is non-decreasing
(iii) p ≥ AV C.
• If there is a positive level of output at which a firm’s profit is maximised in the
long run, three conditions must hold at that output level
(i) p = LRMC
(ii) LRMC is non-decreasing
(iii) p ≥ LRAC.
• The short run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the SMC curve from and
above minimum AVC together with 0 output for all prices less than the minimum
AVC.
• The long run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the LRMC curve from and
above minimum LRAC together with 0 output for all prices less than the minimum
LRAC.
• Technological progress is expected to shift the supply curve of a firm to the right.
• An increase (decrease) in input prices is expected to shift the supply curve of a
firm to the left (right).
• The imposition of a unit tax shifts the supply curve of a firm to the left.
67
• The market supply curve is obtained by the horizontal summation of the supply
Reprint 2024-25
5. What is the relation between market price and average revenue of a price-
taking firm?
6. What is the relation between market price and marginal revenue of a price-
taking firm?
7. What conditions must hold if a profit-maximising firm produces positive output
in a competitive market?
8. Can there be a positive level of output that a profit-maximising firm produces
in a competitive market at which market price is not equal to marginal cost?
Give an explanation.
9. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market ever produce a positive
level of output in the range where the marginal cost is falling? Give an
explanation.
10. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market produce a positive level of
output in the short run if the market price is less than the minimum of AVC?
Give an explanation.
11. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market produce a positive level of
output in the long run if the market price is less than the minimum of AC?
Give an explanation.
12. What is the supply curve of a firm in the short run?
13. What is the supply curve of a firm in the long run?
14. How does technological progress affect the supply curve of a firm?
15. How does the imposition of a unit tax affect the supply curve of a firm?
16. How does an increase in the price of an input affect the supply curve of a firm?
17. How does an increase in the number of firms in a market affect the market
supply curve?
18. What does the price elasticity of supply mean? How do we measure it?
19. Compute the total revenue, marginal
revenue and average revenue schedules Quantity Sold TR MR AR
in the following table. Market price of each 0
68 unit of the good is Rs 10.
1
Introductory
Microeconomics
2
3
4
5
6
Reprint 2024-25
21. The following table shows the total cost schedule
Output TC (Rs)
of a competitive firm. It is given that the price
of the good is Rs 10. Calculate the profit at each 0 5
output level. Find the profit maximising level of 1 15
output. 2 22
3 27
4 31
5 38
6 49
7 63
8 81
9 101
10 123
22. Consider a market with two
firms. The following table Price (Rs) SS1 (units) SS2 (units)
shows the supply schedules 0 0 0
of the two firms: the SS 1 1 0 0
column gives the supply
2 0 0
schedule of firm 1 and the
SS2 column gives the supply 3 1 1
schedule of firm 2. Compute 4 2 2
the market supply schedule. 5 3 3
6 4 4
Reprint 2024-25
25. A firm earns a revenue of Rs 50 when the market price of a good is Rs 10. The
? market price increases to Rs 15 and the firm now earns a revenue of Rs 150.
What is the price elasticity of the firm’s supply curve?
26. The market price of a good changes from Rs 5 to Rs 20. As a result, the quantity
supplied by a firm increases by 15 units. The price elasticity of the firm’s supply
curve is 0.5. Find the initial and final output levels of the firm.
27. At the market price of Rs 10, a firm supplies 4 units of output. The market price
? increases to Rs 30. The price elasticity of the firm’s supply is 1.25. What quantity
will the firm supply at the new price?
70
Introductory
Microeconomics
Reprint 2024-25