Roberts 2002
Roberts 2002
ABSTRACT
The use of surrogate weights based on rankings has been proposed as a method for avoiding difficulties associated
with the elicitation of weights in multi-attribute decision analysis. When the simple multiattribute rating technique
using swings (SMARTS) method is being employed it has been suggested that rank order centroid (ROC) weights
are the best surrogate weights to use. This study shows that ROC weights are appropriate to use as a substitute for
original weights that are constrained to sum to a fixed total (usually 1 or 100) as used in the point allocation method.
If, however, the original weights are determined without any initial restrictions, as in the direct rating method, and
are then normalized, which is the common procedure in SMARTS analysis, then the ROC weights do not provide
the best approximations to the original weights. This paper shows how to obtain rank order distribution (ROD)
weights that provide a better approximation than the ROC approach to unrestricted original weights. The paper also
shows that, as the number of attributes in a decision problem increases, the ROD weights approximate to the more
easily calculated rank sum weights. Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
KEY WORDS: multi-criteria decision making; weight elicitation; rank order centroid weights
1. INTRODUCTION O1 O2 . Om
Decision makers are often required to choose W1 V11 V21 . Vm1
between several alternatives or options where each
option exhibits a range of attributes. When W2 V12 V22 . Vm2
choosing a new home, for example, the different
dwellings (options) under consideration may well . . . . .
vary in such attributes as cost, size, location,
facilities and age. Each option may score well with Wn V1n V2n . Vmn
respect to certain attributes and less well with
others. The relative importance to the decision Totals 1 V(O1) V(O2) . V(Om)
maker of each attribute will, to a large extent,
determine which option is regarded as best overall.
There are many procedures described in the Here Vij is the value assigned to the ith option
literature for formalizing the decision-making and jth attribute, 04Vij 4100. The Wj > 0 are
process under these conditions. Examples are weights reflecting the relative importance Pn of the
found in Keeney and Raiffa (1976), Von Winter- ranges of the attribute values, with j¼1 wj ¼ 1.
feldt and Edwards (1986), Green and Srinivasan In
Pn addition, w1 5w 2 5 5wn > 0 and vðOi Þ ¼
(1990) and Saaty (1994). This paper focuses on j¼1 wj vij where v is the aggregate multi attribute
multi-attribute value evaluation processes that value in the range 1005v50:
involve identifying single attributes and then Because the elicitation of weights can be
evaluating alternatives on them to form an difficult, several methods have been proposed for
‘attributes by options’ matrix. reducing the burden of the process. Many of these
methods involve asking the decision maker simpler
questions about the relative importance of the
attributes and using the responses to identify
*Correspondence to: University of Bath, The Manage- weights that are intended to approximate the
ment School, Bath BA2 7AY, UK. E-mail: mnspg@ decision maker’s ‘true’ weights. One of the more
management.bath.ac.uk recent proposals has been based on the use of rank
order centroid (ROC) weights (Barron and Bar- rating, (ii) point allocation and (iii) ranking. These
rett, 1996a; Edwards and Barron, 1994). In a approaches are outlined below.
series of simulation experiments, designed to assess (i) Direct rating method: The direct rating
the accuracy of ROC weights as approximations to method, discussed by von Winterfeldt and Ed-
‘true’ weights, Barron and Barrett found that wards (1986), uses ‘direct numerical ratio judge-
‘ROC captures. . . a substantial portion of the ments of relative attribute importance’. There are
information content of totally precise weights’ a number of ways of implementing this method. In
and, compared to other approximation methods, one approach the decision maker assigns an
‘ROC is clearly and overwhelmingly the most arbitrary importance of (say) 10 to the least
efficacious’. However, we argue below that the important attribute. Then the next most important
accuracy reported by Barron and Barrett (and by attribute is identified and a decision is made about
Edwards and Barron in a similar study) is based how much more important it is than the previous
on particular assumptions about how decision attribute and so on. The raw weights are P then
makers’ ‘true’ weights are formed and these normalized using the formula wi ¼ wi = ni¼1 wi
assumptions may not be valid in certain circum- where wi is the ith raw ratio weight and wi is the
stances. In the light of this, we propose an ith normalized weight.
alternative method that can be used when the An alternative approach involves arbitrarily
assumptions underlying the ROC method are not assigning a raw weight of 100 to the attribute
applicable. where switching from the worst to the best option
The paper is structured as follows. After a brief on that attribute is most desirable. The desirability
review of weight elicitation methods, we examine of making similar worst-to-best switches on each
the assumptions underlying ROC weights. The of the other attributes is then assessed relative to
alternative method for approximating weights is this, yielding raw weights on a scale with a
then described and formulae are derived to maximum of 100. Finally the weights are normal-
operationalize this method. Finally, the paper ized to sum to either 1 or 100 (see Goodwin and
reports the results of a simulation study which Wright, 1998).
was used to assess the relative efficacy of the alter- (ii) Point allocation method: In the point alloca-
native approximation method when the assump- tion method the decision maker has a ‘budget’
tions underpinning ROC weights do not apply. of points to allocate between the attributes in a
way that reflects their relative importance. For
example, the decision maker may be asked to
2. WEIGHT ELICITATION allocate 100 points between the five attributes
that are relevant to a particular decision. Clearly,
When obtaining the weights (Wj ) that will be in this method there is no need to normalize
associated with the ‘attributes by options’ matrix, the weights since the sum of 100 is already
it is important that they should take into prescribed.
consideration the decision maker’s relative pre- Doyle et al. (1997) declare the point allocation
ference for swings from the worst to the best method is a more difficult task since it is easier to
options on each attribute (Edwards and Barron, take 100 as the weight for the most important
1994; Goodwin and Wright, 1998). This is because attribute and then to allocate weights relative to
the value scale measuring the relative performance this 100 starting point as the weight of successive
of the options on a given attribute will usually attributes. The decision maker has no need to
range from 0 (for the worst option on that worry about the constraint that the total must be
attribute) to 100 (the best). Since similar 0–100 some specified value. Because of this Doyle et al.
scales will be used for all attributes, the weights argue that ‘Since the set of cognitive operations
will need to reflect the relative importance of these required to use the two methods is different, there
0–100 swings to the decision maker. However, in is every possibility that different decision weights
the following discussion, for brevity, we will will result’. Indeed, as Doyle et al. point out,
simply refer to ‘relative importance of the ranges although this method of determining weights and
of attribute values’ as ‘relative importance of the the direct rating method would seem to be minor
attributes’. There are several methods described in variants of each other, in practise they produce
the literature for determining weights. Most different profiles of decision weights, a result that
methods fall into one of three categories: (i) Direct surprised Jia et al. (1998).
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 293
Rank 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
294 R. ROBERTS AND P. GOODWIN
Rank 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Rank 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
simplified alternative to SMARTS called SMAR- ble values of ‘true’ weights it is necessary to
TER (SMART Exploiting Ranks) because consider how the ‘true’ weights might be distrib-
uted. Barron and Barrett (1996a) argue the case
(the) results of extensive simulations . . .suggest for sampling from a uniform distribution on the
that the SMARTS and SMARTER will agree basis that no weight is more likely than another.
on which option has the highest aggregate Consider, first, the simplest example involving
benefit in 75%–87% of cases. Even when they only two attributes. The most important attribute
did not agree, the option identified by SMAR- must be given a weight (w1 ) which is greater than
TER as having the highest aggregate benefit 0.5 and less than 1. As the weights in the points
tended to have a very similar score to the ‘best’ allocation method sum to 1 the weight of the other
option identified by SMARTS, suggesting that attribute must be (1 w1 ). Assuming that the
‘true’ weights are uniformly distributed, the means
an option which was ‘not too bad’ was being
of the two distributions of the ranks would be
picked by SMARTER. 0.75 and 0.25, respectively, and these correspond
with the ROC weights for two attributes. (See
Figure 1.)
4. THE RATIONALE FOR ROC WEIGHTS For problems involving more than two attri-
butes a mathematical approach is required to
In order to investigate how effective the surrogate determine the theoretical distribution of the
weights perform as approximations for the possi- ranked weights following a points allocation
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 295
Distribution of Ranks Point Allocation n = 2 length then the exact probability distribution for
5 the kth largest section is given by Rao and Sobel
(1980) to be
4 n X
nk
j nk
Rank 1
fwk ðxÞ ¼ kðn 1Þ ð1Þ
Rank 2 k j¼0 j
3
f (x)
n2
h1 ðk þ jÞxi ð1Þ
2
where k ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; n and where hai ¼ maxða; 0Þ.
This is equivalent to the formula given by Holst
1 (1980) for the length of the jth longest piece of
stick when a stick of uniform length is broken at
0 random into n pieces and the pieces are then
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 ranked by size. Appendix A lists the equations of
(a) x the piecewise curves which (1) produces for n ¼ 2,
3 and 4. The corresponding distributions for n ¼ 2,
Distribution of Ranks Point Allocation n = 3.
7 3 and 4 are shown in Figure 1. The mean values of
Rank 2
the distributions of the ranks are equivalent to the
6 ROC weights i.e. 0.75, and 0.25 for n ¼ 2, 0.6111,
5
Rank 3 0.2778 and 0.1111 for n ¼ 3, and 0.5208, 0.2708,
Rank 1 0.1458 and 0.0625 for n ¼ 4.
4 Note that the underlying assumption of ROC
f (x)
4
5. RANK ORDER DISTRIBUTION (ROD)
2 WEIGHTS
0 Recall that in the direct rating method the most
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
(c) x
important attribute is commonly assigned a weight
of 100 and the importance of the other attributes
Figure 1. (a) Distribution of Ranks Point Allocation are then assessed relative to this benchmark. The
n ¼ 2, (b) Distribution of Ranks Point Allocation n ¼ 3, ‘raw’ weights (wi ) obtained are then normalized to
(c) Distribution of Ranks Point Allocation n ¼ 4. sum to 1. Assuming that all attributes have some
importance, this means that the ranges of the
procedure. If the interval 0–1 is randomly cut into possible raw weights will be: w1 ¼ 100,
n sections by choosing n 1 random points 05w2 4100, 05w3 4w2 and, in general, 05wi 4
between 0 and 1 and ranking the sections by wi1 (where ia1). These ranges can be approxi-
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
296 R. ROBERTS AND P. GOODWIN
mated by representing all of the inequalities by If the independent variables come from the
less-than-or-equal-to expressions. We can then, U(0,100) distribution, then f ðv1 Þ ¼ f ðv2 Þ ¼ ¼
1
like Edwards and Barron (1994) and Barron and f ðvn Þ ¼ 100 in which case, the joint distribution
1
Barrett (1996a), represent our uncertainty about f ðv1 ; v2 ; . . . ; vn Þ ¼ n! 100 n.
the ‘true’ weights by assuming uniform distribu- To illustrate the use of this distribution we will
tions for them. However, in the case of the direct again use the case where n ¼ 2. Consider attribute
rating method these uniform distributions will values v1 and v2 such that v1 5v2 50.
apply across the ranges specified above for wi As a result of the normalization process, the
rather than those assumed by the ROC method. distribution of the larger value, v1 , after normal-
We know of no empirical evidence that suggests ization can be obtained as follows,
that weights (or errors in the estimation of
v1 1x
weights) follow a uniform distribution, but in the Pr 4x ¼ Pr v2 5 v1
absence of other information, this assumption is v1 þ v2 x
consistent with Bayes’ criterion (e.g. Kwon, 1978, But the expression ðð1 xÞ=xÞv1 50 is true if and
p. 142). In addition to Barron and Barrett, the only if 04x41 and the expression ðð1 xÞ=xÞv1
assumption has also been made by other research- 4v1 is true if and only if 124x41.
ers in this area such as Jia et al. (1998) and For the interval x 2 ½12; 1 it is always true that
Lahdelma and Salminen (2002). ðð1 xÞ=xÞv1 50 and so
Before examining the general problem of Z 100 Z v1
determining approximate weights, assuming that v1 2
Pr 4x ¼ 2
dv2 dv1
direct rating is appropriate, it may be useful to re- v1 þ v2 0 ðð1xÞ=xÞv1 100
consider the simple problem involving two attri- Z 100
2 1
butes. In this case, for simplicity and without loss ¼ 2 v1 dv1
of generality, we will assume that w1 ¼ 100. We 1002 0 x
therefore assume that w2 Uð0; 100Þ. Thus the 1
normalized weights will be ¼ 2
x
w1 ¼ 100=ð100 þ w2 Þ and w2 ¼ w2 =ð100 þ w2 Þ Differentiating gives the probability density func-
tion: fw1 ðxÞ ¼ x12 for x 2 ½12; 1.
so that The distribution of the smaller value v2 after nor-
Z 100 malization is given by Prðv2 =ðv1 þ v2 Þ4xÞ ¼ Prðv2 4
Eðw1 Þ ¼ 1=ð100 þ w2 Þ dw2 ðx=ð1xÞÞv1 Þ and the expression ðx=ð1xÞ=xÞv1 4v1
0 is true if and only if 04x412.
ðgiven the assumption of Therefore,
Z 100 Z ðx=ð1xÞÞv1
uniformity for w2 Þ v2 2
h i Pr 4x ¼ dv2 dv1
100 v1 þ v2 0 0 1002
¼ loge ð100 þ w2 Þ ¼ 0:693 Z 100 Z v1
0 2
þ dv2 dv1
Similarly, it can be shown that Eðw2 Þ ¼ 0:307. 0 0 100 2
These values are to be contrasted with the ROC ¼ x=ð1 xÞ þ 1 ¼ 1=ð1 xÞ
weights of 0.75 and 0.25.
To determine ROD weights for general pro- Differentiating gives fw2 ðxÞ ¼ 1=ð1 xÞ2 for x 2
blems we need to consider the probability dis- ½0; 12
tributions for the normalized weights that follow So for n ¼ 2 the distribution of the normalized
from our assumptions about the distributions of rank 1 is 1=x2 and is only defined between 12 and
the raw weights. The equations of the probability 1. The distribution of the normalized rank 2 is
density functions can be found from the joint given by 1=ð1 xÞ2 for the region between 0 and 12
distribution of n order statistics (see, for example, The means of these probability density func-
the theoretical text by Rice (1988)). tions are Lnð2Þ ¼ 0:6932 and 1 Lnð2Þ ¼ 0:3078,
If v1 ; v2 ; . . . ; vn are n independent random respectively.
variables ranked in order such that v1 5v2 5 5 A similar but more involved mathematical
vn then the joint distribution f ðv1 ; v2 ; . . . ; vn Þ ¼ process can be applied to produce the probability
n!f ðv1 Þf ðv2 Þ f ðvn Þ. density functions for n ¼ 3, 4, etc. For n > 2 the
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 297
Distribution of Ranks. Direct Rating n = 2. The means of each rank order distribution
5 (ROD) for n ¼ 2 to 10 have been found mathe-
matically and are displayed in Table IV. These
4 weights can be compared with the ROC weights
Rank 2 Rank 1 (Table I), the RS weights (Table II), and the RR
3 weights (Table III).
f (x)
6
Rank 1
in the ROC weights). For five attributes the ratio
of w1 to w5 is 5.6 (not 11.1 as in ROC), though
4
Belton and Stewart argue that ratios exceeding 5
2 usually indicate that the least-important attribute
is almost totally dominated by the other attribute.
0 In summary, there is clear theoretical evidence to
(c)
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 show that the ROC weights are the best surrogate
x
weights to use for the point allocation method of
Figure 2. (a) Distribution of Ranks. Direct Rating assigning raw weights and the ROD weights are
n ¼ 2, (b) Distribution of Ranks. Direct Rating n ¼ 3, the best for direct rating methods of assigning raw
(c) Distribution of Ranks. Direct Rating n ¼ 4. weights. We next test this theoretical case empiri-
cally by following Barron and Barrett’s procedure
density functions are a series of piecewise equa- of applying the different weight approximation
tions. These equations, for each of the rank methods to a large set of simulated decisions.
distributions for n ¼ 3 to 5, are set out in the
Appendix B. The equations for n ¼ 6 to 10 are
increasingly more cumbersome but can be pro- 6. EFFICACY OF ROD WEIGHTS
vided by the first author on request. Figure 2
shows the shape of the probability density func- The simulation study was used to compare the
tions for n ¼ 2, 3 and 4. efficacy of the new ROD, the ROC, the RS and the
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
298 R. ROBERTS AND P. GOODWIN
Rank 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 299
Attributes ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR
2 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 88.0 87.2 87.9 85.1 86.4 85.0 86.3 77.3 84.5 83.4 85.0 75.7 84.0 82.1 84.0 75.5
4 92.0 83.2 97.7 97.4 88.4 83.8 88.5 73.9 85.6 81.3 85.9 69.6 84.9 79.7 85.0 66.4 83.0 78.6 83.3 65.2
6 94.4 89.9 94.4 92.0 89.1 82.7 89.2 72.7 87.6 80.6 87.4 68.3 85.9 78.6 86.1 65.1 84.7 76.6 84.9 62.6
8 94.4 88.4 87.1 93.5 90.8 82.3 90.6 72.2 88.1 78.8 88.1 66.7 86.6 76.6 86.7 63.5 85.9 75.8 86.1 61.9
10 95.2 88.0 95.2 93.5 90.8 81.2 90.7 72.2 89.2 77.9 89.2 66.6 88.2 76.5 88.3 63.4 87.6 75.0 87.6 62.6
Attributes ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR ROD ROC RS RR
2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.95 1.08 1.00 3.23 0.99 1.16 1.04 3.66 1.00 1.16 1.04 3.09 0.93 1.11 0.99 2.70
4 0.97 3.11 0.39 0.78 0.73 1.29 0.75 3.57 0.71 1.14 0.70 3.55 0.68 1.11 0.72 3.61 0.70 1.10 0.70 3.46
6 0.40 0.95 0.40 0.54 0.48 1.13 0.49 3.02 0.45 1.05 0.47 2.94 0.47 1.03 0.46 3.05 0.49 1.05 0.49 3.11
8 0.31 1.03 0.15 0.66 0.30 1.05 0.32 2.59 0.32 1.05 0.32 2.74 0.35 1.02 0.35 2.81 0.35 1.00 0.34 2.76
10 0.20 0.96 0.20 0.66 0.25 0.95 0.26 2.31 0.24 1.00 0.25 2.48 0.24 0.95 0.25 2.47 0.24 0.97 0.25 2.39
10 000 simulation trials were undertaken for each 8. AVERAGE VALUE LOSS
of these structures. For every attribute, values
were assigned to each option by giving at random The average value losses of the surrogate weight
one option a value of 0 another a value of 100 and methods are shown in Table VI. It can be seen that
the rest a value randomly selected from a U(0, 100) once again the ROD and RS weights outperform
distribution. the ROC and RR weights in every decision
As the results displayed below show, using the structure. There is little to distinguish between
ROD and RS surrogate weights, the outcome the ROD and RS weights but the RR weights
match with the true weights was impressive and produce relatively high average value losses.
consistently better than the ROC and RR weights
for the two measures of efficacy chosen.
9. CONCLUSIONS
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
300 R. ROBERTS AND P. GOODWIN
light of this, we believe that serious consideration Waid, 1982}though they did not assess the direct
should be given to the use of ROD weights as rating method). This may be because the decision
surrogate weights in direct rating cases. The ROD maker’s initial weights are ill formed and the
weights for n ¼ 2 to 10 have been published in particular elicitation procedure in some way
Table IV and can therefore be easily implemented becomes part of the process of weight formation
by decision analysts. or because the structure inherent in some proce-
The formulae for the distribution of the ROD dures prevents the decision maker from expressing
weights become progressively more complex as the his or her true weights and serves to distort them.
number of attributes increase. Since the RS In the absence of an external, objective, analogue
weights are so easy to calculate and closely match for preferences the accuracy of the weights
the ROD weights for higher numbers of attributes determined through different procedures can only
it is also recommended that serious consideration be assessed on indirect criteria such as the user’s
should be given to the use of RS weights when it is trust in the method or the method’s cognitive
intended to approximate a distribution of weights complexity. Nevertheless, there may be occasions
for problems involving large numbers of attributes when an analyst has good reason to believe that a
and where it can be assumed that the appropriate given decision maker more naturally perceives the
alternative method for eliciting the ‘true’ weights’ weights in a decision problem to be structured as a
would have been the direct rating method. series of swings with an importance that is
Of course, ultimately the true test of a weight perceived to be relative to that of the most
approximation procedure is the extent to which it important (or least important) attribute, rather
accurately represents the decision maker’s true than as an allocation of points across the
preferences. The empirical research suggests that attributes. If the analyst seeks to approximate
the type of elicitation procedure adopted will have the decision maker’s weights on the basis of the
an effect on the attribute weights that are formally ranking of these swings, the method described here
assessed (e.g. Doyle et al. 1997; Schoemaker and is likely to provide the appropriate approximation.
APPENDIX A
The equations of the piecewise curves for each of the rank distributions (point allocation) produced by
formula 1 for n ¼ 2, 3 and 4 are as follows:
n=2
Rank 1 8
0 0
< 2ðð1 xÞ ð1 2xÞ Þ ¼ 0; 04x41=2
fw1 ðxÞ ¼ 0 1=24x41
2ðð1 xÞ ¼ 2;
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 2
2!ð1 2xÞ0 ¼ 2; 04x41=2
fw2 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
For n=3
Rank 1 8
>
> 6ðð1 xÞ 2ð1 2xÞ þ ð1 3xÞÞ ¼ 0; 04x41=3
<
6ðð1 xÞ 2ð1 2xÞÞ ¼ 18x 6; 1=34x41=2
fw1 ðxÞ ¼
>
> 6ðð1 xÞ ¼ 6 6x; 1=24x41
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 2 8
< 12ðð1 2xÞ þ ð1 3xÞÞ ¼ 12x; 04x41=3
fw2 ðxÞ ¼ 12ð1 2xÞ; 1=34x41=2
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 3
6ð1 3xÞ; 04x41=3
fw3 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 301
APPENDIX A (Continued)
APPENDIX B
The piecewise curves for each of the rank distributions (direct rating) for n ¼ 2 to 5:
n=2
Rank 1
(
1=x2 ; 1=24x41
fw1 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
Rank 2
(
1=ð1 xÞ2 ; 04x41=2
fw2 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
n=3
Rank 1
8 3 2
< 1=x þ 3=x ;
> 1=34x41=2
fw1 ðxÞ ¼ þ1=x3 1=x2 ; 1=24x41
>
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 2
8 2 2
< 1=ðx 1Þ þ 1=ð2x 1Þ ;
> 04x41=3
2
fw2 ðxÞ ¼ þ1=x2 1=ðx 1Þ ; 1=34x41=2
>
:
0 elsewhere
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
302 R. ROBERTS AND P. GOODWIN
APPENDIX B (Continued)
Rank 3
(
þ4=ðx 1Þ2 1=ð2x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=3
fw3 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
Rank 2
8
>
> þ1=2ðx 1Þ2 1=ð2x 1Þ2 þ 1=2ð3x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=4
>
>
< 1=x3 þ 9=2x2 þ 1=2ðx 1Þ2 1=ð2x 1Þ2 ; 1=44x41=3
fw2 ðxÞ ¼
> þ1=x3 5=2x2 þ 1=2ðx 1Þ2 ;
> 1=34x41=2
>
>
: elsewhere
0
Rank 3
8 2 2 2
< 8=ðx 1Þ þ 9=ð2x 1Þ 1=ð3x 1Þ ;
> 04x41=4
fw3 ðxÞ ¼ þ1=x2 8=ðx 1Þ2 þ 1=ð2x 1Þ2 ; 1=44x41=3
>
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 4
(
þ27=2ðx 1Þ2 8=ð2x 1Þ2 þ 1=2ð3x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=4
fw4 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
Rank 2
8
>
> 1=6ðx 1Þ2 þ 1=2ð2x 1Þ2 1=2ð3x 1Þ2 þ 1=6ð4x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=5
>
>
>
> 4 3 2 2 2 2 1=54x41=4
< þ1=2x 16=3x þ 43=3x 1=6ðx 1Þ þ 1=2ð2x 1Þ 1=2ð3x 1Þ ;
>
fw3 ðxÞ ¼ 1=x4 þ 23=3x3 85=6x2 1=6ðx 1Þ2 þ 1=2ð2x 1Þ2 ; 1=44x41=3
>
>
>
> 1=34x41=2
> þ1=2x4 7=3x3 þ 17=6x2 1=6ðx 1Þ2 ;
>
>
: elsewhere
0
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)
WEIGHT APPROXIMATION 303
APPENDIX B (Continued)
Rank 3
8
>
> þ8=ðx 1Þ2 33=2ð2x 1Þ2 þ 9=ð3x 1Þ2 1=2ð4x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=5
>
>
< 1=x3 þ 13=2x2 þ 8=ðx 1Þ2 33=2ð2x 1Þ2 þ 1=ð3x 1Þ2 ; 1=54x41=4
fw3 ðxÞ ¼
>
> þ1=x3 9=2x2 þ 8=ðx 1Þ2 1=2ð2x 1Þ2 ; 1=44x41=3
>
>
: elsewhere
0
Rank 4
8 2 2 2 2
< 81=2ðx 1Þ þ 113=2ð2x 1Þ 33=2ð3x 1Þ þ 1=2ð4x 1Þ ;
> 04x41=5
2 2 2
fw4 ðxÞ ¼ þ1=x 81=2ðx 1Þ þ 16=ð2x 1Þ 1=2ð3x 1Þ ;
2 1=54x41=4
>
:
0 elsewhere
Rank 5
(
þ128=3ðx 1Þ2 81=2ð2x 1Þ2 þ 8=ð3x 1Þ2 1=6ð4x 1Þ2 ; 04x41=5
fw5 ðxÞ ¼
0 elsewhere
Copyright # 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Multi-Crit. Decis. Anal. 11: 291–303 (2002)