Draft Final Issues Paper Local Governments Rating Law Workshop Jan 2013
Draft Final Issues Paper Local Governments Rating Law Workshop Jan 2013
Draft Final Issues Paper Local Governments Rating Law Workshop Jan 2013
4.2 The economics of property rating and the linkage with the land information system (LIS) .................. 1
6.1 The rating authority vis a vis the definition of local government ............................................................ 5
6.5 The tax base is too narrow, given the definitions and exemptions in the rating law ........................ 0
6.9 Land information and use of computerized data base system .................................................... 5
1
FINAL DRAFT ISSUES PAPER -LOCAL GOVERNMENTS (RATING) LAW
AND PRACTICE
1.0 Introduction
Property rating in Uganda dates back to 1948 when the first valuation roll was
prepared for Kampala. As might be expected, rating law and practice in Uganda
were modeled on the English system, modified slightly to suit local conditions.
Today, rating is governed by the Local Government (Rating) Act, No. 8 of 2005.
This replaced the Local Governments (Rating) Act, a decree enacted in 1979. The
Local Governments (Rating) Act, 2005 empowers local governments to levy rates on
property within their areas of jurisdiction.
The basic task of this assignment is to carry out a comprehensive review and
analysis of the land-sector laws listed in the TOR for revision and harmonization.
One of the listed laws is the Local Governments (Rating) Act, No. 8 of 2005. The
Consultant is required to identify key issues in rating law and practice that need
addressing if the Client is to achieve its objectives as set out in the TOR.
This Final Draft Issues Paper builds on our earlier paper on this topic. Importantly,
it also takes into account the comments which the Law Reform Working Group
(LRWG) made on the recommendations in our earlier paper. The LRWG’s
comments were made following the retreat it held from 24 - 27 January 2010 to
consider the papers we had presented on various topics under our Terms of
Reference.
This Final Draft Issues Paper must be viewed in the context of a number of
significant Government initiatives. The first is the Second Private Sector
Competitiveness Project (PSCP II). The overall objective of the PSCP II is to create
sustainable conditions for enterprise-creation and growth that respond to local and
export markets. It aims to better position the private sector to respond to market
opportunities, by eliminating restraints on Uganda’s international competitiveness.
2
Important objectives are to encourage investment and reduce the cost of doing
business.
PSCP II has three mutually-reinforcing components. The pertinent one for this
assignment is the Project Component 3 (Improving the Business Environment).
The MTCS also aimed to facilitate the growth of an efficient land market, so as to
stimulate investment and market-led development. From the perspective of the
land sector, a priority was to remedy shortcomings in the land registration system;
these were seen as a significant barrier to investment.
Another initiative is the Land Sector Strategic Plan (LSSP). One of its major aims is
to enhance revenue from the land sector and land-related activities. This will help
to finance land-sector activities and to finance basic infrastructure development and
the delivery of services by local governments.
This brings us to a central point in this Final Draft Issues Paper. Local governments
must have the ability to raise revenue. Without adequate revenue, they cannot
deliver the services that are crucial to a successful decentralization policy. That
policy requires that local governments are effective, efficient centres of good
governance and participatory democracy. They must be able to provide home-
grown solutions to local problems, and be able to set and implement local priorities.
3
empower councils to plan, finance and provide services to their residents;
and
provide a linkage between the payment of taxes and provision of services.
The raising and collecting of local revenue promotes local democracy and public
accountability. It engenders citizen interest in how services are delivered and, in
turn, helps hold local councilors and officials accountable for expenditures. The
Local Government Finance Commission in a Report on Inventory of Best Practices
in Local Revenue Enhancement, 2003 noted that “Local revenue … enhances
ownership and autonomy of local governments”.
The1995 Constitution and the Local Governments Act, Cap 243 empower local
governments to collect local revenue within the areas of their jurisdictions. They
provide the legal framework under which local governments may deliver vital
infrastructure and social welfare services to the people, through a process based on
transparency and accountability. Article 191 of the Constitution allows local
governments to levy, charge, collect and appropriate fees and taxes in accordance
with any laws enacted by Parliament.
The Local Governments Act, Cap 243 specifies the major sources of revenue that
local governments may collect. Property taxes are amongst them. However, it s the
Local Governments (Rating) Act, 2005 that provides the legal basis for local
governments to value, assess and collect rates on properties. That Act empowers
local governments to levy rates on properties within their areas of jurisdiction.
“Local government” is defined in the Act to mean a district council, a city council, a
municipal council, or a town council within the meaning of the Local Governments
Act.
According to the Local Governments (Rating) Act, local governments may levy
such rates as they may determine on the basis of the rateable value of any property
within their areas of jurisdiction. All properties within the jurisdiction of the local
government are rateable, unless exempted by law.
4
4.0 The conceptual framework
4.1 General
The largest proportion of revenue for local governments comes from financial
transfers from central government. Nevertheless, there is considerable scope for
local governments to enhance revenue-generating capacity from their own sources.
For example, the property rates tax is one of the most common local taxes, but its
potential is not fully exploited.
In order to raise more revenue from the property rates tax, both technical expertise
and institutional arrangements in tax administration must be improved. To give
obvious examples: tax administration would be greatly improved by up-to-date
land title records and cadastral base maps; by regular re-valuation of taxable
properties; and by computerized billing systems. It would also be improved by an
incentive system which would reward local governments for their efforts in
tapping the property tax—especially given that it the tax is politically unpopular.
The main aim of any property rating system should be to raise revenue to enable
local authorities to provide services for their citizens. The revenue generated
should normally be used to finance amenity services. Examples are roads, street
lighting, waste disposal, environmental health, and physical infrastructure. The
very nature of these services means that they cannot be financed entirely through
user charges.
In many ways, property tax is the ideal form of local tax. It scores well on the
acknowledged criteria for measuring the potential and performance of taxes. The
following criteria were developed by James McMaster (1994):
Revenue sources should be adequate to meet the costs of the services they are
intended to finance. They should also be elastic, yet stable and predictable.
5
ii. Equity
Specifically for property rates, equity demands that the cost of providing local
services should be equitably shared between all classes of property owners, and
should be fair as between property owners within those classes. An equitable tax
takes cognizance of the benefits received by the property owner as well as his or her
ability to pay.
No tax is popular, but some taxes are more unpopular than others. Political will is
needed to impose taxes, to collect them, and to enforce sanctions against defaulters.
Property taxes are politically sensitive for two reasons:
1. They have to be collected directly from the payers and are, therefore, seen as a
burden even more overtly than income taxes (which may be deducted by
employers).
2. Any increase in tax, whether by rate revision or re-valuation, normally depends
on a deliberate political decision.
v. Economic efficiency
Taxation has a dual purpose: to provide money for public purposes and to
influence economic behavior. Taxes affect the cost of individual decisions—for
example, a property tax affects the profitability of a building. In some jurisdictions,
unimproved site value taxation is used to encourage high-value development and,
conversely, penalize under-development.
4.2 The economics of property rating and linkage with the land information
system (LIS)
The capacity of local governments to supply local services and undertake necessary
infrastructure development is severely constrained by finances. Local governments
face a growing number of responsibilities, many of which arise from the process of
decentralization, under which the obligation to provide services is increasingly
transferred to local government. This is occurring hand in hand with increasingly
inadequate funding from central government.
Local governments may justifiably complain that most of the taxes assigned to
them are less productive and less elastic than those available to the central
government. They see property taxation as a means of raising badly needed
revenues. It is an attractive option for giving local governments access to a broad
and expanding tax base, from which to finance local government operations.
Unfortunately, however, the existing property rating system performs well below
its potential.
1
information system. Most urban areas are unplanned and unsurveyed. It is
extremely difficult to identify individual properties from among numerous units
erected on a single large plot, even in planned and surveyed areas. Maps are out of
date or are unavailable. The title register is grievously out of date. An efficient LIS
would enable local governments and professional valuers to create a “fiscal
cadastre” containing information about property ownership, valuation, and
property tax information. This would facilitate the equitable and efficient
administration of property taxation/rating.
2
5.0 Regional and international experience
5.1 General
Property taxes are compulsory charges or levies that relate specifically to
ownership, occupation or development of land and buildings (McCluskey, 1993).
They are mostly levied on capital value or annual rental value (real or imputed),
and are collected for use by local authorities. Their consequences are both fiscal
(revenue generation) and regulatory (encouraging property development and/or
discouraging land speculation).
One of the most common forms of property taxation is property rating. This in
effect requires residents of a particular area to contribute money year-by-year to
share the cost of providing services to themselves and others within their area.
Property taxes are generally considered to be an ideal source of revenue for local
government. As a percentage of GDP, property taxes average 1.4% in industrial
countries, but just 0.4% in developing countries, and 0.1% in Uganda.
Different African countries use a variety of tax bases for their property tax systems.
This is demonstrated by an analysis of 10 African countries (see the table below).
The legislation in all 10 countries mandates an ad valorem property tax system,
with discrete values for each rateable property. Uganda is the only country in this
group which taxes annual rental value. All the others tax the capital value or sale
value. Most of the countries tax both the land and the buildings on the land.
However, Tanzania taxes just the capital value of the building(s), and Kenya taxes
just the value of the land.
The table below shows the property tax bases in the 10 countries.
3
Country Basis of Assessment
Kenya Unimproved site value
Ghana1 Depreciated replacement cost
Uganda Annual rental value
Tanzania2 Market value and replacement cost
Malawi Open market value (capital value)
Zambia Open market value
Zimbabwe Open market value for non-residential; unit basis for
residential
Namibia3 Open market value for land; depreciated replacement
cost for improvements
South Africa4 Unimproved site value; improved value of land (flat
rating); unimproved value of land + value of any
improvements (composite rating)
Rwanda Area rate (not based on value)
The choice of system largely reflects historical factors. The United Kingdom and
France have traditionally valued property on the basis of rental value; in general,
their one-time colonies in Africa and Asia also do so. Countries influenced by the
United States (e.g. the Philippines, Liberia, and most of Latin America) follow US
practice and levy rates on the basis of capital value. Capital value is also used in
most of Northern Europe (e.g. Germany, the Netherlands) and in Japan, Turkey,
and Indonesia (Dillinger, 1991). Counties in Southern Africa that follow Roman-
Dutch law (i.e. South Africa, Namibia, Botswana, Lesotho and Swaziland) use
multiple rating systems.
1 The basis was changed from “annual rental value” to the “replacement cost”.
2Replacement cost is used where market value cannot be ascertained. The maximum depreciation allowable is
25%.
3Municipalities can generally decide on any of 4 bases: general rate (on the value of the whole of such rateable
property); site value rate (on the value of the land only); improvement rate (on the value of the land and the
value of improvements, but separately).
4 Three options are generally available; reform on tax bases started in 1997 and is continuing.
4
Of course, no individual system is perfect. Some countries, including Uganda and
Ghana, have moved from one system to another. Sometimes more than one rating
system (indeed, up to 4 systems) operates at the same time in the one country.
Before 1979 Uganda operated 2 rating systems—i.e. annual rental value as well as
capital value. Namibia operates 4 tax bases.
6.1 The rating authority vis a vis the definition of local government
The existing Ugandan rating law empowers local governments to levy rates on
property within their areas of jurisdiction. “Local government” is defined in the
law as a district council, a city council, a municipal council or a town council within
the meaning of the Local Governments Act, Cap 243.5 In the case of a district, the
rating authority is the district council; in the case of a city, it is the city council; and
in the case of a municipality, it is the municipal council. The role of the division
councils and sub-county councils is not clear, and yet they are local governments
under the Local Governments Act, Cap. 243.
In relation to the two recommendations that follow, the LRWG noted that they saw
no need to revisit the Local Governments Act, because all sub-counties are catered
for under bigger councils, and the smaller ones cannot pay for rating. However, on
further reflection, we consider that in any thorough-going review these two matters
require attention. Therefore, respectfully, our recommendations remain unchanged.
5Under the Local Government Act, Cap 243, local governments include a district council, a sub-county council, a
city council, a city division council, a municipal council, and a municipal division council.
5
Recommendations
1. The definition of “local government” under the rating law
should be revisited with a view to harmonizing it with the
definition of “local government” under the Local
Government Act, Cap.243.
2. The roles of division councils and sub-county councils, which
are local governments under the Local Governments Act and
which have roles to play in the rating system, should be
properly defined in the rating law. Unless this is done,
clashes in institutional mandates are certain to arise.
The rating law does not empower town councils to appoint valuation courts. In the
interpretation section of the law, “valuation court” means the valuation court
appointed by a district, city or municipal council under the Act. There is also
ambiguity over whether the District Council may appoint one valuation court to
serve all town councils within the district.
Recommendation
3. Town Councils should be empowered to appoint their own Valuation
Courts.
6
Recommendation
4. Town Boards should be recognized as urban areas under the
rating law.
Where do car parking yards (used purely as a business) fall? Examples are
parking yards in Busia Town and Malaba Town, which are used by the Customs
Department of Uganda Revenue Authority.
7
What about properties such as tea estates, sugar cane estates, cut flower
plantations?
In other jurisdictions, the legislation levies rates on property/real property, and not
mere buildings. Properties are usually classified as:
agricultural properties
residential properties
commercial properties, and
industrial properties.
LRWG’s comments: The LRWG disagreed with our view about the insufficiency of
the existing definitions of terms such as “commercial building” “industrial
building” and “non-industrial building”. It considered that the definitions were
adequate, taking into account planning permissions. However, with respect, we
consider that in an overall review of rating law and practice, such matters need
attention. The LRWG made no comment on our recommendation (below) that
Uganda should adopt the practice of rating properties as distinct from buildings.
Recommendation
5. Uganda should adopt the practice of rating properties, as
opposed to rating buildings. The rating law should classify and
define the different categories of properties.
8
6.5 The tax base is too narrow, given the definitions and
exemptions in the rating law
“Property” is defined under the rating law as immovable property and includes
a building (industrial or non-industrial) or structure of any kind, but does not
include a vacant site. Thus, vacant sites are exempt.6
Section 3(5) provides that “for avoidance of doubt, no rate shall be levied in
respect of a residential building in a place not being in an urban area”. This
implies that all residential buildings outside the city council, municipal council
or town council are exempt, even when they are rented. This makes neither
political nor economic sense. The implications are that in Seeta (which is not an
urban area as defined in the law) owners of rented residential properties do not
pay property rates, while those who own commercial properties do pay. This
seems to breach the equity principle, mentioned earlier in this Paper.
Section 3(4) limits the rateable properties outside an urban area to commercial
buildings only. This is because it provides that: “notwithstanding subsection
(3), the rate may be levied in any area outside the urban area in respect of a
commercial building”. While this section extends property taxation powers to
district local governments, at the same time it limits them to taxing commercial
buildings only. What about industrial properties in the districts?
6In many jurisdictions, vacant sites in urban areas are taxed, not only to raise revenue but also to prevent land
speculation. There is a good argument that vacant and underutilized land in urban areas should be taxed, so as
to deter keeping land for speculative profits.
7Property value is an indicator of a taxpayer’s net wealth or income. And most importantly, the intangible
housing benefits which owner-occupants enjoy have to be weighed against the visible flow of rents from
rented properties.
own houses consume the same services as those who rent them out. This type of
exemption is likely to encourage evasion by discriminated property owners.
LRWG’s comments:
The LRWG commented that in urban areas the purpose of rating is to provide
services, and so “every developed premises should pay”. We agree, and our
recommendation will allow this.
In relation to vacant land, key words appear to have been omitted from the
LRWG’s comments, so we are not sure of their views.
Revised recommendation
1
6.6 Overall tax burden
Property rates
Income tax on rental income
VAT on rental income from commercial properties
Stamp duty/transfer tax
Capital gains tax
Estate duty.
All the above taxes, except property rates, are national taxes. By the time local
governments impose property rates, the property owner is already burdened by the
other types of tax collected by the Central Government. Income tax on rental
income works out at about 16% of gross annual rental.
Importantly, property rates are not allowable as an expense against income for tax
purposes. Further, none of the above national taxes are allowable as expenses
against rental income for the purposes of property rates tax. The statutory
deduction on gross rental value, which currently stands at 22%, is not sufficient to
take care of the national property taxes and other outgoings and expenses (such as
mortgage interest, insurance fees, and maintenance and repair costs) which a
property owner must pay.
There is urgent need to review both the national taxation system and the local
government taxation system, with a view to harmonizing them. There is also need
to assess the overall incidence of tax—ie, the combined effect of all taxes. Taxation
should not pose a disincentive to investment. Further, if citizens perceive a tax to
be unfair or excessive, then collection and enforcement becomes difficult and non-
compliance flourishes. The only successful property tax is a collectable one.
LRWG’s comments:
2
The LRWG commented that our recommendations about reviewing the overall
burden of taxation was “not applicable to rating”. However, and with respect, we
disagree. In our view, an equitable tax system requires all aspects of taxation to be
taken into account, including the burden of property taxes. In this regard,
therefore, our Recommendation 7 remains unchanged.
The LRWG made no comment on the subject matter of our Recommendation 8, and
so it also remains unchanged.
Recommendations
7. A comprehensive review of the national property taxation
system should be undertaken with a view to harmonizing
the taxation system at the national level with the system at
the local government level, to eliminate over-taxation
and/or double taxation.
8. The statutory deduction on the gross annual rental value
should be set at a level sufficient to cover the relevant
national property taxes and other expenses to a property
owner.
The rating law permits valuation on the basis of a single property as well as on the
basis of mass valuation. Mass valuation relies, not on direct market information
about any particular property, but on extrapolation by formula from a sample of
properties. It is
used to value common types of properties. It is particularly associated with
computerized multiple regression analysis, which is a method of ascertaining the
relative importance of value-significant characteristics. Mass valuation is most
common in capital value countries—that is, countries which value on the basis of
capital value. Uganda is not one of these countries.
3
condominiums. CAMA is based on mathematical modeling, involving the
determination of a dependant variable (capital value or rental value) from a
number of independent variables (property characteristics). It is easier to develop a
functional model from homogeneous (smoothly varying, non-skipy) data, rather
than from sparse or clustered non-homogeneous data (such as widely varying
property prices, rentals and characteristics affecting value), or from outdated,
incorrect or inconsistent data.
Section 11 of the Local Governments (Rating) Act provides that “there shall be
estimated the rent at which the property might reasonably be expected to let from
year to year…”. This appears to require a valuation on the basis of individual
properties.
LRWG’s comments:
The LRWG commented that mass valuation techniques are suitable for housing of
the same character, where valuation samples can be applied across the whole
category. We agree, and our Recommendation 10 so provides. Accordingly, our
recommendations on these matters remain unchanged.
Recommendations
9. Where small, low value properties constitute a large
proportion of the tax base, simple valuation approaches like
a “points system” should be adopted in place of rental value.
Such a system would assign prices or “points” to specific
property characteristics. This would bring many properties
into the tax system at the lowest possible cost.
10. Mass appraisal techniques should be applied mainly to
housing estates and condominium properties. CAMA should
be applied mainly to homogeneous properties such as high-
rise offices and condominiums.
4
11. Single property valuations should be for unique, high value
properties, where mass appraisal techniques cannot be
applied.
In short, the property rating system requires urgent reforms. The reforms must be
comprehensive, linking property information, valuation, assessment collection and
enforcement.
Currently, the rating system is based on paper files. This dependence on paper
records should be eliminated, or at least minimized. There is a strong case for
computerizing valuation records. There is an even stronger case for a sound legal
and institutional framework for updating (and keeping accurate) information
needed for valuing and assessing properties. The potential tax base is wide, and
requires extensive, ever-changing information on each property. Computers can
8 For more in-depth discusion, refer to:
i. Nsamba-Gayiiya, Eddie (1999) “The Current Rating System in Uganda—A Case Study of Kampala City
Council”.
ii. Nsamba-Gayiiya, Eddie (2001) “Property Assessment and Taxation in Uganda”.
iii. Nsamba-Gayiiya, Eddie (2003): “Property Taxation: Principles and Practices in Africa”.
iv. Kelly, Roy (2000) “Property Taxation in East Africa, the Tale of Three Reforms”.
5
facilitate all aspects of managing individual property information, property
valuation, tax assessment, billing, collection and enforcement.
LRWG’s comments:
Recommendations
12. Legal provision should be made to authorize and facilitate
collecting, retrieving, sharing and updating all information
needed for an efficient and effective rating system.
13. All valuation records should be computerized.
6
6.10 The accountability of local governments to rate payers
Local governments should be accountable to their rate payers for rendering the
services for which they have taxed property owners. The current rating law does
not clearly stipulate the duties that local governments owe to rate payers in this
respect. The provision under section 37(4) permitting property owners and
occupants in any locality to form themselves into a rate payers association to
oversee the provision and delivery of the services, does not go far enough.
LRWG’s comments:
Recommendation
Some local governments have been setting different rates for commercial properties
and industrial properties, on the one hand, and residential properties on the other
(examples are Entebbe Municipal Council and Kampala City Council).
Progressive tax rates—that is, rates that are higher for higher-value property—are
common in developing countries.
7
LRWG’s comments:
The LRWG made no specific comment on this matter, but did comment on
differential rates in relation to residential properties. This we have discussed
earlier. Thus, our Recommendation 15 remains unchanged.
Recommendation
15. Differentiated rates and progressive tax rates should be
introduced into the rating law to achieve equity and other
objectives.
Section 34 of the rating law prohibits the transfer of property where rates are in
arrears. This goes some way to ensuring that arrears of taxes are paid. However,
we would recommend a stronger provision. The Registrar of Titles should be
legally forbidden to register such a transfer unless the purchaser can demonstrate
that all arrears of rates on the property have been paid. This will increase the
collection of revenue, as purchasers will require vendors to prove that outstanding
taxes have been paid; and if taxes are unpaid, purchasers will insist that the
outstanding amounts be deducted from the balance of purchase price payable on
completion of the sale.
Under section 20, a valuation list comes into force from the commencement of the
financial year next after the one in which the chairperson of the valuation court
certifies it. This provision has severe financial implications for local governments.
The Local Governments (Rating) (Amendment) Act, 2006 requires the Chairperson
of the valuation court to certify and sign the draft valuation list with the approval
of the Minister. In our view, Ministerial approval should not be necessary.
8
3. The management of objections to the draft valuation list
Property owners may have queries about rates, or may wish to appeal. In many
cases the query or appeal can probably be settled by agreement without the
necessity of a Valuation Court hearing. The law should be flexible and encourage
disputes to be settled. Where the registered valuer and the objector reach
agreement on the correct figure, then this could be approved by the Valuation
Court.
The LRWG concluded its comments on this Paper by making four points. We deal
with them one by one.
1. There are countries you pay the tax even when you are not occupying the
property. The consultant should make a comparison to such countries.
9
2. Investigation should be done on the ground to establish how much tax should
be charged.
We agree. This, as with point 1, above, must be part of the overall assessment of
tax burden on landowners. How much tax should be charged is then ultimately a
question of policy for the Government to formulate.
3. The consultants should look at taxes paid and justify why they should be
paid.
This is covered by our earlier discussion. In the context of property rates taxation,
the purpose of the system is to provide income for local government bodies to
provide adequate services to citizens. The more generous the services, the higher
the necessary incidence of taxation. The balance becomes a question of
Government policy.
4. The consultants should take into account the presidential directive that was
incorporated into law in 2006. The directive exempts residential areas.
[End].