Externalities
Externalities
Thomas Helbling
There are differences between private returns or costs and the costs or returns to society
as a whole
Most externalities fall into the category of so-called technical externalities; that is, the
indirect effects have an impact on the consumption and production opportunities of oth-
ers, but the price of the product does not take those externalities into account. As a
result, there are differences between private returns or costs and the returns or costs to
society as a whole.
Negative and positive externalities
There are also positive externalities, and here the issue is the difference between private
and social gains. For example, research and development (R&D) activities are widely con-
sidered to have positive effects beyond those enjoyed by the producer that funded the
R&D—normally, the company that pays for the research. This is because R&D adds to the
general body of knowledge, which contributes to other discoveries and developments.
However, the private returns of a firm selling products based on its own R&D typically do
not include the returns of others who benefited indirectly. With positive externalities,
private returns are smaller than social returns.
When there are differences between private and social costs or private and social
returns, the main problem is that market outcomes may not be efficient. To promote the
well-being of all members of society, social returns should be maximized and social costs
minimized. This implies that all costs and benefits need to be internalized by households
and firms making buying and production decisions. Otherwise, market outcomes involve
underproduction of goods or services that entail positive externalities or overproduction
in the case of negative externalities. Overproduction or underproduction reflects less-
than-optimal market outcomes in terms of a society’s overall condition (what economists
call the “welfare perspective”).
Consider again the example of pollution. Social costs grow with the level of pollution,
which increases in tandem with production levels, so goods with negative externalities
are overproduced when only private costs are considered in decisions and not costs
incurred by others. To minimize social costs would lead to lower production levels. Simi-
larly, from a societal perspective, maximization of private instead of social returns leads
to underproduction of the good or service with positive externalities.
Neoclassical economists long ago recognized that the inefficiencies associated with tech-
nical externalities constitute a form of “market failure.” Private market–based decision
making fails to yield efficient outcomes from a general welfare perspective. These econo-
mists recommended government intervention to correct for the effects of externalities.
In The Economics of Welfare, British economist Arthur Pigou suggested that governments
tax polluters an amount equivalent to the cost of the harm to others. Such a tax would
yield the market outcome that would have prevailed with adequate internalization of all
costs by polluters. By the same logic, governments should subsidize those who generate
positive externalities, in the amount that others benefit.
The proposition that technical externalities require government regulation and taxation
to prevent less-than-optimal market outcomes was intensely debated after Pigou’s semi-
nal work. Some economists argued that market mechanisms can correct for the external-
ities and provide for efficient outcomes. People can resolve the problems through mutu-
ally beneficial transactions. For example, a landlord and a polluter could enter into a
contract in which the landlord agrees to pay the polluter a certain amount of money in
exchange for a specific reduction in the amount of pollution. Such contractual bargaining
can be mutually beneficial. Once the building is less exposed to pollution, the landlord
can raise rents. As long as the increase in rents is greater than the payment to the pol-
luter, the outcome is beneficial for the landlord. Similarly, as long as the payment
exceeds the loss in profit from lower pollution (lower production), the polluter is better
off as well.
Public goods
The public good problem is especially notable in environmental economics, which largely
deals with analyzing and finding solutions to externality-related issues. Clean air, clean
water, biodiversity, and a sustainable stock of fish in the open sea are largely nonrival
and nonexcludable goods. They are free goods, produced by nature and available to eve-
rybody. They are subject to no well-defined property rights. As a result, households and
firms do not place enough value on these public goods, and efficient market outcomes
through bargaining typically are not feasible. In other words, environmental issues often
face a collective action problem.
High transaction costs and problems related to uncertainty are other obstacles that pre-
vent parties involved in technical externalities from internalizing costs and benefits
through bargaining solutions. Uncertainty problems are far reaching. In fact, the well-
known moral hazard is a form of externality in which decision makers maximize their
benefits while inflicting damage on others but do not bear the consequences because, for
example, there is uncertainty or incomplete information about who is responsible for
damages or contract restrictions. For example, an insured entity can affect its insurance
company’s liabilities, but the insurance company is not in a position to determine
whether the insured is responsible for an event that triggers a payout. Similarly, if a pol-
luter’s promised preventive actions cannot be verified because of a lack of information,
bargaining is unlikely to be a feasible solution.
Today, the most pressing and complex externality problem is greenhouse gas (GHG)
emissions. The atmospheric accumulation of greenhouse gases from human activity has
been identified as a major cause of global warming. Barring policies to curb GHG emis-
sions, scientists expect this problem to grow and eventually lead to climate change and
its accompanying costs, including damage to economic activity from the destruction of
capital (for example, along coastal areas) and lower agricultural productivity. Externali-
ties come into play, because the costs and risks from climate change are borne by the
world at large, whereas there are few mechanisms to compel those who benefit from
GHG-emitting activity to internalize these costs and risks.
The atmosphere, in fact, is a global public good, with benefits that accrue to all, making
private bargaining solutions unfeasible. Identifying and agreeing on policies for internal-
ization of the social costs of GHG emissions at the global level are extremely difficult,
given the cost to some individuals and firms and the difficulties of global enforcement of
such policies (Tirole, 2008).
References
Coase, Ronald, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3,
No. 1, pp. 1–44.
Cornes, Richard, and Todd Sandler, 1986, The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and
Club Goods (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).
Tirole, Jean, 2008, “Some Economics of Global Warming,” Rivista di Politica Economica,
Vol. 98, No. 6, pp. 9–42.