03 - Exercise Class
03 - Exercise Class
Recitation class
Luiss University
The firms are in strategic interaction, as for example, firm 1 ’s profit depend
not only on 𝑞! but also on 𝑞" .
b) Consider that 𝑝 𝑞 = 1 − 𝑞 and write the profit functions
𝜋! = 1 − 𝑞! − 𝑞" − 𝑐! 𝑞!
𝜋" = 1 − 𝑞! − 𝑞" − 𝑐" 𝑞"
c) Compute reaction functions for each firm and the Nash equilibrium
𝜕𝜋!
= 1 − 2𝑞! − 𝑞" − 𝑐! = 0
𝜕𝑞!
𝜕𝜋"
= 1 − 𝑞! − 2𝑞" − 𝑐" = 0
𝜕𝑞"
and then, we find the reaction function of firm 𝑖 as:
1
𝑞! = 1 − 𝑞" − 𝑐!
2
1
𝑞" = 1 − 𝑞! − 𝑐"
2
By substitution we get:
1 1
𝑞! = 1 − 1 − 𝑞! − 𝑐" − 𝑐!
2 2
1 1 1 1
𝑞! = 1 − + 𝑞! + 𝑐" − 𝑐!
2 2 2 2
1 1 1 1
𝑞! = + 𝑞! + 𝑐" − 𝑐!
4 4 4 2
4 1 1 1
𝑞! = + 𝑐" − 𝑐!
3 4 4 2
∗
1 2
𝑞! = 1 + 𝑐" − 𝑐!
3 3
and by symmetry:
1 2
𝑞"∗ = 1 + 𝑐! − 𝑐"
3 3
d) Check that 𝑞!∗ > 𝑞"∗ and interpret.
We compute the difference between 𝑞!∗ and 𝑞"∗
1 1 2 1 1 1
𝑞!∗ − 𝑞"∗ = + 𝑐" − 𝑐! − − 𝑐! + 𝑐" = 𝑐" − 𝑐!
3 3 3 3 3 3
If 𝑐" > 𝑐! then 𝑞!∗ > 𝑞"∗ , since 𝑐" > 𝑐! means that firm 1 is more efficient than
firm 2.
The Cournot market use more efficient firms.
e) Check the conditions under which 𝑞"∗ = 0
∗ " ! !
𝑞" = 0 means that 𝑐" = + 𝑐! , i.e.
$ $ $
1
𝑐" = 1 + 𝑐!
2
So, when the difference in costs is quite large and firm 2 is so much less
efficient than firm 1, then firm 2 does not enter the market.
!
f) Describe the market under the condition 𝑐" ≥ 1 + 𝑐! . Find and interpret
"
the behavior of firm 1.
∗ !
In this case, 𝑞! = 1 − 𝑐!
"
In order to show that this corresponds to a monopoly behavior we compute
the corresponding price-cost margin. Notice that the price is
∗
1 1 1
𝑝 = 1 − 𝑞 = 1 − − 𝑐! = 1 + 𝑐!
2 2 2
the monopolist’s optimal markup of price over marginal cost, expressed as a
percentage of the price is
1 1
𝑝 − 𝑐! 2 1 + 𝑐! − 𝑐! 2 1 − 𝑐!
∗
1 − 𝑐!
= = =
𝑝 ∗ 1 1 1 + 𝑐!
2 1 + 𝑐! 2 1 + 𝑐!
This is exactly the opposite of the inverse of the elasticity of demand of the
market computed when the quantity is 𝑞! . Indeed,
𝑞 =1−𝑝
and price elasticity of demand is
𝛿𝑞 𝑝 1 + 𝑐!
𝜀%/' = − =
𝛿𝑝 𝑞 1 − 𝑐!
Bertrand competition
Two firms produce a homogeneous good.
Cost function for both firms is 𝐶 𝑞! = 𝑐𝑞! , where 𝑞! is the quantity
sold by firm 𝑖.
Firms compete by simultaneously and independently setting the
price, ready to sell any demanded quantity.
No capacity constraints.
Demand function:
𝑄 =𝛼−𝑝 with 𝑝 = 𝑚𝑖𝑛 𝑝" , 𝑝# and 𝛼 > 𝑐
In case they set the same price then consumers’ demand is split
evenly between them.
Game in Normal Form
Set of players: firm 1 and firm 2
Each firm can choose among non-negative prices, 𝑝! ≥ 0
Set of strategies: 𝑆! = [0, ∞) for 𝑖 = 1,2
Payoff to firm 1:
"
c) 𝑖𝑓 𝑝" = 𝑝# → 𝜋" = 𝑝" − 𝑐
#
𝛼 − 𝑝"
1) Neither firm can be pricing below 𝑀𝐶 = 𝑐 in equilibrium
because in this case at least one of the firms earns a negative
profit, and each firm can guarantee itself a profit of 0 by pricing
at 𝑐.
#"
!"! #"
!"" #!
10
5
5 10 #!
Duopoly with capacity constraints (Bertrand variation)
Two firms produce a homogeneous good and compete by selecting
prices simultaneously and independently
The firms produce at zero cost
There are 10 consumers
Each consumer would like to buy 1 unit of the good and is willing to
pay at most 𝒑 = 𝟏 for the good.
In a setting with unconstrained capacities, all of the consumers
purchase from the firm that sets the lower price, unless this price
exceeds 1 in which case no one buys. If the firms charge the same
price, then the consumers split equally between the firms. The
unique Nash equilibrium of this game without capacity constraints
has 𝒑∗𝟏 = 𝒑∗𝟐 = 𝟎 and profit is zero for both firms.
Case of capacity constraint:
each firm can produce and sell at most 𝟖 units. The firm with the
cheapest price cannot capture the entire market, while the firm with
the highest price can still capture two consumers.
With capacity constraints, the game no longer has an equilibrium in
pure strategies. No NE if 𝑝" = 𝑝# :
• If 𝑝" = 𝑝# > 0, either firm would like to undercut the other firm’s
price by an infinitesimal amount. This will always yield a higher
payoff than choosing the same price as the opponent.
• 𝑝" = 𝑝# = 0 is no longer a NE because if my opponent sets a price
of zero, my best response now is to set a price of $1. This will
ensure me a profit of $2 instead of $0, which is what I would
obtain if I had set my price to zero.
Case of capacity constraint:
What if 𝑝" ≠ 𝑝# ?
• If 𝑝" < 𝑝# ≤ 1, then it must be 𝑝# = 1, since firm 2 would have
two costumers anyway. But if 𝑝# = 1, firm 1 would like to keep
raising 𝑝" by infinitesimal amounts to become closer and closer
to $1. So, the best response by would not be well-defined.
2) but decreases the probability that it will be the lower priced firm
and capture the higher quantity.