Lecture Notes 4
Lecture Notes 4
Chapter 4
Consumption, Saving, and Investment
Learning Objectives
I. Goals of Chapter 4
A. Describe the factors that affect consumption and saving decisions (Sec. 4.1)
B. Discuss the factors that affect the investment of firms (Sec. 4.2)
C. Explain the factors affecting goods market equilibrium (Sec. 4.3)
Teaching Notes
I. Consumption and Saving (Sec. 4.1)
A. The importance of consumption and saving
1. Desired consumption: consumption amount desired by households
2. Desired national saving: level of national saving when consumption is at its desired level
S d Y Cd G (4.1)
Data Application
Recall from Chapter 2 that measured consumption in the national income accounts includes
spending on durable consumption goods, like autos and major appliances. But consumption
theory requires that consumption be defined to include only the services from durable consumer
goods. So empirical researchers must adjust the national income data to arrive at a measure of
consumption that matches the theory. For example, they might assume that durable goods
provide services proportional to the stock of durables.
Theoretical Application
The classic discussions of consumption are the permanent-income hypothesis of Milton
Friedman (A Theory of the Consumption Function, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957)
and the life-cycle hypothesis of Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg (“Utility Analysis and
the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data,” in Ken Kurihara, ed.,
Post-Keynesian Economics, New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University Press, 1954). The
permanent income hypothesis focuses on what consumers do with stochastic income receipts;
the life-cycle hypothesis is concerned with predictable changes in income over the life cycle.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 65
Theoretical Application
You can use the concept of income and substitution effects to show your class how saving responds
to an effective change in the expected real interest rate that occurs because of IRAs (individual
retirement accounts). Since IRAs allow people to avoid taxes on a portion of their income, they
produce two kinks in the budget constraint. Whether IRAs will boost saving or consumption depends
on a person’s preferences, namely how strong the income and substitution effects are. There’s a
substitution effect because the slope of the budget line gets steeper (the return to saving rises), so
people will want more future consumption and less current consumption. There’s an income effect
because the budget line is shifted out, which increases both future and current consumption. So the
overall effect on current consumption, and hence saving, is ambiguous, depending on how strong are
the income and substitution effects. The exception is that if a person would have saved more than the
IRA limit both with and without IRAs, then there’s only an income effect and saving will decline. Or
if, in the presence of IRAs, a person would save exactly the amount of the IRA limit, then whether
saving rises or falls depends on whether, in the absence of IRAs, they would have saved more or less.
Empirical evidence suggests that every $100 of IRA saving reduces current consumption by $32, so
at least for some people, the substitution effect is strong enough to increase saving.
1 0
66 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Data Application
Eytan Sheshinski, in “Treatment of Capital Income in Recent Tax Reforms and the Cost of
Capital in Industrialized Countries,” in Larry Summers, ed., Tax Policy and the economy 4,
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990, pp. 25–42, finds that real after-tax interest rates were
negative for the United States and many other countries in the 1970s. Even with fairly low
inflation, because nominal returns, rather than real returns, are taxed, the real after-tax interest
rate (for taxpayers in the top bracket) is fairly low relative to the pretax real interest rate. For
example, in the United States in 1985, the real pretax interest rate was 6.3%; the real after-tax
interest rate was 0.9% ( 3.6%, t 55%). In 1987 the real pretax rate was 4.9%; the real after-
tax interest rate was 2.1% ( 3.7%, t 33%).
Numerical Problem 1 explores how changes in income, future income, wealth, and interest rates
affect consumption.
G. Fiscal policy
1. Affects desired consumption through changes in current and expected future income
2. Directly affects desired national saving, Sd Y Cd G
3. Government purchases (temporary increase)
a. Higher G financed by higher current taxes reduces after-tax income, lowering desired
consumption
b. Even true if financed by higher future taxes, if people realize how future incomes are affected
c. Since Cd declines less than G rises, national saving (Sd Y Cd G) declines
d. So government purchases reduce both desired consumption and desired national saving
Data Application
This theory is confirmed by empirical data. Shaghil Ahmed, in “Temporary and Permanent
Government Spending in an Open Economy: Some Evidence for the United Kingdom,” Journal
of Monetary Economics, March 1986, pp. 197–224, finds, using a long time series of British
data, that temporary government purchases indeed crowd out consumption spending, even
though the expenditures are useful in increasing the marginal productivity of private capital and
providing a substitute for consumption goods.
4. Taxes
a. Lump-sum tax cut today, financed by higher future taxes
b. Decline in future income may offset increase in current income; desired consumption
could rise or fall
c. Ricardian equivalence proposition
(1) If future income loss exactly offsets current income gain, no change in consumption
(2) Tax change affects only the timing of taxes, not their ultimate amount
(present value)
(3) In practice, people may not see that future taxes will rise if taxes are cut today; then a
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 67
tax cut leads to increased desired consumption and reduced desired national saving
Theoretical Application
There are a number of reasons why Ricardian equivalence may not hold. The text notes that if
people don’t see that future taxes are equal (in present value) to a current tax cut, then Ricardian
equivalence may not hold. An additional reason for the failure of Ricardian equivalence,
liquidity constraints, is covered in Appendix 4.A. It may also be possible for people to avoid
future taxes, even if they foresee them, by moving or dying; however, in the latter case, if those
people planned to leave bequests to future generations, they would increase their bequests by the
increased tax liability (Robert Barro, “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?” Journal of Political
Economy, Nov./Dec. 1974, pp. 1095–1117). Other reasons for the failure of Ricardian
equivalence include: (1) If the current tax cut is given to a different people than those who will
have to pay the future taxes, and those people have differing marginal propensities to consume;
(2) if taxes are distortionary, rather than lump sum; and (3) if future tax rates or future income
aren’t known with certainty. For a useful overview and further details, see Andrew B. Abel,
“Ricardian Equivalence Theorem,” in John Eatwell et al., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary
of Economics, London: Macmillan Press, 1987. Empirically, the evidence on Ricardian
equivalence is mixed; for a review, see B. Douglas Bernheim, “Ricardian Equivalence: An
Evaluation of Theory and Evidence,” in Stanley Fischer, ed., NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1987, pp. 263–304.
1 0
68 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Figure 4.1
Theoretical Application
The first general use of the user cost of capital concept was by Dale Jorgenson, “Capital Theory
and Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, May 1963,
pp. 247–259.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 69
Numerical Problems 2 and 4 give students practice in working with the marginal product of
capital and the user cost of capital.
Data Application
Another simplification that is used in this chapter is the assumption that taxes are based on a
firm’s real revenue. In reality, taxes on nominal revenue combine with inflation to create a large
distortion to investment. The first broad discussion of this issue is by Martin Feldstein,
“Inflation, Tax Rules, and Investment: Some Econometric Evidence,” Econometrica, July 1982,
pp. 825–862.
Theoretical Application
For further discussions of the effects of tax policy on investment, see Robert E. Hall and Dale W.
Jorgenson, “Tax Policy and Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review, June 1967,
pp. 391–414.
1 0
70 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Theoretical Application
Acknowledging that it may take time to get capital in place may be crucial to modeling the
business cycle. See Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, “Time to Build and Aggregate
Fluctuations,” Econometrica, November 1982, pp. 1345–1370.
b. So investment needed to reach the desired capital stock may be spread out over several
years
E. In touch with data and research: investment and the stock market
1. Firms change investment in the same direction as the stock market: Tobin’s q theory of
investment
2. If market value replacement cost, then firm should invest more
3. Tobin’s q capital’s market value divided by its replacement cost
a. If q 1, don’t invest
b. If q 1, invest more
4. Stock price times number of shares equals firm’s market value, which equals value
of firm’s capital
a. Formula: q V/(pKK), where V is stock market value of firm, K is firm’s capital, pK is
price of new capital
b. So pKK is the replacement cost of firm’s capital stock
c. Stock market boom raises V, causing q to rise, increasing investment
5. Data show general tendency of investment to rise when stock market rises; but relationship
isn’t strong because many other things change at same time (text Fig. 4.7)
6. This theory is similar to text discussion
a. Higher MPKf increases future earnings of firm, so V rises
b. A falling real interest rate also raises V as people buy stocks instead of bonds
c. A decrease in the cost of capital, pK, raises q
F. Investment in inventories and housing
1. Marginal product of capital and user cost also apply, as with equipment and structures
Numerical Problem 3 applies the user-cost concept to the purchase or rental of a home.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 71
A. The real interest rate adjusts to bring the goods market into equilibrium
1. Y Cd Id G (4.7)
goods market equilibrium condition
2. Differs from income-expenditure identity, as goods market equilibrium condition need not
hold; undesired goods may be produced, so goods market won’t be in equilibrium
3. Alternative representation: since
Sd Y Cd G,
S d Id (4.8)
B. The saving-investment diagram
1. Plot Sd vs. Id (Figure 4.2; Key Diagram 3; like text Figure 4.8)
Figure 4.2
2. Equilibrium where Sd Id
3. How to reach equilibrium? Adjustment of r
4. Shifts of the saving curve
a. Saving curve shifts right due to a rise in current output, a fall in expected future output,
a fall in wealth, a fall in government purchases, a rise in taxes (unless Ricardian
equivalence holds, in which case tax changes have no effect)
b. Example: Temporary increase in government purchases shifts S left
c. Result of lower savings: higher r, causing crowding out of I
Numerical Problem 5 and 6 and Analytical Problem 5 examine what happens when government
spending changes.
Theoretical Application
What happens to the economy if government taxes change? Under Ricardian equivalence, a tax cut
today that is financed by higher future taxes has no effect on national saving, because private
saving rises by the amount of the tax cut, just offsetting the decline in government saving. Since
there’s no shift in national saving, there’s no change in the equilibrium real interest rate. Suppose,
however, that people don’t foresee the future tax change, or for some other reason national saving
1 0
72 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
declines. Then the shift to the left of the desired saving curve leads to a new equilibrium at a higher
real interest rate and lower level of investment. The true burden of the government debt comes
about because the lower investment rate means a lower capital stock, so that the economy is less
productive in the future. Thus future generations bear the burden of today’s government debt.
Policy Application
Should tax policy be used to promote savings or investment? Many policymakers and
economists have argued that obtaining the correct amount of future economic growth requires us
to have a higher capital stock, so that we need more investment than we have. They suggest tax
policies like IRAs to encourage saving and tax breaks for businesses to encourage investment.
As we’ve seen in this chapter, such policies could indeed affect people’s decisions to save (by
affecting the after-tax real rate of interest) and to invest (by reducing the after-tax cost of
capital). But what isn’t so clear is whether or not investment really is too low. After all, to save
today requires reducing consumption today; people may prefer not to save any more than they
are already saving. Also, if the government goes too far in encouraging investment, we may end
up with an inefficiently large capital stock; for example, in the late 1980s there was a large
overbuilding of commercial real estate (office buildings) in big cities, due partly to tax incentives
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 73
(and partly due to myopia about the future marginal product of office buildings!). In summary, it
isn’t perfectly clear that government policies that encourage saving and investment are
appropriate; we first need to show clearly that some externality creates a need for such
government intervention.
Analytical Problems 1, 2, 3, and 4 all look at shocks to the economy and changes in variables
needed to restore equilibrium.
For a useful summary of research on consumption and investment, see Andrew B. Abel,
“Consumption and Investment,” in B. Friedman and F. Hahn, eds., Handbook of Monetary
Economics, vol. 2, Netherlands: Elsevier Science Publishers, 1990, pp. 725–778.
Figure 4.A.1
Analytical Problem 7 looks at what happens to the budget line when the interest rate on
borrowing differs from the interest rate on lending.
C. Present values
1 0
74 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
1. Present value is the value of payments to be made in the future in terms of today’s dollars or
goods
2. Example: At an interest rate of 10%, $12,000 today invested for one year is worth $13,200
($12,000 1.10); so the present value of $13,200 in one year is $12,000
3. General formula: Present value future value/(1 i), where amounts are in dollar terms and
i is the nominal interest rate
4. Alternatively, if amounts are in real terms, use the real interest rate r instead of the nominal
interest rate i
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 75
Once you’ve established the intuition about the present value formula for one period, you can
extend it to additional periods to show that the present value of an amount X to be received in
n years is X /(1 i)n.
Figure 4.A.2
If students want more help on indifference curves, you can refer them to a principles of economics
or intermediate microeconomics text, such as Michael Parkin, Economics, 5th edition, Reading,
Mass.: Addison Wesley Longman, 2000.
1 0
76 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Figure 4.A.3
Figure 4.A.4
(1) Increases PVLR, so shifts budget line out parallel to old budget line
(2) If there is a consumption-smoothing motive, both current and future consumption
will increase
(3) Then both consumption and saving rise because of the rise in current income
b. An increase in future income
(1) Same outward shift in budget line as an increase in current income
(2) Again, with consumption smoothing, both current and future consumption increase
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 77
(3) Now saving declines, since current income is unchanged and current consumption
increases
c. An increase in wealth
(1) Same parallel shift in budget line, so both current and future consumption rise
(2) Again, saving declines, since c rises and y is unchanged
Numerical Problem 8 deals with the income effect on consumption and saving.
1 0
78 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Figure 4.A.5
c. Real income steadily rises over time until near retirement; at retirement, income drops
sharply
d. Lifetime pattern of consumption is much smoother than the income pattern
(1) In reality, consumption varies somewhat by age
(2) For example, when raising children, household consumption is higher than average
(3) The model can easily be modified to handle this and other variations
e. Saving has the following lifetime pattern
(1) Saving is low or negative early in working life
(2) Maximum saving occurs when income is highest (ages 50 to 60)
(3) Dissaving occurs in retirement
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 79
Figure 4.A.6
a. When the real interest rate rises, one point on the old budget line is also on the
new budget line: the no-borrowing, no-lending point
b. Slope of new budget line is steeper
2. The substitution effect
a. A higher real interest rate makes future consumption cheaper relative to current
consumption
b. Increasing future consumption and reducing current consumption increases saving
1 0
80 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
c. Suppose a person is at the no-borrowing, no-lending point when the real interest rate rises
(Figure 4.A.7)
Figure 4.A.7
(1) An increase in the real interest rate unambiguously leads the person to increase future
consumption and decrease current consumption
(2) The increase in saving, equal to the decrease in current consumption, represents the
substitution effect
3. The income effect
a. If a person is planning to consume at the no-borrowing, no-lending point, then a rise in
the real interest rate leads just to a substitution effect
b. But if a person is planning to consume at a different point than the no-borrowing,
no-lending point, there is also an income effect
c. The intuition of the income effect
(1) If the person originally planned to be a lender, the rise in the real interest rate gives
the person more income in the future period; the income effect works in the opposite
direction of the substitution effect, since more future income increases current
consumption
(2) If the person originally planned to be a borrower, the rise in the real interest rate
gives the person less income in the future period; the income effect works in the same
direction as the substitution effect, since less future income reduces current
consumption further
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 81
Figure 4.A.8
(1) A budget line with the same slope as the new budget line, but going through the
original consumption point (BLint)
(2) The substitution effect is shown by the change from budget line BL1 to budget line
BLint, with the consumption point changing from point D to point P
(3) The income effect is shown by the change from budget line BLint to budget line BL2,
with consumption point changing from point P to point Q
b. The substitution effect decreases current consumption, but the income effect increases
current consumption; so saving may increase or decrease
c. Both effects increase future consumption
d. For a borrower, both effects decrease current consumption, so saving definitely increases
but the effect on future consumption is ambiguous
Analytical Problem 6 asks the student to show the income and substitution effects for a borrower.
e. The effect on aggregate saving of a rise in the real interest rate is ambiguous theoretically
(1) Empirical research suggests that saving increases
(2) But the effect is small
1 0
82 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 83
6. How Are You Trading Off the Present for the Future?
The material in the appendix may seem theoretical and abstract, but it’s easy to show students that they’re
really acting in the way the chapter describes. Ask them what tradeoffs they’re making between the present
and the future. The most obvious tradeoff is the fact that they’re in college, acquiring human capital, rather
than working for pay. Even more, many of them have borrowed money to pay for college, so they are
accumulating debt today to increase income and consumption in the future. And what is the rate at which
they trade off the present for the future? It’s the interest rate—the additional amount they’ll owe because
of their borrowing today.
1 0
84 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
2. When a consumer gets an increase in current income, both current consumption and future
consumption increase. Since current consumption rises, but by less than the increase in current
income, saving increases. When the consumer gets an increase in expected future income, again
both current and future consumption increase. Since current income does not increase, but current
consumption does, saving decreases. When the consumer gets an increase in wealth, both current and
future consumption again rise. Again, there has been no increase in current income, so saving
decreases. At the aggregate level, these changes in consumption and saving made by individuals
are decisions that change the aggregate level of desired consumption and saving.
3. The effect on desired saving of an increase in the expected real interest rate is potentially ambiguous.
An increase in the real interest rate has two effects on desired saving: (1) the substitution effect
increases saving, because the amount of future consumption that can be obtained in exchange for
giving up a unit of current consumption rises; and (2) the income effect may increase or reduce
saving. The income effect reduces saving for a lender, because a person who saves is better off as a
result of having a higher real interest rate, so he or she increases current consumption. However, for a
borrower, the income effect increases saving, because the borrower is worse off having to face a
higher real interest rate, and so reduces current consumption. So the income effects work in different
directions depending on whether a person is a lender or a borrower. For a borrower, then, both the
income and substitution effects work in the same direction, and saving definitely increases. For a
lender, however, the income and substitution effects work in opposite directions, so the result on
desired saving is ambiguous.
4. The expected real after-tax interest rate is the nominal after-tax interest rate, (1 t)i, minus the
expected rate of inflation, e, and represents the real return earned by a saver when a portion, t, of
interest income must be paid as taxes. If the tax rate on interest income declines (that is, t declines),
then 1 t becomes larger, so the expected real after-tax interest rate increases.
5. When government purchases increase temporarily, consumers see that higher taxes will be required in
the future to pay off the deficit. They reduce both current consumption and future consumption, but
current consumption declines by less than the amount of the government purchases. Since national
saving is output minus desired consumption minus government purchases, and government purchases
have increased more than current desired consumption has decreased, national saving declines at a
given real interest rate.
In the case of a lump-sum tax increase, consumers have higher taxes today, but lower taxes in the
future. If consumers take this into account, current desired consumption is unchanged, and since
output and government purchases didn’t change, desired national saving is unchanged as well. This is
the case of Ricardian equivalence, and is controversial because consumers may not understand that
higher taxes today imply lower future taxes. As a result, they may reduce desired consumption today,
increasing desired national saving.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 85
6. The two components of the user cost of capital are the interest cost and the depreciation cost.
The depreciation cost is the value lost as the capital wears out during the period. The interest cost
represents the opportunity cost of not using the funds that purchased the capital in some other way; an
example would be if the money was invested in bonds rather than buying capital goods.
7. The desired capital stock is the amount of capital that allows the firm to earn the largest possible
profit. The higher the expected future marginal product of capital, the higher the desired capital stock,
since any given amount of capital will be more productive in the future. The higher the user cost of
capital, the lower the desired capital stock, since a higher user cost yields lower profits on each unit
of capital. The higher the effective tax rate, the lower the desired capital stock, again because the firm
gets lower profits on each unit of capital.
8. Gross investment represents the total purchase or construction of new capital goods that takes place
during a period. Net investment is gross investment minus the depreciation on existing capital. Thus
net investment is the overall increase in the capital stock. Yes, it is possible for gross investment to be
positive when net investment is negative. This occurs whenever gross investment is less than the
amount of depreciation (and, in fact, happened in the United States during World War II).
9. Equilibrium in the goods market occurs when the aggregate supply of goods (Y) equals the aggregate
demand for goods (Cd Id G). Since desired national saving (Sd ) is Y C d G, an equivalent
condition is Sd Id. Equilibrium is achieved by the adjustment of the real interest rate to make the
desired level of saving equal to the desired level of investment, as shown in text Figure 4.6.
10. The saving curve slopes upward because saving is assumed to increase with an increase in the
expected real interest rate. The investment curve slopes downward because investment is lower the
higher is the expected real interest rate. The saving curve would be shifted to the right by an increase
in current output, a decrease in expected future output, a decrease in wealth, a decrease in government
purchases, and possibly by a rise in taxes. The investment curve would shift to the right by a decline
in the effective tax rate or a rise in expected future marginal product of capital.
1 0
86 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Numerical Problems
1. First, a general formulation of the problem is useful. With income of Y1 in the first year and Y2 in the
second year, the consumer saves Y1 C in the first year and Y2 C in the second year, where C is the
consumption amount, which is the same in both years. Saving in the first year earns interest at rate r,
where r is the real interest rate. And the consumer needs to accumulate just enough after two years to
pay for college tuition, in the amount T. So the key equation is (Y1 C)(1 r) (Y2 C) T.
(a) Y1 Y2 $50,000, r 10%, T $12,600. The key equation gives ($50,000 C)1.1 ($50,000 C)
$12,600. This can be simplified to $50,000 C $12,600/2.1 $6000, which can be solved to
get C $44,000. Then S Y C $50,000 $44,000 $6000.
(b) Y1 $54,200. The key equation is now ($54,200 C)1.1 ($50,000 C) $12,600. This can be
simplified to ($54,200 1.1) $50,000 $12,600 2.1 C, or $97,020 2.1 C, so C $46,200.
Then S Y1 C $54,200 $46,200 $8000. This illustrates that a rise in current income
increases saving.
(c) Y2 $54,200. The key equation is now ($50,000 C)1.1 ($54,200 C) $12,600. This can be
simplified to ($50,000 1.1) $54,200 $12,600 2.1 C, or $96,600 2.1 C, so C $46,000.
Then S Y1 C $50,000 $46,000 $4000. This illustrates that a rise in future income
decreases saving.
(d) With the increase in wealth of W, the total amount invested for the second period is W Y1 C,
so the key equation becomes ($1050 $50,000 C)1.1 ($50,000 C) $12,600. This can be
simplified to ($51,050 1.1) $50,000 $12,600 2.1 C, or $93,555 2.1 C, so C $44,550.
Then S Y1 C $50,000 $44,550 $5450. This illustrates that a rise in wealth decreases
saving.
(e) T $14,700. The key equation is now ($50,000 C)1.1 ($50,000 C) $14,700. This can be
simplified to $50,000 C $14,700/2.1 $7000, which can be solved to get C $43,000. Then
S Y C $50,000 $43,000 $7000. The rise in targeted wealth needed in the future raises
current saving.
(f ) r 25%. The key equation is now ($50,000 C)1.25 ($50,000 C) $12,600. This can be
simplified to $50,000 C $12,600/2.25 $5600, which can be solved to get C $44,400. Then
S Y C $50,000 $44,400 $5600. The rise in the real interest rate, with a given wealth
target, reduces current saving.
2. (a) This chart shows the MPKf as the increase in output from adding another fabricator:
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 87
(b) uc (r d)pK (0.12 0.20)$100 $32. HHHHC should buy two fabricators, since at two
fabricators, MPK f 50 32 uc. But at three fabricators, MPK f 30 32 uc. You want to add
fabricators only if the future marginal product of capital exceeds the user cost of capital. The
MPK f of the third fabricator is less than its user cost, so it should not be added.
(c) When r 0.08, uc (0.08 0.20)$100 $28. Now they should buy three fabricators, since
MPK f 30 28 uc for the third fabricator and MPK f 15 28 uc for the fourth fabricator.
(d) With taxes, they should add additional fabricators as long as (1 )MPK f uc. Since 0.4,
1 0.6. They should buy just one fabricator, since (1 )MPK f 0.6 100 60 32 uc.
They shouldn’t buy two, since then (1 τ)MPK f 0.6 50 30 32 uc.
(e) When output doubles, the MPKf doubles as well. At r 0.12, they should buy three fabricators,
since then MPK f 60 32 uc; they shouldn’t buy four, since then MPK f 30 32 uc.
At r 0.08, they should buy four fabricators, since then MPK f 30 28 uc; they shouldn’t buy
five, since then MPK f 20 28 uc.
4. Since the price of capital declines from 60 to 51, the depreciation rate is 9/60 .15.
(a) uc (r d)pK (.10 .15)60 15 units of output per year.
(b) The desired capital stock is such that MPK f uc, so 165 2K 15, or 2K 150, so K 75.
(c) The tax-adjusted user cost of capital is uc/(1 ), so with .4, the condition for the desired
capital stock is 165 2K 15/0.6, or 2K 140; the solution is K 70. Thus taxation decreases
the firm’s desired capital stock.
(d) The investment tax credit basically lowers the price of capital from 60 to (1 0.2)60 48. So the
tax-adjusted user cost of capital is only (.25 48)/0.6 20. Then the equation for setting the
desired capital stock is 165 2K 20, or 2K 145; the solution is K 72.5. Thus the investment
tax credit increases the firm’s desired capital stock.
5. (a) Desired consumption declines as the real interest rate rises because the higher return to saving
encourages higher saving; desired investment declines as the real interest rate rises because the
user cost of capital is higher, reducing the desired capital stock, and thus investment.
(b) Use the following table, where Sd Y Cd G 9000 Cd 2000 7000 Cd.
r Cd Id Sd Cd Id G
2 6100 1500 900 9600
3 6000 1400 1000 9400
4 5900 1300 1100 9200
5 5800 1200 1200 9000
6 5700 1100 1300 8800
(c) Equation (4.7) says that Y Cd Id G at equilibrium. Looking at the last column of the table,
with Y 9000, this is true only at r 5%. At this point, Sd Id 1200. Equation (4.8) says that Sd
1 0
88 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
r Cd Id Sd Cd Id G
2 6100 1500 1300 9200
3 6000 1400 1400 9000
4 5900 1300 1500 8800
5 5800 1200 1600 8600
6 5700 1100 1700 8400
6. (a) Sd Y Cd G
Y (3600 2000r 0.1Y) 1200
4800 2000r 0.9Y
(b) (1) Using Eq. (4.7): Y Cd Id G
Y (3600 2000r 0.1Y) (1200 4000r) 1200
6000 6000r 0.1Y
So 0.9Y 6000 6000r
At full employment, Y 6000. Solving 0.9 6000 6000 6000r, we get r 0.10.
(2) Using Eq. (4.8):
Sd I d
4800 2000r 0.9Y 1200 4000r
0.9Y 6000 6000r
When Y 6000, r 0.10.
So we can use either Eq. (4.7) or (4.8) to get to the same result.
(c) When G 1440, desired saving becomes Sd Y Cd G Y (3600 2000r 0.1Y) 1440
5040 2000r 0.9Y. Sd is now 240 less for any given r and Y; this shows up as a shift in the Sd
line from S1 to S2 in Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.3
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 89
7. (a) r 0.10
uc/(1 τ) (r d)pK/(1 ) [(.1 0.2) 1]/(1 0.15) 0.35.
MPK f uc/(1 ), so 20 0.02K 0.35; solving this gives K 982.5.
Since K K-1 I dK, I K K-1 dK 982.5 900 (.2 900) 262.5.
(b) i. Solving for this in general:
uc/(1 ) (r d)pK/(1 τ) [(r .2) 1]/(1 0.15) .235 1.176r.
MPKf uc/(1 ), so 20 0.02K 0.235 1.176r; solving this gives K 988.25 58.8r.
I K K-1 dK 988.25 58.8r 900 (0.2 900) 268.25 58.8r.
ii. Y C I G
1000 [100 (.5 1000) 200r] (268.25 58.8r) 200
1000 1068.25 258.8r, so 258.8r 68.25
r 0.264
C =100 (0.5 1000) (200 × 0.264) = 547.2
I = 268.25 (58.8 × 0.264) = 252.7 = S
uc/(1 ) = 0.235 (1.176 0.264) = 0.545
K = 988.25 (58.8 × 0.264) = 972.7
Figure 4.4
1 0
90 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 91
Analytical Problems
1. (a) As Figure 4.5 shows, the shift to the right in the saving curve from S1 to S2 causes saving and
investment to increase and the real interest rate to decrease.
Figure 4.5
(b) This is really just a transfer from the general population to veterans. The effect on saving
depends on whether the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) of veterans differs from that
of the general population. If there is no difference in MPCs, there will be no shift of the saving
curve; neither investment nor the real interest rate is affected. If the MPC of veterans is higher
than the MPC of the general population, then desired national saving declines and the saving
curve shifts to the left; the real interest rate rises and investment declines. If the MPC of veterans
is lower than that of the general population, the saving curve shifts to the right; the real interest
rate declines and investment rises.
(c) The investment tax credit encourages investment, shifting the investment curve from I1 to I2 in
Figure 4.6. Saving and investment increase, as does the real interest rate.
Figure 4.6
1 0
92 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
(d) The increase in expected future income decreases current desired saving, as people increase
desired consumption immediately. The rise of the future marginal productivity of capital shifts
the investment curve to the right. The result, as shown in Figure 4.7, is that the real interest rate
rises, with ambiguous effects on saving and investment.
Figure 4.7
2. (a) With a lower capital stock, the marginal product of labor is reduced, so the labor demand curve
shifts to the left from ND1 to ND2 in Figure 4.8. Then the new equilibrium point is one with lower
employment and a lower real wage. With lower employment and a lower capital stock, full-
employment output will be lower.
Figure 4.8
(b) Because the capital stock is lower, the marginal product of capital will be higher, so desired
investment will increase.
(c) The increase in desired investment shows up as a shift to the right in the Id curve, from I1 to I2 in
Figure 4.9. Then the new equilibrium (assuming no change in desired saving) is at a higher level
of investment and a higher real interest rate.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 93
Figure 4.9
3. (a) The temporary increase in the price of oil reduces the marginal product of labor, causing the
labor demand curve to shift to the left from ND1 to ND2 in Figure 4.10. At equilibrium, there is a
reduced real wage and lower employment.
Figure 4.10
The productivity shock results in a reduction of output. Because the shock is temporary, the only
effect on desired saving or investment is due to the reduction in current output, causing desired
national saving to fall. This shifts the saving curve to the left, raising the real interest rate and
reducing the level of desired investment, as well as desired national saving, as shown in
Figure 4.11.
1 0
94 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Figure 4.11
(b) The permanent increase in the price of oil reduces the marginal product of labor, causing the
labor demand curve to shift to the left, again as in Figure 4.10. (Also, the decline in future
income means the labor-supply curve will shift to the right; but we’ll assume that this shift is less
than the shift to the left of the labor-demand curve.) At equilibrium, there is a reduced real wage
and lower employment.
The productivity shock results in a reduction of current output. Because the shock is permanent,
it reduces future output as well, and reduces the future marginal product of capital. The desired
investment curve shifts to the left, from I1 to I2 in Figure 4.12, because the future marginal
product of capital is lower. The effect on desired saving is ambiguous—the reduction in current
income reduces desired saving, but the reduction in expected future income increases desired
saving. Let’s assume that the former effect outweighs the latter, so that the desired saving curve
shifts to the left from S1 to S2. Then national saving and investment both decline. Again, the
effect on the real interest rate is ambiguous. (Alternatively, if the effects on desired saving of the
reductions in current income and future income offset each other exactly, the desired saving
curve does not shift. In this case, the leftward shift of the investment curve along an unchanged
saving curve reduces the real interest rate, saving, and investment.)
Figure 4.12
4. A temporary increase in government spending reduces national saving. Whether the spending is
financed by current taxes or by borrowing (and raising future taxes), consumption falls, but not by the
full amount of the spending. Since S Y Cd G, national saving declines. This is shown in Figure
4.13 as a shift to the left in the saving curve. The real interest rate must increase to get S I, so I
declines as well. It makes no difference whether the temporary increase in spending is funded by
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 95
taxes or by borrowing.
Figure 4.13
In the case of infrastructure spending, MPK f rises, so investment increases. Saving shifts from S1 to S2
and investment shifts from I1 to I2 in Figure 4.14. With upward shifts in both saving and investment, the
new equilibrium is one with a higher real interest rate. However, saving and investment at the new
equilibrium may be higher or lower. The effect on consumption is unclear as well. The higher real
interest rate reduces consumption, but future income is higher, which increases consumption. If
investment actually rises, then the increase in government spending causes private investment to be
“crowded in” rather than “crowded out.” In this case consumption is crowded out.
Figure 4.14
5. When there is a temporary increase in government spending, consumers foresee future taxes. As a
result, consumption declines, both currently and in the future. Thus current consumption does not fall
by as much as the increase in G, so national saving (Sd Y Cd G) declines at the initial real
interest rate, and the saving curve shifts to the left from S1 to S2, as shown in Figure 4.15. Thus the
real interest rate increases and consumption and investment both fall.
1 0
96 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
Figure 4.15
When there is a permanent increase in government spending, consumers foresee future taxes as well,
with both current and future consumption declining. But if there is an equal increase in current and
future government spending, and consumers try to smooth consumption, they will reduce their
current and future consumption by about the same amount, and that amount will be about the same
amount as the increase in government spending. So the saving curve in the saving-investment
diagram does not shift, and there is no change in the real interest rate.
Since the saving curve shifts upward more in the case of a temporary increase in government
spending, the real interest rate is higher, so investment declines by more. However, consumption falls
by more in the case of a permanent increase in government spending.
6. See Figure 4.16. The consumer is originally on budget line BL1, with consumption at point D. An
increase in the real interest rate shifts the budget line to BL2, with consumption at point Q. The
change can be broken down into two steps. First, the substitution effect shifts the budget line from
BL1 to BLint, and the consumption point changes from point D to point P. The substitution effect
results in higher future consumption and lower current consumption. The income effect shifts the
budget line from BLint to BL2, with the consumption point changing from point P to point Q. The
income effect results in lower current and future consumption. Thus the income and substitution
effects work in the same direction, reducing current consumption and increasing saving.
Figure 4.16
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 97
7. The difference in interest rates between borrowing and lending means there is a kink in the budget
constraint at the no-lending, no-borrowing point, as shown in Figure 4.17. Borrowing is zero when
c y a. If current consumption is less than y a, the person is a saver (lender), and the budget line
has slope (1 rl). If current consumption is greater than y a, the person is a borrower, and faces
a steeper budget constraint with slope (1 rb), because the interest rate is higher.
Figure 4.17
An increase in either interest rate would steepen only the portion of the budget constraint for which
that interest rate is relevant. An increase in the real interest rate on lending is shown as a shift in the
budget line segment from BL1 to BL2 in Figure 4.18. An increase in the real interest rate on borrowing
is shown as a shift in the budget line segment from BL3 to BL4. If the indifference curve hits the
budget line at the no-borrowing, no-lending point, as shown, then there will be no change in current
or future consumption due to a change in either interest rate.
Figure 4.18
1 0
98 Abel/Bernanke/Croushore • Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
An increase in the consumer’s initial wealth would lead to a parallel rightward shift of both segments
of the budget line, as shown in Figure 4.19.
Figure 4.19
2. Real stock prices generally declined in the 1970s, but increased in other decades, especially in the
1990s. As a result, the household saving rate should have been higher in the 1970s than it was in
periods with increases in real stock prices. The prediction roughly holds true in the data.
3. The level of the real after-tax interest rate in the 1970s was usually negative, which favors
borrowers. The level of the real after-tax interest rate in the 1980s was usually positive, which
favors savers.
4.
a. Residential investment as a percent of GDP usually declines in recessions. In that respect,
residential investment is similar to other types of investment.
b. The ratio of residential investment to GDP was higher during the baby boom and lower in
the baby bust.
1 0
Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment 99
5. The high-grade corporate bond rate (AAA) and the mortgage rate (MORTG) tend to be the
highest. They are long-term interest rates with some default risk. The ten-year T-bond rate (GS10)
and the three-month T-bill rate (TB3MS) tend to be the lowest. They are issued by the U.S.
government and have low default risk. All the interest rates tend to move together, with the long-
term rates moving very closely with each other, and the short-term interest rates also moving very
closely with each other.
6. Investment in equipment has an upward trend, investment in structures has a flat trend, and
investment in intellectual property products has an upward trend. Computers and technology have
become relatively more important over time than buildings.
1 0