0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views24 pages

Topic 2 Risk Measures (Week 1)

lgima

Uploaded by

Jiho Lee
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views24 pages

Topic 2 Risk Measures (Week 1)

lgima

Uploaded by

Jiho Lee
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 24

ACTL3301/5301 Quantitative Risk Management

Week 1b: Risk Measures

▶ Risk Measures
▶ Value at Risk
▶ Variance
▶ Expected Shortfall
▶ Coherent Risk Measures
▶ Convex Risk Measures

Version 2024. Copyright UNSW School of Risk and Actuarial Studies


Reading: McNeil et al. (2015), Section 2.3
1 / 24
Risk Measures

▶ Consider a risk (random loss) X.


▶ We are often interested to evaluate the riskiness of X.
▶ Typically this involves determining ρ(X), the risk measure of X.
▶ This can be viewed as a representation of the riskiness of the
position X.
▶ Depending on the context, X can be one transaction, one business
unit, or even representative of the corporation as a whole.

2 / 24
Applications of Risk Measures

▶ In practice, risk measures are used for a number of problems


including in particular
▶ Determination of Economic (Risk) Capital
▶ As a Management Tool
▶ Insurance Premium setting.

3 / 24
Examples of Risk Measures

▶ Value at Risk
▶ Variance
▶ Moment based risk measures
▶ Expected shortfall

4 / 24
Value at Risk

▶ Let FL (l) = P (L ≤ l) be the distribution function of the loss on


a portfolio of risky assets
▶ VaR is defined as follows: Given a confidence level α ∈ (0, 1)
the VaR of the portfolio at confidence level α is the smallest
number l such that with probability at least α the loss L does not
exceed l:

VaRα (L) = inf {l : P (L ≤ l) ≥ α}


= inf {l : P (L > l) ≤ 1 − α}

▶ It is a quantile of the loss distribution


▶ Typical values of α: 0.95, 0.99, 0.995

5 / 24
6 / 24
Value at Risk: Normal distribution
▶ For normal distribution of FL (l) with mean µ and variance σ 2
we have
VaRα (L) = µ + σΦ−1 (α) ,
where Φ is the standard normal distribution function and
Φ−1 (α) is the α quantile of Φ.

7 / 24
Value at Risk: Some Potential Issues

▶ VaR ignores model risk - you may be using the wrong loss model
(and parameters are estimated from data).
▶ VaR ignores liquidity which impacts on time taken to trade
securities.
▶ Horizon for VaR need to reflect the time period the portfolio is
expected to be held
▶ VaR is not sub-additive - the VaR of a portfolio could be greater
than the sum of the VaR’s of the individual risks (to be discussed
in the next lecture).

8 / 24
Variance
For a risk L with mean µ and finite second moment,
var (L) = E (L − µ)2 .

▶ commonly used in finance and portfolio theory


▶ need to assume second moments exist
▶ usually only useful for symmetric risks

9 / 24
Expected Shortfall

▶ Expected shortfall (ES) at level α is defined as1


Z 1
1
ESα = qu (FL ) du
1−α α

where qu (FL ) is the quantile function of FL


▶ Related to VaR:
Z 1
1
ESα = VaRu (L) du
1−α α

▶ The average over VaRu for all u ≥ α

1
Note that different authors use different names with subtle differences.
10 / 24
Exercise
Show that the expected shortfall at level α is always greater than or
equal to the value at risk at the same level α:
ESα ≥ VaRα

11 / 24
Expected Shortfall
▶ For a continuous integrable loss L with continuous df FL ,

E (L; L ≥ qα (L))
ESα = = E (L|L ≥ VaRα ) , α ∈ (0, 1).
1−α

▶ More complicated for discontinuous loss distribution

E (L; L > qα (L)) + qα (L) × (P (L ≤ qα ) − α)


ESα =
1−α

12 / 24
If FL is normal with mean µ and variance σ 2 then

ϕ Φ−1 (α)

ESα = µ + σ
1−α
where ϕ is the density of the standard normal distribution.

13 / 24
Desired Properties of a Risk Measure

▶ One way to determine whether a risk measure is “good” is to


look at its properties.

▶ A risk measure is called a coherent risk measure if it satisfies the


following four properties.
▶ Monotonicity
▶ Translation Invariance
▶ Subadditivity
▶ Positive Homogeneity

14 / 24
Coherence: Monotonicity
Axiom (monotonicity). For two risks L1 and L2 such that L1 ≤ L2
almost surely, we have ρ(L1 ) ≤ ρ(L2 ).

15 / 24
Coherence: Translation Invariance
Axiom (translation invariance). For all risks L and every l ∈ R we
have ρ(L + l) = ρ(L) + l.

16 / 24
Coherence: Subadditivity
Axiom (subadditivity). For all risks L1 and L2 we have
ρ(L1 + L2 ) ≤ ρ(L1 ) + ρ(L2 ).

17 / 24
Coherence: Positive Homogeneity
Axiom (positive homogeneity). For all risks L and every λ > 0 we
have ρ(λL) = λρ(L).

18 / 24
Non-Subadditivity of VaR
Example (non-subadditivity of VaR). Consider a portfolio of two
zero-coupon bonds with a maturity of one year that default
independently. Assume:
▶ Each bond has a default probability p = 0.9%;
▶ The current price of the bonds and the face value of the bonds is
equal to 100;
▶ The bonds pay an interest rate of 5%.
Denote by Li the loss incurred by holding one unit of bond i, and
write L = L1 + L2 .

Show: VaR0.99 (L) > VaR0.99 (L1 ) + VaR0.99 (L2 ).

19 / 24
20 / 24
21 / 24
Coherence of ES
Example 2.26 (coherence of expected shortfall). Translation
invariance, monotonicity and positive homogeneity are immediate
from the corresponding properties of the quantile.

A general proof of subadditivity is given in Theorem 8.14 of the


textbook.

22 / 24
Convex Risk Measure

Axiom (Convexity). For all risks L1 and L2 and all λ ∈ [0, 1], we have

ρ (λL1 + (1 − λ)L2 ) ≤ λρ(L1 ) + (1 − λ)ρ(L2 ).

Definition (Convex risk measure). A risk measure is called convex if


it satisfies the following properties:
▶ monotonicity
▶ translation invariance
▶ convexity

23 / 24
Exercise
Show that a coherent risk measure is a convex risk measure.

24 / 24

You might also like