CH.4 Consumption Function
CH.4 Consumption Function
4.1 Introduction:
The consumption function describes the functional relationship that exists between income and
C=F ( Y )
It is to be noted that consumption will take place even at zero income level. This is because
everyone has basic needs that need to be fulfilled and in order to fulfil such needs, they will turn
to past saving or in other words, dissave in order to maintain their consumption level.
INCOME CONSUMPTION
0 20
60 70
120 120
180 170
240 220
300 270
360 320
The above table tells us that a zero level of income, the individual consumes 20 units of his
income. Here income does not refer to the regular inflow of income but saving. The individual is
dissaving in order to maintain his basic consumption level. When income increases from 0 to
60, consumption increases from 20 to 70. Up until this point, the individual is consuming more
than what he/she can earn. Which means, there is not a single unit of the increment of income
that is being saved. In fact, it is being dissaved. This is because the consumer is trying to fulfil
his “basic” necessities of life which have up unit now remained unfulfilled because of the lack of
a regular stream of income. Income increases from 60 to 120, which increase consumption from
70 units of income to 120 units of income. Which means all units of income are spent on
consumption expenditure. There are no savings or dissaving at this point. At this point, the
person has most likely fulfilled his basic needs and comforts. After this point, income increases
from 120 to 180 and consumption increases from 120 to 170. Its noteworthy to note that
consumption is smaller than income. Income then increases to 240 and consumption increases
to 220. It can be seen that while consumption is smaller than income, consumption increases
less than proportionately with an increase in income. This trend continues to remain the same
for the various increments of income. This theory is known as the Keynesian Psychological
Law of Consumption.
In the above figure, income is represented on the x-axis while consumption and saving are
represented on the y-axis. The 45-degree line, also known as the zero-saving line or income line,
represents income while the ‘C’ curve represents the consumption curve. The consumption curve
cuts the income line at equilibrium point B, where income is OY1. Before point B, the individual
spends more than they consume. They dissave to satisfy their private wants. As income increases
gradually to OY1, the negative gap between income and consumption begins to decline. At point
B the individual spends all units of income on consumption expenditure. Savings at this point
are not negative, but zero. When income increases from OY1 to OY2, consumption also increases
but less than proportionately from BY1 to SY2. This is because as income increases the individual
The average propensity to consume tell us how much of his/her income does an individual
spend on the consumption of goods and services. It tells us the fraction or portion of income
spent on consumption.
C
APC=
Y
The average propensity to consume decreases with an increase in income. This is because as
income levels begin to increase, less and less portion of income is spent on maintaining a basic
consumption level. From this, it can be inferred that the APC of a rich person would be relatively
APC=1−APS
The complement of APC is APS. i.e., average propensity to save. The average propensity to save
tells us how much of income does a person save. The relationship between APS and income is
the complete opposite of that of APC and income. Higher the income levels, higher the amount
When income levels are greater than consumption, APC < 1, and when consumption levels are
greater than income, APC >1. However, APC can never be zero. This is because even when
income levels are zero, people continue to consume. APC although, can be equal to 1. This is
because it is not unthinkable for a person to spend all units of their income on consumption of
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) tells us how much of a change in income results in a
change in consumption.
∆C
MPC=
∆Y
Lower the income levels, higher will be the marginal propensity to consume and vice versa. This
is because rates of change are much more elastic at lower levels of income than its opposite. The
change in consumption from zero-income levels to the bare minimum will be high compared to
the change in consumption due to a change in income from a millionaire to a trillionaire. This is
because the latter has abundant savings, which will most likely make a changes in consumption
Consequently, the marginal propensity to consume of a rich person will be lower than the
MPC=1−MPS
MPC and MPS have an inverse relationship. The marginal propensity to save tells us how much
of a change in come results in a change in savings. Higher the MPC of a person, lower their MPS
and vice-versa.
The marginal propensity to consume fluctuates between 0 and 1. However, it can never be
1 ≥ MPC ≥0
Psychological Law of Consumption. In other words, this theory states that consumption increase
C=a+ bY
Where,
a. C = consumption
c. b = slope/ mpc, which measures the change in consumption due to the change in income
d. Y = income
This is diagrammatically represented in the above figure. Income is represented on the x-axis
while consumption is represented on the y-axis. The 45 ° line represents income while the ‘C’
curve represents the consumption function. The 45 ° line cuts the C curve at equilibrium point E0
where income is OY0 and consumption is OC0. when income increases from OY0 to OY1
consumption also increases from OC0 to OC1. From the above diagram it is clear that the change
in consumption is lesser than the change in income. In Keynes’ words, “consumption increases
2. It states that APC > 1 when income levels are lower than consumption and APC < 1 when
3. This theory states that people spend part of their income on consumption and partly on
savings and it is for this reason that consumption increases less than proportionately
to Smithies and Tobin, empirical studies revealed that while the Keynesian Psychological Law of
They identified the following 7 factors that lead to the proportionality of consumption to income
in the long-run.
1. Increase in Asset holdings: People with more assets have been found to have large
spending habits in comparison to those who don’t. This is because an increase in asset
holdings results in an increase in gains or returns in the form of liquid money. This in
3. Age distribution: Each generation in different economies behave differently. They have
spending habits that are in stark contrast to one another. Therefore, consumption levels
also depend on the demographic dividend of the economy. For example, Indians of the
1980s generally have a larger propensity to save than to spend. But an Indian born in the
2010s might have a hard time reconciling with saving. If latter kind constituted the
4. New products: When new products are introduced into the economy, they make their
former versions obsolete. This results in an increase in the purchase of the current
expenditure and part of it is spent on saving. A decline in saving motive indicates that
there is a larger portion of income that is available for consumption expenditure which
6. Consumer credit: Consumer credit allows a person to consume goods and services that
are beyond his/her means. This creates a faux amount of disposable income that allows
7. Expectation of Income Increasing: When individuals become aware that they are going
to receive income soon, it allows them to splurge a bit more than they usually do because
they know that they aren’t going to run out of money anytime soon. Therefore,
This is represented in the above diagram. Income is represented on the x-axis while
consumption is represented on the y-axis. CL represents the consumption line in the long run
whereas CS2 represents consumption line in the short-run. The CS2 curve cuts the CL curve at
equilibrium point A. When income increases CS2 ‘drifts’ to become CS1. Consumption levels
increase along the CL curve to point B proportionately in the long run due to the above-
mentioned factors.
CS1 curve. i.e., they were no mathematical estimations to back up this rate.
2. According to James Dusenbery, the factors that were mentioned above were not
The Relative Income Hypothesis was introduced by James Dusenbery. He had propounded his
individual is not the function of his absolute income but of the consumption levels of
his neighbours. In other words, people purchase things that are of equal or higher
social status of their neighbours purely out of a social need. For example, A rich man
would spend a small portion of his income to fulfil his consumption needs whereas a
relatively poor man would spend a larger portion of his income trying to maintain the
same level of consumption. In other words, the APC of a rich man would be low while
that of the relatively poor man would be high. This provides the explanation of the
constancy of the long-run APC because lower and higher APCs would balance out in
the aggregate.
consumption levels were highly dependent on business cycles and income levels. He
advocated that during times of boom, when income levels increase, consumption
income levels regressed back to their previous level, consumption levels do not
regress back to its previous levels but decrease less than proportionately. This is
because people have become accustomed to a certain standard of living due to which
they are unable to settle down for lower standards of living. When the economy
enters the recovery period, income levels again increase. But consumption levels only
increase proportionately slowly. This is because the individual is unable to restore his
savings back to its original level quickly. This pattern when plotted on a graph looks
James Dusenbery combined his two hypothesis to create the Relative Income Hypothesis.
The relative income hypothesis is explained graphically in Fig. 4 where CL is the long-run
consumption function and CS1 and CS2 are the short-run consumption functions. Suppose income
is at the boom period level of OY1, where E1Y1 is consumption. Now income falls to OY0. Since
people are used to the standard of living at the OY1 level of income, they will not reduce their
consumption to E0Y0 level, but reduce it as little as possible by reducing their current saving.
Thus, they move backward along the CS1 curve to point C1 and be at C1Y0 level of consumption,
instead of regressing back to E0Y0 consumption levels. When the period of recovery starts,
income rises to the previous boom period level of OY1. But consumption increases slowly from
C1 to E1 along the CS1 curve because consumers can only slowly restore their previous level of
savings.
If income continues to increase to OY2 level, consumers will move upward along the CL curve
from E1 to E2 on the new short-run consumption function CS2. If another recession occurs at
OY2 level of income, consumption will decline along the CS2 consumption function toward
C2 point and income will be reduced to OY1 level. But during recovery over the long-run,
consumption will rise along the steeper CL path till it reaches the short-run consumption
function CS2. This is because when income increases beyond its present level OY1, the APC
becomes constant over the long-run. The short-run consumption function shifts upward from
CS1 to CS2 but consumers move along the CL curve from E1 to E2.
But when income falls, consumers move backward from E2 to C2 on the Cs2 curve. These upward
and downward movements from C1 and C2 points along the CL curve give the appearance of a
ratchet. This is the rachet effect. The short-run consumption function ratchets upward when
income increases in the long run but it does not shift down to the earlier level when income
declines. Thus, the ratchet effect will develop whenever there is a cyclical decline or recovery in
income.
increase in income.
2. It advocated that consumer preferences of an individual were a function of their
neighbour’s consumption patterns, which is empirically proved not to be the case for
most consumers.
3. It stated that consumer preferences were irreversible over time. According to Michael
4. He assumed a linear relationship between consumption and income which was not the
case. Consumption can increase due to many other factors besides income.
5. The Ratchet effect propounded by James Dusenberry was actually the Reverse Lightning
bolt effect due to its zig-zag consumption patterns that highly resembled a lightning
bolt’s mirror-image.
The permanent income hypothesis was introduced by Friedman, the father of the monetarist
revolution. Friedman agreed with the Keynesian statement that consumption does not increase
proportionately with an increases in income. He however also acknowledged the fact that
Dr. Friedman had introduced permanent and transitory characteristics to consumption and
income. i.e., income or measured income could be broken down into permanent and transitory
income and consumption or measured consumption could be broken down into permanent and
transitory consumption.
Permanent income referred to the flow of income to a particular household whose wealth
remained intact even after consumption. In other words, it’s the main source or stream of
income of a family. Transitory income on the other hand, referred to income flows that were
Ym=Yp+ Yt
When transitory income is positive, measured income is greater than permanent income. When
transitory income is negative, measured income is lesser than permanent income. When
Permanent consumption on the other hand, referred to the planned consumption of goods and
Cm=Cp+Ct
income.
Cp=f ( Yp )
Or,
Cp=KYp
Cp
K=
Yp
The above equation indicates that the constant K, represents the APC of the individual in the
long run. K is considered to be constant since permanent income and permanent consumption
are constant values that have already been known previously with certainty to the individual.
Dr. Friedman has tried to identify the factors that has lead to the proportionality of
consumption to income in the long run. He has identified three main factors,
2. Rate of interest,
K=f ( r , w , u )
Friedman had further investigated into permanent income. He advocated that permanent
Yp=αYt + βYt −1
Since we know that permanent consumption is a function of permanent income, the above
the y-axis. The CL curve represents the long run consumption line while Cs and Cs1 represent
short run consumption lines. When the individual’s income level is at OY level, his consumption
level is EY. This comprises of both permanent and transitory income and consumption. When
his income increases from OY to OY1, consumption does not increase from EY to E1Y1; instead, it
increases from EY to E2Y1 along the Cs line. This is because the individual believes that his
consumption in the long run and less than proportional increase of consumption in the short
run.
1. The Permanent Income Hypothesis assumed that transitory income and transitory
2. He assumed that transitory income and permanent income were also uncorrelated which
3. He assumed that expectations were backward-looking when they were in fact forward-
looking.
Ando and Modigliani were the economists who propounded the Life Cycle Hypothesis. The life
2. The individual has earned all his/her assets and has not inherited/bequeathed property
According to this theory, an individual’s life is split into three-time frames: childhood, working
man and old age. When the individual is a child, he does not have a regular flow of income.
However, his consumption levels are not zero. This is because he dissaves to fulfil his basic
needs and necessities. When he becomes a working adult, he has a regular flow of income. His
consumption levels slightly increase. It is at this stage in his life, that he earns the most and
saves the most. When he reaches the last stage of his life, he again dissaves to maintain his
Time is represented on the x-axis and consumption is represented on the y-axis. The CC 1
represents the consumption curve while the Y0YY1 curve represents the income line. The income
line cuts the consumption line at point B in the first time period T1, where dissaving of BCY0
takes place. When income increases slowly from Y0 to Y in the next time frame T1T2, the
individual saves BSY from his earnings. Income levels decline from Y to Y1 due to old age and
was a function of expected labour income (Yϵ ¿ , current labour income (Y ¿ and wealth (W)
C=f (Yϵ , Y , W )
1. This theory assumes planned consumption which is unrealistic and improbable in real
life.
2. This theory neglects locked-up savings (or investments) which are usually done by
3. This theory assumes that consumption and income have a linear relationship when in