Previewpdf
Previewpdf
Previewpdf
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilised in any
form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented,
including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system,
without permission in writing from the publishers.
Notices
Practitioners and researchers must always rely on their own experience and knowledge in
evaluating and using any information, methods, compounds, or experiments described herein.
In using such information or methods they should be mindful of their own safety and the safety
of others, including parties for whom they have a professional responsibility.
Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for
identification and explanation without intent to infringe.
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Appendices
1 Offset Project Types 108
2 Examples of Project Verifiers 116
3 Standards 118
4 Examples of Offset Credit Retailers 125
5 Examples of Institutional Buyers 151
Index 159
List of Figures, Tables and Boxes
Figures
1.1 The greenhouse effect 2
1.2 Growth in the global carbon market 7
2.1 Simplified supply chain of the retail carbon market 18
2.2 A model of common types of transactions in the voluntary
carbon market 29
2.3 A quick sketch of the different kinds of buyers in the voluntary
carbon market 31
3.1 A map of the RPS standards in the United States 40
3.2 Current input-based cap-and-trade system 56
3.3 Current system with 500GWh gas added 56
3.4 Current system with 500GWh wind added 57
3.5 Output-based system with 500GWh natural gas added 58
3.6 Output-based system with 500GWh of wind added 59
3.7 Load-based cap-and-trade 60
3.8 Load-based cap-and-trade with 500GWh of wind added 61
4.1 US GHG emissions 65
A1.1 Commonly used emission reduction and sequestration projects 108
Tables
1.1 Voluntary carbon market size 14
2.1 Project types generating carbon credits for the voluntary carbon
market 20
2.2 Major certification programmes/standards available or soon to
be available for the voluntary carbon offset market 23
2.3 Global sources of pressure in the private sector 33
2.4 Regional sources of pressure in the private sector:
Europe 33
2.5 Regional sources of pressure in the private sector:
North America 33
3.1 REC sales in voluntary markets 42
viii Voluntary Carbon Markets
3.2 Certified REC customers and sales for leading voluntary certifier
Green-e 42
3.3 Utility use of RECs to supply green pricing programmes 43
3.4 Comparison of alternative application systems 62
A2.1 Examples of project verifiers 116
A4.1 Examples of offset credit retailers 125
A5.1 Examples of institutional buyers 152
Boxes
1.1 A look at the science 1
1.2 The Chicago Climate Exchange (CCX) 5
2.1 The additionality debate 24
4.1 Case Study: Mantadia-Zahamena corridor restoration and
protection project, Republic of Madagasca 70
List of Contributors
Martha Isabel Ruiz Corzo, a former music teacher, founded the Grupo
Ecologico Sierra Gorda in 1989 along with her husband and a group of neigh-
bours. The first director of the Grupo Ecologico, she led the effort to obtain the
decree of the Sierra Gorda as a Biosphere Reserve, obtained in 1997. As a result
of this, she was named by the President of Mexico as the first director of the
Sierra Gorda Biosphere Reserve. A recognized social entrepreneur, Ruiz is
an outspoken advocate for the development of payments for environmental
services programmes that work in areas of extreme poverty. She is a member
of the board of directors of Forest Trends.
Marisa Meizlish is the Manager of Advisory Services at New Forests and has
a BA in journalism and political science from Northwestern University in
Chicago, and a Masters in Environmental Management from the University
of New South Wales. Marisa previously worked in the news media and
public relations fields in New York and Chicago.
Dr Janet Peace is a senior research fellow in the eEconomics Program at the Pew
Center on Global Climate Change. At Pew she serves as the in-house economist
and together with the Director of Policy Analysis coordinates the Center’s
research on the economic modelling of climate change policies. As part of this
role, she provides quantitative analysis of policy proposals, assessing relative
merits and dissecting underlying assumptions. She is also responsible for
communicating these results to policy makers, academic researchers and business
leaders, by means of reports, briefings and presentations. Prior to coming to the
Pew Center, Dr Peace was the Director of Offsets Development and Industry
Relations with a Canadian non-profit group, Climate Change Central. Here she
worked on issues related to implementation of the Kyoto Protocol, including
the assessment of cost effective, alternative policies that were politically feasible
for industry and all levels of government. Working with these stakeholders,
she was a founding Chair of the National Offsets Quantification Team – an
intergovernmental/industry group currently developing standardized offset
quantification protocols for use in the Canadian offset system.
David Ross, originally from the state of Ohio in the United States, has worked
for non-profit organizations for more than 18 years, including the American
Civil Liberties Union of San Diego & Imperial Counties, the American
Cancer Society, Butte Environmental Council, Parks & Preserves Foundation
and National Wildlife Federation. He has been working on the project of
biodiversity conservation in the Sierra Gorda Biosphere Reserve since 2003.
He led negotiations on behalf of Bosque Sustentable for its sale of emission
reduction credits to the United Nations Foundation.
Lorna Slade is with Group Corporate Affairs, HSBC Holdings plc. HSBC
Holdings is developing a sustainability-focused business in a number of
areas, particularly low carbon energy, water infrastructure, sustainable forestry
and related agricultural commodities. It has also recently announced a strategy
to help its clients respond to the challenges and opportunities of creating a
lower carbon economy – advising them on the implications of climate change
and the business opportunities that arise. In 2005, HSBC was the first bank
to become carbon neutral.
Ricardo Bayon
Like most books, this one is years in the making and has many parents. It was
first born, however, of the realization that, while there was much talk of the
regulated carbon markets, the voluntary markets were being left behind.
This, despite the fact that these markets appeared to be growing rapidly. But
knowing that something needed to be done and getting it done were two very
far-removed destinations. Getting the book to this stage would simply not
have been possible without the unflagging support of Michael Jenkins and
the rest of our colleagues at Forest Trends. Likewise, none of this would
have happened were it not for the generous contributions of many donors to
the Ecosystem Marketplace. These include:
ABN-AMRO
Conservation International
The Citigroup Foundation
O Boticario
The David and Lucile Packard Foundation
The Gordon and Betty Moore Foundation
The Nature Conservancy
The UK Department for International Development
The UK Forestry Commission
The US Forest Service; and
The US Natural Resources Conservation Service (NRCS)
Our deepest thanks to all of them for being more than sponsors; for being
true partners.
Also, it should be mentioned that a tremendous amount of work that went
into this book came from a report prepared for the Ecosystem Marketplace by
David Brand and Marisa Meizlich at New Forests. Without that initial
impetus, this book wouldn’t have been possible. Likewise, I would like to
thank, in no particular order, Jason Scott, Colin Le Duc, David Tepper,
Richard Burrett, Mark Trexler, Mark Kenber, Renat Heuberger, Richard
Tipper, Jessica Orrego, Toby Janson-Smith, Jonathan Shopley, Bill Sneyd,
Alex Rau, Michael Schlup, and all of the contributors to this book for their
Foreword xiii
Amanda Hawn
Many people helped with the creation of this book, but Peter Barnes and the
managers of The Mesa Refuge – who provided the space to sit down and finally
write – top the list of those to whom gratitude is due. All of the contributors to
the fourth chapter of the book were generous with their time, energy and
insight – for all of these things, the authors are thankful. In addition to those
whose names appear as guest contributors, we are grateful to the many
others who took the time to return phone calls, give interviews, provide
statistics and generally enrich the information herein. We are grateful, too, to
Marion Yuen who organized a great conference – the Green T Forum –
about many of the topics covered in this book in May of 2006. Walker
Wright and Nathan Larsen stayed up to burn the midnight oil during the
final editing phases of the manuscript, and Rob West and his team at Earthscan
were both patient and professional – thank you. Last but not least, I would like
to extend my gratitude to my co-editors – Ricardo Bayon and Katherine
Hamilton - who are as kind and professional, as they are intelligent.
Katherine Hamilton
My gratitude goes to Ricardo Bayon and Amanda Hawn, two talented and
innovative individuals, for the opportunity to contribute to this exciting project
and the work of Ecosystem Marketplace. I’d also like express my sincere
appreciation to Brad Gentry and many others at the Yale School of Forestry
and Environmental Studies, who fostered my research on carbon markets.
Many thanks also go to the numerous experts in this market, including Lars
Kvale, Mark Trexler, Toby Jason-Smith, John Kunz and Erin Meezan, who
willingly took the time to educate, patiently answer questions and offer insights
into this evolving marketplace.
Foreword
The serious debate over the climate crisis has now moved on from the question
of whether it exists to how we can craft emergency solutions in order to avoid
catastrophic damage.
The debate over solutions has been slow to start in earnest because some of
our leaders still find it more convenient to deny the reality of the crisis. The
hard truth for the rest of us is that the maximum that seems politically feasible
still falls far short of the minimum that would be effective in solving the crisis.
T. S. Eliot once wrote:
Between the idea and the reality, Between the motion and the act Falls the
Shadow. Between the conception and the creation, Between the emotion and
the response Falls the Shadow.
Leaders must try to shine some light on a pathway through this terra incognita
that lies between where we are and where we need to go.
Outside of the Kyoto Treaty, business leaders in both political parties have
taken significant steps to position their companies as leaders in addressing this
crisis and have adopted policies that not only reduce CO2 but make their
companies zero carbon. Many of them have discovered a way to increase profits
and productivity by eliminating their contributions to global warming pollu-
tion. A key contributor to the movement to freeze and then reduce carbon emis-
sions and a remarkable area of commercial and policy innovation, is the
voluntary carbon market.
Voluntary Carbon Markets by Ricardo Bayon, Amanda Hawn and Katherine
Hamilton describes a remarkable area of innovation in the fight to control global
warming pollution in describing the foundations upon which many promising
carbon reducing strategies have been built. And in the current absence of a
worldwide regulatory system for carbon reduction, Voluntary Carbon Markets
also foreshadows the factors which will drive the next generation of market-
based innovation for fighting global warming pollution. I commend the work
of Ricardo and the Ecosystem Marketplace Group for jumping into T. S. Eliot’s
void and shining the light on this important market.
The climate crisis is not a political issue. It is a moral issue. It affects
the survival of human civilization. It is not a question of left versus right;
it is a question of right versus wrong. Put simply, it is wrong to destroy the
Foreword xv
habitability of our planet and ruin the prospects of every generation that
follows ours.
What is motivating millions of global citizens to think differently about
solutions to the climate crisis is the growing realization that this challenge is
bringing us unprecedented opportunity.
This is an opportunity for transcendence, an opportunity to find our better
selves and in rising to meet this challenge, create a better brighter future – a
future worthy of the generations who come after us and who have a right to
be able to depend on us.
Al Gore
List of Acronyms and Abbreviations
After decades of searching for creative and innovative ways to protect the
environment, it is time we be brutally honest with ourselves: We are losing
this battle, and losing it in a spectacular way. Every day we hear that yet another
species has gone extinct, yet another acre of forest has disappeared, and yet
another coral reef has been destroyed. And as if that weren’t enough, Earth
has begun warming to such an extent that climate, sea levels, glacial ice, and
even the polar ice caps may be in danger. It is enough to demoralize even the
most determined optimist.
But this is a battle we cannot afford to lose – literally. It is time not to
give up, but to redouble our efforts, to become more creative, and to seek
new ways of working together in situations where confrontation is no longer
effective (if it ever was). The time, in other words, has come for the environ-
mental equivalent of the St Crispin’s day speech in Shakespeare’s Henry V, a
call to arms that does not lament how difficult the task is likely to be – or
how few of us there are – but rather pushes us forward into the wild and
scary unknown.
And, in the case of the environmental movement, the scary unknown is the
use of markets and market-like instruments to protect the environment. To be
fair, we now have nearly two decades of experimentation in the use of market
mechanisms for environmental protection. The US Acid Rain trading
scheme began in the 1980s, and various forms of market-like mechanisms for
environmental protection have been tried all over the world.
But the game is one of scale. Protecting one species, one piece of land, one
watershed may be important, but it is no longer enough. The solutions today
need to be systemic, they need to change the way we do business, the way we
eat, drink, sleep, and think. And this is where we think markets may hold the
greatest promise.
Some years ago, we created Forest Trends with a vision. Our vision was
simple: we believed that by bringing loggers, environmentalists, business-
people, academics, and scientists together into the same room to think about
issues that mattered to all of them we would be better able to stem the loss of
the world’s forests. But we soon realized that – effective as this might be – it
was not enough. We saw that in order to save the world’s forests, society
needed to value standing forests as least as highly as it values soybeans, cattle
Introduction xix
Agincourt – one day, we will look back and either be happy we did, or else wish
we had; the choice is ours.
For hurricane watchers, 2005 was a year for the record books. A startling
number of hurricanes hit the Gulf of Mexico, causing over US$100 billion
in damages. Hurricane Katrina alone displaced 1 million people and left
1,000 dead.
The 2004 hurricane season was a bit less horrific in terms of raw numbers,
but what it lacked in quantity, it made up for in oddity; the year was marked by
an event some believed to be a scientific impossibility, namely a hurricane in the
southern Atlantic. For over 40 years, weather satellites circling the globe have
seen hurricanes and cyclones in the north Atlantic, and on both sides of the
equator in the Pacific, but never – until 2004 – in the southern Atlantic. On
28 March, Hurricane Catarina slammed into Brazil, proving that recent
weather patterns are starkly different from those of the 20th century.
What is going on? Are these freak occurrences or signs of something bigger?
While there is no level of data or anecdote that that will satisfy hardened
sceptics, many scientists now believe that the storms of 2004 and 2005 are
merely symptoms of a bigger problem: global climate change. As the Earth’s
average temperature grows warmer, they say, atmospheric and oceanic patterns
are beginning to shift, fueling increased storms and unusual weather events.
Temperatures at the planet’s surface increased by an estimated 1.4 degrees
Fahrenheit (8F) (0.8 degrees Celsius (8C)) between 1900 and 2005. The past
decade was the hottest on record during the last 150 years, and 2005 was the
hottest year of the last 150 years (Linden, 2006).
Again, sceptics argue that this is part of the natural variability in the Earth’s
temperature, but the majority of scientists now agree that it is more likely due to
increased concentrations of heat-trapping greenhouse gases (GHGs) in the
atmosphere.
You can say: ‘I’m going to ignore that and keep going at 90 miles an hour
because you cannot prove to me that the curve is not banked and therefore I
might make it . . . or you can put on the brakes.’ (Hawn, 2004).
Noting that there could be an oil slick and no bank to the road, Lackner says
the good news is that we have the technology to put on the brakes. He adds,
however, that if we want to stabilize the amount of CO2 in the atmosphere at
double the natural level (roughly 500ppm, which still might leave us with an
ice-free Arctic Ocean), we have to start now (Hawn, 2004).
Market theory
To start towards stabilized levels of atmospheric CO2 , policy makers argue that
we not only need to prime the research pump behind clean energy technologies
and emission reduction strategies, we also must generate the market pull for
them.
Enter the global carbon market. Many think markets for emissions reduc-
tions are among the most innovative and cost-effective means society has of
creating a market pull for new clean energy technologies while, at the same
time, putting a price on pollution and thereby providing incentives for
people to emit less.
The theory is that carbon markets are able to achieve this magic because
they help channel resources toward the most cost effective means of reducing
GHG emissions. At the same time, they punish (monetarily) those who emit
more than an established quota, and reward (again, monetarily) those who
emit less. In so doing, they encourage people to emit less and change the
economics of energy technologies, making technologies that emit less carbon
more competitive vis-à-vis their carbon-intensive counterparts.
There is other magic at work as well: By turning units of pollution into units
of property, the system makes it possible to exchange pollution from Cape
Town with pollution from Cape Cod. If business managers find reducing
their company’s emissions too costly, they can buy excess reductions from a
facility where reductions are less expensive. The bigger the market, the
theory goes, the greater the likelihood that efficiencies will be found.
By aggregating information about the value of carbon allowances, the
market is sending signals to potential polluters. In today’s European emissions
market, for instance, emitting 1 ton of CO2 has in the past cost polluters
anywhere from under 7€ to 30€ (Hamilton, 2006). In a world where pollution
has no price, the default decision will always be to pollute. In a world where
pollution costs between 7€ and 30€ a ton, the decision is no longer quite so
easy. Polluters suddenly must consider a new suite of options: do they
accept the cost of added pollution, change fuel mixes or simply conserve
energy?
Once markets take shape, emitters have a variety of options available to
them. If they believe they can reduce emissions cheaply by changing produc-
tion processes or experimenting with new technology, they have an incentive
4 Voluntary Carbon Markets
to do so. If they believe they can change their production process, but that this
will take time, emitters can purchase credits up front in the hopes that, down
the line, they will be able to make them back through emissions reduction
technologies. If, on the other hand, emitters believe they will emit more in
the long run, they can buy credits now (or options on credits once secondary
markets develop) for use later. In short, the system enables the trading of
emissions across temporal as well as geographic boundaries, a basic benefit of
markets.
The market-based approach also allows other third-party players, such as
speculators, to enter the fray. By agreeing to take on market risks in exchange
for possible paybacks, speculators assume the risks that others are either
unwilling or unable to shoulder. Other interested parties also can get involved.
If, for example, an environmental group wants to see emissions decrease below
a regulated target, they can raise money to buy and retire emissions allowances.
This drives up the cost of emissions and can force utilities to become more
efficient.
It is, of course, important to note that some people dispute the net gain of
such benefits, and others feel that markets allow companies to ‘greenwash’
previously tarnished environmental reputations without changing their
behaviour in important ways. ‘Carbon offsets are based on fictitious carbon
accounting, and can by themselves not make a company carbon neutral’,
argues Larry Lohmann of The Corner House, the UK based non-
governmental organization (NGO). ‘The practice of offsetting is slowing
down innovation at home and abroad and diverting attention away from the
root causes of climate change.’ (Wright, 2006).
This debate notwithstanding, experimentation with environmental markets
is now widespread. Ever since the US established the first large-scale environ-
mental market (to regulate emissions of gases that lead to acid rain), we have
seen environmental markets emerging to trade in everything from wetlands
to woodpeckers.
Carbon markets
The term carbon market refers to the buying and selling of emissions permits
that have been either distributed by a regulatory body or generated by GHG
emission reductions projects. Six GHGs are generally included in ‘carbon’
markets: CO2 , methane, nitrous oxide, sulfur hexafluoride, hydro fluoro-
carbons and perfluorocarbons.
GHG emission reductions are traded in carbon credits, which represent
the reduction of GHGs equal to one metric ton of CO2 (tCO2 e), the most
common GHG. A group of scientists associated with the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has determined the global warming potential
(GWP) of each gas in terms of its equivalent in tons of carbon dioxide (i.e.
tCO2 e) over the course of 100 years. For example, the GHG methane has a
GWP roughly 23 times higher than CO2 , hence one ton of methane equals
The Big Picture 5
and where offset projects are used, CCX requires that an approved third party
organization verify that the project’s emissions reductions are real and that they
meet standards set by the exchange.
Since its launch in late 2003, CCX has grown in membership from 19 institutions
to over 131 institutions. Ford Motor, International Paper, IBM, American Electric
Power, the City of Chicago, the City of Portland, the City of Oakland, the State
of New Mexico, the World Resources Institute and the Rocky Mountain Institute
are just a few of its wide range of members from the business, governmental and
philanthropic sectors. CCX traded 1.45 million tCO2 e in 2005 for a total value of
US$2.7 million. The average weighted price per tCO2 e in 2005 was US$1.95.
Trading prices spiked in the first quarter of 2006 to US$5.00 when post-2006
vintages were announced and – according to sources – a US Senator began
openly speculating that the US. might someday adopt CCX as its de-facto
carbon-trading scheme. The first quarter of 2006 also saw higher trading volumes,
with a total US$1.25 million exchanged (Capoor and Ambrosi, 2006).
In 2005, CCX created the European Carbon Exchange (ECX), a wholly-owned
subsidiary which has since become the largest exchange trading carbon credits on
the EU Emission Trading Scheme (see below). And CCX announced the creation of
three new exchanges in 2006: the Montreal Climate Exchange (MCX), the North-
eastern Climate Exchange (NECX), and the New York Climate Exchange (NYCX).
These initiatives are presumably designed to interface with carbon credit schemes
in Canada and with the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) in the US
Northeast.
Echoing the World Bank’s analysis, Annie Petsonk, international counsel for
Environmental Defense’s Global and Regional Air Program says she is particu-
larly pleased with some of the innovations triggered by the CDM. Inspired by
the active market in Europe, Petsonk says people are now pouring money into
new clean technologies in the hopes of capitalizing on a perceived first-mover
advantage. Indeed, the European experience with carbon trading suggests
that large-scale environmental markets not only are feasible, but also are
capable of changing the way businesses relate to environmental issues
(Kenny 2006).
Movement in the US
While neither Australia nor the US (two of the largest per-capita emitters of
GHGs in the world) chose to ratify the Kyoto Protocol, state governments in
both countries have initiated their own regulatory processes, alone or in
conjunction with others.
The Big Picture 9
In 1997 the US state of Oregon enacted the Oregon Standard, the first
regulation of CO2 in the US. The Oregon Standard requires that new power
plants built in Oregon reduce their carbon dioxide emissions to 17 per cent
below the most efficient combined cycle plant. Plants may achieve this target
by offsetting their emissions through proposed offset projects or by paying
mitigation funds to The Climate Trust, a non-profit organization created to
implement projects that avoid or sequester CO2 emissions. Since its creation,
The Climate Trust has offset more than 1.6 million metric tons of carbon
dioxide. The organization has a portfolio of over US$4 million invested in
greenhouse gas offset projects, and anticipates securing an additional US$4-
to-$6 million in project-based reduction in 2006 (www.climatetrust.org/).
On the East Coast of the US, eight states are developing the Regional
Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), a regional strategy to reduce carbon
dioxide emissions utilizing a cap-and-trade system. The programme commits
participating states to cap their emissions at 1990 levels after 2009 and
then drop them by 10 per cent by 2018. RGGI will cover electric utilities
capable of producing at least 25 megawatts of power, giving power plants
three-year compliance periods to submit one CO2 allowance for every ton of
CO2 emitted.
The programme allows utilities to use offset projects that occur away from
the power plant itself to meet emissions targets, but only on a limited basis.
Initially, utilities may use offset projects – which include capturing landfill
methane, planting trees and energy efficiency programmes – to cover 3.3 per
cent of their emissions. If allowance prices rise beyond expected levels, then
RGGI will allow utilities to use more offsets (Biello, 2006).
Importantly, the RGGI memorandum of understanding highlights an
interest in expanding ‘the geographic reach of the Program.’ In thinking
about future expansion, RGGI’s architects are watching California especially
closely. While California does not have any trading scheme functioning yet,
the state commission charged with developing its GHG programme has
expressed an interest in cap-and-trade programmes and has called for links
with RGGI and the state passed landmark legislation in August 2006 in
the form of a bill called AB32. The bill requires a 25% cut in the state’s
carbon dioxide emissions by 2020, and insiders say that cap-and-trade will,
indeed, be one of the mechanisms used to reach the target. California also
has one of the most highly developed registries of carbon credits (the Cali-
fornia Climate Action Registry, or CCAR), a registry that might be
mimicked not only in the US Northeast, but also in the US Midwest. If
programmes on the East and West coasts link up, say carbon market experts,
a national trading programme in the US, will not be far behind (Anderson,
2006).
Australia’s Pioneers
While Europe’s compliance carbon market clearly leads the world in terms of
sophistication and scale, it is worth noting that the state of New South Wales
10 Voluntary Carbon Markets
pine and eucalyptus trees on their land (Hawn, 2005). AES, like other compa-
nies since, hoped to reduce its ‘carbon footprint’ for philanthropic and
marketing reasons, not because it was forced to do so by legislation or global
treaty. The deal thus was voluntary, marking the beginning of a voluntary
carbon market that remains as controversial and interesting today as it was in
1989.
Unlike the regulated market, the voluntary market does not rely on legally
mandated reductions to generate demand. As a result, the market suffers from
fragmentation and a lack of widely available impartial information. The
fragmented and opaque nature of the voluntary market can, in large part, be
attributed to the fact that it is partially composed of deals that are negotiated
on a case-by-case basis, and that many of these deals neither require the
carbon credits to undergo a uniform certification or verification process nor
register them with any central body. As a result, there are many types of
carbon transactions on the voluntary market and a variety of businesses and
non-profits based on different models sell a range of products, certified to a
wide array of standards.
The lack of uniformity, transparency and registration in the voluntary
market has won it a great deal of criticism from some environmentalists who
claim that it is a game of smoke and mirrors rather than an engine of actual
environmental progress. Many buyers also say they are wary of the voluntary
carbon market since transactions often carry real risks of non-delivery. Some
companies buying carbon credits also fear that they will be criticized by
NGOs if the carbon they are buying isn’t seen to meet the highest possible
standards.
Of concern to environmentalists and buyers, alike, is the fact that the
voluntary carbon market’s lack of regulation may mean it cannot reach the
scale necessary to impact the problem. Because it lacks a regulatory driver,
demand for credits can be volatile and fickle. The sudden explosion of the
Kyoto carbon market in 2005 shows the difference that regulation can make.
Clearly, regulation is key to driving large-scale demand. ‘The voluntary
credit market could grow by an order of magnitude or two orders of magnitude
and it’s still not going to impact the problem,’ explains Mark Trexler, president
of Trexler Climate & Energy Services (Trexler, 2006).
Despite the shortcomings of the voluntary market, many feel it is a fast-
evolving arena with some distinct and important advantages over the regulated
carbon market. While the wide range of products emerging from the voluntary
market can be confusing to potential buyers, these products can also be highly
innovative and flexible. Numerous suppliers say they benefit from this
flexibility and the lower transaction costs associated with it.
For example, the cost of getting a carbon offset project approved by the
CDM Executive Board under the Kyoto Protocol ranges anywhere from
US$50,000 to US$250,000 (Krolik, 2006). By the time the United Nations
CDM Executive Board finally registers a typical small-scale CDM project
(essentially creating the CER that can be sold on the CDM markets), the
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) calculates that the project’s
The Big Picture 13
total up-front costs will account for 14–22 per cent of the net present value of its
revenue from carbon credits (Krolik, 2006). For many projects, coming up with
the start-up capital to register a project for the compliance carbon market is
prohibitively difficult.
The voluntary carbon markets, on the other hand, don’t have these sorts of
transaction costs. They can avoid ‘bottlenecks’ in the CDM methodology
approval process and get carbon financing for methodologies that aren’t
currently ‘approved’ for sale by the CDM process. For example, the Nature
Conservancy is working towards obtaining carbon financing for forest protec-
tion projects (what in Kyoto parlance is referred to as ‘avoided deforestation’), a
concept not currently approved to produce carbon credits within the CDM
process.
The innovation, flexibility and lower transaction costs of the voluntary
carbon market can benefit buyers as well as suppliers. When an organization
purchases carbon offsets to meet a public relations or branding need, creativity,
speed, cost-effectiveness and the ability to support specific types of projects
(e.g. those that also benefit local communities or biodiversity) can often be
clear and valuable benefits.
Having weighed such pros and cons, many non-profit organizations are
supportive of the voluntary carbon market because it provides individuals –
not just corporations and large organizations – with a means of participating
in the fight against climate change in a way that the compliance markets do
not. And since individuals account for most of the GHG emissions currently
being put into the atmosphere (more than 50 per cent by some counts; Biello,
2006), some environmentalists view the voluntary carbon market as an impor-
tant tool for educating the public about climate change and their potential role
in addressing the problem.
Last but not least, some sellers and buyers of carbon credits prefer the
voluntary carbon market precisely because it does not depend on regulation.
As the international political community struggles to implement an effective
climate-change framework, the voluntary carbon market has the potential to
become an active driver of change today.
VCS. According to the bank, the new service will allow buyers and sellers
to transfer voluntary carbon credits in a centralized, secure and paperless
environment. ‘We expect our collective efforts will greatly assist in the
development of this important market,’ says Karen Peetz, senior executive
vice president and head of The Bank of New York’s Corporate Trust Division
(Bank of New York, 2006).
Whatever one’s take on the long term prospects of the voluntary carbon
market, it seems clear that, in the short term, the market is evolving quickly,
creating new economic and environmental opportunities for investors, busi-
nesses, non-profits and individuals. It is therefore important to understand
how this market operates. In the next chapter, then, we will turn our attention
to addressing a basic but all-important question: how does the voluntary carbon
market really work?
References
Anderson, C. (2006) ‘California at the forefront’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.
ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Bank of New York Company (2006) ‘The Bank of New York creates global registrar and
custody service for voluntary carbon units’, Business Wire Inc.
Biello, D. (2006) ‘Eight is not enough’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.
ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Biello, D. (2006) ‘A drive to offset emissions’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.
ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Capoor, K. and Ambrosi, P. (2006) State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2006, The
World Bank, Washington, DC
Hamilton, K. (2006) ‘Navigating a nebula: Institutional use of the U.S. voluntary
carbon market,’ Masters Thesis at the Yale School of Forestry and Environmental
Studies
Hanley, M. (2006) ‘Hitting the target: NSW producers meet compliance deadline in
trading scheme’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Hawn, A. (2004) ‘Don’t wait until ‘‘day after tomorrow’’ to solve fossil fuel emissions
problem’, St. Paul Pioneer Press, Distributed by Knight Ridder, St. Paul, Minnesota
Hawn, A. (2005) ‘Horses for courses – Voluntary vs. CDM carbon projects in Mexico’,
The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Kenber, M. (2006) ‘Raising the Bar for Voluntary Environmental Credit Markets’,
Presentation at GreenT Forum New York, 2–3 May, 2006
Kenny, A. (2006) ‘The thin end of the wedge’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.
ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Krolik, T. (2006) ‘The Argentine Carbon Fund Helps Developers Dance the Dance’,
The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/
Lecocq, F. and Capoor, K. (2005) State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2005, The
World Bank, Washington D.C.
Linden, E. (2006) The Winds of Change, Simon & Schuster, New York
Pacala, S. and Socolow, R. (2004) ‘Stabilization wedges: solving the climate problem for
the next 50 years with current technologies’, Science (August 2004: pp968–972)
Point Carbon (2006), ‘Carbon 2006: towards a truly global market’. H. Hasselknippe &
K Roine eds
16 Voluntary Carbon Markets
Trexler, M. (2006) Presentation at GreenT Forum: Raising the Bar for Voluntary
Environmental Credit Markets. New York, 2–3 May
Walsh, M. (2006) Presentation at GreenT Forum: Raising the Bar for Voluntary
Environmental Credit Markets. New York, 2–3 May
Wright, C. (2006) ‘Carbon Neutrality Draws Praise, Raises Expectations for HSBC’,
The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/
References
Websites
Websites
ClimateBiz, www.climatebiz.com/
Websites
www.yosemite.epa.gov/oar/globalwarming.nsf/content/emissions.html/
Websites