Block 4
Block 4
SYSTEMS
Structure
9.0 Objectives
9.1 Introduction
9.2 The Classical Approach
9.3 Output and Employment in the Classical System
9.3.1Production Function
9.3.2Labour Demand
9.3.3Labour Supply
9.4 Equilibrium Level of Output and Employment
9.5 Aggregate Supply Function
9.6 The Keynesian Approach
9.7 Let Us Sum Up
9.8 Answers/ Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
*
9.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this Unit, you should be in a position to:
9.1 INTRODUCTION
During the 1930s the world economy was passing through severe economic crisis
– there was widespread unemployment, unintended accumulation of inventories,
and persistent decline in prices, output and income. The overall economic
atmosphere was pessimistic. This period is termed as ‘the Great Depression’,
because of the extent and duration of the downslide in global economic
environment. There have been periodic decline in output and employment in
countries; however the severity of the Great Depression is un-matched in
economic history. Prevalent economic theory around that time was neither in a
*
Dr. Kaustuva Barik, IGNOU and Dr. Nidhi Tewathia, Assistant Professor, Gargi College,
University of Delhi
109
The Closed Economy position to explain the ongoing developments nor to provide a solution to the
in the Short-run problem.
In the midst of the Great Depression, J M Keynes came up with the book,
‘The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (published in 1936)’,
which provided fresh insights to the problem. Keeping in view its radical nature
of analysis, fundamentally different explanations, and distinct remedial measures
it is often termed as ‘Keynesian Revolution.
The Keynesian ideas further developed into a vast literature during the next three
decades, which provided further insights and a new school of thought, the
Keynesian economics. It was only during the 1970s that Keynesian economics
lost its glory and gave way to a new school of thought, the New Classical
Economics, which was a revival of classical economics. In this Unit we will
discuss the salient features of classical economics and Keynesian economics.
Keynes termed all economists prior to him as ‘classical’. The classical period,
generally taken as the period before 1930, was dominated by the work of Adam
Smith (Wealth of Nations, 1776), David Ricardo (Principles of Political
Economy, 1817) and John Stuart Mill (Principles of Political Economy, 1848).
Neoclassical economists such as Alfred Marshall and A. C. Pigou extended the
classical ideas. Important features of the classical ideas are as follows:
(iii) Invisible Hand: Adam Smith introduced the concept of the ‘invisible
hand’. According to him, the economy will function well if everyone
pursues his/ her own interest. “It is not from the benevolence of the
110
butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from Classical and Keynesian
their regard to their own interest.” Individuals pursuing self-interest Systems
seem to be led by an ‘invisible hand’ to maximise the general welfare
of everyone in the economy. It is not the generosity of a producer in
selling a commodity; it is his/ her self interest. Similarly, I am not
doing a favour to the producer; I am pursuing my own interest in
buying the commodity. The philosophy of the invisible hand confined
classical economists to the analysis of the behavior of economic
agents; they failed to see any conflict between interest of economic
agents and that of the economy as a whole.
Y F L, K
where Y is the total product (TP) produced, L is the quantity of labour used in
production, and K is the stock of capital (assumed to be fixed in the short run). It
is assumed that in the short run the state of technology and capital stock cannot
be changed; thus they are constant. Output varies according to the amount of
labour employed. The change in output due to an additional unit of labour is
known as Marginal Product of Labour (MPL) and it is given by the expression
ΔY
MPL = .
ΔL
112
economists assumed that the quantity of labour employed would be dependent Classical and Keynesian
upon the demand for and supply of labour in the labour market. Systems
b TP is maximum
Point of
Inflexion
TP
Outupt
L
MPL L1 L2
Labour
MP is maximum
b
L
0 L1 L2 MPL
Labour
113
The Closed Economy 9.3.2 Labour Demand
in the Short-run
Labour is demanded because it contributes to production of goods and services;
thus it is a derived demand. If the demand for commodity A increases, then the
producer of commodity A will hire more labour. Labour as a factor of production
carries an advantage as compared to capital – it is relatively easy to change the
units of labour employed compared to capital.
W
MC
MPL
As per the condition for short run profit maximization, in perfectly competitive
W W
market, P = MC. Hence, P , or, MPL .
MPL P
W/P
MPL
a
W/P
Real Wage
L
O L1
MPL
Thus a firm will hire up to the point where the additional output obtained by
hiring one more unit of labour (MPL) is equal to the real wage (W/P) paid to
labour. Fig. 9.2 shows this condition where employment (number of labour units)
is depicted on the x-axis and real wage (W/P) is shown on the y-axis along with
MPL.
114
W Classical and Keynesian
At point ‘a’ in Fig.. 9.2 we observe that MPL . To the left of point a we Systems
P
W W
have MPL and to the right of point a, MPL . The labour demand
P P
curve is downward sloping due to the law of diminishing returns. With an
W
objective of profit maximization, the firm employs more labour when MPL
P
W
and reduces the number when MPL . The aggregation of the individual
P
firms’ demand curves for labour gives economy wide demand curve for labour.
W
Ld f
P
The negative sign (–) in the expression indicates that a higher real wage rate is
associated with a lower demand for labour.
While maximizing their utility, individuals decide on the amount of work to put
in and the amount of leisure to enjoy. It is assumed that work creates disutility
(discomfort, uneasiness, or burden) in labour and there is a general preference for
leisure to work. Economists use the term ‘leisure’ for all the activities which are
off-the-job such as eating, sleeping, spending time with friends, etc. Because of
its disutility, labour needs to be compensated for work with wage. Individuals
weigh costs and benefits of working before deciding the number of hours to
work.
In Fig. 9.3, real income is measured on the x-axis, and real income/ real wage is
measured on the y-axis. Real income is equal to real wage (W/P) multiplied by
the number of hours the person works. Each vertical intercept represents zero
leisure. In that case the real income will be [W/P × 24]. Indifference curves are
labelled as U1, U2 and U3. Points on these curves give various combinations of
income and leisure which give equal satisfaction to the workers. The slope of the
indifference curve gives the rate at which the person is willing to trade-off leisure
for income. The slope of the indifference curve implies the increase in income
the individual would have to be paid, so that he gives up a unit of leisure. The
cost of foregoing an hour of leisure is the real wage per hour, W/P.
115
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
c
C
b
Real Income
U3
a B
U2
A U1
0 L3 L2 L1 24 leisure
work hours
Ls
Real Wage
B
A
The straight-line rays starting from point 24 on the horizontal axis give the
budget lines facing the individual. The slope of these lines is real wage, W/P.
Higher real wage rate makes the budget line steeper. Three budget lines are
shown in Fig. 9.3 representing three different real wage rates. In the bottom panel
of Fig. 9.3 we plot the labour supply curve, which is upward sloping. We can say
that labour supply is a function of real wage, which is given by
W
LS f
P
116
The positive sign (+) in the above equation indicates that labour supply increases Classical and Keynesian
as real wage (W/P) increases. You should note that labour supply is determined Systems
by real wage and not money wage. Secondly, there are both ‘substitution effect’
and ‘income effect’ in the decision-making process of an individual on the
number hours (s)he would work. As wage rate increases, a person works for more
number of hours (substitution effect). Similarly, lower wage rate would
discourage the person from work. Income of an individual depends on the
number of hours (s)he works, multiplied by the wage rate. A higher wage rate
implies higher income level for individuals. Suppose, person G is willing to work
for 4 hours when wage rate is Rs. 100 per hour. When wage rate increases to Rs.
150 per hour (s)he is willing to work 6 hours a day. The first 4 hours which (s)he
was willing to work at Rs. 100 per hours now pay him Rs. 150 per hour. Thus
her/ his income increases from Rs. 400 to Rs. 900 per day! When her/ his income
increases to a very high level, (s)he may actually decrease her/ his hours of work,
and enjoy more leisure. This is similar to the ‘income effect’ in consumer
demand theory. It is observed that at a very high an individual might reduce the
work hours and increase leisure. This is a situation where the income effect is
dominant. So, at very high wage rates, the labour supply curve assumes a
negative slope and starts bending backwards towards the vertical axis.
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
2) Explain the relationship of labour with output in the short run as per
classical view.
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
117
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
9.4 EQUILIBRIUM LEVEL OF OUTPUT AND
EMPLOYMENT
So far, we have established the following relationships.
Y F L, K
W
Ld f
P
W
LS f
P
𝑊
𝑃 Ls
𝑊 E
𝑃
Real Wage
Ld
Employment
0
L0
E 𝑌 = 𝐹 (𝐾 , 𝐿)
𝑌
Output
Fig.
0 Employment
L0
118
Equilibrium condition in the labour market, i.e., Ld LS along with production Classical and Keynesian
function determines the output, employment and real wage rate in the classical Systems
system. Fig. 9.4 depicts the equilibrium in the labour market, where Y0 is output
W
level, L0 is employment level and is wage rate.
P 0
In the long run if there is a change in the capital stock, there will be a shift in the
production function (because we assumed capital input to be fixed in the
production function that we considered). Simlarly, if there is a change in
technology, the production function will shift. In case of a shift in the production
function, MPL will change, which will shift the labour demand curve.
The labour supply curve however would depend upon a different set of variables
– it will shift if there is change in the size of population and if the individuals’
preferences change due to change in the labour-leisure trade offs. In the classical
system, the levels of output and employment are dependent only on the supply-
side factors.
Let us again consider labour supply and labour demand curves. We look at Ld
and Ls as functions of money wage. We have an upward sloping labour supply
curve, which is a function of money wage (W), assuming a given price level P1.
Let us look at Fig. 9.5. We observe that different price levels give different
labour supply curves. Each price level would mean, for a given money wage, a
different real wage – hence a different labour supply curve.
Thus if money wage rate is constant, change in price level would result in a shift
in the labour supply curve. As prices rise, the LS curve shifts to the right. So, as
prices go up and the money wage does not increase, the individual is left with a
lower real wage and would like to reduce the amount of working hours. This can
be observed from Fig. 9.5. As price level increases from P1 to 2P1 and 3P1; and
the money wage increases from W1 to 2W1 and 3W1, the real wage remains
unchanged.
W1 2W1 3W1
P 2P 3P
1 1 1
This leads to the fact that employment will remain the same at L1.
119
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
𝑊
Ls(P1)
s
L (2P1)
Ls(3P1)
3𝑊
Money Wage
2𝑊
Ld(P1) Ld(3P1)
Ld(2P1)
Labour
0
L L1 L2
W
L =f
P
Real Wage
𝑊
𝑃
W
L =f
P
Labour
0
L1
120
Thus, proportional increases (or decreases) in both money wage and the price Classical and Keynesian
W Systems
level leave the labour supply unchanged. Looking at the demand side, MPL
P
W = MPL × P
Suppose money wage remains unchanged at W and price level increases from P1
to 2P1 and then to 3P1 there is a decline in real wage more labour is demanded.
Proportional increase in the money wage and the price level however will leave
the labour demand unchanged at L1.
The firm takes money wage as given while deciding its level of output. This, in
turn, indicates the amount of labour to hire. As there are many firms, one firm’s
decision will not have any effect on the money wage level. As money wage is
fixed, the output supply curve for the firm is positively sloped. Higher prices lead
to more output as the real wage declines. At the economy level, however we
cannot assume money wage rate to be fixed. Money wage rate must adjust in
order to maintain the equilibrium between supply of and demand for labour. We
observe from Fig. 9.5 that initial levels are: price level (P1), money wages (W1),
employment (L1), and output (Y1). If P1 increases to 2P1 and wage remains at W1,
the labour demand would increase to L2. Higher prices will lead to lower real
wage, so firms will demand more labour – it will result in expansion of output
and employment. At 2P1, labour supply curve shifts to LS(2P1). Therefore, the
supply of labour at W1 would be only L2ʹ. There is an excess demand for labour
which is equal to (L2 – L2ʹ) and hence the money wage will rise. Firms which do
not increase the money wage experience a decline in availability of losing on
labour. Wages will rise till equilibrium is achieved again. It happens at 2W 1 in
Fig. 9.5. The real wage rate is restored at initial level; employment level also is
back at the initial level. Thus, the output supplied at a higher price, i.e., 2P1 is
equal to Y1.
P YS
Aggregate
Price Level
3P1
2P1
P1
Y
Y1
121
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run Similarly, when price level reaches 3P1, wages rise to 3W1, and output remains at
Y1. Hence, the aggregate supply curve is vertical (Fig. 9.6). Higher prices will be
result in higher output only if they are not accompanied with higher money
wages.
In classical view, supply-side factors are more important than the demand-side
factors. According to Say’s law of market, supply creates its own demand.
Further, as price and wage rate are flexible, equilibrium is attained always. There
is no scope for unemployment and output is always at full employment level. As
supply and demand forces lead to an optimum condition for the economy, there is
no need for government intervention. The Great Depression, however, belied
these beliefs. During the 1930s there was widespread unemployment, poverty,
and insecurity among households. At this point, Keynes provided an altogether
different insight into the problems confronting major economies. Some of the
salient features of Keynesian economics are presented below.
a) Demand Creates its Supply: Just opposite to the classical view, Keynes
proposed that demand for a product encourages producers to come up
with products demanded. If there is idle capacity in the economy, output
will increase if aggregate demand increases.
b) Rigidities in Prices and Wage Rate: Prices and wage rate are not
flexible as suggested by classical economists. Suppliers have monopoly
power; perfectly competitive markets do not exist. As we receive our
wages and salaries in nominal terms, we resist downward movements in
wages and salaries. There are several contracts which do not allow
immediate revision in prices and wages. Moreover, adjustments in prices
and wage rate are staggered over a period of time; adjustments are not
instantaneous.
122
d) Government Intervention: If aggregate demand is falling short of Classical and Keynesian
aggregate supply, in Keynesian system the government should increase its Systems
spending. Thus in the Keynesian system government has an active and
important role in the economy. If there is large scale unemployment in the
economy, government should create jobs through investments in
productive activities. If inflation is high, government should adhere to
restrictive policies to reduce the level of aggregate demand.
1) Explain the relationship between real wage, money wage and labour
employment.
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................
3) Bring out the major differences between Classical and Keynesian models.
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
..............................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................................
123
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
9.7 LET US SUM UP
In this Unit we discussed the salient features of classical and Keynesian systems.
The classical economists stressed on the theory of ‘invisible hand’ and advocated
that price level and wage rate should be decided by market forces. Classical
economists suggested that there should be no government intervention in
determination of output, employment, prices and wage rate. According to them,
the economy adjusts to any kind of disturbance through movement of prices and
wage rate, and equilibrium is attained again quickly. The aggregate supply curve
is vertical, reducing the role of aggregate demand to minimum.
1) Go through Section 9.4 and Fig. 9.5. Discuss the role of change in the price
level in terms of real wage and money wage.
2) Refer to Fig. 9.6. Output supplied at a higher price is the same as that
supplied at a lower price.
3) Refer to Sections 9.2 and 9.6.
124
UNIT 10 KEYNESIAN MODEL OF INCOME
DETERMINATION*
Structure
10.0 Objectives
10.1 Introduction
10.2 Equilibrium and Aggregate Demand
10.3 Consumption Function
10.3.1 Relationship between Consumption and Aggregate Demand
10.3.2 Formula for Equilibrium Output
10.4 Multiplier
10.4.1 Concept of Multiplier
10.4.2 Investment Multiplier
10.4.3 Limitations of Multiplier
10.5 Let Us Sum Up
10.6 Answers/Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
10.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this Unit, you should be in a position to
define consumption function and saving function;
explain the concept of multiplier and its operations;
explain the relationship between marginal propensity to consume and
aggregate demand;
calculate the value of investment multiplier; and
explain the concept of Keynesian Cross in a diagram.
10.1 INTRODUCTION
As pointed out in Unit 2, output, income and expenditure are three different ways
of measuring the level of economic activity in an economy. Whatever method we
adopt for measurement, we reach the same level. In this Unit we will discuss
another concept, that is, the equilibrium level of output. At the equilibrium level,
the demand for and supply of output are equal. We assume that prices are fixed
and firms are willing to sell any amount of output at the given level of prices.
To develop the concept of aggregate demand, assuming constant prices is very
important. On supply side, Keynes takes the aggregate supply curve to be
horizontal. We will also discuss the consumption function, factors responsible for
deciding aggregate demand and multiplier.
*
Dr. Nidhi Tewathia, Assistant Professor, Gargi College, University of Delhi
125
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
10.2 EQUILIBRIUM AND AGGREGATE DEMAND
We already know that the total demand for goods and services is known as
‘aggregate demand’. The factors which together make aggregate demand (AD)
are consumption (C), investment (I), government expenditure (G), and net
exports (NX).
AD = C + I + G + NX
In case we assume the aggregate demand for goods and services to be constant,
we get a horizontal AD curve. It means that AD is independent of income and
output levels. In Fig. 10.1, output level (representing aggregate supply) is
presented on the x-axis while aggregate demand is shown on the y-axis. A 45
line shows equality between the variables shown on x-axis and y-axis, i.e., at any
point on this 45 line, AD = Y. In other words, this line represents the locus of
equilibrium points where aggregate demand is equal to the output level.
AD AD= Y
E
AD
45 Y
O Y1
In case the AD curve is horizontal, we can say that the equilibrium exists at point
E where AD = Y. No forces are causing any change at point E. Equilibrium level
of output is Y1. In case firms produce to the left of Y1, aggregate supply is less
than aggregate demand, and there is run down of exiting inventories. On the other
hand, if firms produce to the right of Y1, there is excess supply (aggregate supply
is more than aggregate demand) and inventories will increase. In both the cases,
there will be a movement towards Y1. At E, the firms are selling exactly what
people demand. In case of a deviation from Y1, we have positive or negative
unplanned inventory investment.
UI = Y – AD
When Y > AD, we find that UI is positive, i.e., there is an addition to the stock of
inventory. When Y < AD, we find that UI is negative, i.e., the existing inventory
is to be used in order to meet the aggregate demand. It is also called unplanned
inventory disinvestment. This leads us to the equilibrium condition Y = AD.
C = C + cY
You should note that C is the intercept, i.e., the level of consumption when
income is zero. For each rupee increase in income, the level of consumption
increases by c. This is the slope of the consumption function. It is also known as
marginal propensity to consume (mpc). You should note that mpc will lie
between zero and one, which indicates that when mpc = 0, consumption is not
rising due to rise in income and when mpc = 1 the consumption is rising by the
same amount as the rise in income. In other words, it means if c = 0, then C = C .
Fig. 10.2 shows the consumption function. The mpc is positive and hence the
curve is upward sloping.
Consumption C = C + cY
C
Y
O Income level
We can find out the level of saving in the economy from the consumption
function. If the fraction c is consumed then the remaining portion i.e., (1 – c)
should be saved because, by assumption, income is either consumed or saved.
SY–C
S Y– C – cY
127
The Closed Economy S = – C + (1– c)Y
in the Short-run
Saving is also an increasing function of income with the slope (1 – c). The
marginal propensity to save (mps) in the case of saving function is given by
mps = (1 – c) = s
S = S + sY
Y=C+S
Y C S
Y Y Y
In the above equation, the ratio of consumption to income (C/Y) is called
average propensity to consume (APC). Similarly the ratio of saving to income
(S/Y) is called average propensity to save (APS). Thus, we can re-write the
above equation as
APC + APS = 1
Assuming that the government sector and the foreign sector are absent, we are
left with consumption and investment as the two components of aggregate
demand.
AD = C + I
C + cY + I = AD
AD = C I + cY
AD = 𝐴̅ + cY
where I is planned investment, which is taken as fixed. You should note that
C I is mentioned as 𝐴̅ in the above equation, where 𝐴̅ is the autonomous
expenditure (i.e., independent of income level). The aggregate demand (AD)
curve is obtained by vertically adding I investment to the consumption curve.
As investment is autonomous, it does not affect the slope of the consumption
function. Looking at Fig. 10.3, we get an idea of the AD curve. Equilibrium takes
place at point E with equilibrium level of output at Y0 and equilibrium aggregate
demand at AD0. Slope of AD curve is c because of which AD curve is a parallel
version of the consumption curve.
128
Keynesian Model of
AD AD= Y Income Determination
AD = A + cY
E
AD0 C = C + cY
𝐴̅
C
45 Y
O Y0
Income and Output
On the left of Y0 and on the right of Y0, AD is not equal to Y, i.e., economy
experiences disequilibrium. In such cases, as discussed earlier, either the
inventory is built up or it is run down. Equilibrium is maintained at the output
level where AD = Y. As the 45 line crosses AD curve, we call it ‘Keynesian
Cross’.
Y = A + cY
Y – cY = A
Y (1 – c) = A
1
Equilibrium level of output and income Y0, will be equal to Y0 = A
1- c
AD AD= Y
AD2
E
AD1
A
Y
O Y0 Y 1
Income and Output
129
The Closed Economy We observe that the mpc is in the denominator, with a negative sign. This means
in the Short-run that Y and c are positively related. And clearly, Y and A are also positively
related. Given the intercept, a steeper aggregate demand i.e. higher mpc will lead
to a higher income and output level (Fig. 10.4).
AD AD= Y
AD2
E AD1
A2
A1
Y
O Y0 Y1
Income and Output
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
130
3) What is the relationship between mpc and the AD curve? Keynesian Model of
Income Determination
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
10.4 MULTIPLIER
Suppose output increases by Re.1 to match the rise in autonomous spending. This
rise in output and income in turn gives rise to induced spending as consumption
rises as a result of rise in income. This induced expenditure would be (c . A ).
Production increases further to meet this induced expenditure. By now the output
and income have increased by ( A + c. A ), that is., by (1 + c) A . This will
further give rise to induced expenditure and so on.
131
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
Round Increase in Increase in Total increase in income
demand this production this
round round
1 A A A
2. c A c A A + c A = (1+c) A
3. c.c A c. c A = c2 A A + c A + c2 A = (1+c
+c2) A
- - - -
- - - -
- - - 1
A
1- c
As 0 < c < 1, c2 < c and c3 < c2, the induced expenditure keeps becoming smaller
as the number of rounds progress.
AD = A + c A + c2 A .............
= A (1 + c + c2 + ....) = A ( )
1
AD A Y0
1- c
You should note that here we are dealing with a two sector closed economy
comprising households and firms; there is neither government nor foreign trade.
When we include the government and foreign trade, the above formula will
change.
Examples:
Let us now find out the value of the multiplier for various value of marginal
propensity to consume, given by c.
1
c = 0.5 = =2
1 0.5
1
c = 0.4 = = 1.66
1 0.4
132
1 Keynesian Model of
c = 0.25 = = 1.33 Income Determination
1 0.25
1
c = 0.6 = = 2.5
1 0.6
AD AD = Y
AD’
E’ ∆𝐴 AD
𝐴̅
E
𝐴̅
Y
O Y0 Y1 Income and Output
AD = A + cY0
133
The Closed Economy Or, (1 – c) Y0 = A
in the Short-run
1
Or, Y0 = A .
1 c
Y0 = 𝐼 ̅
For example, if c = 0.2 and I = Rs. 50 crore, let us find out the change in the
equilibrium level of income and output.
1
Y0 = × 50 crore
1 0.2
50
= crore
0.8
The equilibrium level of income (Y0) was initially Rs. 120 crore. Now after an
increase in autonomous investment of Rs 50 crore, the equilibrium level of
income reaches to Rs. 182.5 crore (Rs 120 crore+ Rs. 62.5 crore). An increase of
Rs. 50 crore in investment leads to an increase of Rs. 62.5 crore in the output. If
Y0 1
we calculate the investment multiplier, it will be = 1.25.
I 1- c
In the discussion above, we saw that income increases much more than the initial
investment because of the ‘multiplier’. There are certain limitations to the
multiplier however.
(a) As you know, aggregate output of an economy cannot be more than the
full employment output level. Thus output, income and employment can
expand till the economy has unutilized resources.
(d) It is assumed that there is no time lag between income received, and
expenditure incurred. Sometimes there is a time lag (interval) between the
receipt of income and the spending of it, and similarly between the
spending and its re-appearance as income. If the time lag is long, there is
a decrease in the level of expenditure on consumption in subsequent
periods. This will lead to a smaller value of multiplier.
(e) It is assumed that there is idle production capacity in the economy and
there is no increase in prices due to increase in aggregate demand. If the
price level rises, consumption may be lower, and value of the multiplier
will be affected.
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
136
UNIT 11 FISCAL POLICY IN KEYNESIAN
MODEL*
Structure
11.0 Objectives
11.1 Introduction
11.2 The Government Sector
11.2.1 Government Spending and the Multiplier
11.2.2 Automatic Stabilizers
11.2.3 Effect of Change in Government Spending and Tax Rate
11.3 Government Budget
11.4 Let Us Sum Up
11.5 Key Words
11.6 Some Useful Books
11.8 Answers/Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
11.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this Unit, you should be in a position to
11.1 INTRODUCTION
This Unit is an extension of the previous one. In this Unit we introduce the
government sector in the Keynesian model. We extend our two-sector model to a
three sector model; thus there are three economic agents, viz., households, firms
and government. Thus AD = C + I + G.
*
Dr. Nidhi Tewathia, Assistant Professor, Gargi College, University of Delhi
The Closed Economy revenue by imposing taxes. Government also spends money for the welfare of
in the Short-run
people. Sometimes, government needs to borrow when its revenues are less than
expenditure. Such a situation is called budget deficit. When revenue exceeds
government expenditure, it is a situation of budget surplus. Government
exercises fiscal policy by varying the tax rate or changing the level of
government expenditure. The objective of government intervention is to
smoothen the operation of the economy.
As government sector collects tax from individuals, there may be certain changes
in the consumption function (C = C + cY). Consumption is dependent upon
disposable income (YD) instead of total income. We know that
YD = Y – TA
where Y is the aggregate income and TA is the tax. Another component which
finds its way in the disposable income is government transfers (TR) such as
subsidies, pensions, scholarships, etc. These are an addition to the individual’s
income (Y) but there is no corresponding output. So,
YD = (Y – TA + TR) …(11.2)
So, G= G
TR = TR
TA = tY
138
Now the consumption function can be written as: Fiscal Policy in
Keynesian Model
C = C + c(Y + TR – tY)
= C + c TR + c(1 – t)Y …(11.4)
AD = [ C + c TR + I + G ] + c(1 – t)Y
We have taken all the autonomous terms together and denote it by A . As pointed
out earlier, income and output levels get affected with the introduction of the
government sector. We will see the change algebraically as well as with the help
of a diagram. As you know from the previous Unit, equilibrium is attained when
Y = AD.
Thus, by substituting values from equation (13.5), we obtain
𝑌 = 𝐴̅ + 𝑐 (1 − 𝑡)𝑌
Or, Y – [c(1 – t)Y] = A
Or, Y – (c –ct)Y = A
Or, Y (1 – c + ct) = A
A
This gives us Y … (11.6)
1 c ct
In Fig. 11.1 we present two AD curves; AD1 shows absence of government sector
and AD2 in the presence of government sector. Thus AD2 includes taxes and
transfers. We observe that AD2 is flatter than AD1 and has a higher y-intercept
than AD1. It is because the slope of AD2 is c(1– t) instead of c. The vertical
intercept includes
(c TR G ) in addition to C I , the vertical intercept of AD1.
139
The Closed Economy Thus 𝐴 = 𝐶̅ + 𝐼 ,̅ and 𝐴 = 𝐶̅ + 𝐼 ̅ + 𝑐𝑇𝑅 + 𝐺̅
in the Short-run
AD
AD1
AD2
A2
A1
Y
Income and Output
Fig. 11.2 shows the effect of government sector’s presence on equilibrium levels
of income and output. We consider two cases. In the first case, when the
government sector is not present, equilibrium takes place at point E1 where the
45 line intersects AD1.
AD AD= Y
AD1
AD2
AD2
A
AD1
E1
A
Y
Y1 Y2
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
.......................................................................................................................
ΔY 1 1
or
Δ A 1 c ct 1 c(1 t)
141
The Closed Economy As seen in the previous Unit, in the absence of the government sector, the
in the Short-run
1
multiplier is . We see that the government purchases of goods and services
1 c
make a substantial difference in the economy. The value of the multiplier is
reduced. Let us denote the government multiplier as G . So, we can say that G <
. Let us explain with the help of an example.
Thus we observe that the value of the multipler gets reduced in the presence of
the government sector.
Let us now consider the changes in fiscal policy. Fiscal Policy tools are
government spending, transfers and tax rate. Government changes the magnitude
of these tools as per the situation of the economy.
142
Fiscal Policy in
Let us consider the diagrammatic representation of fiscal policy initiative. Initial Keynesian Model
level of equilibrium output is Y0 as shown in Fig. 11.3. Autonomous spending
i.e., G changes, hence A 0 shifts up to A1 and AD0 shifts parallel upwards to
AD1. As per the equilibrium condition, the equilibrium income and output
becomes Y1 from Y0. Is the increase in income same as increase in autonomous
spending? By how much has the income expanded?
AD AD= Y
AD1
E1 } ∆G
A AD0
E0
A
Y
Y0 Y1
1
ΔY0 G
1 c(1 t)
= G. G
The other tool, i.e., income tax, is generally reduced so that individuals get higher
disposable income. Fig. 11.4 shows the effects of reduction in income tax rate. It
means that there is a decrease in ‘t’, which in turn increases the slope of the AD
curve. Initial equilibrium income is Y0, i.e., intersection between AD0 and the 45
line. As AD0 swivels out to AD1, the new equilibrium occurs at E1 which gives us
the new equilibrium level of output as Y1. As income tax rate decreases, the
equilibrium income and output increases. To find out the change in equilibrium
143
The Closed Economy income, we need to equate the change in income to the change in AD. There are
in the Short-run
two components of change in AD, namely,
AD AD= Y
AD1
E1
AD0
A E0
Y
Y0 Y1
1
Y0 .A
1 c ct
So,
ΔY0 c
.A
Δt 1 c ct 2
and A Y0 1 c ct
ΔY0 c
.Y 1 c ct
Δt 1 c ct 2 0
144
ΔY0 cY0 Fiscal Policy in
Δt 1 c ct Keynesian Model
cy 0
or Y0 .t
1 c ct
cy 0
where 1 c ct is the income tax multiplier, which is normally denoted by t.
ΔY0 c
α TR
ΔTR 1 c ct
c
Y0 . TR
1 c ct
because
cTR A
Y0
1 c ct
Budget is a term which is very important for every individual. The households
are interested in knowing how much of income they will receive and what is their
expenditure for a given time period.
Similarly, the government needs to find out its sources of revenues and areas
where it needs to spend. Hence, the government budget is of great importance. In
this context, we will use the term budget to represent government budget. Budget
is a record of revenues and expenditure. If government is experiencing a budget
deficit, it means government is spending more than earning. In case it
experiences a budget surplus, then the government spending is less than the
revenue. Generally, budget deficit is faced by majority of the governments. .
Algebraically,
where TA = tY
It is common knowledge that when income level is low, the revenue also
becomes low, which lead to budget deficit and vice versa. Fig. 11.5 shows that
the sum of G and TR exceeds tY when income levels are low and vice-versa.
BS
BS = tY – G – TR
Budget Surplus
O Y
Y0
– ( G + TR )
The income level Y0 shows no deficit and no surplus. On the left of Y0,
government runs in deficit and on the right of Y0, surplus exists. This is because,
at high income level, the government tax receipts are large. If the income does
not increase due to fiscal policy tools, government deficit can still decrease. An
increase in the investment (I) will lead to an increase in Y which in turns raises
the tax receipts and that is how the budget deficit decreases. It follows that,
during the time of recession, budget deficits are observed.
It seems logical to think that an increase in the government spending G would
decrease the budget surplus (BS), however it does not hold true always. Because
increase G has a multiplier effect on the equilibrium level of income and output,
this leads to higher tax receipts. There is a possibility that, the negative effect of
such rising G is compensated by the positive effect of rising tax receipts, which
does not reduce the budget surplus. Let us see, algebraically, how the increased
government spending reduces the budget surplus.
t
= 1 Δ G
1 c ct
or
t
= 1 ΔG
1 c(1 t)
t 1 c(1 t)
= ΔG
1 c(1 t)
1 t c(1 t)
= ΔG
1 c(1 t)
1 t c(1 t)
= ΔG
1 c(1 t)
1 t (1 c)
= ΔG
1 c(1 t)
Now, let us consider a numerical example, where c = 0.8, t = 0.25 and G = Re.1
= Rs. – 0.375.
147
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run
So a one rupee increase in government spending reduces the government surplus
by Rs. 0.375. Similarly, the tax hike will lead to a positive effect on the budget
surplus.
If the government raises the tax rate and government purchases by the same
amount, then what will be impact on the budget surplus? The response will
include the explanation of a concept called ‘balanced budget multiplier’. The
equilibrium budget will be unchanged as the multiplier will be equal to 1.
1 1
G = and or ΔY0 G
1 c 1 c
c
T =
1 c
1 -c
or ΔY0 ( c * T ) T
1 c 1 c
Now change in income due to both the changes in government expenditure and
tax rate is:
Y = G.G + T.T
Y = G.G + T.G (as G = T)
Y = (G+T)G
1 c
Y = ΔG
1 c 1 c
1 c
Y = ΔG
1 c
Y = G
149
The Closed Economy
in the Short-run 11.4 LET US SUM UP
In this Unit we introduced the government sector into the Keynesian model and
re-defined the aggregate demand. As the government sector is included, the fiscal
policy tools like taxes, transfers and government spending are exercised by the
government. The government multiplier and the tax multiplier were found to be
smaller than the investment multiplier. Due to automatic stabilizers, the volatility
in the economy is reduced. Subsequently, we understood the concept of
government budget. Government borrows at the time of deficit which makes it
difficult for the private firms to arrange funds. As government spending
increases, the budget will go in deficit. At the same time, however, equilibrium
output increases, which in turn increases the tax receipts. The balanced budget
multiplier shows how the output increases by the same amount as the government
spending increases.
1) C = C + c(Y – TR + tY)
= C + c TR + c(1 – t)Y
1 1
2)
1 c ct 1 0.6 0.6(0.12)
150