Aikman Et Al. (2019) - Macropru Survey
Aikman Et Al. (2019) - Macropru Survey
Aikman Et Al. (2019) - Macropru Survey
A
key response of official sectors around the world to the financial and
economic crises of ten years ago has been the formation of financial stability
committees. Such committees now exist in over 40 countries worldwide
(Edge and Liang 2017). The remits of these committees are “macroprudential.”
Macroprudential policy focuses on potential system-wide risks and amplification
mechanisms, complementing the detailed firm-specific risk assessments of micro-
prudential regulators. In addition, it has the explicit objective to ensure that the
financial system does not amplify a downturn in the real economy—for example,
by being forced to cut back on the supply of credit in a stress (Borio 2003; in this
journal, Hanson, Kashyap, and Stein 2011).
This paper asks whether macroprudential authorities, as they have been
designed over the past decade, could prevent—or materially dampen—a rerun of
the last crisis. To be clear at the outset, macroprudential regulation does not seek to
■ David Aikman is Technical Head of the Macroprudential Strategy and Support Division,
Bank of England, London, United Kingdom. Jonathan Bridges is a Senior Economist, Macro-
prudential Strategy and Support Division, Bank of England, London, United Kingdom. Anil
Kashyap is the Edward Eagle Brown Professor of Economics and Finance at the University
of Chicago Booth School of Business, Chicago, Illinois. Since 2016, he has been a Member of
the Financial Policy Committee, Bank of England. He is also a Research Associate, National
Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, and a Research Fellow, Centre for
Economic Policy Research, London, England. Caspar Siegert is a Senior Economist, Macro-
prudential Strategy and Support Division, Bank of England, London, United Kingdom.
Kashyap is the corresponding author at [email protected].
†
For supplementary materials such as appendices, datasets, and author disclosure statements, see the
article page at
https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.33.1.107 doi=10.1257/jep.33.1.107
108 Journal of Economic Perspectives
eliminate recessions. Instead, it is aimed at ensuring that the financial system does
not create shocks that trigger recessions or amplify other shocks to make recessions
materially worse. With this in mind, the first part of our paper provides an account
of the amplifying factors that made the last crisis so severe. Our diagnosis centers
on two overlapping but distinct vulnerabilities: the increase in leverage and short-
term funding at financial intermediaries, and the build-up in indebtedness in the
household sector. These factors, we argue, can account for around two-thirds to
three-quarters of the fall in US GDP that followed the financial crisis. We describe
and calibrate the policy interventions required to address these vulnerabilities.
We then contrast how well-equipped two prominent macroprudential regulators
are to make these interventions. We argue that the US Financial Stability Oversight
Council would likely make little difference were we to experience a rerun of the
factors that caused the last crisis. It has no macroprudential levers under its direct
control, and not all of its members have mandates to protect financial stability. A
macroprudential regulator modeled on the UK’s Financial Policy Committee stands
a better chance because it has many of the necessary powers. But spotting build-ups
in vulnerabilities in real-time is challenging. And given the role played by loosely
regulated nonbank financial institutions prior to the last crisis—and the continuing
evolution of the financial system—a successful macroprudential intervention would
likely require political backing to be nimble in widening the perimeter of regulation
to capture such institutions. More generally, such a regulator would have to be fairly
aggressive in using its powers. Given the novelty of these powers, there is no clear
evidence on whether such forceful interventions would be realistic were risks to
escalate again. Our conclusion distils some key challenges and priorities for the
development of a successful macroprudential framework.
The test we pose is really not very tough. Today’s macroprudential frameworks
were created in response to the scenario we are revisiting, whereas the challenges
facing macroprudential regulators in the future will likely be new. But while our
essay explores how today’s macroprudential regimes might respond if vulnerabili-
ties similar to those that caused the last crisis were to reoccur, we also invite readers
to use this thought-experiment to consider how macroprudential committees might
respond if other “resilience gaps” opened up in the future.
Table 1
Size and Structure of the Leveraged Financial System
2001:Q4 2007:Q4
Commercial banks 6,552 11.0 6.6% 26.5% 11,182 9.8 4.6% 33.2%
of which: large institutions 2,291 12.2 6.7% 32.9% 5,422 11.8 4.6% 37.5%
Savings institutions 1,317 11.6 3.0% 18.2% 1,852 9.1 2.3% 22.6%
Broker-dealers 2,376 28 2.4% 57.3% 4,686 45 0.4% 63.4%
Government-sponsored 1,417 42.3 0.2% 1,677 23.7 0.7%
enterprises
Total 11,662 19,397
Source: Financial Accounts of the United States; Call Reports; FDIC; Adrian, Fleming, Shachar, and Vogt
(2017); and Annual Reports of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Note: “Leverage” is defined as total assets divided by (book) equity. “Liquid assets” refers to the ratio of
cash and Treasury securities to total assets. For brokers, “short-term funding” refers to repo funding
relative to total assets. For deposit-takers, it refers to (estimated) uninsured domestic deposits and
foreign deposits relative to total assets. While deposits are typically short-term liabilities, many types
of deposits, including insured deposits in particular, are “behaviorally stable” and were not withdrawn
during the crisis (Martin, Puri, and Ufier 2018). “Large commercial banks” are defined as banks with at
least $150 billion in total assets. For 2007, this is adjusted using the Consumer Price Index ($180 billion).
Government-sponsored enterprises include Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Our thesis is that these two factors amplified the initial losses that occurred
when house prices fell. The fragilities in the financial system meant that lenders had
to cut back lending as they struggled to absorb losses, which led to a credit crunch
that reduced investment and employment. As households also struggled to deal
with excessive debt, they cut spending, amplifying the downturn further.
1
Total repo liabilities for all types of institutions recorded in the Financial Accounts of the US data for
end-2001 and 2007 were $2.2 trillion and $4.8 trillion, respectively. None of these numbers were readily
available in the run-up to the crisis, as broker-dealers repo liabilities were only reported on a netted basis
(Eichner, Kohn, and Palumbo 2013; Holmquist and Gallin 2014).
Would Macroprudential Regulation Have Prevented the Last Crisis? 111
Figure 1
Reliance on Short-Term Funding
($ billions)
4,500
4,000
Money market funds
3,500
3,000
Repo liabilities of broker-dealers
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
Commercial paper
500
0
19
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
19 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
20 Q1
80
82
84
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
16
Q
1
Source: March 2018 release of the Financial Accounts of the United States, based on Adrian, de
Fontnouvelle, Yang, and Zlate (2017). The size of money-market funds is measured as outstanding
money market fund shares (liabilities) in table L.121. Commercial paper refers to commercial paper
(liabilities) issued by any sector (table L.2019), which includes asset-backed commercial paper. Repo
liabilities of broker-dealers are based on security repurchase agreements (liabilities) in table L.130.
Figure 2
Mortgage Debt and House Prices
(annual percentage change)
15
Mortgage debt growth
10
Percent (annual)
0
−5
−15
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
Source: Financial Accounts of the United States and S&P Case-Shiller US National Home Price Index.
also extracted housing equity by taking out additional debt. Mian and Sufi (2011)
estimate that existing homeowners borrowed $0.25 on average for every $1 increase
in home-equity value during the housing boom, enough to account for over half of
the increase in debt for homeowners between 2002 and 2006.
Second, there were clear signs in the years before the financial crisis that lending
standards were being loosened and borrower quality was deteriorating. The Federal
Reserve Board’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices
reported easing standards between 2004Q1 and 2006Q3. The expansion of credit to
the most risky borrowers was particularly pronounced. For example, according to the
Federal Reserve’s Survey of Consumer Finances, the share of the stock of mortgagors
with debt of over four times their income more than doubled between 2001 and 2007
from 6 percent to 13 percent. The number of new subprime mortgages nearly doubled
between 2003 and 2005, 80 percent of which were made with short-term “teaser” interest
rates (in this journal, Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund 2009). “Near-prime” mortgages also
increased rapidly. The private-label securitization market, in which these mortgages
were bundled into tranched financial securities and resold, was an important driver of
these frothy credit supply conditions (Keys, Mukherjee, Seru, and Vig 2010).
In summary, the years running up to the Great Recession saw an unprece-
dented surge in US household debt. That boom was accompanied and reinforced
by soaring property prices. Aggressive credit supply expansion, compounded by
financial innovation, provided the undercurrent for an unsustainable cycle. House-
hold balance sheets became increasingly vulnerable to a shock as more credit was
extended to highly indebted households.
David Aikman, Jonathan Bridges, Anil Kashyap, and Caspar Siegert 113
We start this section by asking whether it was possible to spot the vulnerabilities
in both the financial system and in household balance sheets documented above in
real time. We then consider the policies a macroprudential regulator could intro-
duce in response. In the next section, we discuss the institutional frictions that actual
macroprudential regulators would face in implementing such policies in practice.
Table 2
Financial Stability Terms Appearing in Discussions of the Federal Open Market
Committee
General
“Financial stability” 0 1 2 9 5 9 13
Financial System:
“Bank” 502 429 449 302 284 309 1,024
“Capital”/“Leverage” 454 308 340 208 183 177 402
“Shadow”/“Broker”/“Money market” 17 21 40 10 17 28 59
“Fund”/“Liquid”/“Repo” 1,226 962 1,150 1,058 932 1,110 1,779
“Commercial paper”/“Securitization” 23 22 15 3 14 2 133
Housing Market
“House price” 2 23 4 41 160 85 83
“Bubble” 6 15 14 19 114 4 8
“Loan”/“Lend”/“Debt”/“Credit”/“Borrow” 413 442 452 269 409 251 1,563
“Mortgage” 84 100 96 67 176 118 481
“Subprime” 0 3 1 0 8 15 314
“LTV”/“Heloc”/“Teaser”/“Alt-A” 2 1 1 0 40 0 45
Note: For each year, transcripts of the eight FOMC meetings and any Conference Calls were searched. All
transcripts available here: https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomc_historical_year.htm. A
simple count of all words containing the stem words listed in the table above was conducted.
2
Analysis of “GDP-at-risk” and its link to financial indicators is one promising avenue here—see for
example Adrian, Boyarchenko, and Giannone (2016), IMF (2018b), and Aikman et al. (2018).
116 Journal of Economic Perspectives
should be calibrated with some built-in “slack” to account for the inherent difficulty
of risk assessment, particularly in real time.
3
The 15 bank holding companies and broker-dealers that received the largest injections in the Troubled
Asset Relief Program (TARP) were Citigroup, Bank of America, JP Morgan Chase, Wells Fargo, Goldman
Sachs, Morgan Stanley, PNC Financial Services Group, U.S. Bancorp, SunTrust, Capital One Financial,
Regions Financial Corporation, Fifth Third Bancorp, BB&T, Bank of New York Mellon, and Key Corp. The
estimates we report in the text do not include capital provided by this program to other, smaller banks.
4
This number is estimated using published accounts and an average risk-weight of 67.5 percent (based
on the New York Fed Quarterly Trends for Consolidated U.S. Banking Organizations). This total includes
the assets of firms that did not themselves receive TARP assistance, but that in the course of 2008 were
acquired by one of the 15 TARP-recipients on which we focus. These acquired firms include Countrywide
Financial, Merrill Lynch, Wachovia, Bear Stearns, Washington Mutual, and National City Corp.
David Aikman, Jonathan Bridges, Anil Kashyap, and Caspar Siegert 117
Table 3
Countercyclical Capital Buffer Rate (CCyB) That Would Have Been Necessary to
Avoid the Troubled Asset Relief Program
Calculation
Source: US Treasury, Published Accounts; New York Fed Quarterly Trends for Consolidated US Banking
Organizations; Financial Accounts of the United States; Avraham et al. (2012).
Note: For variant 2, we assume that banks balance sheets had grown by 7 percent rather than 1 percent
per year over two consecutive years. This is in line with the difference in the commercial bank credit
growth rate between the 20 years before the crisis and the crisis (Q4 2007 to Q4 2009).
an increase in the US countercyclical capital buffer rate will not pass through one-
for-one into their capital requirements. Using these parameters and the calculations
in Table 3, we estimate that a countercyclical capital buffer of 3 percent would have
provided an equivalent level of resilience as the $200 billion TARP injection. Had a
countercyclical capital buffer of 3 percent been built-up in the run-up to the crisis,
it would have, in effect, brought the capital raising that ultimately proved necessary
forward in time, substituting public provision of capital for private sector resources.
The approach above does not account for the capital that banks raised privately
after the results of the stress tests through the Supervisory Capital Assessment
Program were published in May 2009. Banks had six months to raise any required
capital in private markets, with an explicit backstop option to obtain capital from the
US Treasury if necessary. The banks in our sample raised approximately $70 billion
of capital in order to meet these requirements and did not turn to additional
government funding. If this $70 billion is added to the $200 billion of TARP, our
thought experiment suggests a countercyclical capital buffer of around 4.2 percent
would have been required to bring forward the public and private capital raising
that occurred during the heights of the crisis.
While TARP significantly reduced stress in the banking system, it was not
fully sufficient to restart the provision of credit to the economy.5 Thus, a second
5
Chavaz and Rose (forthcoming) show that the effect of TARP on the provision of mortgage credit differed
across regional markets and that TARP recipients reduced mortgage lending in the average county.
118 Journal of Economic Perspectives
s ensitivity check is to estimate what size of the countercyclical capital buffer would
have allowed banks to continue lending in line with historical credit growth rates. As
shown by the calculations in Table 3, a countercyclical capital buffer of 4.7 percent
would have ensured that banks would have had sufficient capital to avoid applying
for TARP and to continue growing their balance sheets in line with the long-run
average growth rate.
Given its profitability in the years preceding the crisis, the banking system
had ample capacity to meet increases in the countercyclical capital buffer rate of
this magnitude through a combination of new issuance of equity and additional
retentions. Hirtle (2016) finds that between 2005 and the collapse of Lehman
Brothers in 2008, dividend payments of large bank holding companies amounted to
$162 billion, and total share buy-backs amounted to an additional $131 billion.
Indeed, dividend payments and share buy-backs amounted to $49 billion and
$18 billion, respectively, between mid-2007 and the failure of Lehman in September
2008. By mid-2007, New Century Financial Corporation, a leading subprime mort-
gage lender, had already failed, and Bear Stearns and BNP Paribas had started
halting redemptions on a number of their investment funds.
Finally, we note that among the 15 institutions that we consider are some
broker-dealers. These institutions were not subject to standard prudential require-
ments.6 As a first step, a macroprudential authority would have needed to bring
these firms inside the regulatory perimeter. As illustrated in Table 1, bringing all
US broker-dealers to the same capital standards that commercial banks had in 2007
would already have added a substantial amount of capital to the system.
6
In 2004, the Securities and Exchange had created the voluntary “Consolidated Supervised Entities”
program to regulate large investment bank holding companies. However, this regime was primarily
intended to satisfy foreign regulators (Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission 2011). It was generally seen
as being insufficiently robust and was terminated following the failure of Lehman Brothers in 2008.
7
The facilities included the Discount Window Funding, the Term Auction Facility, the Primary Dealer
Credit Facility, the Term Securities Lending Facility, the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, the
Commercial Paper Funding Facility, and the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual
Fund Liquidity Facility.
Would Macroprudential Regulation Have Prevented the Last Crisis? 119
As a method of reducing the risks that entail when banks fund long-term,
illiquid assets with short-term funding, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
proposed a “net stable funding ratio” standard that took effect in 2018 (for an over-
view see, https://www.bis.org/fsi/fsisummaries/nsfr.pdf). Data provided in Lallour
and Mio (2016) suggest that prior to the crisis, applying the net stable funding ratio
to 12 of the largest US banking and investment banking groups at a consolidated level
would have led to an increase in long-term funding of $1.4 trillion by end-2007.8
What impact might such an intervention have on the real economy? While a
$1.5 trillion increase in the supply of long-term debt would probably affect equilib-
rium yields, we think such an intervention would increase firms’ average funding
costs by less than 10 basis points. Conservative estimates suggest this in turn might
increase lending spreads by less than 20 basis points, reducing the level of GDP by
less than 0.2 percent.9
8
The estimates in Lallour and Mio (2016) are based on end-2006 balance sheet data. To make them
comparable to the size of the Fed’s liquidity interventions, we scaled them up to reflect the average
growth of the relevant groups’ balance sheets between 2006 and 2007.
9
The estimate of 10 basis points is based on the conservative assumption of a 100 basis point difference
between the spreads on short-term funding and long-term (five-year) debt. To put this into context, the
average difference between the cost of repo funding and five-year corporate bond spreads in 2006 was
around 70 basis points. The estimated impact on lending spreads is based on the assumption that the
increase in funding costs is fully passed on to borrowers by increasing spreads on loans (which represented
about 50 percent of total assets), and that financial institutions’ cost of equity remains the same despite
the more stable funding base. Given that around 10 percent of banks’ liabilities had to be replaced by
long-term debt, this translates into an increase in lending spreads of 20 basis points. The impact of higher
lending spreads on GDP is estimated based on multipliers in Firestone, Lorenc, and Ranish (2017).
120 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Table 4
Impact of Different Loan-to-Income Limits on Gross Mortgage Lending for
Owner-Occupier House Purchase (First Lien Loans Only)
2003 4.1 2.9 1.3 0.4 0.1 755.8 189.6 59.0 16.1 6.0
2004 4.6 3.2 1.5 0.5 0.1 906.6 245.8 81.9 21.7 6.1
2005 4.8 3.4 1.6 0.5 0.1 1,031.5 288.6 95.8 23.7 6.0
2006 4.2 2.9 1.4 0.4 0.1 939.5 245.9 75.0 18.7 6.0
2007 3.4 2.4 1.2 0.4 0.1 755.9 204.4 67.8 17.7 4.8
Cumulative
total:
2003–2007 21.1 14.8 7.0 2.2 0.6 4,389 1,174 379 98 29
in the run-up to the crisis, whereas household debt rose sharply relative to income.
Adelino, Schoar, and Severino (2017) also document the relatively stable distribu-
tion of combined loan-to-value ratios at origination between 2001 and 2007.10
As a simple illustration, consider how loan-to-income limits would have affected
loan-level mortgage originations for owner-occupier house purchases in the run-up
to the crisis.11 For example, a loan-to-income limit of four times income applied
from 2003 to 2007 would have meant that 2.2 million of the 21 million mortgages
originated would have had to be reduced in size (see Table 4). Assuming all of
these affected loans were still originated at the largest size possible given the limit,
this intervention would have left the mortgage stock on the eve of the crisis around
$100 billion or about 1 percent lower than the $10.6 trillion observed.
However, this naive experiment is likely to understate significantly the effect of
loan-to-income limits on the mortgage stock. First, the data sample excludes second
lien or “piggyback” mortgages, whereas well-designed loan-to-income limits would
take into account the combined value of first and additional loans. To the extent that
these additional loans pushed households’ overall indebtedness above the loan-
to-income limit, some would have been curtailed. This could have had a material
10
Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund (2009) document an increase in the median combined loan-to-value
ratio for non-prime purchase loans between 2003 and 2007. We argue below that income and affordability
limits would have been effective in moderating the boom in non-prime mortgage lending.
11
With thanks to Matthieu Chavaz for assistance, we use annual data resulting from the 1975 Home
Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA), which covers the vast majority of mortgages originated. From this
dataset, we analyse first lien mortgages for house purchase by owner-occupiers where both loan size and
income is reported.
David Aikman, Jonathan Bridges, Anil Kashyap, and Caspar Siegert 121
effect: the total flow of second lien mortgage originations from 2003 to 2007 was
over $200 billion. Second, this experiment focuses only on owner-occupier house
purchase loans, with no impact assumed on investor loans or refinancing, both of
which were important features of the household credit boom. Third, our calcula-
tion assumes that all affected borrowers still receive a loan and at the largest size
possible given the limit—in reality, some borrowers would likely be shifted further
below the limit and some might be excluded altogether. As an upper bound of
the impact, if all originations constrained by a loan-to-income limit of four times
income were excluded altogether—rather than just reduced in size—the impact on
gross lending would rise from around $100 billion to $620 billion.
Borrowers at the riskier end of the spectrum that could either not certify their
income or that had particularly stretched affordability characteristics would have
perhaps been the most likely to have been excluded altogether. We can attempt
to quantify these considerations. Between 2003 and mid-2007, about half of non-
prime mortgage originations for house purchase had low or no documentation
of income, assets, or both (Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund 2009). That amounted to
around 1.7 million loans or 8 percent of the total captured in Table 4 over the same
period.12 These loans performed significantly worse than those with full documen-
tation—by 2008 serious delinquencies on low or no documentation subprime loans
had risen to 25 percent (Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund 2009). Many of these loans
would likely have been curtailed by a loan-to-income limit, given the requirement
that some actual documentation of income is provided in order to implement a
loan-to-income policy. To give a sense of scale, had all of these loans been excluded
by a loan-to-income policy between 2003 and mid-2007, lending could have been
reduced by around $360 billion (next to last line of Table 5).13
As a complement to loan-to-income limits, a macroprudential authority
aiming to enhance the resilience of household sector balance sheets could also
recommend the introduction of affordability tests, which require lenders to assess
borrowers’ capacity to service debts in different circumstances (as discussed in Bank
of England 2017). Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances suggests that by
2007, 20 percent of the total stock of mortgagors had debt service burdens of over
40 percent of their income—a situation that might reasonably have been flagged by
an affordability test. The impact of such tests on the rapid growth in non-prime mort-
gage borrowing could have been significant. For example, 76 percent of subprime
mortgages for house purchase between 2003 and mid-2007 were short-term hybrid
12
The Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund (2009) sample is based on data from First American Loan Perfor-
mance. These data capture the vast majority of securitized, non-prime (that is subprime or near-prime
“Alt-A”) first lien mortgage originations. The sample covers a total of 9.7 million originations, including
investor loans and refinances. For comparability with Table 4, we focus on the subsample of about
3.4 million loans to owner-occupiers for house purchase. When comparing to Table 4, this subsample
underestimates the total share of non-prime loans, since it does not capture mortgages retained by the
lender rather than securitized.
13
This assumes low- or no-documentation loans had a proportionate share in the total value of origina-
tions in Table 4.
122 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Table 5
Potential Impact of a 4× Loan-to-Income Limit and Accompanying Affordability
Test on Household Debt Boom
a
Financial accounts of the United States.
b
Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HDMA) data; gross flow of first lien owner-occupier purchase loans.
Impact estimates do not include potential reduction in second lien loans, investor loans, or loans for
refinance.
c
Number of non-prime first lien owner-occupier purchase loans estimated based on Mayer et al. (2009)
and share in total value of loans assumed to be a proportionate. Exclusions for low- or no-documentation
loans and teaser-rate loans would have overlapped; taken together these borrowers accounted for about
$580bn of lending from 2003 to 2007.
loans with initial “teaser” rates, which were low introductory interest rates that
would last for the first year or two of the mortgage (Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund
2009). By 2008, serious delinquency rates on these loans exceeded 30 percent. An
affordability test that required mortgagors to demonstrate resilience to an interest
rate stress up front would likely have curtailed non-prime lending on teaser rates
significantly. If the test had prevented these loans altogether, it could have reduced
mortgage lending by around $370 billion (last line of Table 5).
Taken together, actions to restrict the borrowing of those that either could not
certify their income or had stretched affordability characteristics would likely have
materially dampened the surge in non-prime lending prior to the crisis. As Table 5
shows, we are left with a wide range of possible effects, but it seems plausible that
combining loan-to-income and affordability rules would have moderated the scale
of the household debt boom in the run-up to the crisis.
The macroeconomic benefit of any limits would incorporate the fact that
they would have targeted the most highly indebted borrowers. Bunn and Rostom
(2015), Andersen, Duus, and Jenson (2016), and Fagereng and Halvorsen (2016)
show a correlation between pre-crisis household leverage and subsequent nega-
tive consumption responses. Although these studies do not demonstrate causality,
they suggest that limiting leverage of the most highly indebted households could
have a stronger aggregate effect on spending in a downturn than reducing debt
uniformly across households. Targeted macroprudential interventions of this kind
could therefore have been particularly effective in dampening the macroeconomic
fallout from the crisis.
Would Macroprudential Regulation Have Prevented the Last Crisis? 123
Table 6
Survey Data on Usage of Macroprudential Tools
All advanced economies (18) 44% of countries 33%of countries 22% of countries
Note: We consider the 19 advanced economies covered in Edge and Liang (2017), minus South Korea,
for which no data on tool usage is available. Numbers are based on country classification in Edge
and Liang (2017) and survey responses on tool usage in IMF (2018a) that consider tools in use at the
date of the survey. “Formal powers” refers to powers to act unilaterally or to issue “comply-or-explain”
recommendations. Results for the United Kingdom have been adjusted to account for measures that had
been agreed but were not yet binding at the date of the survey.
Of the 58 countries surveyed in Edge and Liang (2017) that have created
macroprudential frameworks since the crisis, 41 have set up multi-agency finan-
cial stability committees. Perhaps surprisingly, only 11 of these have formal powers,
including either direct controls over macroprudential policy tools or the right to
issue “comply or explain” recommendations to which other authorities are formally
obliged to respond. The remaining cases rely on the voluntary cooperation of other
regulators to achieve their policy aims.14
There is tentative evidence that financial stability committees with formal
powers are more likely to act than government agencies exposed to short-term
political pressures. Table 6, for instance, presents evidence from a sample of 18
advanced economies that 60 percent of countries with high-powered financial
stability committees have taken bank-focused policy actions; this compares to 38
percent for countries where financial stability policy requires interagency coop-
eration. Similarly, countries with high-powered financial stability committees are
also more likely to have used household-focused macroprudential tools. While the
sample is small and causation is likely to run both ways, this evidence suggests that
institutional frameworks do matter for mitigating biases towards inaction in the
application of macroprudential policies.
If we line up the multi-agency financial stability committees in order of the
powers at their direct disposal, two cases stand out at opposite ends of the spec-
trum. The UK Financial Policy Committee has a wide-ranging toolkit to achieve its
14
Forbes (2018) provides a detailed summary of some of the macroprudential measures that different
countries have put in place after the crisis.
124 Journal of Economic Perspectives
mandate to protect and enhance the resilience of the UK financial system. At the
other end of the spectrum, the US Financial Stability Oversight Council has few
powers under its direct control. In this section, we compare and contrast these polar
cases, and assess what they could do if faced with a rerun of the factors that led to
the last financial crisis.
15
That said, a paper written prior to the collapse in valuations of the senior AAA tranches of collateral-
ized debt obligations argued that these assets were significantly overvalued given the likely states of the
economy when defaults might occur—that is, given the systematic nature of the risks being borne by
investors (Coval, Jurek, and Stafford 2009).
Would Macroprudential Regulation Have Prevented the Last Crisis? 127
Conclusion
16
We would like to thank Sir Jon Cunliffe for suggesting this point to us.
128 Journal of Economic Perspectives
■ We thank Mathieu Chavez, Sir Jon Cunliffe, Beverly Hirtle, Don Kohn, Richard Sharp,
Martin Taylor, Paul Tucker, Skander Van den Heuvel, and Andrei Zlate for helpful
conversations about these issues. Kashyap’s research has been supported by a grant from the
Alfred P. Sloan Foundation to the Macro Financial Modeling (MFM) project at the University
of Chicago and by the Chicago Booth Initiative on Global Markets and Fama-Miller Center.
The views in this paper are those of the authors, and not necessarily those of the Bank of
England or its policy committees.
References
Acharya, Viral V., Thomas Philippon, Matthew Yang, and Andrei Zlate. 2017. “Macroprudential
Richardson, and Nouriel Roubini. 2009. “The Policy: A Case Study from a Tabletop Exercise.”
Financial Crisis of 2007–2009: Causes and Reme- Economic Policy Review 23(1): 1–30.
dies.” Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments Adrian, Tobias, Michael Fleming, Or Shachar,
18(2): 89–137. and Erik Vogt. 2017. “Market Liquidity after
Adelino, Manuel, Antoinette Schoar, and Felipe the Financial Crisis.” Annual Review of Financial
Severino. 2016. “Loan Originations and Defaults in Economics 9: 43–83.
the Mortgage Crisis: The Role of the Middle Class.” Aikman, David, Jonathan Bridges, Stephen
Review of Financial Studies 29(7): 1635–70. Burgess, Richard Galletly, Iren Levina, Cian
Adelino, Manuel, Anoinette Schoar, and Felipe O’Neill, and Alexandra Varadi. 2018. “Measuring
Severino. 2017. “Dynamics of Housing Debt in the Risks to UK Financial Stability.” Bank of England
Recent Boom and Great Recession.” NBER Macro- Staff Working Paper 738
economics Annual 2017, 32(1): 265–311. Aikman, David, Jonathan Bridges, Anil Kashyap,
Adrian, Tobias, Nina Boyarchenko, and and Caspar Siegert. 2018. “Would Macroprudential
Domenico Giannone. 2016. “Vulnerable Growth.” Regulation Have Prevented the Last Crisis?” Bank
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report of England Staff Working Paper 747.
794. Andersen, Asger Lau, Charlotte Duus, and
Adrian, Tobias, Patrick de Fontnouvelle, Emily Thais Lækholm Jensen. 2016. “Household Debt
David Aikman, Jonathan Bridges, Anil Kashyap, and Caspar Siegert 129
and Spending during the Financial Crisis: Evidence American Economic Review 99(3): 628–66.
from Danish Mico Data.” European Economic Review Duffie, Darrell. 2018. Prone to Fail: The Pre-Crisis
89(C): 96–115. Financial System. Forthcoming.
Avraham, Dafna, Patricia Selvaggi, and James Edge, Rochelle M., and Nellie Liang. 2017.
Vickery. 2012. “A Structural View of US Bank “Who is in Charge of Financial Stability, Why, and
Holding Companies.” Federal Reserve Bank of What They Can Do.” Hutchins Center Working
New York Economic Policy Review 7: 65–81. Paper 32. https://www.brookings.edu/research/
Bahaj, Saleem, Jonathan Bridges, Frederic who-is-in-charge-of-financial-stability-why-and-what-
Malherbe, and Cian O’Neill, C. 2016. “What Deter- they-can-do/.
mines How Banks Respond to Changes in Capital Eichner, Matthew J., Donald L. Kohn, and
Requirements?” Bank of England Staff Working Michael Palumbo. 2013. “Financial Statistics for
Paper 593. the United States and the Crisis: What Did They
Balls, Ed, James Howat, and Anna Stansbury. Get Right, What Did They Miss, and How Could
2016. “Central Bank Independence Revisited: They Change?” In Measuring Wealth and Financial
After the Financial Crisis, What Should a Model Intermediation and Their Links to the Real Economy,
Central Bank Look Like?” M-RCBG Associate edited by Charles R. Hulten and Marshall B. Reins-
Working Paper 67. dorf, 39–66. University of Chicago Press.
Bank of England. 2017. Financial Stability Report: Fagereng, Andreas, and Elin Halvorsen. 2016.
June 2017. “Debt and Household Consumption Responses.”
Bassett, William F., Mary Beth Chosak, John C. Norges Bank Staff Memo No. 1.
Driscoll, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2014. “Changes in Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. 2011. The
Bank Lending Standards and the Macroeconomy.” Financial Crisis Inquiry Report: Final Report of the
Journal of Monetary Economics 62: 23–40. National Commission on the Causes of the Financial
Bernanke, Ben. 2018. The Real Effects of and Economic Crisis in the United States. Submitted
the Financial Crisis. BPEA Conference Drafts, pursuant to Public Law 111-21, January. Available
September 13–14. at: https://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/GPO-FCIC/
Borio, Claudio. 2003. “Towards a Macropru- content-detail.html.
dential Framework for Financial Supervision Firestone, Simon, Amy Lorenc, and Benjamin
and Regulation?” CESifo Economic Studies 49(2): Ranish. 2017. “An Empirical Economic Assessment
181–215. of the Costs and Benefits of Bank Capital in the
Borio, Claudio, and William R. White. 2004. US.” Finance and Economics Discussion Series
“Whither Monetary and Financial Stability? The Working Paper no. 2017-034.
Implications of Evolving Policy Regimes.” BIS Fleming, Michael J. 2012. “Federal Reserve
Working Paper 147. Liquidity Provision during the Financial Crisis of
Bridges, Jonathan, Chris Jackson, and Daisy 2007–2009. Annual Review of Financial Economics 4:
McGregor. 2017. “Down in the Slumps: The Role 161–77.
of Credit in Five Decades of Recessions.” Bank of Forbes, Kristin. 2018. “Macroprudential Policy
England Staff Working Paper 659. after the Crisis: Forging a Thor’s Hammer for
Brunnermeier, Markus K. 2009. “Deciphering Financial Stability in Iceland.” Report prepared at
the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–2008.” the request of the Task Force to review monetary
Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1): 77–100. and currency policies for Iceland.
Bunn, Philip, and May Rostom. 2015. “House- Gennaioli, Nicola, and Andrei Shleifer. 2018.
hold Debt and Spending in the United Kingdom.” A Crisis of Beliefs: Investor Psychology and Financial
Bank of England Staff Working Paper 554. Fragility. Princeton University Press.
Chavaz, Matthieu, and Andrew K. Rose.Forth- Gertler Mark, and Simon Gilchrist. 2018. “What
coming. “Political Borders and Bank Lending in Happened: Financial Factors in the Great Reces-
Post-Crisis America.” Review of Finance. sion.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 32(3): 3–30.
Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel. 2014. “The Employ- Greenlaw, David, Jan Hatzius, Anil K Kashyap,
ment Effects of Credit Market Disruptions: and Hyun Song Shin. 2008. “Leveraged Losses:
Firm-Level Evidence from the 2008–9 Financial Lessons from the Mortgage Market Meltdown. In
Crisis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(1): 1–59. Proceedings of the US Monetary Policy Forum, pp. 7–59.
Cochran, Martha L., David F. Freeman, and Greenspan, Alan. 2005. “Regulatory Reform
Helen Mayer Clark. 2015. “Money Market Fund of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises.” Testi-
Reform: SEC Rulemaking in the FSOC Era.” mony before the Committee on Banking, Housing,
Columbia Business Law Review 861. and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate. Speech 63, Board
Coval, Joshua D., Jakub W. Jurek, and Erik of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, US.
Stafford. 2009. “Economic Catastrophe Bonds.” April 6.
130 Journal of Economic Perspectives