Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Neil H Thomas
Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Neil H Thomas
ABSTRACT The paper begins with an ethical case for land redistribution in
Zimbabwe, based on principles of social justice and equity, drawing from a brief
history of land in Zimbabwe from the first European expulsions up to inde-
pendence. Both the moral and economic arguments for land redistribution are
widely and fiercely contested. The paper considers and rejects two specific
criticisms of the economic arguments: that farming in the commercial sector is
more efficient than in the peasant sector; and that land redistribution will not
benefit the land-poor, but rather transfer land to an alternative privileged group.
These arguments are explored through an examination of previous land resettle-
ment programmes in Zimbabwe in these two respects. The paper also evaluates
the objections to land reform related to issues of compensation and legality. It is
concluded that radical redistribution is desirable and feasible, and urges the
British government to finance land development and, if necessary, compensate
commercial farmers.
Conflict over land in Zimbabwe is one of the big news stories of today. But
the media tend to exaggerate the extent to which events there are historically
contingent and driven by the happenstance of President Mugabe’s rule. Instead
the situation should be seen as structurally embedded in the historical processes
of colonial rule and subsequent international diplomacy and intervention. In fact
similar processes are unfolding in neighbouring Namibia, Botswana and South
Africa. The future of Zimbabwe, like the present, will be intimately paralleled by
events in the rest of Southern Africa.
The similarities between Zimbabwe and South Africa are indeed striking. They
suffer comparable land inequalities: 13% of the population of South Africa
(whites) own 87% of the land (Ankomah, 2001: 8). As in Zimbabwe land
redistribution has been very slow: less than 2% has been transferred from white
to black ownership since the ANC came to power in 1994 (McGreal, 2001). Here
too, only those wishing to sell their land need do so—the so-called ‘willing seller,
willing buyer’ principle—with the state providing financial support (Palmer,
1998: 2).
Again perceptions of injustice have elicited similar responses from the dis-
possessed. Many of the seven million black workers on white farms in South
Africa are being expelled, while ‘hundreds of white landowners and their
workers die each year’ through violence on the farms (McGreal, 2001; see also
Palmer, 1998).
Neil H Thomas is in the Department of City and Regional Planning, Cardiff University, Glamorgan
Building, King Edward VII Avenue, Cardiff CF10 3WA, Wales. Email: [email protected].
The war veterans of Zimbabwe also have their counterparts in South Africa,
where several popular militant land-rights groups are co-operating under an
umbrella organisation called the National Landless People’s Grouping (McGreal,
2001), and the Minister of Lands has warned that the slowness of redistribution
in South Africa may lead to ‘a Mugabe-style land grab’ (Palmer, 1998).
It is worrying that the systematic failure of the media, Western governments
and international agencies to grasp the structural basis of Zimbabwe’s
conflict will leave them ill-prepared to react constructively to similar and
imminent conflicts elsewhere, especially in South Africa, with potentially tragic
consequences.
This paper will argue that the land conflict in Zimbabwe should be understood
primarily as a legacy of colonialism, and of emergent neo-colonial relations
between Zimbabwe and a coalition of rich countries and the international
institutions that they dominate—especially the World Bank and the IMF.
In presenting an overview of the land situation in Zimbabwe, an argument will
be made for the desirability of fundamental land reform, for both ethical and
economic reasons. Not only is it right to redistribute land to the dispossessed, but
experience of earlier programmes in Zimbabwe and countless others around the
world demonstrate the potential for major agricultural improvements through
such reforms.
The paper begins with an ethical case for land redistribution, following from a
brief outline of the history of land in Zimbabwe from the first European
expulsions up to independence. Some general economic justifications for land
reform are outlined next, followed by a detailed examination of the experience
of land resettlement programmes in Zimbabwe and of the arguments
levelled against them by their critics—especially the alleged inefficiency of
African farmers, and the corruptness of land allocation. Other opponents of land
redistribution cite the complex questions of compensation and of legality. Their
objections are explored next.
Finally, it is argued that radical land reform is not only desirable and feasible,
but also necessary to prevent serious unrest. The paper concludes that the British
government has a central role to play in averting further disaster, by financing
land development and, if necessary, by compensating dispossessed commercial
farmers.
governments. But in the 1880s there ensued a ‘hasty and haphazard process of
enclosure’ by European powers (Davidson, 1984: 270), driven by suspicion of
the ambitions of rivals.
The Berlin conference of 1884 defined the broad limits of expansion of each of
the European powers. As part of this exercise ‘the British government in 1888
declared the existence of a British sphere of interest between Botswana and the
Zambesi’ (Oliver & Fage, 1988: 164). Thus Mashonaland and Matabeleland were
allocated by the European powers to the British sphere of influence (Douglas,
1984: 184).
In that year the Ndebele king, Lobengula, was misled into signing a mining
‘concession’ which effectively granted Cecil Rhodes the right to occupy
Mashonaland (Douglas, 1984: 182–184). The British government was thereby
persuaded to grant a Royal Charter, which delegated the functions of government
in this region to Rhodes’s British South Africa (BSA) Company (Oliver & Fage,
1988: 164).
The area of present-day Zimbabwe and Zambia (and more) was ceded to the
Company in 1891, and named ‘Rhodesia’ in 1895. Settlers, many of whom had
been urban South Africans in search of gold, demanded land and the labour to
work it. This sparked wars with the Shona and the Matabele, with enormous
casualties (Oliver & Fage 1988: 193; Palmer & Birch 1992). Conflict between
white-ruled Mashonaland and the independent black state of Matabeleland
culminated in the Anglo-Ndebele War of 1893–94, which added Matabeleland to
the BSA Company’s territories (Douglas, 1984: 184).
The settlers helped themselves to the best land, enserfed the original
inhabitants, or else pushed them out into less fertile areas (Douglas, 1984: 137).
The indigenous population had to pay rents and taxes on what remained of their
land and property to the BSA Company. A loose policy of setting aside reserves
for Africans—following the South African policy—began in the 1890s, but
became regularised and intensified in the 1920s. In 1922 the settlers voted to run
the country (now Southern Rhodesia) themselves with only limited supervision
by the British government. It became a self-governing British colony the
following year (Douglas, 1984: 184).
The Land Apportionment Act of 1930 ‘allocated fixed Reserves—generally
poor, remote and inadequate—to the people’ (Douglas, 1984: 137). The alienated
lands of Africans became ‘European areas’ (Elich, 2002). The new government
concentrated all its policies during the next 30 years on the promotion of further
white settlement, and built up its power and economic predominance (Oliver &
Fage, 1988: 189). Through immigration the number of white settlers increased
from 80 000 to 220 000 between 1945 and 1960 (Palmer & Birch, 1992).
There was ‘wholesale forced removal of African people to make room for
white farming up to the 1950s’ (Cliffe, 2000: 36). Indeed, black people continued
to be forced from their land right up to the 1970s (McGreal, 2002); and while
labour was thereby ‘reproduced’ in the African reserves, now re-labelled
‘communal areas’ (CAs), competition in the market from African smallholders
was prohibited (Cliffe, 2000: 36; Jayne & Jones, 1997).
Special designated areas for ‘emergent’ black farmers were first established in
1930 (Munslow, 1985). Here successful (‘master’) farmers were granted portions
693
NEIL H THOMAS
of land up to 100 hectares with the intention of developing a black yeoman class
(Moyo, 1986). These are now called ‘small-scale commercial farmers’ (SSCFs).
Meanwhile in the CAs enormous land pressure was building up: between 1961
and 1977 the area under cultivation increased by 91% at the expense of grazing,
although cattle numbers still increased by 70% (Moyo, 1986: 170). In these areas
no credit or financial institutions supported the farmers. Not until 1978 was a
small farm credit scheme established (Mumbengegwi, 1986: 206).
Ethical implications
The moral arguments in media and political circles for and against land
redistribution in Zimbabwe often fail to distinguish between a number of separate
issues. Here is an attempt to identify those with the greatest moral force.
The first moral argument for land reform is that, regardless of how it came
about, land ownership is highly unequal, and redistribution would increase
equality and hence social justice. This would apply in any population, irres-
pective of the origins of existing land tenure.
A second justification for land redistribution which emerges vividly from the
above sketch of Zimbabwe’s history is the imperative to right past wrongs. It is
uncontested that land was simply stolen from its owners throughout the century
before independence. Redistribution would reverse this process, and return land
694
LAND REFORM IN ZIMBABWE
Zimbabwe, there are also good economic arguments. Below is a brief outline of
the role of redistribution in the promotion of increased production; the fulfilment
of basic human needs; and, more broadly, in the stimulation of the economy.
To maximise agricultural production under-utilised or barren commercial farm
land must be made to fulfil its productive potential. Further, land allocation
should maximise its efficiency of use. Numerous data from around the world
confirm the inverse relationship between landholding size and the following: land
utilisation, proportion of land cropped, and of crops that are food crops, and
productivity per hectare. This is so despite the relatively under-capitalised nature
of small landholdings (Murdoch, 1980). In Kenya in the mid-1970s, for example,
output per hectare was almost 20 times as high on farms of under 0.5 ha than on
those over 8 ha (Hunt, 1984).
In a situation where, according to the government’s Poverty Assessment Study
Survey (SAPRIN , 1999: 5) 61% of households in Zimbabwe live in poverty,
and 45% in extreme poverty, we must also mention the implications of land
redistribution for human needs. As Chattopadhyay (2000) points out, poverty in
the late 1990s occurred in the midst of record harvests. There has, he says, been a
‘break in the relationship between production and consumption’. Sen (1981)
showed that aggregate food availability at the national level is not a sufficient
predictor of a properly fed population. Instead he emphasised ‘the social relations
through which people gain command, or entitlement, over food’ (Crow, 2000:
60). Such entitlement derives from direct ‘endowments’—such as labour power
or access to land—or more indirectly from exchange and trade. In the context of
high unemployment in Zimbabwe rapidly escalating levels of under-nutrition can
therefore be best tackled through the direct provision of land.
Finally, in the words of Oxfam’s Senior Policy Advisor, ‘a properly-financed
and well managed land reform programme could unleash the productive potential
of peasant farmers [in Zimbabwe], much as it did in South Asian countries such
as South Korea, Taiwan and Japan’ (Watkins, 1995: 133). The increased equality
resulting from redistribution would raise demand and promote economic growth
in all sectors.
House in London (Oliver & Fage, 1988: 232). The conference laid down British
terms for the legal independence of Southern Rhodesia, now called Zimbabwe.
The most significant of these terms was the right of all white farmers to retain
their land, at least for 10 years. British aid was only available to purchase lands
of white farmers who chose to sell (Palmer & Birch, 1992: 24). Only ‘under-
utilised’ land could be compulsorily purchased, and that at the full market price,
which the owners could convert into foreign currency (Palmer & Birch 1992). In
exchange the UK agreed to fund half the cost of a resettlement scheme for black
farmers.
In the years immediately before Independence, Western governments had
‘attempted to reassure whites by proposing a trust fund, which among other
things would guarantee compensation abroad if property rights were abused. At
one stage this fund was to be as much as $2 billion’ (Holman, 2000).
The anxiety of the white farmers was shared by Mugabe and Nkomo, co-
leaders of the PF, who asked at the conference for reassurances that land re-
distribution would not be made impossible by entrenched clauses and lack of
funds. According to the liberation delegation these assurances were forthcoming
in private, and they went ‘a long way in allaying the great concern we have over
the whole land question arising from the great need our people have for land and
our commitment to satisfy that need when in government’ (McGreal, 2002).
These promises are ‘now downplayed by British officials’, and by 1996 just
£44 million of the promised hundreds of millions had been forthcoming for land
reform (McGreal, 2002; Holman, 2000). McGreal (2000) believes that Mugabe
would have gone back to war had he known they would gain so little. It may
legitimately be asked whether this alleged deception is the root cause of the
subsequent failure to implement the kind of land reform which could have
satisfied both new settlers and dispossessed commercial farmers.
Nevertheless the new government of Zimbabwe in 1980 set out to acquire
8.3 million ha of land on which to resettle 162 000 families under Phase One of
its Land Reform and Resettlement Programme (LRRP). But between 1980 and
1989 it acquired only 2.6 milllion ha and resettled 52 000 households, 70%
of these by 1983 (Alexander, 1994: 335; Christiansen, 1993: 1552; Potts &
Mutambirwa 1997: 550–551). The ‘willing seller’ principle ensured that whites
only sold the land that had been abandoned during the War of Liberation, or else
was of poor quality, thereby denying new settlers the opportunity to establish a
successful economic sector (Alexander, 1994: 343–344; Cliffe, 2000: 37;
Munslow, 1985).
While the purpose of the resettlement programme was to alleviate land
poverty, it was also designed to ensure that aggregate production would not be
endangered. It was heavily regulated over what was to be produced, how much,
and by what methods. Leases could be revoked unless new settlers carried out
efficient commercial farming (Potts & Mutambirwa, 1997: 551, 560; Kinsey,
1999). Well over 90% of the families resettled were in so-called Model A
schemes, in which farmers receive small plots of around 6–7 hectares to
cultivate, and some grazing land, often held in common with other families
(Kinsey, 1999: 175; see also Potts & Mutambirwa 1997: 551). Most of the rest
(Model B) were collective co-operatives.
697
NEIL H THOMAS
Along with the resettlement programme the government gave assistance to the
60% of people who remained in agro-ecological zones IV and V in the poor
CAs. They received a combination of marketing, credit, extension services and
agricultural inputs. Nevertheless diversity of natural resource endowment within
the CAs themselves meant that these services tended to favour the richer areas and
groups. Such policies of support to CA farmers were thus not sufficient to solve
the problem of poverty, and resettlement remained essential (Cliffe, 1988b: 8).
increasing debt. The World Bank and IMF conferred. In 1992 Zimbabwe devalued
again, and desperately cut back on spending. It was not until March 1992 that a
World Bank loan finally arrived, and now the IFIs called the tune. From here on
Zimbabwe’s economy would be their property.
These events had serious consequences for Zimbabwe’s agriculture. In the
1980s Zimbabwe’s agricultural success had been legendary (Moyo, 1986). The
parastatal Grain Marketing Board (GMB) collected and stored grain through a
country-wide network of depots and collection points, mostly built after
Independence (Stoneman, 1992: 93; Sachikonye, 1992; Gibbons, 1996: 345).
Bumper maize harvests in 1989 and 1990 resulted in the GMB storing more than a
whole year’s harvest in April 1990 (Sachikonye, 1992; Stoneman, 1992).
A wonderful achievement you might think. But the IFIs were more concerned
with the GMB’s deficit, which Stoneman (1993: 95) denies is evidence of its
inefficiency, but rather a result of ‘paying decent prices to farmers and the costs
of storing surplus maize that could not be sold profitably on the world market
because of the dumping of similarly surplus maize by the EC and the US’.
ESAP required the GMB to eliminate its deficit, by closing the less ‘economic’
grain depots in rural areas (Sachikonye, 1992: 93; Stoneman, 1992: 95; SAPRIN,
1999). Nearly all the crop collection points were closed by late 1991 (Gibbons,
1996). The marketing and storage network, which had successfully ensured the
availability of food, was dismantled so that the GMB should become profitable.
Marketing was taken over by middlemen, described by SAPRIN (1999) as
‘exploitative’.
Huge surpluses of maize were immediately replaced by import dependency.
And while the economy began to crumble Zimbabwe was hit by an appalling
drought in 1992 (Sachikonye, 1992; Stoneman, 1992). Consumption of food was
hit particularly hard: between 1990 and 1994, while the general price index
increased by 168%, for food it increased by 225%. This had a greater impact on
the poor, as food represents a higher proportion of their expenditure (Gibbons,
1996: 380).
The problems which ESAP posed for farmers in Zimbabwe have been summed
up by SAPRIN (1999: 5) as ‘continued lack of access to land ... the availability and
price of farm inputs, the loss of ... information previously provided by the
marketing boards, high interest rates, and insufficient technical services’.
sanctions. Ankomah (2003a) cites government sources as saying that ‘all but one
of the international credit lines of the country have been cut, resulting in severe
difficulties in sourcing foreign exchange’.
According to Ankomah (2003a: 14) the resettlement scheme based on model A
‘is now virtually completed with a 100% uptake in all ten provinces’. Govern-
ment figures show 210 520 families have been resettled on 3159 farms totalling
7.43 million ha. However, a parallel resettlement programme to stimulate
competition within the commercial farming sector has ‘triggered the fiercest
resistance from organised white landed interest’.
So, as of April 2003, the FTLR programme is clearly very advanced, although
reliable and consistent data seem to be unavailable. Large-scale commercial
farming has been disrupted, while small-scale farming is impeded by the relative
absence of support, thanks to a combination of sanctions and a domestic
economy in crisis. This critical situation is compounded by a long-lasting and
terrible drought.
The above outline provides the necessary historical background to a discussion
of the two major objections to land redistribution posed by its critics.
that in the 1980s yields of maize per hectare were similar in CAs and LSCFs within
the same NRs (Weiner, 1988: 68), despite inferior inputs in the former.
Evidence concerning the agricultural productivity of black farmers is also
derived from the record of resettlement schemes. There was an evaluation of the
LRRP in 1988, carried out with the assistance of the UK government and other
donors, drawing heavily on an annual sample household survey (Cusworth, 2000:
25). This evaluation, using a standard economic cost–benefit analysis, established
the economic worth of the programme beyond doubt. The report concluded that
improvements were essentially the result of growing crops on previously idle or
extensively farmed land (Cusworth, 2000: 27). World Bank reports in 1991 and
1993 were likewise positive, if with reservations (Cusworth, 2000: 29).
The conclusions are all the more encouraging when it is remembered that a
disproportionately small amount of the land chosen for resettlement—around
10%—was in NRs I and II (Moyo, 1986: 185): resettlement ‘effectively closed off
the highveld (NR II) to small-scale black farmers’ (Weiner, 1988: 80). None-
theless the resettled farmers have still benefited. Kinsey (2000) used survey data
to show that resettled households earn more than three times as much as the
families in the CAs from which they originated (Kinsey, 1999: 194). And this is
not entirely because of the superiority of land in resettled areas: according to
Deininger et al (2000) the incomes of households in resettled areas in NR II is
over five times as high as for those in communal areas in the same NR.
A paper co-authored by two World Bank staff concludes that land redistribu-
tion in Zimbabwe has been good for productivity (Deininger et al, 2000). But
what of the consequences of resettlement for surplus production, and hence the
economy? Resettlement greatly increased the marketing of agricultural products:
by 1997 the value of crop and livestock sales of resettled households was seven
and three times, respectively, as high as in the CA s from where they came
(Kinsey, 1999: 186). Although only comprising 5% of the peasant farmer
population the 70 000 resettled households now produce 15%–20% of the
country’s marketed maize and cotton (Deininger et al, 2000: 2).
The prejudice, for prejudice it is, that black farmers are inefficient is all the
more absurd when it is remembered that many ‘white’ farms are actually
managed by blacks, for absentee white farmers. This is a potent argument against
the view that dispossession of such farmers would have negative effects on
productivity (Moyo, 2000: 79).
Many arguments against redistribution are also based on the presumed
efficiency of the LSCF sector. Thus the Observer laments that ‘the highly pro-
ductive large-scale farms that are the envy of Africa appear to be doomed’
(Meldrum, 2000). In earlier years the CFU, the World Bank and the Shell-financed
Whitsun Foundation expressed comparable sentiments (Cliffe, 1988a: 315–316).
There is of course great diversity in the sizes of LSCFs. Sixty-six per cent of the
LSCF area consists of just 222 farms of between 3000 and 350 000 ha (Moyo,
2000). The largest are bigger than the British county of Berkshire, and these latter
farms are grossly under-utilised: their high productivity is ‘limited to small
portions of their large estates’ (Weiner, 1988: 75). Moyo (2000) estimates that the
LSCF system holds on to about six million hectares of idle land. In Mashonaland,
which contains the fertile highveld and where rainfall is plentiful, the LSCFs
703
NEIL H THOMAS
cropped only 11% of their four million hectares. Elsewhere it was barely 1%
(Weiner, 1988). Further, LSCF farmers use much of their maize to feed cattle
(Moyo, 2000: 75). Weiner (1988: 76) points out that each cow in Mashonaland
‘is allocated 3 to 5 ha of land. This is double what the average peasant household
has, without even considering quality differences’.
All evidence supports the simple but powerful conclusion that ‘Zimbabwe’s
high-potential land is under-utilised, while much of the low-potential land is
over-utilised’ (Weiner, 1988: 84).
Corruption
Critics of the FTLR programme, including donors, the foreign media, and the
opposition Movement for Democratic Change (MDC), contend that redistribution
will only benefit ZANU-PF supporters, government officials and their friends. They
claim that past resettlement has been corrupt, and call for transparency in future
land allocation exercises. It is therefore important to be clear about who exactly
have been the beneficiaries of previous land redistribution efforts in Zimbabwe.
The first such effort was undertaken by the colonial regime in the 1950s. In an
attempt to tackle agrarian and social problems in the deteriorating native reserves
the government created ‘African Purchase Areas’ in which successful (‘master’)
farmers were granted portions of land of up to around 100 ha (Moyo, 1986: 169).
These SSCFs came to occupy 4% of the land, as they still do today.
Then after Independence the early stages of the resettlement programme
exclusively benefited the poor. By 1984, by which time most of the redistribution
was completed ‘slightly over 60% of those resettled were from communal lands,
the rest being refugees, the landless and unemployed persons’ (Moyo, 1986:
193). But from 1982 ‘successful farmers’ were included in the LRRP in an
attempt, as the government saw it, to raise productivity (Alexander, 1994: 333;
Munslow, 1985: 47).
From the middle of the 1980s quite a large amount of LSCF land made available
to the government was not taken up because of the stalling of the land resettle-
ment programme. Instead over a million hectares of land were traded on the
private market (Palmer, 1990: 170). In consequence 7% of LSCF farmers were
black by 1986 (Alexander, 1994: 337).
Eight estates were, however, bought by the government and managed by the
Agricultural and Rural Development Authority ( ARDA ), which had since
Independence run the State Farms established in the 1960s (Moyo, 1986). The
estates were split into several farm units, advertised, and leased to relatively
wealthy members of the new black elite (Van den Brink, 2000). Many of these
farms were to be reallocated by the Commercial Farmer Support Scheme (CFSS)
in 1998. Of these 149 farms the government stated that only two were to be
allocated to ministers and seven to government officials.
It is presumably at the privatisation of LSCF land sales, and CSFF redistribution,
that accusations of corruption are directed. While it is difficult to know the exact
extent of this, it is pertinent that J Msika, the minister co-ordinating the land
reform programme, explained to donors in August 1999 that the government did
not intend to exclude the rich, nor even government officials from the application
704
LAND REFORM IN ZIMBABWE
705
NEIL H THOMAS
Compensation
The feasibility of successful land redistribution is complicated by radically
conflicting interests over the issues of compulsion and compensation between
what are now fashionably called the various ‘stakeholders’. It is primarily for this
reason that 10 years after the expiration of the Lancaster House agreement
virtually no further land had changed hands. Table 1 is a reiteration of the main
events since independence which have a bearing on this issue.
Several important points emerge from this outline of post-independence land
redistribution, and related legislation. First, land has not been forthcoming on a
voluntary basis, and there is no guarantee that it ever would be, even if full
compensation were offered.
Second, the government was unable to pay compensation for loss of land at the
market price even in the mid-1980s when the economy was healthy. In 2003 a
government crippled with debt could not even contemplate such a policy. Not
only are such payments prohibitive, but their opportunity cost would be the loss
of funds for infrastructure and inputs to ensure the programme’s effective imple-
mentation.
Third, donor support for compensation has not been in the form of un-
conditional grants. This was so even in the 1980s, and from the potentially largest
donor, the UK government. It is likely that most future funding would be a
mixture of matched funding and loans. Thus the UK government at a Common-
wealth meeting in Nigeria in September 2001 offered support on the basis of
part-funding (Meldrum, 2001a). The implications are clear. Huge compensatory
sums to commercial farmers are demanded by donors, and these must be re-paid
by Zimbabwe with interest. The Third World debt crisis was born of similar
reasoning. It is simply impossible for a debtor with the desperate economic
problems of Zimbabwe to service such a huge package of loans.
Finally, a decision to acquire commercial farms through compulsion and
without compensation could expose Zimbabwe to a variety of external threats.
Some of these may derive directly from agencies which consider themselves
‘stakeholders’ in Zimbabwe’s future. Thus the IMF suspended a stand-by loan in
706
LAND REFORM IN ZIMBABWE
TABLE 1
Land redistribution events since Zimbabwe’s independence
1979/80 Lancaster House Agreement. Matched funding for voluntary sales only.
Compensation: full market price, convertible to foreign currency
1983 Stalling of the land reform programme (LRRP)
1991 Amended constitution, allowing compulsory acquisition of land with little
compensation, or right to appeal
1992 Land Acquisition Act. The right of the government to acquire land by
compulsion
1997 Decision to implement the 1992 Act and undertake compulsory purchase of
land
1998 (Sept) International Conference. Donor support for voluntary sales only. Various
terms of support: loans, grant, etc
1998 (Nov) Compulsory acquisition orders issued. Dispossessed farmers to be compensated
(‘fair market-value’). Donor condemnation. IMF responds by delaying loan
2000 (May) Amendment to the constitution and the 1992 Act, permitting compulsory
acquisition of land without compensation
2000 (July) FTLR programme started: land expropriated without compensation
707
NEIL H THOMAS
not for the land itself. Thus in April 2000 the government amended their
provisions for land acquisition so that they only paid for improvements to the
land (Ankomah, 2003b). While this made little financial difference it was an
important point of principle.
There is of course fundamental disagreement over the question of who is
responsible for any compensation payments. In an historic letter to Kumbirai
Kangai, Minister of Agriculture and Land in 1997, the British Minister for
International Development, Clare Short, denied British responsibility: ‘we do not
accept that Britain has a special responsibility to meet the costs of land purchase
in Zimbabwe. We are a new Government ... without links to former colonial
interests’ (quoted in Ankomah, 2003b).
Zimbabwe’s contrary opinion is expressed, somewhat surprisingly, by David
Hasluck, Director of the CFU from 1984 to 2002: ‘Because we believe that this
land was taken from our forefathers without compensation and it was often
violently [sic], and there has been no recognition of this by the colonial power,
the British must live with this responsibility’ (Ankomah, 2003b).
Hasluck believes further that Short’s letter reneges on the historic assurances
given at Lancaster House: ‘Clare Short knows damn well that there was a land
issue at Lancaster House’. ‘It was’, he says, ‘not a sensitive, diplomatic way’.
Hasluck ‘sincerely believes’ that the majority of CFU members share this view.
A reasonable conclusion would be that Zimbabwe’s government is neither able
to compensate LSCF farmers dispossessed under the FTLR programme, nor does it
bear the moral responsibility to do so.
each appeal, took one day, the redistribution of 4000 farms would have taken a
minimum of 30 years!
Again, the Supreme Court is the ultimate arbiter in these matters, and the
fairness of its judgements was critical to the success of the land reform
programme. Consequently the constitution of that court and its impartiality were
of paramount importance.
Several of the white judges were appointed under the Rhodesian regime—the
Chief Justice, Anthony Gubbay, who was replaced in March 2001, had been
appointed to the bench in 1977—and on many occasions the government has
openly questioned High Court judgements relating to land redistribution and
accused some judges of being ‘ill qualified to pass judgements on politically
sensitive issues’ (Madinah, 2001: 9).
Of the five Supreme Court judges only two are black, while the judiciary
comprises 23 judges, 12 of whom are black (Madinah, 2001: 9). The exercise of
the ‘rule of law’ could have come down to no more than the bias of just five
people. This should make any defender of democracy uneasy.
Mugabe’s appointment of a new chief justice and three judges to the Supreme
Court in August 2001 had a rapid effect on the speed of land reform. In October
the Court issued an interim ruling, upholding the government’s appeal against its
judgement of December 2000 which had ruled that it should halt farm ‘invasions’
(Meldrum, 2001b). In effect the seizures of LSCFs were now legal.
have been negligent in their indifference to the forces arraigned against any
attempts to put the genie back in the bottle of land reform. Likewise the MDC
would be wise to clarify their own position on this, and whether they can afford
to ignore the land issue as they have up to now.
Conclusion
It is difficult to see how the neoliberal ‘reforms’ urged on the government by the
‘international community’ and by the opposition MDC could possibly alleviate
Zimbabwe’s economic crisis. It should be remembered that the roots of this crisis
can be traced back to the introduction of neoliberal policies under ESAP in 1991.
Instead, whether by accident or design, the government is pursuing the only
available route to recovery, the realisation of its enormous agricultural potential
through land redistribution. But, as we have seen, this approach has exposed the
country to international threats and sanctions.
It is difficult to avoid the conclusion that, in order to achieve land redistribu-
tion without external retribution; and to compensate LSCF farmers without
crippling the economy, outside action is essential. Quite simply the UK govern-
ment must provide the necessary compensation by means of grant aid, without
preconditions, rather than the paltry and heavily circumscribed funds offered up
to now.
Such a course of action would also be morally correct. It may begin to atone
for the brutality of the colonial land grab and the subsequent humiliation and
impoverishment of black Zimbabweans at the hands of the British colonists.
Also, more indirectly, it would compensate for the continuing British exploitation
of Zimbabwe through direct rule, and later through neocolonial and highly
exploitative policies of trade and investment. It is time that the assistance
Zimbabwe has given to the economic development of the UK was acknowledged
and repaid.
Of course it is unfashionable to think like this any more, especially in New
Labour circles, and such an outcome is hard to imagine. But the British govern-
ment should ponder the alternative. The more likely future is that Zimbabwe’s
economy will continue to deteriorate, generating further social unrest and
political repression, whoever is in power. The current flow of refugees will
become a torrent, and Zimbabwe’s ‘social capital’ will bleed away.
The lessons of Zimbabwe’s experience are also vital to neighbouring South
Africa, Namibia and elsewhere. The progress of the FTLR programme has been
followed with interest and concern in South Africa. Zimbabwe’s programme ‘has
put land reform at centre stage for Southern Africa’. Local organisations there
have made it ‘the centrepiece of their strategies in 2003’ (Roman, 2003: 37–38).
In South Africa itself no one believes the existing willing seller approach is
adequate. Roman’s report urges a properly funded rural transformation, without
which time is running out ‘to prevent full-blown confrontation and violence in
rural South Africa’ (Roman, 2003: 37). Surely the correct lessons now need to be
learned quickly from the chaos in Zimbabwe resulting from 20 years of failure to
realise the true meaning of ‘independence’.
710
LAND REFORM IN ZIMBABWE
References
Alexander, J (1994) State, peasantry and resettlement in Zimbabwe, Review of African Political
Economy, 61, pp 325–345.
Ankomah, B (2001) The refugee speaks, New African, July/August, pp 8–9.
Ankomah, B (2003a) Zimbabwe: the land has come back, New African, February, pp 13–15.
Ankomah, B (2003b) Zimbabwe: the conservatives would never have done that, New African, February,
pp 48–55.
Astill, J & Palmer, R (2002) Uncertain future for whites who say they will fight on in the courts,
Guardian, 8 August.
Brown, W (1999) The EU and structural adjustment: the case of Lomé IV and Zimbabwe, Review of
African Political Economy, 79, pp 75–91.
Chattopadhyay, R (2000) Zimbabwe: structural adjustment, destitution and food insecurity, Review of
African Political Economy 27 (84), pp 307–316.
Christiansen, RE (1993) Implementing strategies for the rural economy: lessons from Zimbabwe, options
for South Africa, World Development, 21 (9), pp 1549–1566.
Cliffe, L (1988a) The prospects for agricultural transformation in Zimbabwe, in C Stoneman (ed),
Zimbabwe’s Prospects: Issues of Land, Class, State and Capital in Southern Africa, pp 309–325
(London: Macmillan).
Cliffe, L (1988b) Zimbabwe’s agricultural ‘success’ and food security in Southern Africa, Review of
African Political Economy, 43, pp 4–25.
Cliffe, L (2000) The politics of land reform in Zimbabwe, in TAS Bowyer-Bower & C Stoneman (eds),
Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp 35–45 (Aldershot: Ashgate).
Crow, B (2000) Understanding famine and hunger, in A Allen & A Thomas (eds), Poverty and
Development into the 21st Century, pp 51–74 (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Cusworth, J (2000) A review of the UK ODA Evaluation of the Land Resettlement Programme in 1988
and the Land Appraisal Mission of 1996, in TAS Bowyer-Bower & C Stoneman (eds), Land Reform
in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp 25–34 (Aldershot: Ashgate).
Davidson, B (1984) Africa in History (London: Paladin).
Deininger, K, Van den Brink, R, Hoogeveen, H & Moyo, S (2000) How land reform can contribute to
economic growth and poverty reduction: empirical evidence from international and Zimbabwe
experience, at www.eldis.org/static/doc7760.htm.
Douglas, RGS (1984) Zimbabwe Epic: National Archives (Harare: Mardon Printers).
Elich, G (2002) Zimbabwe under siege, at www.swans.com/ library/art8/elich004.html, 26 August.
Gibbons, P (1996) Zimbabwe 1991–94, in P Engberg-Pedersen et al (eds), Limits of Adjustment in Africa,
pp 347–397 (Oxford: James Currey).
Government of Zimbabwe (GoZ) (1991) Second Five-Year Development Plan 1991–1995 (Harare: GoZ).
Holman, M (2000) A shaky grip on Zimbabwe’s moral high ground, Financial Times, 13 April.
Hunt, D (1984) The Impending Crisis in Kenya: The Case for Land Reform (Aldershot: Gower).
IMF (2002) ‘IMF concludes 2001 Article IV consultation with Zimbabwe, Public Information Notice (PIN)
no 02/64, IMF.
Integrated Regional Information Network (IRIN) (2003a) Zimbabwe: year-ender 2002—rumblings of
compromise as economy faces collapse, www.irinnews.org, 21 January.
IRIN (2003b) Zimbabwe: land reform beneficiaries under scrutiny, www.irinnews.org, 25 February.
Jayne, TS & Jones, S (1997) Food marketing and pricing policy in Eastern and Southern Africa: a survey,
World Development, 25 (9), pp 1505–1527.
Kinsey, BH (1999) Land reform, growth and equity: emerging evidence from Zimbabwe’s resettlement
programme, Journal of Southern African Studies, 25 (2), pp 173–196.
Kinsey, BH (2000) The implications of land reform for rural welfare in TAS Bowyer-Bower & C
Stoneman (eds), Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp 103–118 (Aldershot:
Ashgate).
La Guardia, A (2000) Vote gives Mugabe a fee rein to seize land of white farmers, Daily Telegraph, 7
April.
Lupiya, B & Hakata, M (2001) Around Africa, New African, February.
Maisokwadzo, F (2001) Government seizes 90% of CFU farms, Zimbabwe Independent, 6 July.
Madinah, T (2001) Did he jump, or was he pushed?, New African, March 2001, p 9.
Maisokwadzo, F (2001) Government seizes 90% of CFU farms, Zimbabwe Independent, 6 July. 2001.
Mandaza, I (ed) (1986) Zimbabwe: The Political Economy of Transition 1980–1986 (Dakar: CODESRIA).
McGreal, C (2000) MDC targets reduction of Mugabe’s power, Guardian, 1 July.
McGreal, C (2001) South Africans vow to grab the land, Guardian, 26 July.
McGreal, C (2002) The trail from Lancaster House, Guardian, 16 January.
McGreal, C & Wintour, P (2000) Mugabe mobilises army for huge farm invasion, Guardian, 2 August.
Meldrum, A (2000) Mugabe plan to kill opponents is foiled, Observer, 6 August.
711
NEIL H THOMAS
Meldrum, A (2001a) Mugabe’s party backs deal to buy white farms, Guardian, 19 September.
Meldrum, A (2001b) Judges free Mugabe to seize farms, Guardian, 3 October.
Meldrum, A (2002) Zimbabwe opposition leader stands up to coup threats from military, Guardian, 4
February.
Meldrum, A & MacAskill, E (2000) Mugabe legalises land grab, Guardian, 25 May.
Moyo, S (1986) The land question, in I Mandaza (ed), Zimbabwe: The Political Economy of Transition
1980–1986, pp 165–201 (Dakar: CODESRIA).
Moyo, S (2000) The political economy of land redistribution in the 1990s, in TAS Bowyer-Bower & C
Stoneman (eds), Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp 73–82 (Aldershot:
Ashgate).
Moyo, S, Rutherford, B & Amanor-Wilks, D (2000) Land reform and changing social relations for farm
workers in Zimbabwe, Review of African Political Economy, 84, pp 181–202.
Msika, J (Vice President) (2000) Statement on announcing the fast-track approach, 17 May.
Mugabe, R (1998a) President Mugabe’s address at Mount Pleasant Farm, Murehwa 27th August ...
Manyoni Farm, Matobo District 17th September...Wakefield Farm, Makoni 29th October ... Bungwe
Farm 5th November, at www.gta.gov.zw/land%20issues/mt.html.
Mugabe, R (1998b) Address to the Donors Conference on land reform and resettlement, Harare, 9
September, 1998.
Mumbengegwi, C (1986) Continuity and change in agricultural policy, in I Mandaza (ed), Zimbabwe:
The Political Economy of Transition 1980–1986, pp 203–222 (Dakar: CODESRIA).
Munslow, B (1985) Prospects for the socialist transition of agriculture in Zimbabwe, World
Development, 13 (1), pp 41–58.
Murdoch, WW (1980) The Poverty of Nations: The Political Economy of Hunger and Population
(London: Johns Hopkins).
Oliver, R & Fage, JD (1988) A Short History of Africa (London: Penguin).
Palmer, R (1990) Land reform in Zimbabwe, 1980–1990, African Affairs, 98, pp 163–181.
Palmer, R (1998) Mugabe’s ‘land grab’ in regional perspective, presented at Conference on Land
Reform: Zimbabwe—The Way Forward, SOAS, 11 March.
Palmer, R & Birch, I (1992) Zimbabwe: A Land Divided (Oxford: Oxfam).
Potter, RB et al (1999) Geographies of Development (Harlow: Longman).
Potts, D & Mutambirwa, C (1997) ‘The government must not dictate’: rural–urban migrants’ perceptions
of Zimbabwe’s Land Resettlement Programme, Review of African Political Economy, 74,
pp 549–566.
Reuters (2000) Mugabe backtracks on invasions, Daily News, 4 August.
Roman, R (2003) South Africa: land ownership at crisis point (report to South Africa’s Commission into
Farm Attacks and Rural Security), New African, March, pp 36–39 .
Sachikonye, LM (1992) Zimbabwe: drought, food and adjustment (Briefings), Review of African
Political Economy, 53, pp 88–94.
SAPRIN (1999) Zimbabwe society perspectives on structural adjustment policies, at www.development
gap.org/dgap/saprin/ zimbabwe_forum.html.
Sen, A (1981) Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Deprivation (Oxford: Clarendon
Press).
Shaw, A (2002) Mugabe says ‘loyal’ farmers can keep some land, Guardian, 13 August.
Shoko, R (2003) Oh God, let the rains come!, New African, January, pp 18–19.
Stoneman, C (1992) The World Bank demands its pound of Zimbabwe’s flesh (Briefing), Review of
African Political Economy, 53, pp 94–96.
Stoneman, C (1993) The World Bank: some lessons for South Africa, Review of African Political
Economy, 58, pp 87–98.
Stoneman, C (2000) Zimbabwe land policy and the land reform programme, in TAS Bowyer-Bower & C
Stoneman (eds), Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp 47–57 (Aldershot:
Ashgate).
Van den Brink, R (2000) Zimbabwe land reform update, at www.oxfam.org.uk/landrights/ZimWBupd.
rtf.
Watkins, K (1995) Adjustment in Africa, in K Kapoor (ed), Africa’s Experience with Structural
Adjustment, Proceedings of the Harare Seminar, 2 May 1994, World Bank Discussion Paper,
pp 130–140.
Weiner, D (1988) Land and agricultural development, in C Stoneman (ed), Zimbabwe’s Prospects: Issues
of Land, Class, State and Capital in Southern Africa, pp 63–89 (London: Macmillan).
712