Overview DefaultBonds
Overview DefaultBonds
12.1 Background
Moody’s and S&P are the most widely known rating agencies in the world.
There are possibly smaller organizations in some areas. The bond issuers
are allocated different rating classes depending on the perceived ability of
the issuer to meet future payment obligations. For example, Moody’s allo-
cate a rating of Aaa to denote the best corporate rating implying almost no
probability of default. The next best rating is given by Aa, and then comes
A, Baa, Ba, B, and Caa. In practice only bonds with ratings Baa or above
are considered to be of investment grade. The S&P has also similar rating
classes using different naming convention. Moody’s increases the granu-
larity of the rating classes by introducing addition classes such as Aa1,
Aa2 and Aa3 within the rating class Aa. Similarly, there are classes like
A1, A2 and A3 within the A class bonds. Further details of such classifica-
tion may be found on the respective organizations’ websites.
Bond traders take into account of the rating class of a particular issuer to
come up with a price for a bond issued by such an issuer. The construction
of zero coupon yield curve for Treasury securities is well established.
Similar approach may be adopted to construct a basic zero coupon yield
curve for a given rating class from the market prices of actively traded
bonds of this rating class. This basic zero coupon yield curve for the par-
ticular rating class is then used to price any newly issued bond of the same
class. There is some theoretical issue with this assumption and the inter-
ested reader may consult Hull (2003), chapter 26.
In figure 12.1 the typical appearance of the zero coupon yield curves for
different rating classes over the corresponding Treasury zero-coupon yield
curve is shown. It is quite obvious that the spread expands as the credit rat-
ing goes down. Besides, as the maturity of the bond increases the spread
for lower rated bonds expand at a faster rate.
Here we discuss how we are able to quantify the default loss from the
available bond prices under some simplifying assumptions. For a given
maturity we can compare the prices of Treasury issued zero-coupon bond
with the prices of similar bonds issued by corporations of different rating
classes. The lower prices of corporate bonds may be thought of as due to
the effect of losses inherent in such bonds. We then express this price dif-
ference as a percentage of the Treasury (or no default) prices. Although
12.3 Losses Expected Due to Default 3
there are some theoretical issues in the assumption that the price difference
is entirely due to credit risk, we will continue with this approach.
2.5
1.5
0.5
0
3m 6m 2y 7y 10y
AAA AA BBB1 B1
Fig. 12.1 Yield spread for different rating classes as a function of maturity
q ( T ) = 1 − exp ⎡⎣ − { y ( T ) − y 0 ( T )} × T ⎤⎦ . (12.2)
With the help of the equation (12.2) we can now compute the cumula-
tive default probability for the data shown in Tables 122.1 and 12.2. These
are shown below in Tables 12.3 and 12.4. The last column in these tables
shows the probability of default in the two consecutive years given in the
first column. This is computed as the difference between the two consecu-
tive cumulative probabilities. We also note that the cumulative probability
is the same as that computed as the default loss expected in Tables 12.1
and 12.2. These results are, of course, under the assumption of no recovery
in case of default.
6 12 Overview of Default Risky Bonds
( )
q′ ( t ) = h ( t ) exp − ∫ h ( τ ) dτ .
t
0
(12.3)
Thus, either the hazard rate or the default probability density could be
used in quantifying this phenomenon. We can illustrate this concept using
the data in Table 12.4. The marginal probability of default for the AAA
bond issuer in year 10 is 3.492%. The probability of no default until year 7
is (1-0.05115) = 0.94885. Thus the hazard rate for default between year 7
and year 10 is (0.03492/0.94885) = 0.03680.
In the discussions so far we have assumed that when the company defaults
the amount recovered is zero. In practice though there is always some
amount is recovered by the lenders depending upon the seniority of the se-
curity held by a particular investor. We are not, however, involved in ana-
lyzing the time it might take through the legal system to recover any such
amounts.
We simply focus on the concept of the recovery rate of the claimable
amount of the debt. For the bond like security it is possible to assume that
the claimable amount is a percentage (R) of the no-default value of the
bond. Thus the recovery rate is assumed to be R.
Keeping our focus on the zero coupon bonds and under the assumption
that the default can only occur at the maturity date we can state that if there
is no default the holder receives $1 (face value of the bond) and the value
of this today is exp ( − y ( T ) × T ) . If the bond defaults with a probabil-
ity q ( T ) , the received amount is R × e xp ( − y 0 ( T ) × T ) . Thus, we can
write,
q (T) =
( )
1 − exp − ⎡⎣ y ( T ) − y 0 ( T ) ⎤⎦ T
.
(12.5)
1− R
The discussion in this section follows the ideas in Hull (2003) and the
spreadsheet accompanying this topic shows how the models are imple-
mented on Excel. The earlier analysis was based on the zero coupon bonds
issued by a company. Since such corporate bonds are almost non-existent
we discuss in this section corporate coupon paying bonds of different ma-
turities. We will also make two different assumptions about the claimable
amount if default occurs. We, however, maintain the assumption that a de-
fault can only occur at a bond maturity.
In order to quantify the results of this analysis and also to help the
reader implement the model on a spreadsheet, we need several symbols
with specific meanings to be defined. These are itemized below.
Certain other technical assumptions are needed for the analysis below to
hold and these are pointed out in Hull (2003, page 615).From the defini-
12.7 Multiple Bonds Issued and Realistic Scenario 9
tions of the terms above it is clear that the present value of the loss if there
is a default at time I, then,
a J,I = d I ⎡⎣ FJ,I − RC
ˆ ⎤
J,I ⎦ .
(12.6)
Since pI is the probability of default at time I, the total present value of the
losses from the Jth corporate bond may be written as,
J (12.7)
G J − BJ = ∑ pi a J ,i .
i =1
G1 − B1 (12.8)
p1 = .
a1,1
The remainder of the probabilities could be obtained from the equation be-
low:
J −1 (12.9)
G J − BJ − ∑ pi a J ,i
pJ = i =1
.
a J,J
2×T (12.10)
⎛ r⎞
F = (S − I ) ⎜1 + ⎟ .
⎝ 2⎠
The above relation assumes that the risk-free interest rate is r p.a. and it is
compounded half-yearly basis. This is a common assumption since the
corporate bonds pay half-yearly coupons.
The sample of corporate bonds analyzed is described in the table below:
The analysis assumes that the risk-free rate is at 4.75% p.a. through out the
sample period. The computed probability of default is given in the follow-
ing table for two different assumptions about the claimable amount in case
of default and 30% recovery rate.
In this section we just outline the modification needed in the analysis given
in the previous section when we allow the bonds to default at any time and
not just on bond maturity. It is intuitively clear that the problem is much
more complex in this situation. Additional details could be found in Hull
(2003) as well as in Schönbucher (2003).
In this situation we have to deal with the default probability density
q ( t ) as discussed earlier. If we assume that this is constant over the inter-
′
val t I−1 < t < t I , then the equivalent expression for (12.6) is,
tI (12.11)
b J,I = ∫ d t ⎡⎣ FJ,t − RC
ˆ ⎤
J,t ⎦ dt .
t I−1
J −1 (12.12)
G J − BJ − ∑ q′i b J,i
q′J = i =1
.
b J,J
b0 = p 0,1 + p0,2
.
v 0 = p0,1 × v1 + p0,2 × v 2
⎡ p0,1 p0,2 ⎤
b0 = ( p0,1 + p0,2 ) ⎢ + ⎥
⎣⎢ p0,1 + p 0,2 p0,1 + p0,2 ⎦⎥
⎡ p 0,1 p0,2 ⎤
v 0 = ( p0,1 + p0,2 ) ⎢ v1 + v2 ⎥.
⎣⎢ p0,1 + p0,2 p0,1 + p0,2 ⎦⎥
We should note from the definition that the gross risk-free return ( r0 ) is
1 p 0,1 p0,2
given by . We also define, q1 = , q2 = .
p0,1 + p0,2 p0,1 + p0,2 p0,1 + p0,2
Then the above expressions simplify to,
12.11 Merton’s Model of Default Risky Bonds 13
1
b0 = ( q1 + q 2 ) ,
r0
1
v0 = ( q1 × v1 + q 2 × v 2 ) .
r0
Merton (1974) used the option pricing framework to develop a model for
pricing the corporate bonds. The model assumes that a firm has a single
zero-coupon bond in its capital structure. The firm has promised the bond
holder to repay the face value of the bond on its maturity date. If the firm’s
value on the bond’s maturity date is less than the face value of the bond,
the firm actually defaults in its promised payment. It also assumes that the
claim of the bond holder is superior to that of the equity holder. Thus, if
the firm’s market value at maturity is greater than the face value of the
bond the debt holder gets the full face value back. On the other hand, if the
firm’s value is less than that of the face value of the bond the debt holder
gets the lower amount. This payoff pattern of the risky debt at maturity re-
sembles that of an option where the underlying asset is the firm’s value
and the exercise price is the face value of the debt.
We can now quantify this idea and explain how Back-Scholes option
pricing model might be utilized to compute the value of the risky bond.
We need the following symbols for this purpose and follows the presenta-
tion in Hull (2003).
E T = max ( VT − D, 0 ) . (12.13)
The equity is thus a call option on the value of the firm’s assets with the
exercise price of D. Assuming that the Black-Scholes framework applies
here, we can write the value of the firm’s equity today as the price of the
European style call option. This gives,
E 0 = V0 N ( d1 ) − De − rf T N ( d 2 ) , (12.14)
where rf is the risk-free interest rate for the same maturity. N ( i ) repre-
sents the cumulative normal distribution with the appropriate argument.
These arguments are defined as,
1 ⎡ ⎛ V0 ⎞ ⎛ σ2V ⎞ ⎤ (12.15)
d1 = ⎢ln ⎜ ⎟ + ⎜ rf + ⎟ T⎥
σV T⎣ ⎝D⎠ ⎝ 2 ⎠ ⎦.
d 2 = d1 − σ V T
σ E E 0 = N ( d1 ) σ V V0 . (12.16)
For publicly traded firms the equity value and its volatility are quite easily
measurable from the market observations. Thus using the equations
(12.14) and (12.16) V0 and σV may be jointly estimated by solving these
two non-linear equations. This essentially becomes a non-linear optimiza-
tion problem under a suitable norm. The example in Hull (2003) clarifies
this issue further.
12.12 Conclusions
Exercise 1:
Suppose that a company has issued four bonds of different maturities
and coupon rates as tabulated below. All coupons are paid half yearly. The
yield spread over the risk-free rate of the four bonds is also given in the ta-
ble. The risk-free rate is assumed to be flat at 6% p.a. Assume that today’s
date is 13 July 2004. Estimate the probability of default for these bonds
under the assumptions that the bonds can only default on the maturity
dates and the claimable amounts are face value plus the accrued interests.
References
Merton, R. (1974), On the pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Inter-
est Rates, Journal of Finance, 29, pp. 449-470.
Bluhm, C., Overbeck, L. and Wagner, C. (2002), An Introduction to Credit Risk
Modeling, Chapman & Hall.
Hull, J. (2003), Options, Futures and Other Derivatives, Fifth edition, Prentice
Hall.
Schönbucher, P. J. (2003), Credit Derivatives Pricing Models, Models, Pricing and
Implementation, Wiley Science.