A. J. Taylor - Progress and Poverty in Britain, 1780-1850
A. J. Taylor - Progress and Poverty in Britain, 1780-1850
A. J. Taylor - Progress and Poverty in Britain, 1780-1850
I 780-1850: A REAPPRAISAL
A. J. T A Y L O R
University College, London
i
D I D THE CONDITION of the working classes improve or deteriorate
during the period of rapid industrial change between I 780 and I 850?
The controversy is as old as the Industrial Revolution itself. For men
like Andrew Ure and Thomas Carlyle, as for Porter and Engels, the
issue was one of contemporary politics. While Ure, a nineteenth-
century Dr. Pangloss, so admired the new industrial order that he could
compare factory children to ‘lively elves’ a t play,g Carlyle saw the world
of the millhand as ‘but a dingy prison-house, of rebellious unthrift,
rebellion, rancour, indignation against themselves and against all men’.4
Even among the classical economists there was a sharp division of
opinion. O n the one hand were those like Porter, whose optimism had
its roots in the doctrines of The Wealth of Nations; on the other those
whose pessimism reflected the less sanguine approach of Malthus and
Ricardo.
With the marked improvement in national prosperity which Britain
experienced in the third quarter of the nineteenth century, the debate
lost something of its early vigour and urgency. The statistical investiga-
1 Trans. W. 0. Henderson and W. H. Chaloner (Oxford, 1958), p. 10.
P. 532.
a A. Ure, Philosophy of Manufactures (1835), p. 301.
4 T. Carlyle, Chartinn (1839), p. 35.
A . J. TAYLOR ‘7
tions of Leone Levi and Sir Robert Giffen5 tended to confirm what the
observation of contemporaries already suggested: that, in common with
the nation at large, the working classes were enjoying a perceptibly
higher standard of living in 1875 than twenty-five years earlier. The
will to resist the tide of industrial growth was declining as its benefits
became more apparent, and with the logic of time the controversy was
passing from the hands of the publicists and reformers into those of the
economic historians.
The transition was, however, by no means an immediate one.
Thorold Rogers, an early historian of the Industrial Revolution, in
1884 welcomed the return of the political economist ‘to his proper and
ancient function, that of interpreting the causes which hinder the just
and adequate distribution of wealth’.6 To Rogers the years of rapid
industrial change were a ‘dismal period’ for the working classes, and
the quarter century after 1790 ‘the worst time in the whole history of
English labour’.’ Arnold Toynbee’s verdict echoed that of Rogers. ‘We
now approach’, he said, ‘a darker period-a period as disastrous and as
terrible as any through which a nation ever passed; disastrous and ter-
rible because side by side with a great increase of wealth was seen an
enormous increase of pauperism.’B In both these interpretations the
voice of the social reformer mingles with that of the historian: and the
view thus firmly expressed commanded general acceptance for more
than a generation. I t is to be found as much in the writings of Ashley
and Cunningham as in those of the Webbs and the Hammonds.
I t was not until after the first world war that a new and less dismal
note was struck.9 Then within the short space of little more than a year
the pessimists’ interpretation was four times put to serious question. I n
her London L$e of the Eighteenth Century, lo Mrs. Dorothy George argued,
largely on the basis of mortality statistics, that the standard of life of the
London labourer had improved considerably in the course of the
eighteenth century. This thesis was reinforced and extended a year later
in the work of Miss M. C. Buerll and G . Talbot Griffith.12 Each found
cvidence of a declining death-rate in the country as a whole between
1750 and 1850, and from this drew the general conclusion that living
standards were rising. At the same time an even more powerful ‘opti-
mist’l3 entered the lists. From the evidence of nineteenth-century wage
6 L. Levi, Wages and Earnings of the Working Classes (1885); R. Giffen, Essays in Finance,
Second Series (1886), pp. 365-474.
Thorold Rogers, preface to abridged version of Work and Wases (1885).
7 Zbid., pp. 140, 128.
A. Toynbee, The Industrial Revolution (1884), p. 84.
For a Dossible anticipation of Clapham’s conclusion (see below), .. see Dictionary- of- Political
Economy, Grid edn. (1go8),iii. 802 (A: L. Bowley’s article).
Pubd. 1925.
l1 M. C. Buer, Health, Wealth and Population in the Earb Days of the Industrial Revolution (1926).
l e G . T. Griffith, Population Problems of the Age of Malthus (1926).
Is The terms ‘pessimist’ and ‘optimist’, though not wholly apposite, have now obtained
general currency. They are certainly preferable to the alternatives ‘classical’ and ‘modern’
recently used. The so-called ‘modern’ theory of improving living standards has as long an
ancestry as its ‘classical’ antithesis.
18 PROGRESS A N D P O V E R T Y I N BRITAIN
statistics and commodity prices, Sir John Clapham concluded that the
purchasing power of the English labourer in town and country had
risen substantially between I 785 and 1850.~~
This new turn in the controversy not only redressed the balance of
forces, but, by reintroducing the statistical weapon, revived methods
of argument largely disused since the days of Rogers and Giffen. Where
the Hammonds, like Engels before them, turned to the evidence of the
blue books and the pamphleteers, Mrs. George and Griffith appealed to
the bills of mortality, and Clapham to the wage books. Faced with so
great a display of statistical force, J. L. Hammond conceded-though
not uncritically-this part of the field.16 He was content to rest his case
on the written and verbal testimony of contemporaries to the physical
and spiritual suffering which, he contended, had been the inevitable
concomitant of the new order. Men might have more food for their
bcllies and cheaper clothing for their backs but the price exacted for
these benefits was out of all proportion to the gains. ‘The spirit of wonder
... could not live at peace in treadmill cities where the daylight never
broke upon the beauty and the wisdom of the world.’le
As a via media between two hitherto irreconcilable viewpoints, Ham-
mond’s compromise was readily accepted by writers of general histories,
and it has retained an unshaken place in their affections; but it could
be no final settlement of the debate. Thirty years now separate us from
the work of Clapham and Hammond. I n those years discussion has con-
tinued sporadically but vigorously. Most recently T. s. Ashton and
E. J. Hobsbawm, in particular, have opened up new fields of evidence
and lines of enquiry. I t is appropriate to ask how far their findings
have changed the broad pattern of argument and interpretation,
ii
Of the twin sides of the debate that which relates to the qualitative
aspects of the labourer’s life has, not surprisingly, made least progress.17
The bleakness and degradation of much urban life in the early nine-
teenth century needs no underlining. The mean streets and insanitary
houses still surviving in many industrial towns, and the mute desolation
of large areas of South Wales and the West Midlands are as eloquent
testimony to the drabness of nineteenth-century life as are the pages of
the parliamentary reports. This was an England ‘built in a hurry’ and
with little thought for the health and wellbeing of its rapidly growing
multitudes. But, asJ. D. Chambers has observed:18‘Whatever the merits
of the pre-industrial world may have been, they were enjoyed by a
l4 J. H. Clapham, Economic History of Modem Britain, i. (1926), pp. 128,466, 560-2.
l6 J. L.Hammond, ‘The Industrial Revolution and Discontent’, Econ. Hist. Rev., ii (rgso),
2 I 5-28. J. L. and B. Hammond, T h Age of the Chartists (1930),p 365.
l7 For a recent re-statement of the issues, on the whole favourable to the pessimistic
viewpoint, see W. Woodruff, ‘Capitalism and the Historians: A Contribution to the Dis-
cussion on the Industrial Revolution in England‘, Jour. Econ. Hist., xvi (1956),1-17.
J. D. Chambers, l71c Vulc of Trent r670-rBm (Econ. Hist. Rev. Supplements, 3, n.d.),
P. 63.
A. J. TAYLOR 19
deplorably small proportion of those born into it.’ If the industrial
towns carried the seeds of physical and spiritual death for some, they
also brought new life and opportunity to others. Not only did the towns
ultimately give enhanced possibilities of physical health and enjoyment
to the many; they also provided those widening cultural opportunities
which, side by side with more debasing attractions, have come to dis-
tinguish the urban societies of the modern world. The older generation
perhaps suffered most in the upheavals and disorders of early industrial
development: for the younger and more adaptable the transition may
not all have been disenchantment. But at this point argument comes
close to dogmatism, for the historian’s assessment of gain and loss must
inevitably be coloured by his personal value judgements and
predilections.
This overriding difficulty is not entirely absent from the parallel
controversy about material living standards; but here at least the his-
torian can appeal to the statistics. Although this particular oracle is in
no sense infallible-too often it is mute or, when vocal, ambiguous-it
offers some firm foundations for argument. I t is essential, therefore, at
this point, that we examine, however briefly, the main types of statistical
evidence available to the historian.
The most direct route to the assessment of changing living standards
lies through the measurement of the movement of real wages. Real.
wages relate money earnings to retail prices, and their movement, there-
fore, reflccts the changing purchasing power of the consumer. Clapham’s
calculation of the movement of real wages suggests that the purchasing
power of the industrial worker rose by some 16 per cent between I 790
and 1840, and by 70 per cent over the slightly longer period from I 790
to 1850.10 I n the same periods the real earnings of farm-workers in-
creased by 2 2 per cent and 60 per cent.20These assessments were based
on the wage statistics assembled at the beginning of the present century
by A. L. Bowley and G. H. Wood, and on a cost-of-living index computed
by N. J. Silberling. Since Clapham’s guarded findings were published,
however, Silberling’s index has been tested and found wanting,21 and
its rejection has inevitably invalidated the conclusions which Clapham
based upon it.
Where Silberling failed, others have ventured with little greater
success.22 But even were a satisfactory cost-of-living indcx established,
and in the nature of things this would seem unlikely, it would still leave
unsolved the equally complex problem of devising a satisfactory general
index of working-class earnings. Here, as in the case of prices, the funda-
mental obstacle is the insufficiency and unreliability of the surviking
lo Based on Clapham, p. 561. 20 Ibid., p. 128.
81 See emeciallv T. S. Ashton. ‘The Standard of Life of the Workers in England., 1740-
Y ._
1830’, 30uL Econ.‘Hist., Supplement ix (1949), 29-30.
E.g. E. W. Gilboy, ‘The Cost of Living and Real Wages in Eighteenth-CenturyEngland’,
Reu. Ecan. Statistics, xviii (1936), 134-43; R. S. Tucker, ‘Real Wages of Artisans in London,
17zg-1935’,Jour. Amcr. Statistical Sac. (1936),73-84.
20 PROGRESS A N D P O V E R T Y I N B R I T A I N
iii
Where so much remains legitimately controversial, the historian can
at best draw only tentative conclusions. The evidence, however, would
appear to permit two immediate generalizations. There is reason to
believe that after an early upsurge in living standards in the first stages
of rapid industrialization, the pace of advance slackened, and decline
may even have set in, by the beginning of the nineteenth century. It is
also evident, notwithstanding Porter’s assertion to the contrary,42 that
the progress of the working class lagged increasingly behind that of the
nation at large. Had working-class incomes kept pace with the growth
of the national income, the average worker could have expected to find
himselfsome 50 per cent better off in real terms in 1840than thirty years
earlier.43Even the most sanguine of optimists would hardly claim that
such was in fact the case.
To explain how this situation arose is in a measure to validate the
facts themselves. Thorold Rogers, writing in the 1880s, attributed the
poverty of the working classes in the earlier part of the century to a
variety of causes: to the unrestricted employment, before the first
effective factory act in 1833, of juvenile labour; to restrictions on, and
the weakness of, trade unions; and to the attitude of employers and of
the law.44 But, significantly, he added that, although ‘the sufferings of
the working classes . ..
might have been aggravated by the practices of
employers, and were certainly intensified by the harsh partiality of the
.
law. . they were due in the main to deeper causes’.46Chief among
these, Rogers cited the protracted wars against France, the economic
dcrangements which accompanied them, and the behaviour of successive
governments, which were slow to remedy social evils, yet intervened
‘l M. R. Reinhard, Hirtoire dc la Population Mondiale ds 1700 d 1948 (Paris, 1949), passim.
‘* Porter, pp. 531-2.
Based on the national income estimates assembled by P. Deane, ‘Contemporary Esti-
mates of National Income in the First Half of the Nineteenth Century’, Econ. Hist. Rev.,
2nd ser. viii (1956), 339-54.
’’ Rogers, pp. 130 ff.
dB Ibid., pp. 140-1.
26 PROGRESS A N D POVERTY I N B R I T A I N
unwisely to maintain the price of bread and to impede the development
of trade unionism.
Modern historians have tended to endorse Rogers’ findings, though
with varying degrees of emphasis. They have also added two other
factors, made evident by more recent economic experience: the effect of
the claims of long-term investment on current c o n ~ u m p t i o nand
, ~ ~ the
movement of the terms of trade. A brief examination of the interaction
of these varied factors is relevant to our discussion of living standards.
In the early stages of rapid industrial growth, a society is obliged to
make heavy investments not only in buildings, machinery, stocks and
equipment, but also in communications and public utilities. Such in-
vestment must inevitably be made at the expense of current consumption,
unless, as in the case of the United States, foreign investors are willing
to prime the pump of economic development. Thus Soviet Russia
declared a virtual moratorium on increased living standards while lay-
ing the foundations of her industrial greatness in the 1920s. Britain after
I 780 was erecting textile-mills and iron-works, constructing a great net-
work of canals and laying the nucleus of a greater railway system, and
building reservoirs, gas-works and hospitals to meet the present and
future needs of a rapidly growing urban population, Like Russia a
century later, though less consciously, she was sacrificing present com-
fort to the pursuit of future wealth and prosperity. By 1850 this early
investment was yielding abundant fruit, and future expansion, in terms
of railways, steamships, steel-mills, and electrical plant, was no longer
to be incompatible with rising living standards.
The needs of capital accumulation, therefore, supply a partial ex-
planation of the relative depression of working-class living standards
in this period of rising national wealth. I t would be unwise to press this
argument too hard, however. In Japan, for example, whose industrial
growth after 1918closely paralleled that of Britain in the early nine-
teenth century, it proved possible to reconcile industrial growth with a
perceptible advance in living standards.47 We must, therefore, look
further afield if we are to explain not only the slow but still more the
inconstant rise of living standards in nineteenth-century England. It is
here, in particular, that significance is to be attached to the effects of
the French Wars and to the frequently adverse movement of the terms
of trade.
The wars against revolutionary and Napoleonic France imposed a
severe strain upon the resources of the nation, and offset, in part at
least, the gains of industrial and commercial expansion. Large-scale
borrowing by the state during the war, and the imposition of severely
regressive taxation at its end, not only induced serious wartime in-
flation but tended further to redistribute the national income in favour
46 For a recent restatement of this thesis, see S. Pollard, ‘Investment, Consumption and the
Industrial Revolution’, &on. Hisf. Rev., 2nd ser. xi (1958), 215-26.
4’ G . C. Allen, Short Economic History of Modern Japan (1946),p. I 06.
A . J. TAYLOR 27
of the men of property. War thereby, both directly and indirectly, acted
on balance to the economic detriment of the nation at large and to that
of thc working class in particular.
The movement of the terms of trade also proved disadvantageous to
the working-class consumer. During the first half of the nineteenth
century the terms on which Britain dealt in foreign markets steadily
worsened, more particularly between I 800 and I 8I 5, and between I 830
and 1840.~~ In order to pay for a given volume of imported goods,
Britain had to export almost twice as much in 1840as she had done in
1800.Specifically, the price of cotton exports fell much more rapidly
after 1815than did that of imported foodstuffs. In part-though only
in part-cotton manufacturers and their employees were able to find
compensation in a reduction of the pricc of their imported raw material:
for the rest they had no alternative but to accept lower profit margins
and reduced piece-rates. A significant share of the bcnefits of Britain’s
new industrial efficiency, therefore, went neither to her workers nor to
her industrialists, but to the foreign consumer.
Behind these pervasive but temporary factors lay the insistent force
of population pressure. In so far as population increase may be ascribed
a determinant r61e in the economic growth of this period, it is easy to
understand how the upward thrust of population, though it facilitated
and encouraged industrial advance, also retarded the improvement in
living standards which industrialization brought in its train. Since the
value of labour, as of any other commodity, gains with scarcity, an over-
abundant supply of labour is plainly inimical to the advance of working-
class living standards.
How plentiful then was the supply of labour in early ninetcenth-
century England? Thc question admits of no categorical answer. The
rapid increase in population, the influx of Irish immigrants, particularly
into industrial Lancashire and western Scotland, the readiness with
which women and young children could be employed in mills and work-
shops, are all pointers to an abundant labour supply. But the supply of
workers must be measured against the demands of employers. That the
number of those seeking employment in a year of intense depression like
1842 was far in excess of demand is tragically evident; but we need to
deepen our knowledge of employment conditions in boom years like 1835
before we can pass final judgement on the general state of the labour
market. The relative immobility of labour, in terms both of geographical
and of occupational movement, tended to create not one but a number
of virtually independent ‘markets’for labour, in some of which workmen
were in short, and in others in abundant supply. If a generalization is
to be ventured it must be that, except at the level of the skilled worker
or in years of exceptional demand, employers had little difficulty in
48 A. H. Imlah, Economic Elements in the Pax Britannica (Cambridge, Mass., 1958),pp. 94-98.
For a somcwhat different approach to the terms of trade, see Ashton, ‘Standard of Life of
the Workers in England’, pp. 25-8.
28 PROGRESS AND POVERTY IN BRITAIN
finding hands; and to this extent the worker, lacking effective trade
union organization, was generally placed in a weak position in his
dealings with his employer.
To dwell thus upon these three major forces is not to deny the signifi-
cance of more traditional explanations of working-class discontent; but
it may serve to place these in a new perspective. That the scales were
heavily weighted against the working classes is indisputable. There is
no shortage of evidence, in the blue books and elsewhere, of capitalist
excesses, some of them committed in the name of so-called sound
economics, some of them less worthily motivated. I n face of these, the
worker could find little help from a state which made him the weaker
partner in every contract and frustrated his efforts at collective self-
help. But these evils, although they were the most apparent and the
most easily remediable, were neither the only, nor probably the most
important, causes of the failure of the working classes to derive early
benefits from the rapid growth of industrial enterprise and productivity.
iv
We may now sketch in rather fuller detail the general movement of
working-class living standards between 1780 and 1850.The limited
evidence suggests that down to about I 795 working-class families were
gaining at least a share in the benefits of quickening economic activity. 49
Prices for manufactured goods in foreign markets were buoyant and
industry was reaping the full reward of its increased productivity,
Workers in the newly stimulated industries enjoyed rapidly rising living
standards; this was above all the golden age of the Lancashire handloom
weaver. From the mid-1790~ a new and less happy trend is apparent.
War, inflation, and worsening terms of trade spelt distress for all but
limited sections of the working class. ‘Wages limped slowly behind the
cost of living, the standard of living of the workers was lowered.’ 50
Recovery after 1815was slow and interrupted. There were good years
like 1825,when employment was high and earnings moved upwards,
and even better ones like 1836,when a strong demand for labour went
hand in hand with falling food prices. At such times working-class living
standards, particularly in the industrial North, reached heights much
above those of the best years of the eighteenth century. But there were
also years, like I 8I 7 and I 842,when work was scarce and food dear, and
the position of the labourer, not least in the towns, was little if a t all
better than that of his predecessor in the leanest years of the earlier age.
It is evident that by 1840the material progress of half a century had not
yet sufficed to insulate the working class against the worst effects of
economic depression. The ebb and flow of working-class fortunes, as of
those of the economy in general, had in some respects tended to become
4D See Hobsbawm, ‘British Standard of Living’, p. 46. For a different view of these years,
see Salaman, pp. 487 ff. 60 Ashton, The Industrial Revolution, 1760-1830 ( I @ ) , p. 150.
A . J. TAYLOR 29
more marked with the growth of industrialism and of the nation’s ex-
port trade. To this extcnt the labourer suffered more sharply under the
pressure of industrial distress, though he gained equally substantially
when business activity moved upward. In the exact calculation of gain
and loss which a comparison with an earlier age involves, it is necessary
to take account not only of both prosperous and depressed years but also
perhaps of the new insecurity which the changing character of the
business cycle brought with it. But the calculation, however nicely
weighted, depends on the accuracy of the information at the historian’s
disposal, and the vagaries of the evidence must leave the ultimate
question still an open one.
To say this may appear tantamount to suggesting that a generation
of historians has laboured to bring forth a mouse. But the appearance is
deceptive. Although the central issue may remain unresolved-and is
perhaps likely to remain so-the area of controversy has been sub-
stantially and significantly reduced. Optimist and pessimist now agree
in seeing the years before 1795 and from the early 1840s as periods of
advance-the latter to be sustained until almost the end of the nine-
teenth century; each views the quarter century of war as a time of
deterioration; and each also draws distinctions between the experiences
of different types of worker.61 It is common ground that the skilled en-
joyed relative prosperity; and among these are to be numbered not only
the craftsmen called into existence by the new order, but also the older
artisan, now pressed into fuller and wider service. I n this group are to be
found machine-makers, iron-moulders, builders, printers and not least
hewers of coal and ore. There is similar agreement that decline in living
standards was the lot of the domestic worker in those industries where
the machine had taken early command, in cotton weaving and hosiery
knitting, for example. But in 1840 the majority of English workers, in-
cluding the vast and varied army of farm-labourers and the smaller
company of textile operatives, fell outside these two groups, and their
experience in terms of gain or loss can be neither so easily nor so in-
disputably defined.
All this would suggest that the area of disagreement has contracted.
Certainly it has become more clearly defined: and this is also true in a
further sense. It is perhaps no more than an accident that Professor
Ashton speaks of the Standard of Life of the Workers in England and
Dr. Hobsbawm of the British Standard of Life. Neither makes great play
with the implicit distinction;62but from the point ofview of the general
controversy its importance can scarcely be exaggerated, a fact which
Porter recognized a century ago, when he restricted his claim ofimproving
E.’ Cf. Ashton, An Economic History of England: 7he Eighteenth Century (1g55), pp. 234-5;
also ‘Standard of Life of the Workers in England‘, pp. 33-8, Hobsbawm, ‘Thc Labour
Aristocracyin Nineteenth-CenturyBritain’ in Democracy and the Labour Movement (ed.J. Saville),
pp. 101-39 (especially pp. 205-8).
6 a But n.6. the distinction between English and Irish experience made by Ashton, Industrial
Revolution, p. 161.
30 PROGRESS A N D POVERTY IN BRITAIN
[This article was in the printer’s hands before the appearance of R. M. Hartwell’s ‘Inter-
pretations of the Industrial Revolution in England: a Methodological Inquiry’, journal of
Economic History,xix, 1959, pp. 229-49. Mr. Hartwell’s essay represents a parallel and in
some respects complementary approach to that attempted here.]