Praveen Jha-Labour Condition in Rural India
Praveen Jha-Labour Condition in Rural India
Praveen Jha-Labour Condition in Rural India
Developing Countries
Nicola Pontara is Head of South Sudan World Bank Office, South Sudan.
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work are entirely
those of the authors and should not be attributed in any manner to the World
Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent.
Routledge ISS Studies in Rural Livelihoods
Editorial Board: A. Haroon Akram-Lodhi (Trent University), Saturnino M.
Borras Jr. (Institute of Social Studies), Cristóbal Kay (Chair) (Institute of Social
Studies) and Max Spoor (Institute of Social Studies).
Routledge and the Institute of Social Studies (ISS) in The Hague, the Netherlands
have come together to publish a new book series in rural livelihoods. The series
will include themes such as land policies and land rights, water issues, food policy
and politics, rural poverty, agrarian transformation, migration, rural-oriented social
movements, rural conflict and violence, among others. All books in the series will
offer rigorous, empirically grounded, cross-national comparative and inter-regional
analysis. The books will be theoretically stimulating, but will also be accessible to
policy practitioners and civil society activists.
Edited by
Carlos Oya and
Nicola Pontara
First published 2015
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2015 selection and editorial matter, Carlos Oya and Nicola Pontara;
individual chapters, the contributors
The right of the editors to be identified as the authors of the editorial
matter, and of the authors for their individual chapters, has been asserted
in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the Copyright, Designs and
Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or
utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now
known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in
any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing
from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or
registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation
without intent to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Rural wage employment in developing countries: theory, evidence and
policy / [edited by] Carlos Oya, Nicola Pontara.
pages cm
Includes bibliographical references and index.
1. Manpower policy, Rural–Developing countries. 2. Labor market–
Developing countries. 3. Rural development–Developing countries.
I. Oya, Carlos. II. Pontara, Nicola.
HD5710.85.D44R874 2015
331.109173'4–dc23 2014047691
List of figures xi
List of tables xii
Notes on contributors xiv
Acknowledgements xvii
List of abbreviations xix
1 Introduction 1
2 Putting employment back into the poverty reduction policy
debates 5
3 The challenge of capturing rural wage labour in developing
countries: invisible wage workers? 11
4 Rethinking theory: towards a political economy of rural labour
markets in poorer countries 17
5 Key features of rural labour markets and contemporary
struggles of rural labour 21
6 Concluding remarks 26
1 Introduction 37
2 History and methodology: an account of the neglect of rural
wage employment in Senegal and Mauritania 39
3 Emerging evidence about the significance and the types of wage
labour relations in rural areas 46
4 Key aspects of rural wage employment in Senegal and
Mauritania 54
5 Concluding remarks 61
viii Contents
3 Lifting the blinkers: a new view of power, diversity, and
poverty in Mozambican rural labour markets 69
CHRISTOPHER CRAMER, CARLOS OYA, AND JOHN SENDER
1 Introduction 69
2 Survey rationale and methodology 71
3 Variations in methods of pay: monthly, daily, and piece-work
pay 75
4 Variations in rates of pay for agricultural work 80
5 Variations in payment rates for non-agricultural work 82
6 A classification of jobs and payment methods 82
7 The political economy of labour control 88
8 Some characteristics of the poorest workers and their labour
market prospects 90
9 Conclusion 92
1 Introduction 101
2 A history of violence: the formation of the rural proletariat in
South Africa 103
3 Post-apartheid policy and invisibility of rural wage workers in
South Africa 107
4 From violence to economic coercion: the case of forestry 112
5 Conclusion 121
1 Introduction 128
2 Labour market and household surveys in Southern Africa 129
3 Limitations of surveys in assessing employment and migration 131
4 The changing context of migration and employment 135
5 Alternative surveys of agricultural migrant employment 137
6 Conclusions 139
1 Introduction 144
2 Taking stock: conventional wisdom on rural labour markets in
Tanzania 145
Contents ix
3 An alternative method 149
4 Revealing the true extent of labour market relations in rural
Tanzania: a case study of the West Usambara Mountains 151
5 Policy conclusions for poverty reduction and rural
development 160
1 Introduction 171
2 Who are the poorest? Conflicting evidence on rural poverty 171
3 People working for other people: key characteristics and
sources of vulnerability 191
4 The policy neglect of rural labour markets 195
5 Concluding remarks 199
1 Introduction 205
2 Data pointers from large-scale surveys 206
3 Insights from field studies 214
4 Conclusion 222
1 Introduction 230
2 Historical background 231
3 China’s transition to capitalism and the growth of rural wage
employment 233
4 The dynamics of wage employment and the circulation of
labour 241
5 Wage work and socio-economic differentiation 247
6 Conclusions 249
1 Introduction 254
2 Emergence of the grape branch and its labour force 256
x Contents
3 Structuring the rural labour market: containing labour’s
developmental gains 264
4 Summary, conclusions, and policy implications 271
1 Introduction 276
2 The growth and transformation of labour markets in Colombia’s
coffee industry 278
3 Lemons, a major fresh fruit export industry in Tucumán,
northern Argentina 286
4 Conclusion 298
1 Introduction 305
2 Migrant social networks 306
3 Costa Rica’s agricultural development and supporting
institutions 308
4 The wide and beaten path into Costa Rica coffee farms 309
5 Entering the exclusive non-traditional export sector 317
6 Conclusion 323
1 Introduction 329
2 Policy implications 330
3 Concluding remarks 345
Index 351
Figures
Figures
3.1 Possession scores by type of job in agriculture 92
6.1 Share of kibarua incomes as percentage of total EHH income 159
Map
2.1 Fieldwork areas in Mauritania and Senegal 44
Tables
Praveen Jha is Professor of Economics at the Centre for Economic Studies and
Planning (CESP), School of Social Sciences, Jawaharlal Nehru University,
New Delhi, India. He is currently Honorary Visiting Professor at Rhodes Uni-
versity, Grahamstown, South Africa, and at the African Institute for Agrarian
Studies, Harare, Zimbabwe. He is one of the editors of the journal Agrarian
South: Journal of Political Economy. His broad area of research and teaching
is political economy of development, with an emphasis on labour, agriculture,
natural resources, public finance, education, and history of economic thought.
Sutti Ortiz is Emerita Professor at Boston University. She has written exten-
sively about risk and the decision-making process of peasants and small
farmers, predominantly in Latin America. Since 1984 her research has
focused on agricultural labourers in export industries, with particular atten-
tion to modes of control and labourers’ bargaining power. She is the author of
Harvesting Coffee, Bargaining Wages: Rural Labor Markets in Colombia,
1975–1990 and has published widely in various academic journals.
Carlos Oya is Reader in Political Economy of Development, Development
Studies Department, at SOAS, University of London. He has published
widely on various aspects of agrarian change, agrarian capitalism, rural
poverty, and labour markets, mostly on Africa, from an agrarian political
economy perspective. Current research interests also include the impact of
certified standards on agricultural wage employment, and methodological
questions on the political economy of large-scale land deals in Africa. He is
co-editor of the Journal of Agrarian Change.
Nicolas Petit holds an MSc in Development Studies from SOAS, University of
London. He currently works as Senior Consultant on Sustainable Develop-
ment with a focus on agricultural commodities. Nicolas has worked for the
European Commission, United Nations and various non-governmental organ-
izations. Until recently he was the Director of Standards and Assurance at the
Better Cotton Initiative.
Nicolas Pons-Vignon is a Senior Researcher at the School of Economic & Busi-
ness Sciences (SEBS), University of the Witwatersrand, Johannesburg, South
Africa. He holds a PhD from EHESS (Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences
Sociales, Paris). Nicolas’ research focuses on labour markets, economic
policy, and the role of the state in economic development. He has been the
editor of the Global Labour Column since its inception in 2009. Nicolas initi-
ated the African Programme on Rethinking Development Economics
(APORDE) in 2007, taught in South Africa, which he directed for seven years
before joining the Scientific Committee.
Nicola Pontara holds a PhD in Development Economics from SOAS, Univer-
sity of London. Nicola worked in the Ministry of Planning and Finance in
xvi Contributors
Maputo, Mozambique, as an Overseas Development Institute Fellow before
moving to the World Bank in Washington, DC. At the World Bank his work
and research interests have included social protection and labour, poverty,
labour markets, and political economy of development. He is currently the
Head of the World Bank South Sudan Country Office based in Juba, South
Sudan.
Matteo Rizzo is a Lecturer at SOAS, University of London and works across
the Departments of Economics and Development Studies. His main research
interests include informal labour and globalization, urbanization, and the
political economy of agrarian change. He is currently completing a mono-
graph entitled Taken for a Ride: Neoliberalism, Informal Labour and Trans-
port in an African Metropolis, 1983–2010 (Routledge).
Ben Selwyn is Senior Lecturer in International Relations and Development
Studies at the University of Sussex. He is the author of Workers, State and
Development in Brazil: Powers of Labour, Chains of Value (2012) and The
Global Development Crisis (2014).
John Sender is Professor Emeritus at the Economics Department, SOAS, Uni-
versity of London. He has designed surveys and conducted fieldwork in many
rural areas of Africa and Asia over a period of almost 40 years, usually focus-
ing on the development of labour markets and rural poverty. His publications
include important references for the study of capitalist development and
labour markets in Africa such as The Development of Capitalism in Africa
(Methuen, 1986) and Poverty, Class and Gender in Rural Africa: A Tanza-
nian Case Study (Routledge, 1990), both co-authored with Sheila Smith.
Qian Forrest Zhang holds a PhD from Yale University, and is currently Asso-
ciate Professor of Sociology at the School of Social Sciences, Singapore
Management University. His research on China’s political agrarian economy
aims at developing a new understanding of the dynamics of agrarian change
in China, covering topics such as accumulation, dispossession, and differenti-
ation, through the lens of commodification processes.
Acknowledgements
1 Introduction
This book makes an important contribution to the literature on development
studies and the political economy of development by filling a considerable
research gap. There has been remarkably little research on rural labour markets
and on rural wage labour in sub-Saharan Africa (henceforth Africa), Latin
America, and Asia.1 The dearth of evidence concerns in particular Africa, where
the study of labour relations and, more specifically, rural wage employment is
remarkably rare. This volume, therefore, includes substantial material on Africa.
Publications on rural poverty, particularly in low-income countries (LICs),
continue to spill a great deal of ink on proposals to improve the lives and pro-
spects of small producers (smallholder farmers), self-employed workers and
micro-entrepreneurs. By contrast, not much attention has been paid to the fate of
those who lie at the bottom of production chains as wage labourers, or those who
eke out a living by combining different kinds of economic activities to survive,
including both wage and self-employment. Theory, evidence, and policy have
been particularly silent about seasonal and casual agricultural wage workers, a
segment of the rural working class that is not adequately captured in official sta-
tistics but that remains central to poverty reduction strategies, since a large pro-
portion of rural wage workers tend to be extremely poor (World Bank 2007).2
As a result, the policy debate on the constraints to and the opportunities for
expanding wage labour demand, the levels of real wages, and the prevailing
working conditions, has been squeezed out. Drawing from a broad literature as
well as the contributions presented in this volume, this chapter explores some of
the reasons for this neglect, especially how ideology and theoretical preferences
have shaped a poverty agenda which does not feature the employment question
at its centre.
Second, the lack of attention to rural wage employment is reinforced by the con-
ventional wisdom that most wage employment is created in urban areas,9 espe-
cially during processes of industrialization and urbanization; that in developing
countries – again, particularly in Africa – rural labour markets are either absent
or very thin and rural wage labour is negligible (Barrett et al. 2005; Binswanger
6 C. Oya and N. Pontara
et al. 1989; Mellor 2014; Valdés et al. 2010). This belief is particularly strong in
relation to agricultural wage employment (Mwamadzingo 2003; FAO et al.
2005). Thus, even the emerging mainstream literature that does acknowledge the
importance of rural livelihood diversification and the rise of off-farm income
sources (Barrett et al. 2005, 15) asserts the ‘limited place of off-farm agricultural
wage labour in rural African livelihoods’.10
Reardon (1997), in one of the most widely cited articles on the emerging
RNFE, reviews a large body of literature on off-farm employment in Africa and
concludes, for example, that agricultural wage income is quantitatively not very
significant as a source of income compared to non-agricultural income sources.
However, he concedes that there is a substantial knowledge gap on hired labour
markets in the ‘rural nonfarm sector’. The relatively low share of farm wages in
Reardon’s findings does not necessarily suggest a low incidence of agricultural
wage employment, especially among the poor, but may reflect the fact that agri-
cultural wages are well below wage and non-wage earnings in other sectors of
rural economies. It also reflects the fact that remittances from migrants employed
as agricultural wage labourers are rarely reported as agricultural wage income in
the standard household surveys and simply appear as an income category without
reference to whether wage or self-employment are the key sources. Moreover,
the relative importance of agricultural wage employment cannot be simply
implied from imprecise estimates of income shares. Accessing a casual job at a
critical time in a year – the ‘hungry season’ when food stocks run out, harvests
are not ready and food prices are at their peak – can make the difference between
the ability to feed oneself or starving, even if the share of farm wages in total
imputed income in a year is low.
A reason for the neglect of the most insecure and poorly paid forms of rural
wage labour is that often this activity is lumped together with a heterogeneous
set of non-farm activities, which are often associated with a higher socio-
economic status (as in Reardon et al. 2000; Barrett et al. 2005; Mellor 2014),
making the links between poverty and farm or non-farm rural wage employment
uncertain. By lumping together very different forms of wage labour, income-
based studies fail to appreciate the importance of wage employment for the most
vulnerable rural people, especially very poor women (Sender 2003; Cramer et
al., this volume; Mueller, this volume). The literature on African RNFE, overly
focused on the binary ‘own-account farm income vs non-farm income’, usually
fails to distinguish clearly between wage employment and other forms of RNF
employment, as well as between wage employment in agricultural activities and
other forms of rural wage employment. In fact, it is often hard to classify indi-
viduals clearly in one category or the other. For example, how to classify a rural
woman who is employed to clean the house and cook in a rural area, but must
also work as a coffee picker for her employer during the harvest? Is she an agri-
cultural wage labourer or a domestic servant?11 To be sure, an important aspect
of this ‘stylized fact’ is acknowledged by some of the contributions to the main-
stream literature, notably Lanjouw (2007) and Winters et al. (2008). Lanjouw
(2007, 57) states that: ‘[a] fairly robust stylized fact about rural poverty in many
Introduction 7
parts of the developing world is that the poor are highly represented among agri-
cultural wage labourers’. This finding is especially ‘robust’ in the case of Latin
America and Asia (Lanjouw primarily writes about South Asia) but much less so
in Africa (Winters et al. 2008, 8; Davis et al. 2010), where data on rural wage
employment are certainly less reliable and generally patchy. The problem is that
non-farm activities, and wage employment within them, are very diverse and
context-specific, so a clear link with poverty is hard to establish. In general, the
finding that the rural poor are over-represented among those who participate in
the rural labour market, especially as agricultural wage labour, is intimately
related to the phenomenon of social differentiation that lies at the heart of pro-
cesses of socio-economic transformation in the countryside (Lenin 1982). While
there is a wealth of fascinating scholarly material on social differentiation and
rural labour market formation (on Africa, for example, see Sender and Smith
1990; Kitching 1980; Ghai and Radwan 1983), this kind of literature has seen a
remarkable decline since the mid-1980s. This decline has partly mirrored the
gradual marginalization of political economy in economics (Milonakis and Fine
2009) and the growing dominance of (new) neoclassical economics and neo-
populist approaches to rural development, which have focused so much research
on smallholder producers, commodity markets and price reforms (Oya 2011).12
The ideological blinkers that lead researchers and policy makers to neglect
rural wage employment in developing countries, especially agricultural wage
employment, could not, by themselves, conceal the importance of rural labour
markets for the poorest people. The ideology requires statistical support in the
form of ‘representative’ numbers. Thus the lack of attention to wage employ-
ment in rural areas is often supported by official statistics from national house-
hold surveys, labour market surveys and population censuses, which tend to
paint a picture of a rural world dominated by own-account workers (in farming
or in the RNFE) and their family members. According to the 2013 World Bank
World Development Report on ‘Jobs’ (World Bank 2012, 6), ‘a job does not
always come with a wage’. In fact, figure 1 in that report suggests that, on
aggregate, employment is usually dominated by non-wage employment (a com-
bination of own-account farming and non-agricultural self-employment). This is
particularly true in sub-Saharan Africa, where the reported proportions of men
and women who engage in some forms of wage employment is very low,
matched only by female wage employment in the Middle East and North Africa.
Only in Europe and Central Asia, and Latin America and the Caribbean are wage
employment markets well developed. Our own calculations from ILO data show
that the median percentage of total wage employment is 20, 45, and 58, respec-
tively, in Africa, a sample of middle-income Asian countries, and a sample of
six large Latin American countries (Table 1.1). For combined figures (urban and
rural), the degree of variation within sub-Saharan Africa is stark, with a number
of countries clustered in Southern Africa having between 70 and 85 per cent of
their employed population in wage jobs, in contrast to the majority of other
African countries where the proportion of wage employment does not exceed
25 per cent, and much less in rural areas (Oya 2010, table 2). So, overall, official
8 C. Oya and N. Pontara
Table 1.1 Employment status: key variables for selected regional samples (recent surveys)
Source: adapted from Oya (2013, 253); author’s calculations from data from Key Indicators of the
Labour Market database, ILO (7th edition) www.ilo.org/kilm.
statistics would suggest that sub-Saharan Africa is indeed different from other
developing regions in terms of labour market outcomes.
Cross-country contrasts on the incidence of rural wage employment are
even more pronounced. In terms of agricultural wage employment, only 4 per
cent of adult men and 1.4 per cent of women are reported to ‘mainly’ work as
agricultural wage labourers in rural Africa, compared with 22 per cent of men
and 11.4 per cent of women in South Asia, and 21 per cent and 2.3 per cent,
respectively, in Latin America. Moreover, non-agricultural rural wage
employment also appears to be significant in South Asia, Middle East and
North Africa (MENA), East Asia and Latin America (between 15 per cent and
31 per cent for men, and up to 12 per cent for women). This is in marked con-
trast to Africa, where this type of employment only applies to 9 per cent of
men and 3 per cent of women (World Bank 2007, 205, table 9.2). A recent
study by Davis et al. (2010), reporting income sources for a selected sample
of developing countries, confirms these contrasts and illustrates huge (and
perhaps inconsistent) discrepancies in findings between African countries.13
While these survey data confirm the high rural labour market participation in
Latin America, they paint a very inconsistent picture in Africa: 55 per cent of
rural people have worked for agricultural wages in Malawi, compared to 3.7
per cent in Ghana and 3.8 per cent in Nigeria. When the reported indicator is
income shares, the average income share from agricultural wage employment
in Malawi is only 11 per cent, still much higher than that of Ghana (1.4 per
cent) and Nigeria (2 per cent). These studies report that for non-farm wage
employment (still an excessively aggregated category), variation in labour
market participation is also substantial: from 50 per cent in Pakistan and over
30 per cent in Nicaragua and Vietnam, to estimates in Africa of nearly 16–18
per cent in Malawi and Ghana, and only 9 per cent in Nigeria.
Unfortunately, official employment statistics of the kind reported by the ILO,
FAO, and the World Bank in their databases, and therefore estimates from
studies that essentially analyse data from the existing national databases, are
fraught with problems. Section 3 of this chapter will describe some of them, par-
ticularly the issues that most affect the reliability of estimates of rural wage
employment.
Introduction 9
2.2 Contrasting assumptions and narratives on poverty reduction
The neglect of rural wage employment and the ideological, analytical, and statis-
tical biases that underpin it have contributed to the acceptance of a simple nar-
rative of poverty reduction that hinges on a number of assumptions about the
characteristics of the rural poor. Sender (2003) argues that the rural poor are
thought to be composed of a homogeneous set of small, self-employed farmers –
e.g. ‘smallholders’, ‘subsistence farmers’, ‘peasants’ – who rely on non-market
mediated consumption of the items produced on their own farms. At times,
claims are put forward that a sub-group of small farm households – female-
headed households – contain poorer people than other rural households. On the
basis of this interpretation of rural poverty, two overarching policy conclusions
are often made. First, the rural poor would benefit from the introduction of pol-
icies that provide appropriate price incentives to expand production on the farm.
Second, to respond to such incentives, producers need timely and realistically
priced inputs to their farming operations. Hence, it becomes imperative to
provide poor smallholders with improved access to inputs and seasonal and
medium-term production credit. In order to tackle the gender dimension of rural
poverty, moreover, such programmes would do well to privilege rural females.
Such policy prescriptions have been adapted somewhat in the mainstream liter-
ature, based on the belated recognition that: a very large number of the rural
poor in Africa are landless or near-landless; and, among them, many rural
African women only have land of insufficient size or quality to enable them to
farm effectively. It follows that it would be hardly possible for them to survive
on the basis of consumption derived from production on their own plots. There-
fore, a common recommendation to overcome (female) deprivation in rural
Africa is to promote other forms of rural self-employment, especially non-farm
self-employment, through the support of micro-credit programmes.14
A closely related popular literature strand recommends ‘income diversification’
as a potentially effective way for the rural poor to escape poverty or at least to cope
with uncertainties and shocks (Ellis 2000; Reardon et al. 2000; Mellor 2014). Much
of the burgeoning literature on the RNFE stems from this intellectual tradition,
which uses the so-called ‘livelihood approach’ (one dominant variant in the 2000s
being the ‘sustainable livelihood approach’) to analyse rural people’s ‘choices’
facing uncertainty, poverty, and shocks. This approach, although currently in
decline (Scoones 2009), has influenced countless researchers and policy makers
interested in rural development and poverty, but has made little contribution to the
understanding of rural labour markets and wage employment (see Pontara 2010 for
a comprehensive critical review).15 Many of the assumptions listed by Sender
(2003) are in fact replicated in this tradition. Methodological individualism, coupled
with choice theoretic production and consumption theory from neoclassical eco-
nomics and influenced by pro-smallholder farming approaches have helped con-
struct a narrative whereby availability of ‘assets’ (land, labour, savings, ‘human
capital’, ‘social capital’), risk-coping mechanisms, and the ‘portfolio’ of economic
activities largely determines success or failure in getting out of poverty.
10 C. Oya and N. Pontara
By contrast, a different account, framed within a political economy tradition,
suggests that rapid poverty reduction historically requires the entry of low-
skilled people into secure wage-earning jobs in higher-productivity activities; a
process that always involves structural transformation (Amsden 2012). These
socio-economic transformations (structural change, urbanization, occupational
changes, income growth, and changes in consumption patterns) are usually
driven by major state interventions in infrastructure, credit provision, innovation,
and targeted subsidies. In short, the fastest and most sustained poverty reduction
stories are to be found in those developing countries where a process of dynamic
structural transformation has been achieved. Processes of structural transforma-
tions are usually driven or accompanied by accelerated transformations in the
countryside, what the agrarian political economy calls ‘agrarian transitions’, for
which there is a variety of historically specific paths (Byres 2003). These trans-
formations obviously imply the gradual decline (and transformation) of ‘land-
based’ activities, resulting in what some call ‘de-agrarianization’, a phenomenon
that is observed virtually everywhere in the developing world (Bryceson et al.
2000; Rigg 2006). While some scholars consider this process a threat to the
‘rural poor’, understood as the mass of smallholder farmers who struggle under a
‘neoliberal regime’ (Bryceson 2000), many political economists consider this a
longstanding stylized fact of capitalist development in most societies, with its
progressive features and contradictions (Byres 2003; Amsden 2012; Chang
2010).16 In this narrative, transformations result in processes of social differenti-
ation in rural areas, which are intimately related with the growing dependence
on wage employment, especially for the most disadvantaged labour market
entrants whose bargaining and fall-back positions are weak (Lenin 1982). The
changes take time and the capacity of emerging industrial and service sectors to
absorb the growing labour supply may be limited, thus making the rural labour
market a potentially important survival option for impoverished farmers, should
employment opportunities arise, through expanded agricultural commodity pro-
duction, public work programmes, and non-agricultural growth (especially as a
domestic servant or in petty services, trade, and transport).
The heterodox narrative, which is usually empirically grounded in extensive
field research, presents a number of alternative assumptions and stylized facts
about the ‘rural poor’ (Sender 2003; Lerche 2010; and contributions in this
volume by Cramer et al., Oya, Petit and Rizzo, Mueller, Selwyn, and Pons-
Vignon). Thus very poor households tend to: have very little land and hardly any
productive assets; contain men and especially women who have failed to com-
plete many years of education or are illiterate; contain a relatively high propor-
tion of women who have started to have children as teenagers; have high child
mortality rates and malnutrition; contain few adult males who regularly earn
some income (hence women in these household are often divorced, abandoned,
or widowed); possess far fewer assets (e.g. radios, bicycles, watches or other
basic assets, including livestock) and have more precarious dwellings than those
found in less destitute rural households; belong to vulnerable or discriminated
social groups (as in Dalits in India); and contain household members (often
Introduction 11
women) who perform manual agricultural wage labour and earn wages that are
crucial for the survival of their households. The fundamental tenet supported by
the evidence presented in this literature and most contributions in this volume is
that the standard of living and the rate at which the poorest poor rural people can
escape from poverty will be determined by the quantity and quality of wage
employment they manage to find, in a context of highly insecure and casualized
jobs. As will be argued in the concluding chapter, interventions designed to
tighten rural labour markets by boosting demand for unskilled agricultural and
non-agricultural wage labour and strengthening workers’ bargaining power are
more likely to directly affect the poorest rural people, whether in Asia and Latin
America, where there is more acceptance of these arguments, or in Africa, where
recommendations to promote self-employment continue to dominate. However,
for any intervention to be appropriately designed, the evidence base on rural
wage employment must be substantially improved, especially in the poorest
countries where statistical systems are weak and under-resourced.
[In] most developing economies no efforts at all are made to collect time-
series data on the wages of those employed in small-scale farm and non-
farm rural enterprises, especially on the wages of those who are irregularly,
seasonally, or casually employed. In most of these economies, in fact, there
is no reliable data on the number of people or households that depend upon
earnings in these types of employment; it is simply assumed that the rural
poor are, or will become self-employed.
6 Concluding remarks
This introductory chapter has attempted to provide an overview of the main
analytical themes and issues contained in this book. One of the key objectives
Introduction 27
was to discuss the linkages between the literature on labour and the literature on
rural poverty, making a case for the significance of rural labour market studies
for poverty analysis. The study of rural labour markets in developing countries
presents a number of complex theoretical, methodological, and policy chal-
lenges. The case studies selected for this collection engage with these various
challenges and propose ways forward. The relative lack of adequate quantitative
evidence and policy attention on rural labour markets and employment strategies
for poverty reduction are disappointing, if not new, findings, but this book is the
first systematic attempt to reveal these gaps with field-based comparative evid-
ence. However, much more high-quality field-based research and much more
methodological and theoretical openness to different (old and new) ways of
looking at rural labour are needed. The case for interdisciplinarity, survey design
innovations and adjustments and conceptual rethinking cannot be overstated. It
is frustrating that, after so many decades of research and policy work on rural/
agrarian development and rural poverty, we still know so little about the nature
and evolution of rural/agricultural labour markets. What are the current agricul-
tural money wage rates in Senegal, Mozambique, Brazil, or China? What have
been the trends in real wages over the past 30 years? To what extent and why do
rural women access what type of casual and seasonal wage jobs? Why are there
such variations in rural working conditions within countries and sectors? These
and other questions might perhaps be answered if more resources had been dir-
ected to fund carefully designed LFS and independent research on rural wage
employment. Even a fraction of the funding provided by aid agencies and inter-
national NGOs to engage villagers in participatory exercises and to produce
poverty indicators together with highly contested poverty lines would make a
difference to our understanding of rural labour relations.
Addressing the theoretical and methodological challenges is also crucial to
start engaging more productively with policy issues and policy priorities for
poverty reduction. The concluding chapter of this book puts forward a number
of policy proposals that may strengthen the prospects for an improvement in the
living standards of some of the poorest and most vulnerable segments of the
rural working population in the surveyed areas. Given the heterogeneity of rural
wage working classes and the specificity of contexts, the aim here cannot be to
provide universal policy blueprints; rather, through comparative evidence, to
help readers think about the realistic range of policy options to improve the
quantity and quality of rural wage employment, and their political feasibility in
each context.
Notes
1 In this book rural wage labour refers mainly to agricultural (off-own farm) labour,
paid in cash or kind, permanent, seasonal, or casual.
2 This is particularly true for Africa. By contrast, in Latin America and the United
States there has traditionally been more interest and therefore more research, particu-
larly on migrations of agricultural labourers. See, for example, Cornelius and Martin
(1993) on Mexican rural migrants, Thomas (1992), and Wells (1996).
28 C. Oya and N. Pontara
3 See Prasch (2004) for an extended discussion of the problems with neoclassical eco-
nomics’ treatment of labour as a commodity.
4 See Banaji (2010, 143–147) on a wide range of forms based on wage-labour in very
different contexts and epochs. Although nowadays unpaid apprentices are still
common in many developing countries, especially in poorer economies, there are
exceptions such as the case analysed by Ortiz in Argentina (this volume).
5 This is what Breman and van der Linden (2014) refer to as the ‘Standard Employment
Relationship’ based on regular salaried employment subject to regulations and a
variety of forms of protection.
6 See Banaji (2010) for a discussion of this argument, and Hilton (1976) for evidence
that wage labour was also present in feudalism even though as part of specific feudal
relations of production. In contrast, Wood (2002) and Cohen (2000) maintain that the
expansion of wage employment and the ultimate universal dependence on wage
employment, broadly defined, are defining and necessary conditions for capitalist
accumulation.
7 Pontara (2010) looks at the literature on the labour content of PRSPs in Africa,
whether policies/mechanisms are in place for creating employment opportunities;
improving the conditions of employment; targeting for employment purposes, at the
group, regional, and sector levels; and quantifying the impact of policies on different
dimensions of employment. Based on Nkurunziza (2007, 172), of the 21 PRSPs
examined up to 2004, only one displays a medium to high employment content:
Tanzania.
8 Paci and Serneels (2007) argue that despite the much-trumpeted importance of labour
market structures and outcomes for growth, the analytical work on this relationship
remains limited and heavily biased towards high-income countries. The existing work
on growth and poverty leaves the role of employment in transmission processes
largely unexplored, and remains outside mainstream labour economics.
9 Reardon (1997, 736) shows that in Africa, Latin America, and Asia ‘labor market
studies have tended to focus on cities and towns’. The edited volume on ‘informal
labour markets and development’ (Guha-Khasnobis and Kanbur 2006) is essentially a
book on urban employment as the notion of ‘informality’ is typically associated with
‘urbanity’.
10 Valdés et al. (2010) is a good example of the kind of generalizations of the rural poor
questioned by Sender (2003). It is also remarkable how key academic texts in devel-
opment studies make practically no mention of rural wage labour or agricultural wage
employment in sections on rural development, poverty, or even employment. An
example is Desai and Potter (2014).
11 There are plenty of examples in the literature of individuals who combine different
kinds of jobs in different sectors and also for the same employer. Chapters by Oya,
Cramer et al., Ortiz, Lee, and Zhang, for example, illustrate such cases.
12 See Lipton (2006) as a leading exponent of this tradition.
13 This is part of the RIGA (Rural Income Generating Activities) programme and data-
base (www.fao.org/economic/riga/riga-database/en), which is an unusual attempt to
extract more detailed labour statistics and specifically wage employment data from
existing national household surveys. Davis et al. (2010) and Winters et al. (2008)
report the key findings.
14 See Amsden (2010, 2012), and Sender (2003) for critical reviews of these mainstream
perspectives, which contain several references reflecting the mainstream view. See
also Bateman (2010) for a comprehensive critical review of microfinance.
15 A number of critiques have been levied against the ‘sustainable livelihoods’ and
income diversification approaches on conceptual and empirical grounds (see Fine
1997; Murray 2002; O’Laughlin 2004; Scoones and Wolmer 2003; Toner 2003).
16 ‘De-peasantization’ in Brazil has been examined in a more positive and progressive
fashion. Pereira (1997) analyses the rise of the labour movement in the 1980s in North
Introduction 29
East Brazil (Pernambuco). He maintains that the transformation of labour into a com-
modity corrodes old solidarities based on ties to the land but also opens up the possib-
ilities of new forms of solidarity and collective action and the achievement of
democratic rights. Rural labour can play an important role in fostering change in con-
texts where capitalist development in agriculture has begun to disintegrate the peas-
antry, but has not gone so far as that the rural proletariat has become insignificant.
Selwyn makes similar points in this volume.
17 This section substantially draws on Oya (2013) and will not develop some of the argu-
ments and debates presented in that article but will concentrate on a number of key
methodological questions.
18 See Oya (2013, 254 and table 2) for a critical analysis of this hypothesis.
19 See Hyden (2006, 138–160). For criticisms of this position, see classics like Kautsky
(1988), Kitching (1989), Wuyts (1978), Sender and Smith (1990), and more recent
field-based work in Tanzania presented in Mueller’s chapter in this book. Patnaik
(2010) also elaborates an argument, which is reminiscent of old-dependency theory
positions, that capitalism in the ‘periphery’ is not like capitalism in the ‘centre’, and
therefore will not be able to generate wage employment, at best jobless growth, and
the example of India is provided in that regard. For a critique of the employment pess-
imism with regards to India, see Dasgupta (2009).
20 See Swindell (1985, chapter 5) for a nuanced analysis of the nature, decline, and per-
sistence of cooperative/reciprocal labour exchange and the extent to which a col-
lective workgroup may conceal disguised forms of wage labour, when reciprocity is
not demonstrated and some individuals tend to benefit much more than others. See
also Whitehead (2006) for a similar point in relation to labour exchange in Nigeria.
21 The implication of data problems being at the heart of the misrepresentation of rural
wage employment in developing countries is that efforts at applying sophisticated
econometric techniques to analyse highly problematic national survey data may be
futile and reminders of the old computer science adage GIGO: ‘Garbage In, Garbage
Out’.
22 See Jerven (2013), who provides compelling evidence of the unreliability of basic
macroeconomic indicators in Africa, often used in econometric analysis, and docu-
ments the major challenges faced by national statistical agencies to produce enough
good-quality data on various aspects of development.
23 Rizzo et al. (2014) also provide detailed examples of the problems of questionnaire
design and specifically how questions on employment are ‘lost in translation’ in the
context of Tanzania, leading to a biased characterization of employment patterns for
informal labour.
24 See also their discussion of ‘residential’ versus ‘economic’ definitions of the house-
hold and how they affect rural labour market statistics (Cramer et al. 2014).
25 See also Erlebach (2006) for a rare in-depth study of rural wage employment in
Rwanda, which confirms the huge importance of wage jobs for the poorest rural
people.
26 See also a recent collection of essays on unfree labour introduced by Barrientos et al.
(2013).
27 For other views on this and more emphasis on realities of workers’ resistance, includ-
ing migrants, in China see Chan (2014) and Friedman (2014).
28 See also recent work on wage differences and segmentation across different types of
commercial farms in Ethiopia (Wendimu and Gibbon 2014).
29 Attached labour is a contract that typically involves tying of labour over specified
time periods and often such contracts are very fuzzy with reference to responsibilities
of workers. It is a form of ‘unfree’ labour of which there has been historically a signi-
ficant amount in India.
30 See, for a different view, Dasgupta (2009).
30 C. Oya and N. Pontara
31 De Haan and Rogaly (2002, 1), writing on rural labour migration more broadly, argue
that despite the wealth of literature on migration in and from Asia and Africa, ‘too
little is known about this type of migration’, i.e. ‘of migration of rural people for
various forms of work elsewhere, often returning to the place they started from.’
32 For a more general account of migrant labourers in such contexts, see Stichter (1985)
and Wells (1996) for a lucid analysis in the context of California, United States.
33 Today labour migration to South African agriculture comes back to centre stage as a
result of the mass movements of migrant workers escaping the harsh realities of con-
temporary Zimbabwe and flocking to the gates of capitalist farms (Bolt 2013; Ruther-
ford and Addison 2007).
34 See the classic contribution by Elson and Pearson (1984) on the idea of ‘nimble
fingers’ and ‘docility’, often associated with the incorporation of women workers to
the labour market in export sectors in developing countries. See also Maertens and
Swinnen (2012) and Dolan (2004).
35 See Gordon (1996) and Stichter and Parpart (1988) more generally on the trajectories
of patriarchy under capitalism development in Africa.
36 See also Pearson and Kusakabe (2012) on Burmese women migrant workers in
Thailand.
37 On positive impacts of access to plantation jobs in Senegal, see also Maertens et al.
(2011), Maertens and Swinnen (2012) and Maertens and Verhofstadt (2013), who
produce evidence that women’s employment in agribusiness export sectors have
positive effects on their children’s schooling and especially on gender disparities in
schooling.
References
Amsden, A.H., 2010. ‘Say’s Law, Poverty Persistence, and Employment Neglect.’
Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 11 (1): 57–66.
Amsden, A., 2012. ‘Grass Roots War on Poverty’. World Economic Review, 1: 114–131.
Austin, G.M., 2005. Land, Labour and Capital in Ghana. Rochester, NY: University of
Rochester Press.
Banaji, J., 2010. Theory as History: Essays on Modes of Production and Exploitation.
Leiden: Brill.
Bardhan, P. and A. Rudra, 1986. ‘Labour Mobility and the Boundaries of the Village
Moral Economy’. Journal of Peasant Studies, 13: 90–l15.
Barrett, C.B., M. Besfuneh, D.C. Clay, and T. Reardon, 2005. ‘Heterogeneous Con-
straints, Incentives and Income Diversification Strategies in Rural Africa.’ Quarterly
Journal of International Agriculture, 44 (1): 37–60.
Barrientos, S., U. Kothari, and N. Phillips, 2013. ‘Dynamics of Unfree Labour in the
Contemporary Global Economy’. Journal of Development Studies, 49 (8): 1037–1041.
Bateman, M., 2010. Why Doesn’t Microfinance Work? The Destructive Rise of Local
Neoliberalism. London: Zed Books.
Belchamber, G. and S. Schetagne, 2013. ‘Outcomes of the 19th ICLS on Work Statistics:
What Counts as a Job?’ Global Labour Column, 156, November. http://column.global-
labour-university.org (accessed 10 November 2014).
Bernstein, H., 2010. Class Dynamics of Agrarian Change. Halifax: Fernwood.
Berry, S., 1993. No Condition is Permanent: The Social Dynamics of Agrarian Change in
Sub-Saharan Africa. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.
Bharadwaj, K., 1989. Formation of Rural Labour Markets: An Analysis with Special Ref-
erence to Asia. International Labour Organization Working Paper WEP 10-6/WP98,
Rural Employment Policy Research Programme, Geneva.
Introduction 31
Bharadwaj, K., 1990. ‘Paradigms in Development Theory: Plea for “Labour-Ist”
Approach’. Economic and Political Weekly, 27 January, PE20–PE28.
Binswanger, H. and M. Rosenzweig, eds, 1984. Contractual Arrangements, Employment,
and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Binswanger, H., J. McIntire, and C. Udry, 1989. ‘Production Relations in Semi-arid
African Agriculture’. In The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, ed. P. Bardhan.
Oxford: Clarendon.
Bolt, M., 2013. ‘Producing Permanence: Employment, Domesticity and the Flexible
Future on a South African Border Farm.’ Economy and Society, 42(2): 197–225.
Breman J., 1996. Footloose Labour: Working in India’s informal economy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Breman, J., 2006. ‘Informal Sector Employment’. In The Elgar Companion to Develop-
ment Studies, ed. D.A. Clark, 281–285. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Breman, J. and M. van der Linden, 2014. ‘Informalizing the Economy: The Return of the
Social Question at a Global Level’. Development and Change, 45 (5): 920–940.
Bryceson, D.F., 2000. ‘African Peasants’ Centrality and Marginality: Rural Labour Trans-
formations’. In Disappearing Peasantries? Rural Labour in Africa, Asia and Latin
America, eds D. Bryceson, C. Kay and J. Mooij. London: ITDG Publishing.
Bryceson D., C. Kay and J. Mooij, eds, 2000. Disappearing Peasantries? Rural Labour
in Africa, Asia and Latin America. London: ITDG Publishing.
Byres, T.J., 2003. ‘Paths of Capitalist Agrarian Transition in the Past and in the Con-
temporary World’. In Agrarian Studies: Essays on Agrarian Relations in Less
Developed Countries, eds V.K. Ramachandran and M. Swaminathan, 54–83. New
Delhi: Tulika Books.
Chan, C.K.C., 2014. ‘Constrained Labour Agency and the Changing Regulatory Regime
in China’. Development and Change, 45 (4): 685–709.
Chand, R. and S.K. Srivastava, 2014. ‘Changes in the Rural Labour Market and Their
Implications for Agriculture’. Economic and Political Weekly, 49 (10): 47–54.
Chang H.J., 2010. 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism. London: Penguin
Books.
Cohen, G.A., 2000. Karl Marx’s Theory of History: A Defence. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Cordell, D., J. Gregory, and V. Piché, 1996. Hoe and Wage: A Social History of a
Circular Migration System in West Africa, 1900–1975. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Cornelius, W.A. and Martin, P.L., 1993. ‘The Uncertain Connection: Free Trade and
Rural Mexican Migration to the United States’. International Migration Review, 27 (3):
484–512.
Cramer, C., 2008. ‘From Waging War to Peace Work: Labour and Labour Markets’. In
Whose Peace? Critical Perspectives on the Political Economy of Peacebuilding, eds
M. Pugh, N. Cooper, and M. Turner, 123–140. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Cramer, C., D. Johnston, B. Mueller, C. Oya, and J. Sender, 2014. ‘How to do (and how
not to do) Fieldwork on Fair Trade and Rural Poverty’. Canadian Journal of Develop-
ment Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du développement, 35 (1): 170–185.
Dasgupta, I., 2009. ‘On Some Left Critiques of the Left’. Economic and Political Weekly,
44 (31): 109–111.
Davis, B., P. Winters, G. Carletto, K. Covarrubias, E.J. Quiñones, A. Zezza, and S. Di
Giuseppe, 2010. ‘A Cross-Country Comparison of Rural Income Generating Activ-
ities’. World Development, 38 (1): 48–63.
de Haan, A. and B. Rogaly, 2002. ‘Introduction: Migrant Workers and Their Role in
Rural Change’. Journal of Development Studies, 38 (5): 1–14.
32 C. Oya and N. Pontara
Desai, V., and R.B. Potter, 2014. The Companion to Development Studies. London:
Routledge.
Dirven, M., R. Echeverri Perico, C. Sabalain, A. Rodríguez, D. Candia Baeza, C. Peña,
and S. Faiguenbaum, 2011. ‘Hacia una nueva definición de “rural” con fines estadísti-
cos en América Latina’. Documento de Proyecto. Comisión Económica para América
Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL), Santiago.
Dolan, C. 2004. ‘On Farm and Packhouse: Employment at the Bottom of a Global Com-
modity Chain’. Rural Sociology, 69 (1): 99–126.
du Toit, A. and F. Ally, 2003. ‘The Externalisation and Casualisation of Farm Labour in
Western Cape Horticulture’. Programme for Land and Agrarian Studies, University of
the Western Cape, Cape Town, research report no. 16.
Ellis, F., 2000. Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Development Countries. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Elson, D. and R. Pearson, 1984. ‘ “Nimble Fingers Make Cheap Workers”: An Analysis
of Women’s Employment in Third World Export Manufacturing’. In For a New
Labour Internationalism, ed. P. Waterman, 120–141. The Hague: Ileri.
Erlebach, R.W., 2006. ‘The Importance of Wage Labour in the Struggle to Escape
Poverty: Evidence from Rwanda’. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. School of Orien-
tal and African Studies, University of London.
FAO, ILO, and IUF, 2005. Agricultural Workers and their Contribution to Sustainable
Agriculture and Rural Development. Rome: FAO.
Fields, G., 2007. Labor Market Policy in Developing Countries: A Selective Review of the
Literature and Needs for the Future. Policy Research Working Paper 4362, World Bank.
Fine, B., 1997. ‘Entitlement Failure?’ Development and Change, 28: 617–647.
Fine, B., 1998. Labour Market Theory: A Constructive Reassessment. Routledge: London.
Friedman, E., 2014. ‘Alienated Politics: Labour Insurgency and the Paternalistic State in
China’. Development and Change, 45 (5): 1001–1018.
Ghai, D. and S. Radwan, 1983. ‘Agrarian Change, Differentiation and Rural Poverty in
Africa: A General Survey’. In Agrarian Policies and Rural Poverty in Africa, eds D.
Ghai and S. Radwan, 1–30. Geneva: ILO.
Gindling, T.H. and D. Newhouse, 2012. Self-employment in the Developing World. Policy
Research Working Paper 6201, World Bank.
Gordon, A.A., 1996. Transforming Capitalism and Patriarchy: Gender and Development
in Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Guha-Khasnobis, B. and S.R. Kanbur, 2006. Informal Labour Markets and Development.
New York: Palgrave MacMillan.
Heintz, J., 2014. ‘Jobs, Justice and Development: A Review of Working Hard, Working
Poor’. Development and Change, 45 (4): 799–811.
Hill, O., 1970. Rural Capitalism in West Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hilton, R., 1976. ‘Feudalism and the Origins of Capitalism’. History Workshop Journal,
1 (1): 9–25.
Huang, P.C.C., 2013. ‘Misleading Chinese Legal and Statistical Categories: Labor, Indi-
vidual Entities, and Private Enterprises’. Modern China, 39 (4): 347–379.
Huang, P.C.C., Y. Gao, and Y. Peng, 2012. ‘Capitalization Without Proletarianization in
China’s Agricultural Development’. Modern China, 38: 139–173.
Hyden, G., 2006. African Politics in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Jerven, M., 2013. Poor Numbers: How We are Misled by African Development Statistics
and What To Do About It. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Introduction 33
Kandiyoti, D., 1988. ‘Bargaining with Patriarchy’. Gender and Society, 3: 274–290.
Kautsky, K., 1988 [1899]. The Agrarian Question. London: Zwan Publications.
Kay, C. 2009. ‘Estudios rurales en América Latina en el periodo de globalización neolib-
eral:¿ una nueva ruralidad?’. Revista Mexicana de Sociología, 71 (4): 607–645.
Kevane, M., 1994. ‘Village Labor Markets in Sheikan District: Sudan’. World Develop-
ment, 22 (6): 839–857.
Kitching, G.N., 1980. Class and Economic Change in Kenya: The Making of an African
Petite Bourgeoisie 1905–1970. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Kitching, G.N., 1989. Development and Underdevelopment in Historical Perspective.
London: Methuen.
Konings, P., 2012. Gender and Plantation Labour in Africa. The Story of Tea Pluckers’
Struggles in Cameroon. Bamenda and Leiden: Langaa and African Studies Centre.
Lanjouw, P., 2007. ‘Does the Rural Non-farm Economy Contribute to Poverty Reduc-
tion?’ In Transforming the Rural Non-agricultural Economy: Opportunities and
Threats in the Developing World, eds S. Haggblade, P. Hazell, and T. Reardon, 55–79.
Baltimore, MD: IFPRI and Johns Hopkins University Press.
Lenin, V.I., 1982 [1899]. ‘The Differentiation of the Peasantry’. Reproduced in Rural
Development: Theories of Peasant Economy and Agrarian Change, ed. J. Harriss,
130–138. London and New York: Routledge.
Lennihan, L., 1987. ‘Agricultural Wage Labor in Northern Nigeria’. In State, Oil, and
Agriculture in Nigeria, ed. M. Watts, 248–267. Berkeley: Institute of International
Studies, University of California.
Lerche, J. 2010. ‘From “rural labour” to “classes of labour”: Class fragmentation, caste
and class struggle at the bottom of the Indian labour hierarchy’. In The Comparative
Political Economy of Development: Africa and South Asia, eds B. Harriss-White and J.
Heyer, chapter 4. London: Routledge.
Lindsay, L.A., 2003. Working With Gender: Wage Labor and Social Change in South-
western Nigeria. Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann.
Lipton, M., 2006. ‘Can Small Farmers Survive, Prosper, or be the Key Channel to Cut
Mass Poverty?’ Electronic Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics, 3 (1):
58–85.
Luetchford, P., 2008. ‘The Hands that Pick Fair Trade Coffee: Beyond the Charms of the
Family Farm’. Research in Economic Anthropology, 28: 143–169.
Maertens, M., and J.F. Swinnen, 2012. ‘Gender and Modern Supply Chains in Develop-
ing Countries’. Journal of Development Studies, 48 (10): 1412–1430.
Maertens, M. and E. Verhofstadt, 2013. ‘Horticultural Exports, Female Wage Employ-
ment and Primary School Enrolment: Theory and Evidence from Senegal’. Food
Policy, 43: 118–131.
Maertens, M., L. Colen, and J.F. Swinnen, 2011. ‘Globalisation and Poverty in Senegal:
A Worst Case Scenario?’ European Review of Agricultural Economics, 38 (1): 31–54.
Mellor, J.W., 2014. ‘High Rural Population Density Africa: What are the Growth
Requirements and Who Participates?’ Food Policy, 48: 66–75.
Milonakis, D. and B. Fine, 2009. From Political Economy to Economics: Method, the
Social and the Historical in the Evolution of Economic Theory. London: Routledge.
Morrison, J. and Murphy, S. 2004. Agricultural Trade and Poverty Reduction: Oppor-
tunity or Threat. London: DFID.
Murray, C., 2002. ‘Livelihood Research: Transcending Boundaries of Time and Space’.
Journal of Southern African Studies, 28 (3): 489–509.
34 C. Oya and N. Pontara
Mwamadzingo, M., 2003. Assessing the Decent Work Deficit in African Agriculture: Pri-
ority Issues, International Labour Organisation, Sub-Regional Office for Southern
Africa, Discussion Paper 21, International Labour Office, Geneva.
Nkurunzika, J., 2007. ‘Generating Rural Employment in Africa to Fight Poverty’. In
Towards Full and Decent Employment, ed. J.A. Ocampo and K.S. Jomo. London: Zed
Books.
O’Laughlin, B., 2004. ‘Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Developing Countries: Book
Review’. Development and Change, 35 (2): 385–403.
Oya, C., 2010. Rural Inequality, Wage Employment and Labour Market Formation in
Africa: Historical and Micro-level Evidence. Geneva: International Labour Office.
Oya, C. 2011. ‘Agriculture in the World Bank: Blighted Harvest Persists’. In The Political
Economy of Development: The World Bank, Neoliberalism and Development Research,
ed. K. Bayliss, B. Fine, and E. Van Waeyenberge, 146–187. London: Pluto Press.
Oya, C., 2013. ‘Rural Wage Employment in Africa: Methodological Issues and Emerging
Evidence’. Review of African Political Economy, 40 (136): 251–273.
Oya, C. and J. Sender, 2009. ‘Divorced, Separated and Widowed Women Workers in
Rural Mozambique’. Feminist Economics, 15 (2): 1–31.
Paci, P. and P.M. Serneels, eds, 2007. Employment and Shared Growth: Rethinking the
Role of Labor Mobility for Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Patnaik, P., 2010. ‘The Diffusion of Activities’. Economic and Political Weekly, 45 (10):
40–45.
Pearson, R. and K. Kusakabe, 2012. ‘Who Cares? Gender, Reproduction, and Care Chains
of Burmese Migrant Workers in Thailand’. Feminist Economics, 18 (2): 149–175.
Pereira, A.W., 1997. The End of the Peasantry: The Rural Labour Movement in North-
east Brazil, 1961–1988. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Pérez-Niño, H., 2015. ‘Post-Conflict Agrarian Change in Angónia: Land, Labour and the
Organization of Production in the Mozambique–Malawi Borderland’. Unpublished
PhD dissertation, SOAS, University of London.
Pincus, J. and J. Sender, 2008. ‘Quantifying Poverty in Viet Nam: Who Counts?’ Journal
of Vietnamese Studies, 3 (1): 108–150.
Pontara, N., 2010. ‘A Critical Examination of Theoretical and Methodological
Approaches to Low-income Country Labour Markets: A Case Study of Mauritania’.
Unpublished doctoral dissertation, SOAS, University of London.
Prasch, R.E., 2004. ‘How is Labor Distinct from Broccoli? Some Unique Characteristics
of Labor and Their Importance for Economic Analysis and Policy’. In The Institution-
alist Tradition in Labor Economics, eds D.P. Champlin and J.T. Knoedler, 146–158.
New York: Sharpe.
Ramachandran, V.K., 1990. Wage Labour and Unfreedom in Agriculture. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Rao, M. 1988. ‘Fragmented Rural Labour Markets’. Journal of Peasant Studies, 15 (2):
238–257.
Reardon, T., 1997. ‘Using Evidence of Household Income Diversification to Inform
Study of the Rural Non-farm Labour Market in Africa’. World Development, 25, 5.
Reardon, T., J.E. Taylor, K. Stamoulis, P. Lanjouw, and A. Balisacan, 2000. ‘Effects of
Non-farm Employment on Rural Income Inequality in Developing Countries: An
Investment Perspective’. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51 (2): 266–288.
Rigg, J., 2006, ‘Land, Farming, Livelihoods, and Poverty: Rethinking the Links in the
Rural South’. World Development, 34 (1): 180–202.
Introduction 35
Rizzo, M., B. Kilama, and M. Wuyts, 2014. ‘The Invisibility of Wage Employment in
Statistics on the Informal Economy in Africa: Causes and Consequences’. Journal of
Development Studies, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2014.968136.
Rosenzweig, M.R., 1989. ‘Labor Markets in Low-Income Countries’. In Handbook of
Development Economics, eds H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan, chapter 15. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Rousseau, N., 1995. What is Rurality?. Occasional paper, Royal College of General Prac-
titioners, 71 (1).
Schaffner, J.A., 1993. ‘Rising Incomes and the Shift From Self-employment to Firm-
based Production’. Economics Letters, 41 (4): 435–440.
Scoones, I. (2009). ‘Livelihoods Perspectives and Rural Development’. Journal of
Peasant Studies, 36 (1): 171–196.
Scoones, I., and W. Wolmer, 2003. ‘Introduction: Livelihoods in Crisis: Challenges for
Rural Development in Southern Africa’. IDS Bulletin, 34 (3): 1–14.
Sender, J., 2003. ‘Rural Poverty and Gender: Analytical Frameworks and Policy Proposals’.
In Rethinking Development Economics, ed. H.J. Chang, chapter 18. London: Anthem
Press.
Sender, J. and S. Smith, 1990. Poverty, Class and Gender in Rural Africa, London:
Routledge.
Sender, J., C. Cramer, and C. Oya, 2005. Unequal Prospects: Disparities in the Quantity
and Quality of Labour Supply in Sub-Saharan Africa. Social Protection Discussion
Paper No. 0525, World Bank.
Standing, G., 2006. ‘Labour Markets’. In The Elgar Companion to Development Studies,
ed. D.A. Clark, 323–328. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Stichter, S.B., 1985. Migrant Labourers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stichter, S.B. and J.L. Parpart, eds, 1988. Patriarchy and Class: African Women in the
Home and the Workplace. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Swindell, K., 1985. Farm Labour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Thomas, R.J., 1992. Citizenship, Gender, and Work: Social Organization of Industrial
Agriculture. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Toner, A., 2003. ‘Exploring Sustainable Livelihood Approaches in Relation to Two Inter-
ventions in Tanzania’. Journal of International Development, 15 (4): 771–781.
Valdés, A., W. Foster, G. Anríquez, C. Azzarri, K. Covarrubias, B. Davis, and A. Zezza,
2010. A Profile of the Rural Poor. Background paper for the IFAD (International Fund
for Agricultural Development) Rural Poverty Report 2011.
Wells, M., 1996. Strawberry Fields: Politics, Class, and Work in California Agriculture.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Wendimu, M.A. and P. Gibbon, 2014. ‘Labour Markets for Irrigated Agriculture in
Central Ethiopia: Wage Premiums and Segmentation’. IFRO Working Paper 2014/06,
Department of Food and Resource Economics, University of Copenhagen.
White, H., J. Leavy, M. Mulumbi, G. Mulenga, and V. Seshamani. 2006. ‘Rural Develop-
ment and Labour Markets in Africa: Preliminary Findings from a Research Project in
Northern Province, Zambia’, Mimeo, discussion draft, IDS, Brighton.
Whitehead, A., 2006. ‘Persistent Poverty in North East Ghana’. Journal of Development
Studies, 42 (2): 278–300.
Winters, P., A.P. de la O, E.J. Quiñones, T. Hertz, B. Davis, A. Zezza, K. Covarrubias,
and K. Stamoulis et al., 2008. Rural Wage employment in Developing Countries.
Rome: FAO. ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/011/aj301e/aj301e.pdf.
Wood, E.M., 2002. The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View. London: Verso.
36 C. Oya and N. Pontara
World Bank, 2007. World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank, 2012. World Development Report 2013: Jobs. Overview. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Wuyts, M., 1978. Camponeses e economía rural em Moçambique. Centro de Estudos
Africanos, Maputo.
Wuyts, M., 2011. The Working Poor: A Macro Perspective. Valedictory Address as
Professor of Applied Quantitative Economics delivered on 8 December 2011 at the
Institute of Social Studies, The Hague.
References
68 C. Oya
Idson, T.L. and W.Y. Oi, 1999. ‘Workers are More Productive
in Large Firms’. American Economic Review, 89 (2):
104–108.
Rubin, D.K. and J.M. Perloff, 1993. ‘Who Works for Piece
Rates and Why’. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 75 (4): 1036–1043.
Bundy, C., 1988. The Rise and Fall of the South African
Peasantry, 2nd edition. Cape Town and Johannesburg: David
Philip.
Lewis, J., 1984. ‘The Rise and Fall of the South African
Peasantry: A Critique and Reassessment’. Journal of
Southern African Studies, 11 (1): 1–24.
Bruce, J. and C.B. Lloyd, 1992. Finding the Ties that Bind:
Beyond Headship and Household. New York: New York
Population Council.
168 B. Mueller
170 B. Mueller
Save the Children UK, 2000a. The North Wollo Highland Belg
Food Economy Zone: Baseline Report. Ethiopia Programme.
Save the Children UK, 2001a. The North Wollo Abay- Tekeze
Watershed Food Economy Zone: Baseline Report, Ethiopia
Programme.
228 P. Jha
Jha, P. and A.N. Thakur, 2012. ‘30 Years On: Notes on Work
and Well Being from Rural Bihar’. Paper presented at the
International Conference on Understanding Change in Rural
India: Perspectives from Longitudinal Village Studies,
19–20 November 2012, Jawaharlal Nehru University (JNU),
New Delhi (mimeo).
274 B. Selwyn
304 S. Ortiz
328 S. Lee
Jha, P. and A.N. Thakur, 2012. ‘30 Years On: Notes on Work
and Well Being from Rural Bihar’. Paper presented at the
International Conference on Understanding Change in Rural
India: Perspectives from Longitudinal Village Studies,
19–20 November 2012, Jawaharlal Nehru University (JNU),
New Delhi (mimeo).