Consumer & Cost Theory
Consumer & Cost Theory
1
Consumer preferences
1. Completeness
– Preferences are well-defined: we can rank (bundles of) goods
– Real-life complexity → computational “impossibility”
2. Transitive
– Preferences don’t depend upon the comparison
– Framing can induce “preference reversals”
3. Monotone
– More is better
– Forced consumption or storage can make a “good” a “bad”
4. Diminishing Marginal Utility (risk-aversion)
– Each additional unit is worth less
– Gambling, risk-seeking behavior
2
Optimal Bundles
Consumers maximize their utility subject to a budget constraint.
• Suppose there are just two goods, x and y:
max 𝑢(𝑥, 𝑦)
𝑥,𝑦
𝑠𝑢𝑏𝑗𝑒𝑐𝑡 𝑡𝑜: 𝑝𝑥 𝑥 + 𝑝𝑦 𝑦 ≤ 𝐼
3
Example: optimal bundle
Suppose you buy only two goods: eating at home and eating at a
restaurant. You have the following information:
• Prices: ph = $10 and pr = $25
• Income: $1000
• Utility: 𝑈 ℎ, 𝑟 = 2ln(ℎ) + 4ln(𝑟) (“ln” is the natural log)
2 4
• Marginal Utility: 𝑀𝑈ℎ = , 𝑀𝑈𝑟 =
ℎ 𝑟
What is the optimal split between eating at home and dining out?
4
Example: optimal bundle
1. Determine how much you can eat at home, given your dining out:
10h+25r = 1000
h = 100 – 2.5r
𝑀𝑈𝑟 4ൗ𝑟
=
𝑝𝑟 25
2
𝑀𝑈ℎ 2ൗℎ 100 − 2.5𝑟
= =
𝑝ℎ 10 10
5
Example: optimal bundle
2. Solve for the optimum by equalizing “bang for the buck”:
2
100 − 2.5𝑟 4ൗ
𝑴𝑼𝒉ൗ 𝑟 𝑴𝑼𝒓ൗ
𝒑𝒉 = 10
=
25
= 𝒑𝒓
50 40
=
100 − 2.5𝑟 𝑟
50𝑟 = 4000 − 100𝑟
4000
𝑟∗ = ≈ 26.67
150
ℎ = 100 − 2.5𝑟 = 100 − 2.5 4000ൗ150 ≈ 33.33 = ℎ∗
6
Example: optimal bundle
How does this change as the value of eating out increases?
• Prices: ph = $10 and pr = $25
• Income: $1000
• Utility: 𝑈 ℎ, 𝑟 = 2ln(ℎ) + 5ln(𝑟)
2 5
• Marginal Utility: 𝑀𝑈ℎ = , 𝑀𝑈𝑟 =
ℎ 𝑟
What is the new optimal split between eating at home and dining out?
7
Example: optimal bundle
1. Determine how much you can eat at home, given your dining out:
10h+25r = 1000
h = 100 – 2.5r
5ൗ
𝑀𝑈𝑟ൗ 𝑟
𝑝𝑟 =
25
2
2ൗ
𝑀𝑈ℎൗ
= ℎ = 100 − 2.5𝑟
𝑝ℎ 10 10
8
Example: optimal bundle
2. Solve for the optimum by equalizing “bang for the buck”:
2
100 − 2.5𝑟 5ൗ
𝑴𝑼𝒉ൗ 𝑟 𝑴𝑼𝒓ൗ
𝒑𝒉 = 10
=
25
= 𝒑𝒓
50 50
=
100 − 2.5𝑟 𝑟
50𝑟 = 5000 − 125𝑟
∗
5000
𝑟 = ≈ 28.6
175
ℎ = 100 − 2.5𝑟 = 100 − 2.5 5000ൗ175 ≈ 28.6 = ℎ∗
9
What goods don’t we purchase?
• For any two goods purchased, at the optimum, it must be that
𝑀𝑈𝑥 𝑀𝑈𝑦
=
𝑝𝑥 𝑝𝑦
10
Activity: New Wardrobe
We want to understand how our preferences and budget affect our optimal
bundle and the value we receive from a good.
1. Suppose that you get 1000 units of utility from your first pair of pants.
– How much utility do you get from having two pairs? 3, 4 pairs?
– How much utility do you get from having one shirt? 2, 3, 4 shirts?
– How much utility do you get from having one pair of shoes? 2, 3, 4 pairs?
11
Where do we get market demand?
• For each individual, we can plot
Price
12
Consumer surplus
Price
1 2 3 4 Shirts
13
Consumer surplus
Price
1 2 3 4 Shirts
14
Consumer surplus
• Consumer surplus measures how
Price
15
Consumer surplus and elasticity
16
How do we account for uncertainty?
Suppose you could choose between two investments:
17
How do we account for uncertainty?
Both investments have the same expected payoff:
1. 𝑥ҧ = 50%*($2 million) + 50%*(0) = $1 million
2. 𝑥ҧ = 25%*($4 million) + 75%*(0) = $1 million
But they differ in their riskiness, captured here by the variance:
1. 𝜎 2 = 50%*(2 – 1)2 + 50%*(0 – 1)2 = 1
2. 𝜎 2 = 25%*(4 – 1)2 + 75%*(0 – 1)2 = 3
18
Expected utility
Utility
Risk-aversion is equivalent to
consumer’s possessing a declining
u($4m) marginal utility of wealth.
19
Risk Tolerance
Utility
Risk-aversion is equivalent to a
consumer possessing a declining
marginal utility of wealth.
u($2m) – u($0) > u($4m) – u($2m)
u($4m)
Risk-seeking is equivalent to a
u($2m) consumer possessing an increasing
marginal utility of wealth.
u($4m)
u($2m) – u($0) < u($4m) – u($2m)
u($2m)
$2m $4m Wealth
20
Expected Utility
With risk-aversion, the expected payoff ≠ expected utility:
– Expected payoff = σ𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝑥𝑖 (p: probability, x: payoff)
– Expected utility = σ𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝑢 𝑥𝑖 (p: probability, u(x): utility from payoff)
21
Expected Utility
Suppose you flip a coin: heads, you win $100,000, tails, you win $0.
With risk-aversion, expected payoff > price you’d be willing to pay:
– Expected payoff = σ𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝑥𝑖 (p: probability, x: payoff)
• This implies you would not give up $50,000 for this bet!
22
Risk Premium
We can measure the impact of uncertainty using the risk premium.
• Essentially, the risk premium measures how much of the expected payoff you
would be willing to give up to make the investment risk-free.
– Example: If you are indifferent between an investment that produces $10k risk-free and
a risky investment with expected payoff of $15k, the risk premium is $5k.
• Alternatively, the risk premium is the required compensation (reduction in price)
for holding a risky asset.
– Example: You would never be willing to pay more than the present value of $10k (risk-
free) for the risky investment with expected payoff of $15k described above.
23
Risk Premium
We can measure the impact of uncertainty on your willingness to pay
using the risk premium.
(1) What does this imply about risky asset holdings across individuals?
(2) What does this imply about expected returns on investments?
24
Risk-aversion: Implications
How can a goods producer (i.e., a firm) reduce the impact on sales?
– Warranties or product guarantees
– Return Policies
– Reputation
25
Economic costs
• Proper economic decision-making requires knowledge of all
relevant economic costs.
26
Ignore sunk costs!
• We typically have multiple opportunities to decide whether to
push forward with a decision
– As a result, when we consider whether we want to continue an
action, we may have already expended resources
27
Accounting costs are not the same
• Accounting costs are backward-looking and focus exclusively
on explicit costs.
– As a result, while they will incorporate …
• Wages paid to employees
• Rent on an office space
• Price paid to acquire raw materials
– … they do not include
• Entrepreneur’s foregone wages
• Price you would receive from subletting the office space
• Current market price of raw materials
28
What is the optimal production plan?
• For any two inputs utilized, at the optimum, it must be that:
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝑀𝑃𝐾
=
𝑤 𝑟
– At the optimum, marginal productivity per dollar spent is the same
• All economic costs (explicit + opportunity) are captured by “w” and “r”.
29
How do prices impact input choice?
It will generally be the case that as the price of an input
increases, we will use less of it (and we will not use more).
This is just the law of demand!
– If the cost of capital goes up, firms demand less of it (𝜕𝐾
𝜕𝑟
≤ 0)
– If the cost of labor goes up, firms demand less of it (𝜕𝑤
𝜕𝐿
≤ 0)
30
Activity: Building a Cost Curve
We want to understand how to create a cost curve.
You can use either capital (K) or labor (L) to produce your good.
– Output: f(K,L) = 10K + L implies MPK = 10 & MPL = 1
– Costs: r = $8,000 (cost of capital), w = $500 (cost of labor)
31
Total Costs
A firm can also decompose its costs along production levels.
1. Fixed costs: invariant to the quantity produced
• Examples: Rent, legal expenditures, advertising
• Can be sunk or non-sunk
– If they are sunk, they are incurred even if nothing is produced
– If they are non-sunk, they are incurred only with production
– In this class fixed costs are non-sunk
• In the short-run, certain capital costs may be fixed
2. Variable costs: will change with the quantity produced
• Examples: Materials, labor, shipping
• In the long-run, both labor and capital are variable
32
Total Cost Curve
Cost
33
Total Cost Curve
• Average cost is TC(q)/q
Cost
34
Connecting marginal costs & productivity
• Marginal cost falls when the
Cost/unit
35
Connecting average & marginal costs
36
Connecting average & fixed costs
• Marginal cost could also always
be increasing
Cost/unit
37
What is the short-run? The long-run?
• Long-run and short-run is meant to distinguish between firm’s
level of flexibility and do not correspond to a set length of time
• In the long-run, we assume firms can choose each input
optimally: there are no constraints to how it is produced
• In the short-run, we assume that certain inputs are fixed in the
production process: given these constraints, the firm chooses
optimally how to produce the good.
– We will generally assume that in the short-run, capital is invariant.
– Of course, other factors may also be pre-determined, including labor.
38
Short-run v. long-run total cost
Cost
39
Short-run v. long-run average cost
Short-run
Cost\unit
40
Activity: Where would you locate?
We want to understand how fixed and marginal costs affect production in
both the short-run and the long-run.
41
Microeconomics in the News
• “Investors Should Go Where the Float Is”, 8/19/22
• “Peloton Rides Covid-19 Wave, Adding Products, Cutting Bike Price”, 9/8/20
42