The Myth of Sector Rotation Non Blind
The Myth of Sector Rotation Non Blind
Abstract
Conventional wisdom suggests that sectors/industries provide systematic performance and that
business cycle rotation strategies generate excess market performance. However, we find no
evidence of systematic sector performance where popular belief anticipates it will occur. At
best, conventional sector rotation generates modest outperformance, which quickly diminishes
after allowing for transaction costs and incorrectly timing the business cycle. The results are
robust to alternative sector and business cycle definitions. We find that relaxing sector rotation
assumptions and letting any industry excess return predict future returns of other industries
results in predictability not significantly different than what would be expected by random
chance.
1 Alexander Molchanov (corresponding author).QB2.55, Massey University, Auckland, 0630, New Zealand. Phone: +64 9
414 0800 ext. 43152. E-mail: [email protected]
Jeffrey Stangl. Massey University, Auckland, New Zealand. Phone: +64 9 414 0800 ext. 43163. E-mail:
[email protected]
The authors would like to thank Ben Jacobsen for helpful comments on the earlier version of this paper.
1
1. Introduction
Sector rotation refers to a common investment strategy that targets investments in particular
economic sectors at different stages of the business cycle. Bodie, Kane, and Marcus (2009)
suggest the “way that many [financial] analysts think about the relationship between industry
analysis and the business cycle is the notion of sector rotation.” Similarly, Lofthouse (2001)
states that financial analysts “think in terms of stylized economic cycles, with different sectors
performing at different stages of the cycle.” Fabozzi (2007, pg. 581) acknowledges, “Sector
rotation strategies have long played a key role in equity portfolio management.”
The seemingly mythical belief that tactically timing sector/industry investments generates
systematic excess returns persists unabated with certain investors, as supported by the media.
Popular investment websites (Investopedia, Stockcharts, and Seeking Alpha) detail the sector
rotation strategy, while providing examples of practical application. Any number of “How to
Guides”, starting with “Sector Investing” (1996) to “Trading for Dummies” (2013) also provide
step-by-step instruction on timing sector investments with business cycles. While the largest
investment companies (iShares, Vanguard, and Fidelity), provide a suite of sector funds that
facilitate sector rotation application. Several direct sector rotation funds are available, including
the Sector Rotation ETF (XRO), Line Industry Rotation Portfolio Fund (PYH), and Sector
Rotation Fund (NAVFX). However, comparing NAVFX returns since inception (2010-2018)
with the S&P 500 Index over the same period reveals roughly 5% underperformance (7.34%
versus 12.23%). Raising the question, does investor belief in sector rotation outperformance
Our study tests the two fundamental assumptions of sector rotation. Do certain sectors provide
systematic performance across business cycles? Does sector rotation generate excess market
performance? Bodie, Kane, and Marcus (2009) comment that “sector rotation, like any other
2
form of market timing, will be successful only if one anticipates the next stage of the business
cycle better than other investors.” This study overcomes the obstacle of correctly timing
business cycles with a simple and intuitive approach. That approach gives sector rotation
investors the benefit of the doubt, by assuming investors can perfectly time business cycle
turning points. If the business cycle drives sector returns, then an investor who perfectly times
business cycle stages and rotates sectors following popular belief on sector performance should
generate excess returns. Our analysis begins with the assumption of a sector rotation strategy
assumptions of a specific sector rotation model, testing performance of all sectors across all
Investors can choose to implement sector rotation at sector, industry, or firm level. The choice
depends on how precisely an investor wants to target expected sector performance and the
implementation. Industries allow a targeted approach to sector exposure, while still maintaining
the benefits of diversification. For instance, the healthcare sector includes pharmaceutical,
healthcare provider, and medical equipment industries. A sector rotation investor might
expected industry performance. Our initial analysis focuses on the Fama and French 49
industry portfolios. Expanded robustness analysis considers alternative sector and industry
groupings.
The initial analysis documents sector rotation outperformance – but only marginally so. The
(NBER) dated business cycles from 1948 to 2018. The NBER defines only broad phases of
economic expansion and recession. The analysis first divides broad NBER phases into
3
additional sub-periods. We then map industries to business cycle stages where popular belief
anticipates optimal performance will occur. With few exceptions, industries expected to
perform well in various stages show no systematic performance. The analysis next combines
outperformance. Investors, guided by popular belief on sector performance and with perfect
foresight in timing business cycle stages, achieve a risk-adjusted return of 0.11 percent per
month before transaction costs. While this may seem high, a simple market timing strategy that
invests continuously in the market except during early recession generates a 0.15 percent
The results are robust to variety of tests and specifications. The analysis investigates whether
the results differ when investors anticipate business cycles early or late. Alternatively, we
examine business cycle stages delineated by the Chicago Federal Reserve National Activity
Index (CFNAI). When considering alternative sector and industry groupings, the results remain
unaffected. The main results are also robust to various performance measures such as the
Sharpe ratio and Jensen’s alpha. The results remain the same whether measured by a single
Lastly, the study generalizes the analysis to allow for all variations of sector rotation. The initial
analysis follows a commonly accepted version of sector rotation, as defined by Stovall (1996)
in Table 3 and illustrated by Standard & Poor’s in Figure 1. However, there are other potential
versions of sector rotation. The results are thus subject to the criticism of being limited to a
specific sector rotation model. To counter such criticism, the analysis tests for systematic
performance of any sector across any business-cycle stage. Measuring statistically significant
outperformance, the generalized results align with a hypothesis of neither systematic nor
persistent differences in sector returns across business-cycle stages. The significance levels
observed are only marginally different from those expected to occur randomly, without any
4
systematic outperformance. The result suggests that no sector rotation variant provides
systematic outperformance, questioning the popular belief that timing sector investments with
This study contributes to the literature as the first to question the underlying assumptions of
sector rotation: systematic sector performance and the opportunity for investors to profitably
time sector rotation with the business cycle. Elton, Gruber, and Blake (2011) and Avramov and
Wermers (2006), suggest the importance that sector rotation plays in mutual fund performance.
Apart from a return predictability perspective, this study provides additional insights. Sector
rotation generates order flows, which transmit information about asset fundamentals. For
instance, Beber, Brandt, and Kavajecz (2010) provide evidence that sector-order flows forecast
macroeconomic conditions. The evidence suggests that sector-order flows, however, do not
translate into systematic sector performance. Evidence in Avramov and Wermers (2006) finds
that switching industry investments across business cycles drives equity fund performance.
Jiang, Yao, and Yu (2007), similarly, conclude that industry rotation underlies mutual fund
timing strategies, where fund managers switch between cyclical and non-cyclical stocks. A
natural question to ask is whether mutual funds follow conventional sector rotation or
alternative timing strategies. The results suggest that mutual funds profit from the latter. This
study contributes to a renewed interest in the literature on rotation strategies and industry
hypothesis, the idea that investors systematically profit from sector rotation. Sector prices
should instantaneously reflect all available information and fundamental value – irrespective
of business-cycle stages. Yet, the prominence of sector rotation in practice suggests that
investors profit from timing systematic sector performance with the business cycle.
5
The apparent ability to profit from sector rotation might be consistent with the Hong and Stein
(1999) gradual information diffusion hypothesis. Gradual information diffusion, as Hong and
Stein (1999) describe, involves two groups of traders (news watchers and arbitrageurs) and the
lead-lag relation of their responses to economic news. News watchers have a limited ability to
process news and consequently revise asset prices with a delay. Arbitrageurs, in contrast, fully
incorporate news in their price adjustments and devise simple trading strategies that generate
excess returns. Analogously, one can view sector rotation investors as arbitrage traders who
Hong, Torous, and Valkanov (2007) empirically test the gradual information diffusion
hypothesis with U.S. industries. They conjecture that economic news affect industry
fundamentals differently, and that the information content in the performance of certain
industries diffuses slowly across asset markets. Related literature documents differences in the
and Roley (1993) find that the S&P 500 decreases in value with news of economic growth
when the economy is strong and increases in value when the economy is weak. Boyd, Hu, and
Jagannathan (2005) find that the impact of unemployment news on equity returns depends on
whether the economy is in a period of expansion or recession. The empirical evidence thus
shows that the effect of economic news on expected sector performance depends not only on
Empirical research provides evidence that fund managers time their sector investments with
business cycles and that their order flows coincide with conventional sector rotation. Lynch,
Wachter, and Boudry (2004) also note that fund manager performance varies over business
cycles. Avramov and Wermers (2006) show that predictable variation in fund performance
relates to a manager’s skill in timing industry rotation with NBER business-cycle turning
points. Jiang, Yao, and Yu (2007) also observe that fund managers adjust industry allocations
6
based on common business cycle proxies. In a related study, Beber, Brandt, and Kavajecz
(2010) conclude that active order flows, defined as flows in excess of market capitalization,
directly link to economic news. Notably, for the motivation of this study, Beber, Brandt, and
Kavajecz (2010) observe that aggregate sector rebalancing emulates a conventional sector
rotation strategy, one that exploits the relative outperformance of certain sectors at different
business-cycle stages. Moreover, and of further interest for this study, they find institutional
order flows into certain sectors predict economic direction. For instance, order flows into the
basic materials sector predict economic expansion while order flows into the
contraction. Such investment flows also coincide with popular belief on the sequence of sector
performance.
researchers and investors. According to Hong and Stein (1999), informed arbitrage traders can
generate excess returns with simple trading strategies based on the release of economic news.
Sector- and industry-level investing also constitutes a dynamic growth segment in financial
markets. Cavaglia, Brightman, and Aked (2000) and Conover, Jensen, Johnson, and Mercer
Kacperczyk, Sialm, and Zheng (2005) find that active managers with concentrated industry
widespread availability of sector funds and ETFs makes sector allocation strategies more
feasible than ever. Nonetheless, there is an apparent absence of empirical research on sector
Related literature does describe the performance of alternative business-cycle timing strategies.
For instance, Siegel (1991) illustrates the potential of profitably timing allocations between
7
equities and cash. The author documents 12 percent annual market outperformance switching
between equity and cash at NBER business-cycle turning points. Brocato and Steed (1998)
Further, Levis and Liodakis (1999) and Ahmed, Lockwood, and Nanda (2002) report
Johnson, and Mercer (2008) show 3.4 percent annual outperformance to a strategy that times
investments in cyclical and non-cyclical stocks with Federal Reserve monetary policy. While
closely related, this study fundamentally differs from previous research, by thoroughly
analyzing sector and industry performance across different measures of business-cycle stages.
Additionally, as Fama and French (1997) and Lochstoer (2009) identify time-variant industry-
risk premiums related to business cycles, this study also evaluates industry performance using
different risk correction measures. Some more recent work on sector rotation profitability
includes Sarwar et al. (2018), Guris and Pala (2014), Chava et al. (2018).
The above discussion leads to a formal statement of this study’s null and alternative hypotheses.
H0: Industry returns are unrelated to the stage of a business cycle stage.
H1: There is a systematic relationship between industry performance and stages of the business
cycle.
H2: Rotating sector investments with business cycle stages generates systematic excess returns.
Answering these hypotheses tests the fundamental assumption of sector rotation investors that
timing industry allocations with the business cycle is a profitable investment strategy.
8
3. Business Cycles
Government agency responsible for dating business cycles is the NBER. While academics and
practitioners widely accept NBER cycle reference dates, other business-cycle measures are also
available.3 The NBER dates cycle peaks and cycle troughs that broadly define phases of
economic expansion and economic recession. Panel A of Table 1 reports business cycle
durations from business cycle peak to business cycle peak. The sample covers the 10 business
cycles enumerated in the far left column of Panel A. Each business cycle spans the first month
following a peak to the subsequent peak. Business cycles average 70 months over the sample.
Earlier business cycle durations are much shorter than recent cycles, particularly during phases
of economic expansion.4
commonly divide expansions and recessions into more discrete stages. Investment
professionals and practitioner guides, such as Stovall (1996), commonly divide expansions into
three equal stages (early/middle/late) and recessions into two equal stages (early/late). Three
stages of expansion allow for the longer duration of expansions relative to recessions. Other
research, such as DeStefano (2004), divides both expansions and recessions into two equal
stages. Our analysis evaluates sector/industry performance across five business cycle stages.
Subsequent analysis further evaluates performance across two-stage and four-stage business
cycle partitions.
2 Eleventh business cycle is still ongoing, with the latest peak recorded on December 2017. However, the 11 th business cycle
already has all five stages – 9 months each of early and late contractions, 40 each of early and middle expansions, and 29 of
late expansion.
3 For a survey of business cycle dating methodologies, see Cover and Pecorino (2005).
4 Moore (1974) provides a detailed discussion of post-1948 differences in business cycle dynamics.
9
The analysis measures expansions from the first month following a cycle trough to the
subsequent cycle peak and recessions from the first month following a cycle peak to the
subsequent cycle trough. The analysis also delineates three equal stages of expansion and two
equal stages of recession. The five business cycle stages are early expansion (Stage I), middle
expansion (Stage II), late expansion (Stage III), early recession (Stage IV), and late recession
(Stage V). Panel B of Table 1 reports the duration of expansions, recessions, and stages over
10 business cycles occurring from 1948 to 2018. Recessions average approximately 10 months
The analysis first investigates whether the five NBER delineated stages are consistent with
well-known business cycle proxies. The common business cycle proxies (BCP) in the literature
Studies by Keim and Stambaugh (1986), Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986), Fama and French
(1989), Schwert (1990), Campbell (1987), Chen (1991), Jensen, Mercer, and Johnson (1996),
and Petkova (2006), among others, document the relation between these proxies and business-
cycle conditions.
Panel A of Table 2 provides a summary of expected business cycle proxy changes over the five
NBER delineated stages. For instance, term-spread, default-spread, and dividend yield are
smallest near economic peaks and largest near economic troughs (Fama and French (1989)).5
The expectation is that these variables will decrease across early, middle, and late stages of
expansion. Conversely, these same variables should increase across stages of early and late
recession. Other studies, such as Balvers, Cosimano, and McDonald (1990) and Chen (1991),
document a close link between business cycles and both unemployment rates and industrial
5 The term-spread, default-spread, and dividend yield data come from http://www.globalfinancialdata.com
10
production. Stock and Watson (1999) and Hamilton and Lin (1996) show, for example, that
industrial production peaks and unemployment rates bottom out as the economy enters
recession. Industrial production should increase across successive stages of expansion and
decrease across early, middle, and late expansion, then increase across early and late recession.
Panel B of Table 3 reports proxy averages by business-cycle stage estimated with Equation 1,
where Ds is a dummy variable that takes the value of one or zero dependent on the current
5
BCPt s Ds ,t t (Eq. 1)
s1
Next, the table reports changes in business-cycle proxy values (s-s-1) between successive
business-cycle stages. Panel B establishes that changes in the selected business-cycle variables
track NBER delineated business-cycle stages and show the mostly expected signs as reported
in Panel A. For instance, the results should indicate a significantly negative default-spread
difference between early expansion and late recession. The analysis tests for statistical
significance using a simple difference in means test. Panel B reports p-values under the null
as Ho: s = s-1. Failure to reject the null would indicate no statistically significant difference in
the business-cycle proxy across successive stages and would invalidate the stage delineations.
For example, there is an average -0.5% difference between early expansion and late recession.
The results document that changes in the business-cycle proxies across successive business-
cycle stages, with few exceptions, have the expected sign and are highly significant.
11
4. Industry Performance across Business Cycles
website. Market returns represent the total value weighted returns for all NYSE, AMEX, and
NASDAQ listed stocks. The analysis initially uses the Fama and French 49 industry portfolios.
Fama and French map firms to industry groupings based on their standard industrial
classification (SIC).6 Firms mapped to the “other” industry come from a variety of sectors and
industries. As such, the “other” industry holds no relevance in a sector rotation strategy.
Consequently, the analysis omits the “other” industry, leaving 48 of the original Fama and
French 49 industries.7 The one-month Treasury bill serves as a proxy for the risk-free interest
rate.
Table 3 shows the particular stage of the business cycle where popular belief anticipates
industries will perform best. We follow the popular Stovall (1996) practitioner guide to sector
investing. Stovall (1996) divides all equities into 10 basic sectors. He then maps sectors and
sub-sector industry groups to one of five business cycle stages.8 For example, Stovall suggests
that the technology and transportation sectors provide early expansion performance, basic
materials and capital goods provide middle expansion performance, and so forth. As Table 3
illustrates, there are four technology sub-sector industries and two transportation sub-sector
industries. Conventional guidance suggests each industry in those sectors provides early
recession performance. Performance then shifts from sector to sector across business-cycle
(1986). There are also different variants of mapping sector performance to business-cycle stages. Salsman (1997) uses
dividend yield, short-term interest rates, and precious metal prices to map sector performance. The present study concludes
with the total relaxation of any assumed sector rotation model.
12
stages. The analysis maps each of the 48 industry portfolios to a corresponding sector, then
Table 4 provides industry descriptive industry statistics and nominal performance for the
business-cycle stage popular belief anticipates outperformance will occur. The table reports the
average number of firms, number of observations, mean returns, standard deviation of returns,
and single-index betas by the indicated stage. For comparison, Table 4 reports mean returns,
standard deviation of returns, and single-index betas for the full 1948–2018 sample. The table
also reports industry averages and market statistics beneath each business-cycle stage.
The second column of Table 4 reports the average number of firms in an industry.
Implementing sector rotation at industry level allows for more precise targeting of
performance. The wide variety of available industry funds and ETFs reflects the popularity of
industry-level investing. The increased precision targeting industry versus sector performance,
however, comes at the cost of reduced diversification benefits. The defense, tobacco, and coal
industries, for instance, comprise on average fewer than 10 firms. As such, investments in those
industries are subject to a high level of firm-specific risk. It is unlikely, however, that sector
rotation investors would invest in only one industry during a particular business-cycle stage.
For example, there are 12 industries, including defense, expected to provide middle expansion
performance. Overall, conventional sector rotation investors would thus hold a well-diversified
differences occur over business cycles. The analysis then observes whether industry
9For an overview of tradeoffs in implementing sector rotation strategies at sector, industries, and firm levels, see
http://us.ishares.com/portfolio_strategies/investment_strategies/sector_strategies.htm
13
performance coincides with popular belief. Computer software, for instance, should provide
early expansion performance and basic materials should provide middle expansion
performance. Table 4 also reports p-values from a Wald test under the null hypothesis that
industry returns are not significantly different across business-cycle stages. However, in most
cases, the p-values reject the null, indicating that industry performance varies across business-
cycle stages. Sector rotation investors would find this initial result encouraging. Failure to
reject the null hypothesis of equal returns would question the basic premise of sector rotation
Table 4 also reports average market returns beneath each business cycle stage. The analysis
compares industry and market returns to provide a simple relative return metric. As an example,
Table 4 reports transportation industry returns 1.84 percent, compared with 1.30 percent
average monthly market returns for early expansion. The transportation industry thus provides
expected outperformance does not always occur. Out of the 48 industries, 29 have nominal
returns higher than market returns, in the stage of expected outperformance. Thus, 60 percent
however, comes at a price. All but one industry (communications) has higher return volatility
than the market. Observing average industry performance for two stages reveals surprising
results. The 1.12 percent average return for industries expected to perform well in early
expansion actually underperforms the market by 0.18 percent. Similarly, average returns for
industries expected to perform well in middle expansion earn 0.13 percent less than the market.
Based on the initial results, popular belief holds true in the remaining three stages. Industries
on average outperform the market, as expected, in late expansion, early recession, and late
14
recession. Nominal sector performance coincides only partially with popular expectations.
Moreover, industry standard deviations and betas indicate that risk-adjusted performance will
coincide even less with popular expectations. For instance, in early and middle expansion,
average industry underperformance coincides with average standard deviations higher than the
market.
The nominal industry performance results are not encouraging for sector rotation investors.
The next section investigates whether industries provide systematic risk-adjusted business-
cycle performance.
factor alphas, and Carhart (1997) four-factor alphas by business-cycle stage. The table reports
Equation 2 estimates excess market industry performance (m), with a regression of excess
market industry returns (ri-rm) on the five business-cycle dummy variables (Ds). The regression
coefficient ism measures market outperformance for industry i during business cycle stage s.
The results show that 7 of 48 industries, approximately one in seven, generate statistically
significant excess market performance when expected. More than half of the significant excess
market performance occurs in early and late recession. Notably, excess market performance
comes before any adjustment for systematic exposure to known sources of risk, which the
5
rit rmt ism Dst it (Eq. 2)
s 1
15
Equation 3 estimates a Jensen’s alphas (J) attributable to each business-cycle stage with a
5 5
rit rft isJ Dst m,is (rmt rft ) Dst it (Eq. 3)
s 1 s 1
Equation 3 runs a regression of industry returns in excess of the one-month Treasury bill (ri-rf)
on one of five business-cycle timing variables (Ds) and the conditional market risk premium
(rm-rf). The Fama and French market index represents the market proxy.
To ensure the results do not depend on exposure to other well-known risk factors, the analysis
also estimates Fama and French three-factor alphas and Carhart four-factor alphas. The Fama
and French alphas (F), estimated with Equation 4, control for size and value risk factors in
addition to market risk. Lastly, the Carhart four-factor alphas (C), estimated with Equation 5,
5 5
rit rft isF Dst ism(rmt rft ) issSMBt isvHMLt Dst it (Eq. 4)
s1 s1
5 5
rit rf t isC Dst ism (rmt rf t ) iss SMBt isv HMLt isc MOM t Dst it (Eq. 5)
s 1 s 1
statistically significant industry outperformance where popular belief would suggest. The
performance results strengthen the earlier findings reported for nominal returns. Based on
Jensen’s alphas, there are four industries with significant outperformance. Based on the Fama
and French three-factor model, and using the Carhart four-factor model, there are no industries
16
5. Sector Rotation Performance
Can conventional sector rotation still be profitable, despite limited evidence of systematic
performance of sector rotation across the last 10 business cycles. The strategy assumes
investors perfectly time NBER business-cycle stages and rotate the 48 Fama-French industries
following the conventional sector rotation strategy and compares the result with a simple
market investment. Panel A of Table 6 provides mean monthly returns, as well as strategy
Sector rotation outperformance amounts to an average of 0.11% per month, which, at first
glance appears economically large. However, in perspective, this number presents the
maximum outperformance. Only the investors who followed popular market wisdom over the
last 70 years, ignored transaction costs, and perfectly timed the last 10 business cycles would
have realized 0.11% per month outperformance. It is also important to note that sector rotation
strategy has a higher standard deviation, higher beta, and lower Sharpe ratio than the simple
market portfolio.
Siegel (1991) suggests a simpler market timing strategy, showing that shifting between equities
and cash at business cycle turning points generates significant outperformance. However,
Siegel (1991) also recognizes the difficulty in correctly timing business cycles. To provide
perspective on sector rotation outperformance, the results also report the performance of the
simpler market-timing strategy suggested by Siegel (1991). Here, the analysis assumes a
theoretical investor who correctly times NBER recessions and expansions. Such an investor,
shifting from equities to cash early recession and back to equities late recession, would have
realized 0.15 percent average monthly outperformance. That same investor would have also
17
Under a more realistic assumption of transaction costs, the results for sector rotation strategy
become even bleaker. Transaction costs, both explicit and implicit, are difficult to estimate
precisely. Estimated transaction costs include commissions, bid-ask spread, and market impact.
Actual costs depend on the stock, where it trades, and when it trades.10 Estimates vary
considerably and change over the sample.11 As an allowance, we estimate transaction costs that
range between 0.5 and 1.5 percent. Sector rotation has 53 round-trip transactions and the
market-timing strategy has 21 round-trip transactions from 1948 to 2018. With the inclusion
of transaction costs, the base-case sector rotation outperformance decreases to between 0.07 to
0.01 percent and becomes statistically indistinguishable from zero. The alternative market-
Thus far, the results indicate only marginal sector rotation outperformance for sector rotation
implemented in accordance with popular wisdom, even if one assumes investors can correctly
time business cycles. Results for industries expected to perform well in early expansion and
middle expansion are particularly disappointing. Still, it would be premature to conclude that
sector rotation does not work. Investors may use different industry or sector classifications,
may time business cycles in advance or with a delay, which could generate outperformance.
The robustness tests also investigate whether the results improve if investors anticipate changes
in business-cycle turning points earlier or later. In addition to NBER business cycles, the
analysis tests business-cycle stages constructed from the CFNAI. The analysis concludes with
10See for example Goyenko, Holden, and Trzcinka (2009) and Hasbrouck (2009).
11Estimates of total trading costs vary greatly depending on the study. For instance, Lesmond, Schill, and Zhou (2004)
estimate round-trip transaction costs of 1 to 2 percent for most large-cap trades while Keim and Madhavan (1998) estimate
total round-trip transaction costs as low as 0.2 percent.
18
the total relaxation of any specific sector rotation model, testing for the systematic performance
6. Robustness Checks
The analysis thus far has focused on a fairly specific version of a sector rotation strategy – a
five stage, 48-industry model based on Stovall’s (1996) rotation logic. While this particular
model is widely used, it is one of potentially thousands of sector rotation models available for
alternative way to measure the business cycle, as well as timing the cycle in advance or with a
delay. We then deviate from Stovall’s model and consider every possible form of a sector
rotation strategy. We then relax the assumptions even further, looking if any industry’s
performance can act as a predictor of any other industry’s returns irrespective of the business
cycle.
As such, our analysis might merely reflect a particular industry grouping. The following
analysis investigates the performance of two alternative sector and industry groups. The
analysis maps the original Fama and French 49 industries to 10 sector portfolios and 23 major
industry portfolios, as listed in Table A1. The 10 sector portfolios are constructed following
the Kacperczyk, Sialm, and Zheng (2005) mapping of the Fama and French 48 portfolios. The
additional computer software industry included in the Fama and French 49 industry portfolios
goes into the business equipment and services sector. Additionally, the analysis maps the Fama
and French 49 industries to one of 23 GICS major industry groups. The Global Industry
Classification Standard (GICS), first introduced in 1999, provides a widely accepted alternative
19
to SIC classifications.12 Bhojraj, Lee, and Oler (2003) report GICS classifications are superior
The results are presented in Panel B of Table 6. Both 10-sector and 23-industry groupings
generate similar mean monthly sector rotation returns to the ones generated by 49 Fama-French
industries (1.03% and 0.99% vs. 1.00%). Neither grouping generates mean returns higher than
a simple market timing strategy. Sector rotation performance based on alternative industry
groupings is also inferior to market timing in terms of volatility, beta, and Sharpe ratio. This
leads us to believe that our results are not driven by a particular industry classification13.
follows a common approach, one can potentially construct any number of business cycle
partitions. As a result, the base-case results face criticism that they are specific to particular
delineation of business cycle stages. The NBER officially dates the U.S. business cycle peaks
and troughs, delineating one stage of expansion and one stage of contraction. DeStefano (2004)
further separates the NBER stages of expansion and contraction into two equal halves, four
stages in all. The following analysis considers both NBER two-stage and DeStefano (2004)
four-stage partitions, to verify that the results are robust to alternative business cycle stage
definitions. The two-stage analysis uses NBER cycle dates to delineate one stage of expansion
and one stage of recession. The two-stage analysis maps early, middle, and late expansion
industries into one stage expansion, and early and late recession industries into one stage of
recession. The four-stage analysis further divides expansions and recessions in halves. Early
20
and late expansion stages last on average 302 and 314 months. Early and late recessions last
The results for sector rotation strategy performance based on two- and four-stage business cycle
delineations are reported in Panel C of Table 6.14 The strategy based on two-stage delineation
underperforms the market portfolio across all dimensions. Although the strategy based on four-
stage delineation marginally outperforms the five-stage strategy, it is still inferior to the market
timing strategy reported in Panel A, having lower outperformance (0.12% vs. 0.15%), higher
standard deviation (4.85% vs. 3.99%), higher beta (1.04 vs. 0.89), and lower Sharpe ratio (0.21
improvement on the base case and the previous results continue to hold.
This section considers the Chicago Federal Reserve National Activity Index (CFNAI) and
Conference Board Leading Indicator as alternatives to NBER cycle dates. As results for these
two indicators are similar, the analysis focuses on the CFNAI.15 In contrast to static NBER
business cycle conditions. The CFNAI incorporates 85 economic variables that cover four
broad categories: production and income; employment, unemployment, and hours; personal
consumption and housing; and sales, orders, and inventories. CFNAI construction follows the
methodology of Stock and Watson (1989), who create an index based on the first principal
components of a large number of variables that track economic activity. By construction, the
CFNAI has a zero mean and unit standard deviation. Positive (negative) CFNAI values indicate
14 Just as with alternative industry groupings, we have produced industry descriptive statistics and risk-adjusted performance
measures. Just as with base-case results, we find very limited evidence of systematic industry outperformance across
business cycles. The results are not reported to save space. They are available from the corresponding author upon request.
15 The CFNAI and detrended Conference Board leading indicator have a 78 percent correlation coefficient. Both indices thus
reveal similar business cycle information. The study focuses on the CFNAI because it is freely available to the public and
released monthly by the Chicago Federal Reserve Bank.
21
above (below) trend economic activity. Publication of the CFNAI began in 2001 with data
available from 1967.16 Figure 4 overlays the CFNAI on NBER delineated phases of economic
expansion and contraction (shaded area). The CFNAI closely tracks NBER cycle dates, with
some variation. The variation may better reflect investor uncertainty when attempting to
The analysis partitions CFNAI business cycles into five equal stages. CFNAI values of 0.702,
0.312, -.0113, and -.637 delineate stages of early expansion through late recession. We then
proceed as with the five-stage NBER business cycle delineation. Sector rotation strategy results
are presented in the last line of Table 6 (Panel C). Such a strategy underperforms across the
board. All performance characteristics are inferior to market, market timing, as well as all
investors consistently assume that turning points occur earlier or with a delay from actual
NBER business cycle dates. If so, the base-case scenario might underestimate actual sector
rotation outperformance. To explore that possibility, the analysis advances the implementation
of sector rotation by one month, two months, and three months prior to NBER business-cycle
turning points. Similarly, the analysis considers delays from one to three months. Table 7
There appears to be some benefit to anticipating business cycle one and two months in advance
when it comes to sector rotation strategy. However, (1) the improvement is very marginal and
22
6.5. Analyzing all possible sector rotation strategies
While the preceding robustness checks have relaxed a number of assumptions, the basic model
is still based on the one described in Stovall (1996). Conventional sector rotation presupposes
the sequential performance of sectors across business cycle stages. For instance, Standard &
Poor’s sequencing in Figure 1 shows that performance in the technology sector follows the
performance in the financial sector, which in turn follows performance in the utilities sector.
While it depicts largely congruent beliefs on sequential sector performance, other variations
are possible. After all, throughout the analysis we have assumed that agricultural sector,
reasonable, but it is an assumption nonetheless. One could come up with a plausible argument
We now explicitly address this by analyzing every possible combination of sector rotation
strategy using a 10-sector industry definition and a two-stage business cycle partition. This
gives us 1,022 possible strategies. Return distribution of all of the possible strategies are
presented in Figure 4.
The results provide even more discouragement for a potential sector rotation investor. Average
return of these strategies is 0.86% per month, actually lower than that of a buy-and-hold
strategy of 0.89% (coincidentally, a two-stage partitioning model based on Stovall (1996) also
provides a raw return of 0.89%). A market-timing strategy based on a two-stage business cycle
partition (invest in an index during booms and in T-bills during recessions) yields an average
Not surprisingly, some sector rotation strategies outperform both a buy-and-hold and a market
timing strategy. Only 35 out of 1,022 strategies (3.4%) outperform the market timing strategy,
and only 132 out of 1,022 (12.9%) outperform the buy-and-hold. Accounting for transaction
23
costs will make these strategies even less attractive. The mean of sector rotation strategies is
significantly lower than that of a buy-and-hold, providing strong evidence that any
performance across business cycles may not fully align with those partitions. To overcome
such obstacles, we next relax any assumed pattern of sequential performance and completely
ignore business cycle stages. The analysis tests whether the excess market returns of one sector
predict future excess market returns of other sectors at different lags. The analysis examines
lags from one to 24 months, to allow for different performance sequencing and business cycle
stage durations.
Figure 5 illustrates the distribution of t-statistics for cross-sector predictability of excess sector
performance. First, the analysis maps the Fama-French 49 industries to 10 equally weighted
sector portfolios following Table A1. Next, the analysis runs individual regressions of excess
market sector returns on the excess market returns of the remaining sectors at lags from one to
24 months. In total, there are 2,160 (10 x 9 x 24) t-statistics, covering all possible combinations
of sectors and lags. Figure 5 compares the resultant t-statistic distribution against an expected
normal distribution. The figure illustrates that the distribution of t-statistics for excess market
significance level, the estimations should indicate 5 percent positive significance and 5 percent
negative significance – even in the absence of actual excess market predictability. In total, t-
statistics are significantly positive 6 percent of the time and significantly negative 5 percent of
the time. Most significant predictability occurs at a one-month lag, indicating some short-term
24
distribution. As such, the results suggest that cross-sector predictability occurs only randomly,
without indicating any real evidence of statistically significant sequential sector performance.
7. Conclusion
Despite thorough empirical tests, there is scant evidence that conventional sector rotation
across business cycles generates systematic excess returns. The analysis assumes that sector
rotation investors perfectly time business cycles and rotate sectors in accordance with popular
belief on sector performance. Even then, sector rotation generates, at best, 0.11 percent monthly
business cycle mistiming. In comparison, a similar investor, with perfect market timing ability,
would realize 0.15 percent monthly outperformance by simply switching to cash during early
recession.
The analysis generalizes the base case to allow for all possible sector rotation variations. The
analysis explores whether any industry provides systematic performance across any business-
cycle stage. The general results again provide limited evidence of systematic industry
performance over business cycles. The results suggest that no variation of sector rotation
provides systematic outperformance, questioning the popular belief that timing sector
investments with business cycles generate excess returns. The results do not necessarily
preclude investors from profiting through sector rotation. Different investments in sector and
industry funds, beyond the scope of this study, may outperform the market. The results simply
show that sectors fail to provide systematic performance across the business cycle and question
25
References
Ahmed, P., L. Lockwood, and S. Nanda, 2002, Multi-style rotation strategies, Journal of
Portfolio Management 28, 17-29.
Avramov, D. and R. Wermers, 2006, Investing in mutual funds when returns are predictable,
Journal of Financial Economics 81, 339-377.
Balvers, R., T. Cosimano, and B. McDonald, 1990, Predicting stock returns in an efficient
market, The Journal of Finance 45, 1109-1128.
Beber, A., M. Brandt, and K. Kavajecz, 2010, What does equity sector order flow tell us about
the economy? Review of Financial Studies 24, 3688-3730.
Bhojraj, S., C. Lee, and D. Oler, 2003, What's my line? A comparison of industry classification
schemes for capital market research, Journal of Accounting Research 41, 745-774.
Bodie, Z., A. Kane, and A. Marcus, 2009. Investments (McGraw Hill Irwin)
Boyd, J., J. Hu, and R. Jagannathan, 2005, The stock market's reaction to unemployment news:
Why bad news is usually good for stocks, Journal of Finance 60, 649-672.
Brocato, J. and S. Steed, 1998, Optimal asset allocation over the business cycle, The Financial
Review 33, 129-148.
Campbell, J., 1987, Stock returns and the term structure, Journal of Financial Economics 18,
373-399.
Carhart, M., 1997, On persistence in mutual fund performance, Journal of Finance 52, 57-82.
Cavaglia, S., C. Brightman, and M. Aked, 2000, The increasing importance of industry factors,
Financial Analysts Journal 56, 41-54.
Chava, S., A. Hsu, and L. Zeng, 2018. Does history repeat itself? Business cycle and industry
returns. SSRN working paper.
Chen, N., 1991, Financial investment opportunities and the macroeconomy, Journal of Finance
46, 529-554.
Chen, N., R. Roll, and S. Ross, 1986, Economic forces and the stock market, The Journal of
Business 59, 383-403.
Conover, M., G. Jensen, R. Johnson, and J. Mercer, 2008, Sector rotation and monetary
conditions, Journal of Investing 34-46.
Cover, J. and P. Pecorino, 2005, The length of u.S. Business expansions: When did the break
in the data occur?, Journal of Macroeconomics 27, 452-471.
DeStefano, M., 2004, Stock returns and the business cycle, Financial Review 39, 527-547.
26
Elton, E., M. Gruber, and C. Blake, 2011, An examination of mutual fund timing ability using
monthly holding data, Review of Finance 3, 619-645.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1989, Business conditions and expected returns on stocks and bonds,
Journal of Financial Economics 25, 23-49.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance
47, 427-465.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1997, Industry costs of equity., Journal of Financial Economics 43,
153-193.
Goyenko, R., C. Holden, and C. Trzcinka, 2009, Do liquidity measures measure liquidity?,
Journal of Financial Economics 92, 153-181.
Guris, S., and A. Pala, 2014. Equity returns, firm-specific characteristics and sector rotation:
Evidence from Turkey. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues 4,
264-276.
Hamilton, J. and G. Lin, 1996, Stock market volatility and the business cycle, Journal of
Applied Econometrics 11, 573-593
Hasbrouck, J., 2009, Trading costs and returns for U.S. Equities: Estimating effective costs
from daily data, Journal of Finance 64, 1445-1477.
Hong, H. and J. Stein, 1999, A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and
overreaction in asset markets, Journal of Finance 54, 2143-2184.
Hong, H., W. Torous, and R. Valkanov, 2007, Do industries lead stock markets?, Journal of
Financial Economics 83, 367-396.
Jensen, G., J. Mercer, and R. Johnson, 1996, Business conditions, monetary policy, and
expected security returns, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 213-237.
Jiang, G., T. Yao, and T. Yu, 2007, Do mutual funds time the market? Evidence from portfolio
holdings, Journal of Financial Economics 86, 724-758.
Kacperczyk, M., C. Sialm, and L. Zheng 2005, On the industry concentration of actively
managed equity mutual funds, Journal of Finance 60, 1983-2011.
Keim, D. and A. Madhavan, 1998, The cost of institutional equity trades, Financial Analysts
Journal 54, 50-69.
Keim, D. and R. Stambaugh, 1986, Predicting returns in the stock and bond markets, Journal
of Financial Economics 17, 357-390.
Lesmond, D., M. Schill, and C. Zhou, 2004, The illusory nature of momentum profits, Journal
of Financial Economics 71, 349-380.
27
Lofthouse, S., 2001. Investment management (Wiley).
Levis, M. and M. Liodakis, 1999, The profitability of style rotation strategies in the United
Kingdom, Journal of Portfolio Management.
Lochstoer, L., 2009, Expected returns and the business cycle: Heterogeneous goods and time-
varying risk aversion, Review of Financial Studies 22, 5251-5294.
Lynch, A., J. Wachter, and W. Boudry, 2004, Does mutual fund performance vary over the
business cycle?, AFA 2004 San Diego Meetings.
Markese, J., 1986, The stock market and business cycles, AAII Journal 8, 30-32.
McQueen, G. and V. Roley, 1993, Stock prices, news, and business conditions., Review of
Financial Studies 6, 683.
Moore, G., 1974, Some secular changes in business cycles, The American Economic Review
64, 133-137.
Petkova, R., 2006, Do the fama-french factors proxy for innovations in predictive variables,
The Journal of Finance 61, 581-612.
Salsman, R., 1997, Using market prices to guide sector rotation, (CFA Institute).
Sarwar, G, C. Mateus and N. Todorovic, 2018. US sector rotation with five-factor Fama-French
alphas, Journal of Asset Management 19, 116-132.
Siegel, J., 1991, Does it pay stock investors to forecast the business cycle, Journal of Portfolio
Management Fall, 27-34.
Schwert, W., 1990, Stock returns and real activity: A century of evidence., Journal of Finance
45, 1237.
Stock, J. and M. Watson, 1989, New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators,
NBER macroeconomics annual 351-394.
Stock, J. and M. Watson, 1999, Business cycle fluctuations in U.S. Macroeconomic time series,
Handbook of Macroeconomics (Elsevier), Chapter 1.
Stovall, S., 1996. Standard & poor's guide to sector investing (McGraw-Hill).
28
Figure 1. Popular guidance on sector rotation
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/cycle.shtml
http://www2.standardandpoors.com/spf/pdf/index/Global_Sector_Investing.pdf
29
Figure 2. Stylized business cycles with stage partitions
Figure 2 illustrates a stylized business cycle. The official government agency responsible for dating U.S.
business cycles is the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). The NBER publishes dates for business
cycle peaks and troughs. Phases of expansion run from the month following a trough to the next peak and
phases of recession run from the month following a peak to the next trough. Similar to Stovall (1996) and
common practice, the analysis divides expansions into three equal stages (early/middle/late) and recessions into
two stages (early/late).
NBER peak
Expansion Recession
30
Figure 3. CFNAI delineated business cycle stages
Figure 3 illustrates the CFNAI economic indicator over the period 1968–20018. Shaded areas indicate NBER
defined periods of economic contraction. The analysis partitions the range of CFNAI values over 1968–2018 into
five equal periods of economic activity. The five periods correspond to early expansion (SI), middle expansion
(SII), late expansion (SIII), early recession (SIV), and late recession (SV). Business-cycle stage delineations are
at CFNAI values of 0.702, 0.312, -.0113, and -.637 for boundaries SI|SII, SII|SIII, SIII|SIV, and SIV|SV
respectively.
2.5
1.5
0.5
-1.5
-2.5
-3.5
-4.5
31
Figure 4. Distribution of all possible sector strategy returns
Figure 4 presents the distribution of returns of 1,022 sector rotation strategies formed by 10 sectors using a two-
stage business cycle partition.
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
32
Figure 5. Predictability of excess industry performance
Figure 5 illustrates the distribution of t-statistics for cross-sector predictability of excess market performance. The
analysis constructs sector rotation portfolios from the Fama and French 49 industries mapped to one of 10 GICS
sectors reported in Table A1. The analysis tests lags from one to 24 months to allow for the possibility of different
performance sequencing and business cycle stage durations. To illustrate, Figure 1 shows financial sector returns
should predict subsequent technology sector returns. There are 2,160 t-statistics, covering all possible
combinations of cross-sector predictability at up to 24 lags.
25.00%
20.00%
15.00%
10.00%
5.00%
0.00%
1 to 1.65
0 to 0.5
0.5 to 1
< -3.29
> 3.29
-1 to -0.5
-3.29 to -2.58
-2.58 to -1.96
-1.96 to -1.65
-1.65 to -1
-0.5 to 0
1.65 to 1.96
1.96 to 2.58
2.58 to 3.29
33
Table 1. NBER reference business cycle dates and stage partitions
Panel A of Table 1 reports NBER published business cycle peak and trough reference dates. Periods of recession
run from the first month following a cycle peak to the subsequent trough, and periods of expansion run from the
first month following a cycle trough to the subsequent peak. The sample covers 10 business cycles from 1948 to
2007, enumerated in the first column. The last column reports the total months in a business cycle from one month
after a peak to the next peak. The last recorded NBER business cycle date is the economic peak dated December
2007. Panel B of Table 1 reports the duration in months for stages of expansion and recession that correspond
with the business cycles reported in Panel A. The analysis partitions NBER defined periods of expansion into
three equal stages (early, middle, and late) and NBER defined periods of recession into two equal stages (early
and late). The bottom of Panel B reports the average duration of each business cycle stage.
Panel A: NBER business cycle dates from Jan 1948 - Dec 2007
Business Peak Trough Peak Total
Cycle Date Date Date Months
1 11/48 10/49 07/53 56
2 07/53 05/54 08/57 49
3 08/57 04/58 04/60 32
4 04/60 02/61 12/69 116
5 12/69 11/70 11/73 47
6 11/73 03/75 01/80 74
7 01/80 07/80 07/81 18
8 07/81 11/82 07/90 108
9 07/90 03/91 03/01 128
10 03/01 11/01 12/07 81
Panel B: Number of months in NBER delineated business cycle stages
Business Periods of Recession Periods of Expansion
Early Stage Late Stage Total Early Stage Middle Stage Late Stage Total
Cycle Months Months Months Months Months Months Months
1 6 5 11 15 15 15 45
2 5 5 10 13 13 13 39
3 4 4 8 8 8 8 24
4 5 5 10 35 35 36 106
5 6 5 11 12 12 12 36
6 8 8 16 19 19 20 58
7 3 3 6 4 4 4 12
8 8 8 16 30 31 31 92
9 4 4 8 40 40 40 120
10 4 4 8 25 25 23 73
stage average: 5 5 10 20 20 20 60
34
Table 2. Business cycle proxies across business cycle stages
Panel A of Table 2 lists the expected change in business cycle proxies from one business cycle stage to the next.
Panel B of Table 2 reports business cycle proxy means by business cycle stage and changes in means from the
preceding stage estimated with Equation 1, where business cycle dummy variables (Ds) take the value of one or
zero depending on the current business cycle stage. The analysis then calculates the difference in proxy means
between successive business cycle stages. As an example, Panel B reports an average 0.3% difference in term-
spread between the stages of early expansion and late recession ( 1-5). Lastly, the analysis performs a simple
difference in means test, to verify the statistical significance of the difference in means between the current and
preceding stage. The table reports p-values under a null hypothesis of no difference in proxies across successive
business cycle stages, formally stated as Ho: s=s-1.
Panel A: Change Change Change Change Change
Early Expansion Middle Expansion Late Expansion Early Recession Late Recession
Term-spread negative negative negative positive positive
Default-spread negative negative negative positive positive
Dividend yield negative negative negative positive positive
Unemployment negative negative negative positive positive
Industrial production positive positive positive negative negative
35
Table 3. Business cycle stages of expected industry performance
Table 3 reports the business cycle stage of anticipated sector/industry outperformance following the Stovall (1996)
classification and the investment websites illustrated in Figure 1. The table divides the periods of expansion into
three equal stages (early/middle/late) and periods of recession into two equal stages (early/late). The Fama and
French 49 industry portfolios (excluding “other”) are mapped to corresponding sectors.
Period of Expansion Period of Recession
Early Expansion - Stage I Middle Expansion - Stage II Late Expansion - Stage III Early Recession - Stage IV Late Recession - Stage V
Technology: Basic Materials: Consumer Staples: Utilities: Consumer Cyclical:
Computer Software Precious Metals Agriculture Gas & Electrical Utilities Apparel
Measuring & Control Equip. Chemicals Beer & Liquor Telecom Automobiles & Trucks
Computers Steel Works Etc Candy & Soda Business Supplies
Electronic Equipment Non-Metallic & Metal Mining Food Products Construction
Transportation: Capital Goods: Healthcare Construction Materials
General Transportation Fabricated Products Medical Equipment Consumer Goods
Shipping Containers Defense Pharmaceutical Products Entertainment
Machinery Tobacco Products Printing & Publishing
Ships & Railroad Equip. Energy: Recreation
Aircraft Coal Restaurants, Hotels, Motels
Electrical Equipment Petroleum & Natural Gas Retail
Services: Rubber & Plastic Products
Business Services Textiles
Personal Services Wholesale
Financial:
Banking
Insurance
Real Estate
Trading
36
Table 4. Industry summary statistics by business cycle stages
Table 4 reports industry summary statistics for the business cycle stage popular belief anticipates outperformance
will occur, as listed in Table 3. The table also reports Wald p-values under a null hypothesis of equal industry
returns across all five business cycle stages. For comparative purposes, the table provides industry summary
statistics for the full sample 1948-2018. The table reports equally weighted industry averages and market returns
beneath each business cycle stage.
Business Cycle Stage Full Sample 1948:01-2007:12
no. no. Wald
Sectors/Industries firms obs. mean std.dev. beta p-value mean std.dev. beta
Early Expansion - Stage I:
Computers 90 241 1.17 6.48 1.34 0.00 0.97 6.75 1.22
Computer Software 175 169 0.27 9.08 1.48 0.01 0.38 11.11 1.63
Electronic Equipment 157 241 1.20 6.96 1.43 0.00 0.91 7.21 1.39
Measuring & Control 70 241 0.92 6.23 1.31 0.00 0.98 6.64 1.28
Shipping Containers 26 241 1.32 5.10 0.99 0.01 0.94 5.39 1.00
Transportation 93 241 1.84 4.93 1.00 0.00 0.85 5.54 1.07
Industry Averages 1.12 6.46 1.26 0.00 0.84 7.11 1.27
Market 241 1.30 3.90 1.00 0.00 0.89 4.23 1.00
37
Table 4 continued:
Business Cycle Stage Full Sample 1948:01-2007:12
no. no. Wald
Sectors/Industries firms obs. mean std.dev. beta p-value mean std.dev. beta
Early Recession - Stage IV:
Utilities 137 62 -0.32 4.92 0.79 0.02 0.85 3.77 0.53
Communication 43 62 -0.71 4.60 0.77 0.02 0.80 4.27 0.74
Industry Averages -0.52 4.76 0.78 0.02 0.83 4.02 0.64
Market 62 -1.58 4.65 1.00 0.00 0.89 4.23 1.00
38
Table 5. Industry performance measures by business cycle stage
Table 5 reports industry excess market returns, Jensen’s alphas, Fama and French (1992) three-factor alphas, and
Carhart (1997) four-factor alphas for the business-cycle stages of expected outperformance listed in Table 3.
Equations 2-5 estimate excess market returns, Jensen’s alphas, Fama and French alphas, and Carhart alphas by
business-cycle stage. Emboldened alpha performance indicates 10 percent statistical significance estimated with
White (1980) heteroskedasticity consistent t-statistics.
39
Table 5 continued:
Jensen's alpha Fama-French alpha Carhart alpha
40
Table 6. Performance comparison of alternative investment strategies
Table 6 reports means, standard deviations, betas, and Sharpe ratios for market timing and sector rotation strategies
under different assumptions.
41
Table 7. Comparison of strategy performance with different timing
Table 7 reports the performance of sector rotation and market timing with advanced or delayed strategy implementation at
business cycle stage turning points by the indicated months. The strategy rotates the Fama and French 49 industry portfolios
according to Table 3. Table 7 reports mean returns, standard deviations, and Sharpe ratios. Beta estimates come from a single-
index model. The reported performance results are before transaction costs.
Sector Rotation:
- 3 months 0.97% 4.88% 0.99 0.20
- 2 months 1.02% 4.90% 1.00 0.21
- 1 month 1.01% 4.98% 1.02 0.20
at turning point 1.00% 5.02% 1.04 0.20
+ 1 month 0.98% 5.01% 1.03 0.20
+ 2 months 0.93% 5.07% 1.05 0.18
+ 3 months 0.93% 5.00% 1.04 0.19
Market Timing:
- 3 months 0.95% 3.90% 0.85 0.24
- 2 months 1.01% 3.94% 0.87 0.26
- 1 month 1.02% 3.95% 0.88 0.26
at turning point 1.04% 3.99% 0.89 0.26
+ 1 month 1.05% 3.98% 0.88 0.26
+ 2 months 1.04% 3.99% 0.89 0.26
+ 3 months 0.98% 4.01% 0.90 0.24
42
Table A1. Alternative industry definitions
Table A1 provides a mapping of the Fama and French 49 industry portfolios to 23 Global industrial Classification
Standard (GICS) industry groups and 10 sector classifications.
43