Unit 4.2
Unit 4.2
Preference
BBA(H)-Managerial-Economics
Semester-3
Introduction
• Economists use the theory of consumer choice to analyze consumers’
decisions and to derive demand curves.
• To answer questions about individual consumer choice (or any kind of
individual decision making) we need a model of individual behavior.
• The standard economic model of consumer behavior is based on the
following premises or assumptions.
• Individual tastes or preferences determine the pleasure or satisfaction
people derive from the goods and services they consume.
• Consumers face constraints or limits on their choices, particularly because
their budgets limit how much they can buy.
• Consumers seek to maximize the level of satisfaction they obtain from
consumption, subject to the constraints they face. People seek to “do the
best they can with what they have.
• Consumers spend their money on the bundles of products that give
them the most pleasure or satisfaction.
• Someone who likes music and does not have much of a sweet tooth
might spend a lot of money on concerts and relatively little on sweet
desserts.
• By contrast, a consumer who loves chocolate and has little interest in
music might spend a significant amount on gourmet chocolate and
never go to a concert
• Consumers must make choices about which goods to buy.
• Limits on the amount they can spend (called “budget constraints”)
prevent them from buying everything that catches their fancy. Other
constraints such as legal restrictions on items such as alcohol and
recreational drugs may also restrain their choices.
• Therefore, consumers buy the bundles of goods they like best subject
to their budget constraints and subject to legal or other relevant
constraints
• If Jason gets pleasure from smoking, an economist does not confuse
the economic analysis of Jason’s choices by interjecting his or her
own personal judgment that smoking is undesirable.
• Economists accept the consumer’s tastes and seek to predict the
resulting behavior.
• Accepting each consumer’s tastes is not the same as condoning the
resulting behaviors.
• An economist might reasonably believe that smoking should be
avoided. However, if the economist wants to know whether Jason will
smoke more next year if the price of cigarettes decreases by 10%
Consumer Preferences
• Consumer Preferences: We use three properties of preferences to
predict which combinations or bundles of goods an individual
prefers to other combinations.
• The realms of consumer behaviour were expanded to new horizons with the
introduction of indifference curve analysis by J.R. Hicks and R.G.D. Allen.
• The crux of this analysis is that utility is ordinally measurable. From the above
discussion on ordinal approach, you can promptly infer that given two
commodities M and N, a consumer is able to rank different combinations of the
commodities in order of preference or indifference.
• If we plot the quantities of the two commodities on the two axes, then we can
draw a set of points that would represent alternative combinations of M and N,
between which the consumer would be indifferent.
• The curve formed by joining such points is known as an indifference curve.
• Each point on an indifference curve represents a consumption basket,
having a combination of the two goods consumed.
• Thus, point A on the curve shows a combination of 1 sandwich and 6
glasses of cold coffee, which would give the consumer the same level of
satisfaction as 3 sandwich and 3 glasses of cold coffee, shown by point B,
• or 5 sandwich and 2 glasses of cold coffee, shown by point C, or 7 sandwich
and 1 glasses of cold coffee, shown by point D.
• You may, thus, infer that the level of satisfaction remains the same at all
points on the same indifference curve and the consumer would as such
be indifferent between all such combinations of the two goods
consumed.
• The consumer can make many more combinations of the two goods, with less of any
one, or both of the goods.
• Points below an indifference curve will have lesser utility than any point on the curve.
• In Panel “a” of Figure 3.5, an indifference curve (say, I0) can be drawn through points
below I1;
• Each point on such a curve would give lesser satisfaction than points on I1. Similarly, an
indifference curve (say, I2) can be drawn through points above I1; each point on such a
curve would render greater satisfaction than those on I1. In fact, it is possible to draw
numerous such curves like I0, I2 and I3, each representing a unique level of utility and
none intersecting any other.
• The family of such indifference curves, shown in Panel “a”, is referred to as the
indifference map
Assumptions
• You know that the basic premise is that the consumer is rational; besides the
indifference curves analysis is based on certain other assumptions:
i. At any given point of time, the consumer has only two goods in his/her
consumption basket.
ii. It is not possible to quantify the utility availed from the consumption rather the
consumer is able to rank his/her preferences on a scale.
iii. The consumer is never completely satisfied; this is in accordance to the
assumption on non-satiation you have read earlier in this chapter. In other words,
more is always wanted.
iv. The consumer is consistent in his choices. This implies that if a consumer is
indifferent between butter and ghee, and between ghee and cheese, he would be
indifferent between butter and cheese as well.
Yes, you got it right: this is the same as the assumption of transitivity discussed
earlier.
v. The two goods under consideration are perfectly divisible in small units. This
implies that indifference curves would be continuous in nature.
Properties of Indifference Curves
(i) Downward Sloping-
• Indifference curves are downward sloping. This is because of the
assumption of non-satiation. You know that an indifference curve
shows various such combinations of two goods which give same
utility to the consumer.
• As per assumption of non-satiation, more is better; this will be
negated on an upward sloping indifference curve
(ii) Higher Indifference Curve Represents Higher Utility
• An indifference curve placed higher will represent higher level of
utility. Let us explain how.
• Observe the curves in Panel “a” of Figure 3.5. If we consider point A
on the curve I1 and point C on I2, then you can follow from the figure
that C has more of both M and N.
• However, a point on a higher indifference curve may not necessarily
have greater amounts of both the goods; but it will have greater
quantity of at least one of the two commodities and a greater
quantity of any one of the two commodities will render a higher level
of utility
(iii) Indifference Curves can Never Intersect
• Indifference curves cannot intersect.
• This follows from the assumptions of transitivity and higher utility at a higher
indifference curve.
• Let us start with the assumption that indifference curves do intersect; we would
check the feasibility of this assumption to prove that indifference curves do not
intersect.
• Suppose I1 and I2 are two indifference curves that intersect at point C in Panel
“b” of Figure 3.5. Points A and C lie on I2 and points B and C lie on I1; I2 is higher
than I1.
• You can readily infer from the assumption of transitivity that since A and C give
same utility and B and C give same utility, therefore A and B also give same utility
to the consumer.
• Now since a higher indifference curve represents higher utility, then following the
properties of indifference curves, A must be preferred to B.
• This is nothing but a contradiction. Hence, indifference curves can never intersect
(iv) Convex to the Origin
• Indifference curves are convex to the origin, i.e., they are bowed out
towards the origin.
• This is because two goods cannot be perfect substitutes of each
other.
• Therefore, as you have more of one commodity, you would like to
sacrifice less of the other commodity for an additional unit of the fi
rst commodity. The explanation of this property needs an elaboration
on another concept, namely that of marginal rate of substitution.