0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views36 pages

Term 2 Lecture 2 (Profit Maximisation)

Uploaded by

DanielAccoUtani
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views36 pages

Term 2 Lecture 2 (Profit Maximisation)

Uploaded by

DanielAccoUtani
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 36

Profit maximisation

(Ch. 20)

Dr Bibhas Saha
[email protected]
Objectives:

1. Short- and long-run technologies


2. Maximising profit by directly choosing inputs
3. Short- and long-run input demand functions
4. Output supply
Short versus long run

´ We need to think in terms of timeframe that a firm is constrained to


operate in

´ Short run
´ 1) Technology (i.e., production function) cannot be changed [the
firm is stuck with the technology it got, even if it is not state of the
art]
´ 2) Some factors of production cannot be adjusted upwardly,
downwardly, or both ways.

´ Long run
´ Every aspect of technology can be potentially changed.
´ All inputs can be freely adjusted.
Short run

´ Which factors will be difficult to adjust?


´ That depends on the industry, region and country.

´ Example:
´ 1) A university can find a temporary teacher on a short notice, but a film
production company may not quickly replace a screenplay writer.
´ Reason: Apart from the availability, union agreements can be a factor.

´ 2) A café can quickly install a new automatic coffee maker but may not be
able to hire another employee.

´ Assume: one of the two (or many) inputs remains fixed; cannot
be increased or decreased
Other short-run possibilities

´ Of course, it is possible to adjust some inputs downwardly, but not upwardly

´ Example: In the US an employee can be fired in a moment’s notice. But hiring a


worker requires a minimum amount of time.
´ In the UK, the employer needs to give minimum 1 week to maximum 12 weeks’
notice.

´ When upward adjustment is possible, but not downward


´ Example: Unions object to redundancy, but new staff can be hired from temporary
labour markets.
´ New machines can be bought easily, but may not be easy to resale the old
machines.

´ But we will assume that for some input(s) neither (upward or downward) adjustment
is possible.
Short run production: Imperfect
substitute inputs

x2

A D
𝑥̅! B C

y’ y’’

x1

Production can be increased only along points A, B, C, D.


If there are diminishing returns to factor, then production
will increase slowly.
Short run production: Perfect
Complements inputs

x2

𝑥̅!
y’’

y’
y

x1

Production cannot be increased beyond y’’


Short run production: Perfect
substitute inputs

x2

𝑥̅!

y’’
y y’
x1

Production can be increased without any efficiency loss,


because x2 is not essential.
Long run

´ How long is the long run?

´ It is hard to tell.
´ [Keynes once famously said: In the long run we are all
dead.]
´ Netflix took ten years to establish itself.
´ Stand alone movie theatres disappeared after 40/50
years of existence.

´ Mathematically: Every input can be adjusted and the


best technology can be acquired.
Our firm

´ Firms are profit-maximisers


´ Objective: Earn maximum profit [What the firm wants]
´ Action: Maximise profit [How to get that?]

´ Confusing!!
´ For small businesses both are same. But for large corporations
they can be different.

´ Corporations: Managers run the show.


´ Managers may want to maximise sales to give maximum profit
to the shareholders. (That is why we get large discounts in
supermarkets, online streaming services etc.)
Price-taker firms

´ We assume that our firm is a profit maximiser, but it


cannot change the price of the product and the
prices of any inputs.

´ Key assumption: Firms are price takers in all (inputs


and output) markets they operate in. [Firms have no
market power]

´ These markets are perfectly competitive.


Short-run profit maximisation
!/# !/#
´ Suppose 𝑦 = 6𝑥! 𝑥$

!/#
´ Assume x2 is fixed at 8 units. 𝑦 = 12𝑥!

´ The firm maximises profit by choosing x1:


!
"
´ 𝜋 = 𝑝𝑦 − 𝑤! 𝑥! − 𝑤$ 𝑥$ = 𝑝12𝑥! − 𝑤! 𝑥! − 8𝑤$

´ Cost of buying 8 units of x2 is a fixed input cost. Cost of


x1 is the variable input cost.
Short-run profit maximisation
#$
´ FOC: π! 𝑥" = 0 ⟹ #/% = 𝑤"
%"

´ VMP of input 1= input price [VMP: Value of


marginal product]

&$
´ SOC: π!! 𝑥" < 0 ⟹ − & <0
'%"%
´ [Diminishing returns to factor is required]

´ Solution: Input demand for x1 :


#$ '/*
´ 𝑥" =
("
Short-run input demand

´ Cobb-Douglas technology:

´ If 𝑦 = 𝐴𝑥#$ 𝑥%& (with a<1) and x2 is fixed,


then the input demand function for x1 is
of the following form:

' #/(#+$)
´ 𝑥# = 𝐵 (!
where B is a constant
Properties of the short-run input
demand functions

´ For any technology (regardless of Cobb-Douglas or


not), the following must be true:

´ Input demand is increasing in the product price and


decreasing in the (own) input price.

´ If p and w1 increase by the same proportion, input


demand does not change. [Homogeneous of degree
zero in p and w1]

´ Input demand changes if the real input price (w1/p)


changes.
Short-run output supply function

´ Substitute x1 into the production function:

#/.
-' ./% ' #/%
´ 𝑦 = 12 (!
= 24 (!

´ More generally, the Cobb-Douglas supply


function is:
$/(#+$)
& $ '
´𝑦= 𝐴𝑥̅% 𝐵
(!

´ Output is positively related to p (a concave


function of price if a<1/2, and a convex function of price if
a>1/2)
Short-run profit function

( */! +( ,/!
´ Profit: 𝜋' = 𝑝24 )!
− 𝑤* )!
− 8𝑤!
"
("/$ ($
´ 𝜋' = 24 !/$ −8 ! − 8𝑤!
)!
)!$

("/$
´ = 16 !/$ − 8𝑤!
)!
Short-run profit function

´ General Cobb-Douglas:
! !
- . !%& ( !%&
´ 𝜋' = 1 − 𝑎 𝐴𝑎 𝑥̅ ! & − 𝑤! 𝑥̅!
)!!%&

´ [You can check it at home. To derive the above


expression go slowly.]

!
. !%&
´ Also check that in our example, 1 − 𝑎 𝐴𝑎- 𝑥̅! =
*
1− 24 = 16
,
x1 y
p

Concave
Because a=1/3
(<1/2)

p p p
−8𝑤!

Input demand Output supply Profit

Short-run functions
Graphically, when flipping the axes

p p
p

When a<1/2

x1 y −8𝑤! p

Input demand Output supply Profit

Short-run (inverse) functions


Profit function: Properties

´ Important: For all profit functions

´ Profit is a convex and increasing function of


the output price

´ If all input prices and the output price are


doubled, profit is doubled!! [ homogeneous
of degree 1]
Profit function

´ For short-run profit function price must be above a


critical level to have positive profit, because some
inputs are fixed.

´ The shapes of the three curves are also worth


noticing.

´ Input demand and profit functions are convex


functions of the output price. The output supply
function can be concave or convex.
The long-run story

All inputs can be freely chosen

´ Problem:

max p ( K , L) = pf ( K , L) - (vK + wL)


K ,L

´ Solution: 𝐿∗ (𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤); 𝐾 ∗ (𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤)

´ Unconstrained optimisation problem in 2 variables


Input choice
´ FOCs: ¶p/¶𝐿 = 𝑝 [¶𝑓/¶𝐿] – 𝑤 = 0
¶p/¶𝐾 = 𝑝 [¶𝑓/¶𝐾] – 𝑣 = 0

𝑝𝑀𝑃, = 𝑤
𝑝𝑀𝑃- = 𝑣

´VMPi = i-th input price

%&#
´FOCs also imply cost minimisation: 𝑇𝑅𝑆 = − = − 𝑤/𝑣
%&$
Input choice
´ SOCs for a maximum:
p𝐾𝐾 = 𝑓𝐾𝐾 < 0
p𝐿𝐿 = 𝑓𝐿𝐿 < 0
p𝐾𝐾 𝜋,, − p𝐾𝐿2 = 𝑓𝐾𝐾𝑓𝐿𝐿 – 𝑓-, 2 > 0

´capital and labour must exhibit sufficiently diminishing


marginal productivities so that marginal costs rise as
output expands
´Production function must be strictly concave
Input choice
´ Solving FOCs, we get the long-run input demand function

𝐾 ∗ = 𝐾 𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤 and 𝐿∗ = 𝐿(𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤)

´ NOTE: these demand functions must be homogeneous


of degree 0 in 𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤 .

This is obvious from the FOC: 𝑝𝑀𝑃' = 𝑤 and 𝑝𝑀𝑃( = 𝑣


´ If p, v and w are all doubled input demands (and output
supply) do not change., and the output supply will (and
output) also not change;

´ but profit will be doubled. [homogeneous of degree 1]


Example
! !
Production function y = 𝑓 𝐾, 𝐿 = 4𝐾 𝐿 . ' '

Fix 𝑣 = 4, 𝑤 = 16

* *
max 𝜋 𝐾, 𝐿 = 𝑝4𝐾 + 𝐿+ − (16𝐿 + 4𝐾)
0,2

𝜕𝜋 1 *
3
, *
3
,
= 𝑝4𝐾 + 𝐿 + − 16 = 0 → 𝑝𝐾 + 𝐿 + = 16 ⋯ ⋯ ⋯ (1)
𝜕𝐿 4
𝜕𝜋 1 3
, *
3
, *
= 𝑝4𝐾 𝐿 − 4 = 0 → 𝑝𝐾 + 𝐿+ = 4 ⋯ ⋯ ⋯ ⋯ (2)
+ +
𝜕𝐾 4

Dividing (1) by (2)

(!) (
= 4 → 𝐾 = 4𝐿 ⋯ ⋯ ⋯ (3)
($) '
Long
Examplerun profit maximisation-input
continued:

choice

Substitute (3) into (1)

! "
+% ,-!/%
𝑝(4𝐿) 𝐿
% = 16 à = 16
'
,' -!/' ,'
= 𝐿∗ ⟹ 𝐿∗(𝑝) =
!.' !$0
𝑝 $4𝑝$
𝐾 ∗(𝑝) = 4𝐿∗ = =
128 32
,' ,' ,
𝑦∗ =𝑓 𝐾 ∗, 𝐿∗ =4 !/- !/- =
#$ !$0 $

Long-run input demand functions are a convex function of p,


But the output supply function is linear in p in this example
(because it is a Cobb-Douglas case and a+b=1/2).
General Cobb-Douglas case

Suppose 𝑦 = 𝐴𝑥*- 𝑥!. (with a+b<1)

Then the solution to the long-run profit maximisation problem is :


(you can check at home)

* *
𝑝 *3-3. 𝑝 *3-3.
𝑥* = 𝐵* , 𝑥! = 𝐵!
𝑤**3. 𝑤!. 𝑤*- 𝑤!*3-

Input demands are convex in p (as a+b<1)

Diminishing returns to scale is NECESSARY


General Cobb-Douglas case (check at home)

Output supply function

- .
𝑝 *3-3. 𝑝 *3-3.
𝑦= 𝐴𝐵*- 𝐵!.
𝑤**3. 𝑤!. 𝑤*- 𝑤!*3-

*
-4. *3-3.
𝑝
𝑦 = 𝐴𝐵*- 𝐵!.
𝑤*- 𝑤!.

If a+b=1/2 the output supply function will be linear in the output price
General Cobb-Douglas case (check at home)

Profit function

𝜋 = 𝑝𝑦 − 𝑤* 𝑥* − 𝑤! 𝑥!

* * *
𝑝-4. *3-3. 𝑝 *3-3. 𝑝 *3-3.
𝜋 = 𝑝 × 𝐴𝐵*- 𝐵!. − 𝑤* 𝐵* − 𝑤! 𝐵!
𝑤*- 𝑤!. 𝑤**3. 𝑤!. 𝑤*- 𝑤!*3-

*
𝑝 *3-3.
𝜋 = (1 − 𝑎 − 𝑏) 𝐵,
𝑤*- 𝑤!. B3 is some constant

Profit is a convex function of the output price


(because a+b<1 is required)
Properties of the long-run
profit function

´ Profit is homogeneous of degree 1 in 𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! .

´ Hotelling’s Lemma:
56((,)!,)$)
´ = 𝑦(𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! ),
5(
56((,)!,)$) 56((,)!,)$)
´ = −𝑥* (𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! ) and = −𝑥! (𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! )
5)! 5)$

´ Long-run profit cannot be smaller than the short-run


profit [because of fixed input in the short-run]
Hotelling’s Lemma

()(+,-! ,-" )
´ Hotelling’s Lemma: = 𝑦(𝑝, 𝑤/ , 𝑤0 ),
(+

´ Differentiate the profit function with respect to p:


()(+,-! ,-" ) (1 (2! (1 (2"
´ (+
= 𝑦 𝑝, 𝑤/ , 𝑤0 + 𝑝 (2 − 𝑤/ (-!
+ 𝑝 (2 − 𝑤0 (-"
! "

= 𝑦 𝑝, 𝑣, 𝑤

=0 (by FOC of profit


maximisation)

In the same way you can derive

56((,)!,)$) 56((,)!,)$)
= −𝑥* (𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! ) and = −𝑥! (𝑝, 𝑤* , 𝑤! )
5)! 5)$
Long-run versus short-run profit functions

´ Long-run profit cannot be smaller than


the short-run profit [because of fixed
input in the short-run]

´ Slope of the long-run profit function (w.r.t.


p) is greater than the slope of the short-
run profit function. [LeChartelier principle]
Long-run Short-run
Profit
profit function profit
function

𝜕𝜋
𝜕𝑝 Short-run
profit
𝜕𝜋'
function
𝜕𝑝

p
p0

56 56(
> LeChatelier principle
5( 5(
References

1. Varian Ch. 20

(Supplementary)
1. Snyder and Nicholson 11th edition, Chapter 11
2. Nechyba, 3rd edition, Chapter 12

You might also like