0% found this document useful (0 votes)
69 views76 pages

PA00MDKD

The document reviews regulatory, policy and institutional constraints affecting Zimbabwe's livestock sector. It identifies issues with input availability, on-farm production regulations, marketing rules, processing regulations and post-processing standards. Recommendations are provided around reforming policies to align with the draft livestock policy's goals and better support the livestock value chain.

Uploaded by

Cyborg Surgeon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
69 views76 pages

PA00MDKD

The document reviews regulatory, policy and institutional constraints affecting Zimbabwe's livestock sector. It identifies issues with input availability, on-farm production regulations, marketing rules, processing regulations and post-processing standards. Recommendations are provided around reforming policies to align with the draft livestock policy's goals and better support the livestock value chain.

Uploaded by

Cyborg Surgeon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 76

USAID STRATEGIC ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND

ANALYSIS – ZIMBABWE (SERA) PROGRAM

REVIEW OF LIVESTOCK SECTOR


PRODUCTION POLICIES, STRATEGIES AND
INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURES IN
ZIMBABWE
CONTRACT NO. AID-613-C-11-00001
USAID STRATEGIC ECONOMIC RESEARCH
AND ANALYSIS – ZIMBABWE (SERA)
PROGRAM
REVIEW OF LIVESTOCK SECTOR
PRODUCTION POLICIES, STRATEGIES
AND INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURES IN
ZIMBABWE
CONTRACT NO. AID-613-C-11-00001

Program Title: USAID Strategic Economic Research & Analysis – Zimbabwe (SERA)
Sponsoring USAID Office: USAID/Zimbabwe
Contract Number: AID-613-C-11-00001
Contractor: Nathan Associates Inc.
Date of Publication: September 2016
Author: Chrispen Sukume

DISCLAIMER

This document is made possible by the support of the American people through USAID. Its contents are the sole responsibility of
the author or authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of USAID or the United States government.

2
Contents
Executive Summary ............................................................................................................................7
1.0 Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 11
2.0 Review of the Livestock Sector .............................................................................................. 11
2.1 Livestock in the agricultural sector ............................................................................................. 11
2.2 Livestock and the changed farming landscape ........................................................................... 12
2.3 Cattle Production ........................................................................................................................ 13
2.4 Small Livestock Production ......................................................................................................... 19
2.5 Hides, Skins and the Leather Industry ........................................................................................ 24
3.0 Policy and Institutional Environment ..................................................................................... 25
3.1 Policies ........................................................................................................................................ 25
3.2 Legislation ................................................................................................................................... 27
3.3 Institutions .................................................................................................................................. 27
3.4 Financing ..................................................................................................................................... 28
3.5 Livestock Marketing .................................................................................................................... 28
4.0 Regulations Affecting Livestock Value Chains ......................................................................... 31
4.1 Inputs Related Regulations ......................................................................................................... 31
4.2 On-farm Production Related Regulations ......................................................................................... 41
4.3 Livestock Marketing Related Regulations ......................................................................................... 44
4.4 Processing Related Regulations .................................................................................................. 54
4.5 Post Processing Regulations ....................................................................................................... 57
5.0 Conclusions and recommendations ....................................................................................... 65
5.1 Broad Policy Recommendations ....................................................................................................... 65
5.2 Livestock input regulations ............................................................................................................... 65
5.3 Farm related regulations................................................................................................................... 66
5.4 Marketing related regulations .......................................................................................................... 67
5.5 Processing related regulations .......................................................................................................... 68
5.6 Post processing related regulations .................................................................................................. 69
ANNEX: Summary of regulatory constraints, impacts and suggested reforms ..................................... 71
A. Input Related Policy Constraints......................................................................................................... 71
B: Farm level regulatory constraints ....................................................................................................... 73
C: Regulatory constraints affecting marketing of livestock .................................................................... 74

3
D: Regulatory constraints affecting processing of livestock ................................................................... 75
E: Regulatory constraints affecting post processing of livestock products ............................................ 76

4
ACRONYMS

AMA Agricultural Marketing Authority

BM Blood meal

CAPF Comprehensive Agricultural Policy Framework

COG Control of Goods

CSC Cold Storage Company

DDP Dairy Development Programme

DLPD Department of Livestock Production and Development

DLVS Department of Livestock and Veterinary Services

DR&SS Department of Research and Specialist Services

DVS Department of Veterinary Services

E&M Economics and Markets Division

EMA Environment Management Agency

EU European Union

FMD Foot and Mouth Disease

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GMO Genetically modified organism

GMB Grain Marketing Board

GMAZ Grain Millers Association of Zimbabwe

Kg Kilogramme

LITS Livestock Identification and Traceability System

LMAC Livestock and Meat Advisory Council

MoAMID Ministry of Agriculture, Mechanisation and Irrigation Development

MBM Meat and bone meal

MCC Milk collection centre

MDM Mechanically deboned meat

MoLGURD Ministry of Local Government, Urban and Rural Development

Mt Metric tonnes

5
NBA National Biotechnology Authority

PWMA Parks and Wildlife Management Authority

RDC Rural District Council

SA South Africa

SADC Southern African Development Community

SARS South African Revenue Services

SI Statutory Instrument

SMA Stockfeed Manufacturers Association

VAT Value added tax

VPH Veterinary Public Health

WHO World Health Organisation

ZAIP Zimbabwe Agricultural Investment Plan

ZIMRA Zimbabwe Revenue Authority

ZimASSET Zimbabwe Agenda for Sustainable Socio-economic Transformation

ZimSTAT Zimbabwe National Statistics Agency

6
Executive Summary
This study provides an overview of the key regulatory, policy and institutional constraints to )i a e s
livestock sector performance. Value chain stakeholders welcome the recognition of livestock as an
important sub-sector through the creation of a separate Deputy Minister's post within MoAMID and the
development of a value-chain focused livestock policy with wide participation of stakeholders.
However, this new policy framework has yet to be formally adopted by government and accompanying
strategies have not yet been developed to implement the policy. As the review of key regulatory
constraints shows, a multitude of regulations exist that go against the attainment of goals in the draft
livestock policy all across the livestock value chain (see Annex for summary).

I. Input related policy constraints, impacts and suggested reforms


The study identifies a number of regulatory constraints that hinder availability of inputs to the livestock
sector both from local production and from importation.

I.a AMA registration and local input availability


Excessive annual registration fees charged by the Agricultural Marketing Authority (AMA) under
Statutory Instrument 147 of 2012 and SI 140 of 2013, for buyers of grain and oilseeds, need to be
removed or at least significantly reduced. These regulations lead to high overhead costs, discourage
small volume buyers and sellers from participating in the market, and also discourage companies from
engaging in contract farming arrangements.

I.b VAT on agricultural processing by-products used in feeds manufacture


Statutory Instrument 273 of 2003 zero rates agriculture processing by-products used in animal feeds.
However, currently ZIMRA charges 15% VAT on molasses a key input in cattle feeds. The standard rating
of molasses for VAT purposes leads to an increase in the cost of dairy and beef pen fattening feeds. The
study recommends the zero rating of molasses used for stock feed manufacture.

I.c MoAMID maize price policy and availability of maize


MoAMID has been setting GMB pricing grain at greater than import parity while GMB has been charging
less than import parity price to its processing divisions. The high GMB buying prices have led to side-
marketing to GMB by contracted maize farmers leading to discouragement of contract farming while
low prices charged to GMB milling and feeds divisions give them an unfair advantage over private
processors. The study suggests that Government should either let GMB buy at going market prices or
set a GMB floor price based on the landed price of Zambian maize into Zimbabwe to ensure farmers get
a better price than their Zambian counterparts but prices remain at or below import parity to protect
contract farming.

I.d AMA registration fees and availability of imported feed raw materials
Feed manufacturers who import some of their raw materials are required to register under the Farm
Feeds and Remedies Act, and also pay annual fees to AMA. AMA's role in raw material importation is
just to provide a letter of support which duplicates the role played by the Economics and Markets
Division in the MoAMID. The study therefore argues that the AMA licensing be abolished as its effect is
to increase cost of feeds.

7
I.e NBA regulations for GMO certification and availability of imported livestock inputs
The National Biotechnology Authority (NBA) charges an annual registration fee of $500 for importers of
commodities that are subject to GMO-free certification, though there is no statutory instrument to
support the regulation. In addition there is a processing fee payable for each shipment. The study
suggests that registration with NBA should be free of charge, while the processing charge per shipment
continues. In addition, there is need to remove wheat grain and bran from list requiring GMO-free
certificate as there is no commercial GMO wheat under production in the world.

I.f Delays in processing import permits for livestock inputs


Importers of hatching eggs, grain, soya meal, wheat and maize bran, minerals and vitamins, powdered
milk, breeder day-old chicks, breeding animals and semen need to obtain an import permit. To obtain a
permit as required by the Control of Goods Act, importers have to get approval from numerous agencies
including DVS, NBA, AMA, E&M, Plant Protection, and MoAMID leading to excessive delays. There is
need to remove duplication and streamline the import permit process.

II. Farm level regulatory constraints


At the farm level the study identifies regulations applied by the Environment Management Agency as
the most problematic to livestock production. Effluent and Solid Waste Disposal Regulations of 2007
requires farming operations that generate effluent and solid waste to register and pay an annual
registration fee; an annual inspection fee; and a quarterly discharge fee based on estimated amount of
waste discharged. These levies increase the cost of production in livestock enterprises such as poultry,
piggeries, dairy and pen-feeding operations without contributing to environmental benefits since most
wastes and effluent is used as fertiliser on farm. This suggests that the levies are not warranted and
should be abolished.

Similarly the Hazardous Substances, Pesticides and Toxic Substances Regulations of 2007 requires
farmers using agrochemicals or carrying more than 200 litres of fuel to have a license and pay an annual
fee. Rather than charging fees, there is need to draft protocols on good agricultural practices on the
correct handling, storage and handling of these essential chemicals and help farmers adopt these.

III. Regulatory constraints affecting marketing of livestock


Reducing transactions costs in livestock marketing is very important in improving competitiveness and
economic viability. However, the study finds a number of regulations that increase transactions costs.

III.a Rural District Councils marketing levies and livestock marketing


In the majority of cattle dependent districts, Rural District Councils have been charging a levy of 10.5%
on all live cattle sales. This is excessive. The study recommends that councils charge a flat $2 fee per
animal traded at auctions. In addition, the charge of $2 per head should be on cattle sold to abattoirs for
slaughter, but no charge be put on cattle sold to farmers for their herd building investments.

III.b Livestock movement controls and permits


Zimbabwe does not have a comprehensive and functional livestock identification and traceability system
to management cattle movements and proof of ownership. Proof of ownership is required by police,

8
and results in involvement of third parties such as headmen and other witnesses before exchange of
animals. A simplified framework for livestock identification and traceability is currently under discussion
which would simplify the process of clearing cattle before exchange. This needs to be supported and
implemented urgently by Government.

III.c VAT regulations and commercialisation of small ruminants


Currently, sheep and goat meat is subject to VAT of 15%, whereas meat such as beef and chicken is not.
Standard rating of sheep and goat meat, and the transfer of table eggs from zero rated to VAT
exemption, increases the cost of these livestock products relative to other livestock proteins. The study
proposes zero rating of sheep and goat meat, and table eggs, for VAT purposes.

III.d Carcass grading system and fairness in cattle trade


In Zimbabwe carcass grading and classification is still based on the old system developed in the 1970s.
This was based on large framed exotic breeds that dominated commercial cattle marketing at the time.
Since most cattle commercially traded on local markets now are from smallholder farming areas
dominated by small framed indigenous breeds this grading system is biased against them. Stakeholders
and the DLPD have drafted a grading system that removes the bias on small framed adapted breed in
the country. This system needs to be implemented by Government.

IV. Regulatory constraints affecting processing of livestock


In the processing sector the study found EMA regulations, Veterinary Public Health, AMA regulations
and municipal bye-laws to be constraining and sometimes overlapping.

IV.a EMA and livestock processing


As noted earlier, Environment Management Effluent and Solid Waste Disposal Regulations of 2007
requires processing operations that generate effluent and solid waste to register and pay various
registration, inspection and a quarterly fees. In addition to this solid waste and effluent discharge is also
covered under the Animal Health Act, as well as municipal bye-laws when waste is discharged into sewer
systems, leading to double taxation. In addition, waste boiler waster is a benign waste with no effect on
the environment. There is need to rationalise the conflict between Animal Health Act provisions, EMA
and Municipal bye-laws to avoid overlapping taxation.

Processors are also subject to EMA air pollution regulations as prescribed under SI 72 of 2009 which
requires them to pay an annual registration fee; an annual monitoring fee; and a quarterly discharge
fee. This regulation has been applied on processing plants that have forklifts and generators - a
necessity to maintain the cold chain for most livestock processing plants given erratic power supply.
These levies constitute a double taxation and need to be removed.

IV.b Veterinary Public Health and Meat Inspection Regulations and livestock processing
Public Health (Abattoir, Animal and Bird Slaughter and Meat Hygiene) regulations of 1995 require that
all abattoirs are registered by DLVS, pay an annual fee, and also pay carcass inspection fees. However,
some Municipal Councils also charge for meat inspection implying double taxation. There is therefore

9
need to rationalise inspection fees. Specifically, in abattoirs under DLPD inspection regime, municipality
should not be allowed to also charge for the same services.

IV.c AMA registration and meat processing


Abattoir operators are also required to register with AMA under SI 147 of 2012 Regulations and pay
annual fees. While VPH registration fees cover services of inspection of facilities to ensure that products
coming from plants are safe for the market, AMA's justification for registration is that there is need to
collect statistics from producers, traders, processors and retailers. This is despite the fact that the Meat
Graders section of DLPD already collects such information. The study concludes that the double
registrations introduced by AMA are unnecessary and need to be eliminated.

V. Regulatory constraints affecting post processing of livestock products


Finally, abattoirs produce a number of by-products that potentially feed into other upstream industries
(e.g. tanneries, processed meat producers and feeds) or be exported. However, a number of regulations
reduce the effectiveness of the sector to realise these extra values and earn valuable foreign exchange.

V.a Export tax on raw hides exports


In the 2015 Mid-Term Fiscal Policy Review, Government with effect from 1 October 2015 imposed an
export surtax on raw hides and skins at the rate of US$0.75 per kg. This has effectively made it
uneconomic to export raw hides. However, the local tanneries have been unable to absorb all hides on
offer and there has been a build-up of hides stocks at abattoirs with increased spoilage, a loss to the
national economy. It is suggested that Government rescinds the surtax of $0.75/kg on raw hides and
wet-blue tanned hides, respectively.

V.b Duty on MDM imports


Mechanically deboned meat, a raw material in the meat processing industry, currently attracts a duty of
40%, similar to duties applied on most finished food products. It is suggested that the duty charged on
imports of MDM be reduced from 40% to 5% in line with other raw materials.

V.c Processing by-products of livestock processing (DLVS)


Current restrictions on private abattoirs to process abattoir wastes such as meat, bone meal, and blood
meal, is denying the country a key source of raw materials for the feed manufacturing industry. There is
need for the DVS to revise its guidelines for abattoir waste rendering these in line with FAO minimum
standards that allows cheap and safe transformation of abattoir wastes into valuable feed raw materials
by private abattoirs.

10
1.0 Introduction
This study is intended to provide an in-depth analysis of the key regulatory, policy and institutional
fa to s u de l i g )i a e s poor performance in the livestock sector. Based on this assessment, it is
proposed to outline alternative policies and strategies will be outlined which will result in a high growth
trajectory to address poverty, self-sufficiency and the supply requirements of processing and other
industries. The focus will be on the following major issues:

a) The policy, regulatory and institutional environment guiding the production and marketing of
livestock and livestock products, and whether or not this is constraining sustained high growth
in this sector.
b) The policy and regulatory environment constraining supply related factors such as feed stocks
which are of relevance to the efficient functioning of the sub-sector.
c) A clear assessment of the current livestock support strategy and whether or not this will bring
about high growth in this sector.
d) An alternative set of proposals for a high growth livestock production strategy, along with policy
and regulatory reforms which will facilitate the success of this strategy.

2.0 Review of the Livestock Sector

2.1 Livestock in the agricultural sector


Zimbabwe is well suited for the rearing of grazing animals as it is situated in the tropics, with annual
average temperatures of 20 – 35oC and a savannah grassland type of vegetation. The rainfall pattern is
uni-modal and highly seasonal, with major precipitation occurring between November and March.
Therefore, for nine months of the year conditions are dry, affecting the quality of the veld and
nutritional status of grazing animals. In recent years, the frequency of droughts has increased and mid-
seasonal droughts are more pronounced, reflecting the effects of climate change.

Most of the cattle, goats and sheep in Zimbabwe are found in natural regions 3 – 5, which makes up
nearly 65% of the land area and is characterized by low rainfall and high temperatures and averaging
40oC in the hot season. Approximately 70% of communal farming areas are in natural regions 3, 4 and 5
where livestock contribute 86% to household income1. A significant proportion of these areas are found
in the provinces of Matabeleland North and South and parts of Midlands, Manicaland and Masvingo.
Livestock are, therefore, important sources of livelihoods, contributing to nutrition, income and support
for crop production. In general, these drier areas follow an extensive system of production based on
rangelands characterized by sweet veld and browse which are nutritious, but of limited availability due
to low rainfall. Being the biggest user of natural resources, the production of grazing livestock in such
areas is often linked to the degradation of land.

Agriculture currently contributes 11% to the gross domestic product (GDP) and ranks third after mining
and services in the economy of Zimbabwe. Livestock are estimated to contribute 22% to the agricultural
1
Draft Livestock Policy, Ministry of Agriculture, Mechanisation and Irrigation Development, 2015

11
GDP. This is in contrast to the contribution of 45% in highly developed economies, clearly indicating a
production gap2.

The livestock sector contributes to national income, human nutrition and foreign currency earnings with
upstream and downstream linkages to industries such as stockfeeds, leather, soap, confectionery and
beverage manufacture.

The most important species are cattle, sheep, goats, pigs and poultry. Aquaculture, crocodile farming
and apiculture are also gaining in commercial importance. These provide products such as meat, milk,
hides and skins, eggs and other by-p odu ts. The se to eets the ou t s i te al de a d fo eef,
goat meat, chicken meat, table eggs and presently exports fish, hatching eggs, chicks, hides and a limited
range of dairy products.

66% of the Zimbabwean population derives their livelihood from agriculture, with 40% doing so from the
livestock sector3. Food producing animals are an important source of protein, vitamins and other
essential micro-nutrients required in human nutrition. Livestock assets are also a wealth store and a
source of disposable income. In addition, livestock make a significant contribution to crop agriculture by
providing manure, draught power for tillage and transportation. Therefore, the livestock sector is an
important contributor to the national economy as well as to human health and well-being.

2.2 Livestock and the changed farming landscape


The farming systems which sustained livestock production up to 2002 have changed significantly, mainly
as a result of the land reform programme. The distribution of farmers operating on small holdings of
between 30 to 50 hectares increased with the introduction of the A1 farmer category. At the same time,
the proportion of large scale commercial farmers with up to 1500 hectares, especially in the higher
rainfall areas, was drastically reduced4. High levels of land utilisation efficiency involving intensification
are now required, coupled with sustainable natural resource management, which will also address the
need for deliberate pasture cultivation and improving the management of rangelands.

Land parcel demarcation is necessary in line with animal identification and traceability to control animal
and zoonotic disease and pests as well as in meeting certain market assurances in connection with
environmental hazards. Most land parcels are not meeting these requirements due to financial
constraints and the non-existence of veterinary and road fences which had assisted regional disease
control in the past. This situation affects market access which relies on the availability of such
infrastructure.

2
Draft Livestock Policy. Ministry of Agriculture, Mechanisation and Irrigation Development, 2015.
3
Draft Livestock Policy. Ministry of Agriculture, Mechanisation and irrigation Development, 2015.
4
Sam Moyo(2004). "Overall Impacts of the Fast Track Land Reform Programme"
http://archive.kubatana.net/docs/agric/aias_land_reform_040513.pdf

12
2.3 Cattle Production

2.3.1 Beef cattle production


The national cattle herd has been increasing since 2008 and is currently estimated to be 5.4million (see
Figure 2.1 below). In general, the cattle production system is dominated by family-based small- scale
producers, characterized by low input mixed farming, with unviable high stocking rates and limited
grazing. Nearly 90% of the national herd is owned by smallholder farmers. Of the 60% of households
owning cattle, each owns between 2 and 5 cattle. The productivity of smallholder herds is low, with
average calving rates of 45% against a possible 60%, and off-take rates of 6%, against a recommended
20% needed to meet internal and export demand5. The smallholder cattle herd represents a value that
could be unlocked to the advantage of the national economy, household food and nutrition security and
employment, but productivity remains inefficient and uncompetitive.

Figure 2.1: Population of Non Dairy Cattle


5.600.000
5.500.000
5.400.000
5.300.000
5.200.000
5.100.000
5.000.000
4.900.000
4.800.000
4.700.000
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Cattle 5.048.218 5.011.840 5.106.673 5.221.720 5.156.753 5.241.192 5.368.105 5.477.338

Source: Department of Livestock and Veterinary Services, MAMID

Some of the underlying causes of production inefficiencies include poor nutrition and animal health,
infertility, unsuitable genetics, inefficient marketing, inadequate infrastructure, equipment and funding,
low level of entrepreneurial and technical skills and weak institutional support. The limited
effectiveness of animal husbandry and health extension also has negative implications on food safety
and animal health in general.

Given a past in which the country successfully exported cattle products, including beef to the European
Union between 1985 and 2002, there is good potential to resuscitate the cattle industry. However, this
should be preceded by a cost-benefit analysis of this market given the size of direct and indirect
investment that went into securing the necessary bio-security. An in-depth review is required of the

5
Draft Livestock Policy. Ministry of Agriculture, Mechanisation and Irrigation Development, 2015

13
debt of US$23 million at the Cold Storage Company (CSC), decaying infrastructure suffering from years
of under-utilisation, and a human capacity severely limiting its ability to maintain the flagship brand in
the advent of more competition following market liberalisation and the entry of private players into the
industry.

Current challenges, particularly the sustainability of beef supply, have led to suggestions for more
o p ehe si e oo di atio of the eat alue hai s, u de a o o Meat Boa d fo i p o ed
coherence. This element needs to be interrogated for its merits in addressing production and marketing
challenges.

Higher input cattle production on the other hand, attributed to better resourced producers on
commercially viable entities, account for 10% of the national herd. However, stocking densities in this
farming system are sub-optimally low on unimproved grazing and producers lack organised rotational
grazing management6. A significant number of A2 farmers in this sector are relatively new, with limited
skills in livestock farming as a business, and do not belong to common-interest unions for lobby power.
They are also poorly served by public sector extension due to lack of resources. This adds to the
prevailing environment of low productivity and the poor quality of products that are delivered to
markets.

The beef sector should be poised for growth but continues to face major hurdles. The sector is struggling
to bring Foot and Mouth Disease (FMD) under control in the Masvingo, Midlands and Matabeleland
provinces. There is commendable effort though in suppressing the incidence of anthrax (Figure 2.2).
Apart from disease occurrences, the two successive years of low rainfall in 2013 and 2015 have also
reduced dry season grass resources in the main beef producing areas of Matabeleland, Masvingo,
Midlands and northern parts of Mashonaland provinces.

Figure 2.2: Incidence of Livestock Disease


20.000
18.000
16.000
14.000
12.000
10.000
8.000
6.000
4.000
2.000
-
1997 1999 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
FMD 376 29 1.536 5.877 18.561 4.971 1.094 115 6.884 278 110 2.052 2.537 150 6.334 13.446 14.847
Anthrax 288 478 318 278 584 7.639 1.017 1.163 1.482 1.041 88 307 83 120 128 249 -

Source: DLVS

6
Draft Livestock Policy. MAMID, 2015

14
Cattle slaughters have remained stable in recent years but are 60% lower than in 2000 (see Figure 2.3
below). Due to low disposable income, demand for beef has shifted to the lower grades, which has
reduced the price differential between grades. Whereas in 2009, commercial grade beef fetched a 50%
higher price than economy grade, by early 2014, the difference had been reduced to 8.5% (see Figure
2.4 below). There have been reported sightings of imported chicken in retail outlets despite the fact that
no import permits have been issued. This implies that chicken is illicitly imported into the country
without duties being paid which puts on local livestock product prices.

Figure 2.3: Cattle Slaughters

Source: Meat Grader Section, DLPD

Figure 2.4: Beef grade price trends

Source: MC Meats

15
2.3.2 Dairy production
The national dairy herd is at 33 000 animals, producing 57 million litres of milk per annum (figure 2.5).
However, milk production has been on the decline since the early 1990s. At its peak in 1994, the dairy
industry produced 300 million litres of milk on 383 registered dairy farms and the national dairy herd
was at 104 483 head, including 53 073 milking cows. Currently, 250 large and medium scale producers
deliver to the formal market as well as 3 000 small scale producers and 10 000 subsistence producers
who also sell milk informally. Added together with imports (liquid equivalent) of 36 million litres per
year, current consumption is only 7 to 8 litres/head/year. This is considerably lower than previous
consumption levels of 25 litres/head/year7.

The national average daily milk production per cow stands at 7 litres per day, against an optimal 20 to 40
litres, depending on breed (genetics) and management systems. Over the past 13 years, the dairy value
chain has been characterised by a decline in milk production, cow numbers and producers. The “ hools
Milk P og a e lau hed the )i a e Dai I dust T ust i e ui es that this p odu tio
gap be closed. This has been associated with rising levels of dairy imports and a negative balance of
trade. Input costs have increased while milk prices have remained constant and producers are
experiencing a cost-price squeeze. These conditions have resulted in the growth of the informal sector
which falls outside the formal regulatory regimes and, therefore, cannot provide safeguards for product
quality and safety.

Figure 2.5: Milk Production


70.000.000

60.000.000

50.000.000

40.000.000
Litres

30.000.000

20.000.000

10.000.000

0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Milk Production(lts) 47.188.093 50.603.345 55.929.694 54.627.134 55.479.075 57.544.906

Source: Dairy Services, DLPD.

Low productivity per cow is multifactorial, largely due to poor nutrition and inferior genetics.
Production efficiency can be raised through improved nutrition, especially by growing high quality
forages on-farm, reducing the cost of grain and pulse-based feed supplements and improving the

7
Dairy Services, DLPD; and Zimbabwe Association of Dairy Farmers

16
genetic potential through the use of imported superior genetics. For optimal performance, it is also
necessary to establish the correct genetic makeup of dairy animals for producers in a range of ecological
and farming systems. While imported breeding animals may offer respite to individual farmers, this is
costly and not sustainable in the long term. Solutions relying on internal relationships based on
technology adaptation and development by way of research and extension would be more sustainable.
Primary importation of foundation stock can be scaled up at multiplication centres for onward
purchasing by producers, backed up and enhanced by capacity building as well as investment into
technology transfer for the production of sexed semen and embryos.

There are 3 000 registered smallholder producers, jointly owning 9 000 cows who are members of 28
milk collection centres, set up under the Dairy Development Programme (DDP) within the Agricultural
Rural Development Authority. They either deliver milk to the formal market or sell locally through
informal channels. Management related milk yield, quality and safety issues in this sector and among
other emerging producers, affect their potential to meet milk standards required for keeping quality and
value addition by processors.

Smallholder producers generally rely on natural servicing by bulls, usually associated with low
conception rates, due to challenges with bull supply and management issues, compromising milk
production efficiency. Breeding technologies such as artificial insemination still have to take root and
are affected by organisational, logistical and cow management issues. Given the small numbers of cows
per owner, heifer replacement costs, the high cost of overheads and the effect of the cow s dry period
on incomes, the viability of small dairy herds is questionable. Group-managed ventures to reduce costs
needs to be evaluated in the context of viability of the individual dairy cow owner.

The commercial dairy industry, a capital intensive business, has been in decline since the 1990s. Despite
government efforts to maintain dairy producers under the current land tenure system, there is a sense
of insecurity amongst the remaining dairy farmers. Finalisation of security of tenure will encourage
greater investment for quicker turnaround in the sector.

Milk collection and delivery distances are relatively long, averaging 15 kilometres nationwide. Transport
problems are compounded by lack of storage facilities which are not conducive to storing highly
perishable dairy products. Use of solar powered milk storage facilities and on-farm training on value-
addition of milk will reduce the need for transport. Group marketing will not only ease transport
problems, but will also result in higher premium prices and profits for smallholder milk producers.

Government needs to improve its support to DDP and Dairy Services to promote smallholder dairying.
Although they have managed to leverage some direct support for their schemes from some
development partners, DDP faces operational challenges to provide effective extension services to
farmers. Under DDP, farmers were mobilised into associations, enacted a Constitution and chose
management committees to run ilk olle tio e t es MCC s . These are commercially run operations
which require that farmers be equipped with practical skills to manage the MCC profitably. However,

17
there is need for MCCs to become more efficient, with better trained local managers from within their
membership.

At the farmer level, practical management skills for dairy farming in terms of feeding, disease control
and handling of milk are limited. Tick-borne and bacterial diseases are the most prevalent diseases in
smallholder dairy sector as a result of infrequent dipping, lack of de-worming and poor access to animal
drugs and vaccines.

18
2.4 Small Livestock Production

2.4.1 Small ruminants


Smallholder farmers own nearly 4 million goats and 450 000 sheep (Figures 2.6 and 2.7). A mix of breeds
exist, including indigenous types such as the Matebele goat and Sabi sheep which are better adapted to
local conditions. Despite this adaptation to local conditions, kid losses can be as high as 30%, reducing
potential off-take8. Stronger efforts to promote goat meat as a healthier, low cholesterol alternative to
beef and goat milk as a known substitute for human milk for children who suffer from milk allergy will
be appropriate. Skins of small-ruminants have been successfully commercialised in some parts of the
world, but this value has not been realised locally. Present demand for small ruminants indicates that
their population can easily be increased to at least 10 million9.

Figure 2.6: Goat Population


4.500.000
4.000.000
3.500.000
3.000.000
2.500.000
2.000.000
1.500.000
1.000.000
500.000
-
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Goats 3.320.000 3.170.000 4.200.000 3.100.000 3.500.000 3.800.000 3.941.274 4.049.528

Source: DLVS, MAMID

8
Homann S, van Rooyen A, Moyo T and Nengomasha Z. 2007. Goat production and marketing: Baseline
information for semi-arid Zimbabwe. PO Box 776, Bulawayo, Zimbabwe: International Crops Research Institute for
the Semi-Arid Tropics. 84 pp.
9
Draft Livestock Policy. MAMID, 2015

19
Figure 2.7: Sheep Population
600.000

500.000

400.000

300.000

200.000

100.000

-
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Sheep 390.000 400.000 480.000 500.000 512.500 525.000 521.607 456.627

Source: DLVS, MAMID.

Small ruminants play an important role in providing animal protein at household level and they are an
easy source of disposable income. An increasing number of women and youths are engaged in small-
stock production for their livelihoods. Small ruminants dominate the informal market and as a result,
produce s suffe f o u e s a ket effe t hile o su e s e ai u p ote ted due to poo
regulatory support necessary for quality and safety assurances. There is no reliable information to fully
account for the value of small livestock in rural economies.

In order for smallholder producers to be integrated into the national economy, significant investments
need to be made into infrastructural development to promote contact with service providers and for
marketing purposes. Innovative marketing will also benefit producers which will result in the
commercialisation of this sector.

2.4.2 Pig production


Since 2008, the pig population has increased from 180 000 to 345 000 (see Figure 2.8 below), most of
which are in the smallholder farming sector and consists of a sow herd of approximately 40 000 under
free range and semi-intensive production. Commercial pig production, with a sow herd of 12 000, is
concentrated in areas with high grain production as they need maize and soya for their diets, placing
them in direct competition with human food needs. Feed inputs make up more than 60% of the costs of
production in intensive pig production systems, rendering their products non-competitive, especially for
export10. This has led to the high retail cost of pork, resulting in low effective demand at 3.6

10
Pig Industry Board, Zimbabwe

20
kilogrammes (kg) per capita and there is, therefore, potential for resuscitating export markets11.
Commercial pig production, however, runs in compartments and follows a producer/industry code of
p a ti e ethi s, the Zimbabwe Quality Assured Pork Programme to fu the assu e iose u it . In spite
of the environmental risk to highly contagious trade sensitive diseases such as FMD, African and
Classical Swine Fever, commercial pig production is already highly geared for export. Based on inquiries
by importers, there are signs that exports of pork to Namibia and Angola can be resuscitated and that
new regional markets can be developed.

Figure 2.8: Pig Population


400.000

350.000

300.000

250.000

200.000

150.000

100.000

50.000

-
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Pigs 180.000 200.000 290.000 255.000 275.000 300.000 342.227 345.449

Source: Pig Industry Board

The Pig Industry Board believes that extension services for pig producers are grossly inadequate,
especially for the small rural producer where concerns about productivity and public health are high.
Given the importance of feed inputs, greater attention is needed to provide genetic makeup with high
feed conversion ratios and shorter intervals to market weight.

2.4.3 Poultry production


Most rural, urban and peri-urban households keep backyard or free range chickens. More than 90% of
poultry kept in rural households are indigenous breeds, which are believed to be adapted to harsh
conditions12.

11
Mutambara, J. A preliminary review of regulatory constraints affecting pig industry in Zimbabwe. Livestock
Research for Rural Development 25 (3) 2013. http://www.lrrd.org/lrrd25/3/muta25043.htm

12
Draft Livestock Policy. MAMID 2015

21
The commercial poultry (broilers and layers) industry is one of the fastest growing livestock sub-sectors.
Between January 2009 and September 2014, monthly broiler meat production grew from 1 000 metric
tonnes (mt) to 14 000 mt (see Figure 2.9 below). However, since then growth has stalled and averaged
12 000mt per month in the first nine months of 2015. The smallholder sector has been the biggest
contributor to broiler growth and currently accounts for about 65% of national broiler meat output.

Figure 2.9: Monthly Broiler Meat Production

14.000

12.000

10.000

8.000

6.000

4.000

2.000

-
Jän.11
Jän.09
Mai.09

Jän.10
Mai.10

Mai.11

Jän.12
Mai.12

Jän.13
Mai.13

Jän.14
Mai.14

Jän.15
Mai.15
Sep.09

Sep.10

Sep.11

Sep.12

Sep.13

Sep.14

Sep.15
Total Smallholder Large scale

Source: Zimbabwe Poultry Association

Table egg production has also experienced phenomenal growth since 2009. Between January 2009 and
December 2011, monthly table egg production grew from 277 000 dozen to nearly 4,5 million dozen
(see Figure 2.10 below). Since then, production has remained relatively stable around 4.5 million dozen
per month. Between January 2009 and September 2013, the smallholder sector accounted for 50% of
production. However, since then, there has been steady growth in smallholder egg production and a
decline in the contribution from the large scale sector. By late 2015, the smallholder sector accounted
for 67% of eggs sold in the country.

Growth in the poultry sector has been accompanied by growth in the hatchery sector. Four new
hatcheries were established during the period 2009 to 2014. There has also been significant growth in
the feed sector with new feed mills being established and the volume of feed produced increasing in
tandem. Poultry production accounts for 72% by volume and 77% of the value of feed produced13.

13
Stockfeeds Manufacturers Association of Zimbabwe

22
Figure 2.10: Monthly Table Egg Production ('000 dozen)
5.000

4.000

3.000

2.000

1.000

Mai.13
Jän.09
Mai.09
Sep.09
Jän.10
Mai.10

Jän.11
Mai.11

Jän.12
Mai.12

Jän.13

Jän.14
Mai.14

Jän.15
Mai.15
Sep.10

Sep.11

Sep.12

Sep.13

Sep.14

Sep.15
Total Smallholder Large scale

Source: Zimbabwe Poultry Association (ZPA)

While providing a source of income for the unemployed, poultry rearing in urban or high settlement
areas poses a challenge to the spread of highly contagious animal or zoonotic diseases and pests. This
also threatens the viability of large commercial poultry enterprises, which are vertically integrated and
compartmentalised for biosecurity. Free-range poultry production systems result in highly favoured
organoleptic qualities, presenting opportunities to access lucrative urban niche markets. Other under-
developed niche poultry products include guinea fowl, quail, duck and turkey.

The biggest challenge facing poultry production is the high cost of feed, which can be up to 78% of the
cost of production14. This is largely caused by the high cost of the main ingredients, maize and soya
meal. To enable the poultry industry to be more competitive, there is need to encourage increased local
production of maize and soya beans. Similarly, an improvement in management and the use of superior
poultry genetics will improve efficiency.

2.4.4 Aquaculture
Fish Farming
Zimbabwe has the largest number of medium sized and small inland water bodies in the Southern
African Development Community (SADC) region, providing good potential for fish production to meet
the need for high quality but low cost protein. The Department of Livestock Production and
Development (DLPD) and Parks and Wildlife Management Authority (PWMA) are sources of fry supplies
for stocking water bodies.

14
Budgets by the Zimbabwe Poultry Association

23
There is a dearth of data on inland fisheries production, except for Lake Harvest on Lake Kariba, the
largest cage fishery enterprise in Africa, which produces bream for the local and export markets.
Exports to regional markets are proving highly viable with Zambia alone importing 60% of the fish
produced, while the United Kingdom imports 7%15. The company annually exports up to 8 000mt of
frozen fillets and whole fish and potential exists to treble this over a 3-year period. The o pa s pla
to contract maize and soya production to local farmers is bound to have an effect on stimulating
demand. Lake Harvest currently employs 600 people.

In line with the current need to promote fish as a healthy alternative to beef16, unpolluted water
resources at irrigation schemes and ponds at village level are being targeted for development. Fish
production can also be integrated with the production of other livestock in a permaculture system
involving pigs, poultry and ruminants, while addressing the need for diversification.

Crocodile farming
There are 3 main producers of crocodile in the country (Padenga on Lake Kariba, Nuanetsi and Binga),
targeting markets in the Far East, primarily for the high value skin, with tail meat being favoured in some
European (Belgium) and Hong Kong markets. The meat sells at US$5.00/kg in Europe. Plans to export
tail meat to North America are advanced. Padenga Holdings alone employs at least 800 people.

2.4.5 Apiculture
Apiculture is important in supporting the horticultural industry. By 2010, 21 000 farmers were involved
in apiculture throughout the country. Rural farmers have an average of 1 – 4 beehives for subsistence
and a few commercial producers have up to 300 beehives. Production by most smallholders is largely for
home consumption.

Production is estimated at 150mt annually and an unmet demand of 60% exists, especially by
pharmaceutical firms and supermarkets17. As a result, this gap is met by imports from Zambia, Malawi
and South Africa (SA). However, export opportunities exist to regional markets whose demands are also
not met. Efforts must now be made to provide the biosecurity assurances required in the support of
trade. There is need for capacity building in bee health and diseases, and to develop producer capacity
through extension. Given the low capital requirements, apiculture has potential as a viable livelihood
source for rural households.

Small stock production has the potential to contribute to increased economic growth and livelihood
resilience and should be supported by conducive policy and institutional frameworks.

2.5 Hides, Skins and the Leather Industry


The industry is made up of hides from cattle and skins from small ruminants and crocodiles. With the
demise of the ostrich industry in response to low world prices, presently only bovine hides and crocodile
skins are being produced, with semi-processed crocodile skin being exported to the Far East. Up to the

15
ZIMSTATS EXPORT STATISTICS
16
Draft Livestock Policy. MAMID 2015.
17
Draft Livestock Policy. MAMID 2015.

24
end of 2013 and due to under-capacity in the industry, cattle hides were exported in their raw form18.

Approximately 1 168 entities operate in the industry, providing 5 610 jobs, all of which are under severe
pressure from cheaper non-leather products, mostly from China and SA.

In 2013, the Ministry of Industry and Commerce launched the Zimbabwe Leather Sector Strategy (2012 –
2017). This was in line with the Industrial Development Policy (2012-16) with an objective to transform
the leather value chain from production and export of raw leather and semi-processed products, to the
export of value-added footwear, garments and other products. This is expected to generate up to
US$116 million in revenue by 2017. In order to encourage value addition, a levy of US$0.75/kg is
applicable to all exports of raw hide.

The leather industry is a natural component of the beef industry. Good quality leather is a function of
good animal nutrition, animal health and welfare. The product is easier to collect and handle when it
arises from registered abattoirs, which meet the pre-processing handling conditions. Registered
abattoirs are also likely to receive and slaughter cattle from entities which have observed Good
Agricultural Practices, prerequisites for product quality and safety. Therefore, high value leather and
leather products are a result of farmer skills and knowledge received from extension and veterinary
services support. These services need to be strengthened to better support the leather strategy.

3.0 Policy and Institutional Environment

3.1 Policies
The policy environment of the livestock sector is provided for by the draft Comprehensive Agricultural
Policy Framework of 2013 (CAPF), which outlines four livestock policy objectives, each supported by
several policy statements as follows:
(i) Improved production and productivity of all classes of livestock:
 Promote preservation, improvement and expansion of existing pedigree herds,
especially indigenous breeds;
 Promote research on appropriate and applicable technologies in livestock production;
 Promote adoption of good animal husbandry practices;
 Promote establishment of strategic feed reserves;
 Promote improved pasture and rangeland management; and
 Introduce a livestock fund.

(ii) Effective and economic control of livestock diseases:


 Strengthen veterinary services;
 Facilitate investments in disease surveillance and prevention measures; and
 Promote establishment of veterinary infrastructure.

18
Zimbabwe Association of Abattoirs

25
(iii) Strengthened institutional arrangements to co-ordinate the livestock industry:
 Promote the establishment and maintenance of production and marketing
infrastructure.

(iv) Improved integration of crop-livestock farming systems


 Promote the introduction of resilient and adapted animal breeds to improve provision
of draught power;
 Promote appropriate manure management practices in all farming sectors; and
 Promote cost effective use of livestock and crop residues as alternative energy sources.

Zimbabwe has accepted the CAPF and its associated Zimbabwe Agricultural Investment Plan (ZAIP) as
the framework to guide all future agricultural development investments. In line with CAPF, the overall
programme objective of ZAIP is to facilitate sustainable increase in production, productivity and
competitiveness of Zimbabwean agriculture.

However, most of these policy frameworks have not sufficiently catered for the livestock sector to
benefit from optimal levels of investment and development. A stand-alone livestock policy would be
ideal to guide investments into the sector. This should be supported by specific sub-sector strategies
covering major commodities, especially for meat, dairying and breeding.

In a regional context, the need for revised national livestock sector policies has been advised following
the SADC regional livestock sector policy. Similarly, the African Union, noting the opportunities
presented by Africa in livestock production, is supporting the review and development of policies for the
livestock sector.

Following the promulgation of the National Food and Nutrition Security Policy in 2013, the livestock
sector is poised for the important role of making animal protein and other nutrients available that are
required to balance the human diet. This position is further enshrined in the Zimbabwe Agenda for
Sustainable Socio-economic Transformation (ZimASSET) blue print, which also emphasises the
component of food and nutrition, while indicating a need to address livelihoods through poverty
reduction and economic empowerment.

Growth of some small livestock species is also being hampered by a lack of policy alignment between
agriculture and environment ministries. This applies to fish farming and quail farming where the two
ministries seem to be at odds regarding which should regulate the sub-sector. Most fish farming
involves pond culture where farmers buy fingerlings and feed them to market weight, similar to broiler
production where farmers buy day-old chicks and feed them to market weight. The Ministry of
Environment, Water and Climate has regulations that guide catch fisheries which are different to pond
fish farming. Similarly, quail farming involves breeding of exotic quail birds for meat and eggs. The quail
species utilised by farmers are not related to wild quail found in Zimbabwe and there is no risk of cross
breeding between the species.

26
3.2 Legislation
Legislation exists to regulate food, animal health, feeds, drugs and remedies as well as public health, in
the interest of human and animal health, consumer interests and protection of the environment.
National commitments to international conventions involving trade (the World Trade Organisation),
environment (the Convention on Biological Diversity and its Biosafety Protocol) and international health
(the Wo ld Health O ga isatio s [WHO] International Health Regulations), also provide guidance on
best practices relating to production, processing, storage and marketing of livestock products. Livestock
production, therefore, is expected to respond to international standards such as World Animal Health
and international food code standards (Food and Agriculture Organisation / WHO Codex Alimentarius
guidelines).

Greater cooperation between PWMA and the Department of Livestock and Veterinary Services (DLVS) is
needed in aquatic animal disease surveillance as well as control, especially through imports and internal
transfer of live fish and other aquatic animal species, to curtail the spread of diseases and pests that
decimate fish populations, including the introduction of predator species in water bodies.

Government policy is against the use of genetically modified (GM) feedstuffs in the production of
livestock. In the face of maize and soya production deficits for a number of reasons, this is one factor
with direct implications on the cost of production in intensive poultry, pig, dairy and aquaculture
enterprises. It is also impossible to avoid importing animal products such as milk, hatching eggs and
meats from animals which have not been exposed to GM feeds, as most countries with export surpluses
are growing and using GM based grains in livestock.

3.3 Institutions
The livestock sector is served by both public and private sector institutions. The major public service
institution is DLVS, which as the coordinating public institution, provides technical, extension and
advisory services and regulatory oversight in animal production and health. The Department of Research
and Specialist Services (DR&SS) provides research services into livestock production. Agricultural and
Extension Services provides technical skills in extension and complements livestock extension as mixed
crop/livestock production is undertaken in many areas. The Pig Industry Board provides development
support to pig producers as well as improved breeding stock. Other government departments include
Agricultural Marketing Authority (AMA), Environmental Management Agency (EMA), Agricultural
Research Council, Agricultural and Rural Development Authority, national universities and agricultural
colleges. Extension support may also be obtained by farmers from private sector service providers.

CSC, which formed an important part of the processing sector of the export beef value chain and played
a strong part in developing the livestock industry, should be analysed in this context. Its key remaining
viable assets are its ranches which have potential to bolster production of superior breeding stock for
use by farmers wanting to improve their herds. This would be complemented by private breeders,
government research stations, multiplication centres and agricultural colleges, using imported and/or
local improved genetics. In the past, CSC also played a role in restocking following droughts as well as
supplying cattle to producers through their cattle finance scheme. Against a background of rangeland

27
and feed constraints, the CSC ranches could also serve as an important resource for the generation of
ualit pastu e o fodde ops o as a ehouse holdi g g ou ds fo se u itised attle. The a ilit to
raise the numbers of cattle held could be exploited by re-opening selected abattoirs.

Producers are represented through a variety of producer organisations, unions and commodity groups.
Unions are the voice of farmers and producers and provide fora for articulating and presenting
e e s i te ests. O e the ea s, the effe ti e ess of lobbying by farmers unions has declined and a
significant proportion of farmers are not unionised for ease of interaction. The Livestock and Meat
Advisory Council (LMAC) is an important forum for stakeholders in the livestock industry and has
representatives from all major stakeholders, including government departments, processors, producers
and the retail trade.

3.4 Financing
Financing for the livestock sector, in common with the rest of the agricultural sector, is inadequate. The
agricultural sector is believed to utilise 18% of the total credit portfolio in Zimbabwe. Financial
institutions blame the lack of liquidity and collateral as reasons for not extending finance support.
However, 85% of the deposits in the banking sector are short term, unsuitable as a basis for medium-
and long-term lending. Micro-finance institutions demand secure repayment conditions and offer loans
with high rates of interest, inappropriate for medium- and long-term agricultural financing.

Agribank is the largest lender to the agricultural sector, but most of its lending is directed towards short-
term loans for crop production. This position is also reflected in lending policies of other banks. As the
land bank, Agribank should be the major public financing institution to the agricultural sector but under
the current difficult economic environment, it has not been able to effectively carry out its mandate
because of low capitalisation. Livestock farming is capital intensive and for cattle with a long production
cycle, medium- to long-term loan facilities need to be available to unlock the full potential of the sector.
Financial investment can be further protected through insurance services to manage the associated risk.

The warehouse receipt concept now being proposed by the MAMID for crop commodities, needs to be
extended to the livestock sector to allow producers to leverage the value of livestock for other
investments. Information communications technology models linked to financial institutions can be
investigated for their utility, including simplifying livestock identification and traceability services
required for associated risk management from a financial, as well as biological, point of view.

3.5 Livestock Marketing


The marketing of livestock and livestock products is conducted both formally and informally. A
structured marketing system exists for live animals through public auctions and this follows an annual
livestock sales calendar. However, private sales of live animals also take place. Proliferation of privately
owned abattoirs has created fierce competition on the cattle market, with the result that with poor
liquidity some key stakeholders such as the CSC have been elbowed out.

28
Concerns have been raised about the high cost of compliance in the marketing of livestock, which is
fueling the informal market to the disadvantage of both the producer and consumer. Local authorities
collect up to 12% of the value of sales in fees/levies but do not demonstrate how this addresses the
p odu e s eeds. The attle a keti g s ste e ui es u ge t e ie hi h should e a i e
responsibilities of the private sector and how to simplify the fee system, possibly through a Livestock
Development Fund.

Contract farming exists for poultry, dairying and pigs in the form of out-grower schemes and the new
contract farming provisions under development by the MoAMID will need to encompass the legal and
ethical needs and responsibilities of stakeholders in the livestock sector.

Veterinary Public Health (VPH) regulations promote consumer protection by encouraging formal
marketing of livestock products such as fresh meat and milk in areas of high human population
settlement such as urban and industrial areas. Government livestock and meat grading as well as dairy
services provide regulatory oversight to assure product quality and facilitate the promotion of ethics in
livestock and livestock product marketing. These technical and sanitary controls need to be applied to
an integrated value chain from the farm to the consumer in order to be effective in supporting
compliant producers and processors to remain viable. An integrated value chain approach also results in
high quality products such as milk, hides and skins that are presently suffering from poor animal
nutrition, health and welfare practices. However, low staff capacities, poor farmer awareness and other
logistical issues affect the delivery of these regulatory and extension services.

Pricing for livestock and livestock products is determined by supply and demand and there is no price
control. Opportunities exist which could be exploited for export trade both within the region and
internationally. Per capita consumption of beef is estimated to have declined from 13.5kg to 4.3kg over
a 20 year-period19. Historically, beef and farmed ostrich and crocodile meat has been exported to the
European Union, farmed ostrich skins to the Far East, dairy products to Malawi and Botswana and
chicken and pork to Namibia. Although individual farmers are likely to have found the beef exports to
Europe lucrative, there has never been a benefit-cost analysis of this trade to determine the true
benefits to the country, given the high cost of compliance, infrastructure and institutional support which
was applied by the EU in ensuring sanitary safety through veterinary services. SADC and the Common
Market for Eastern and Southern Africa regional trading blocs have domesticated trade protocols to
facilitate inter- and intra-regional trade, which still has to be fully exploited.

In general, the domestic demand for animal products is subdued due to low disposable income against
relatively high retail prices, especially on the formal market. For example, the national demand for beef
is estimated at only 4.3kg per capita (for formal and informal markets). The picture for other animal
products is similar, as evidenced by seasonal stockpiles of poultry and pork. The question that may be
posed is how the population is able to meet its protein requirements with such a low consumption of
animal products. It has been suggested that the intake of alternative sources of protein, including

19
ZIMSTAT, 2012. Poverty, Income, Consumption and Expenditure Survey(PICES).

29
insects such as mopane worms and kapenta fish may be complementing conventional protein sources.
The contribution and value of these alternative protein sources need to be evaluated.

It is the formal sector that has been structured enough to meet the demands of the export market
through compliance with standards applying to product quality and safety for competitiveness. Vertical
integration with well-developed market linkages is characteristic of large scale commercial poultry,
farmed fish and pork. It remains to be assessed as to what extent the smallholder producer will address
the costs of compliance with quality and safety standards required on the integrated value chain from
fa to fo k , fo a ket a ess, as this p ese ts a so io-economic dimension that needs deliberate
programming. Promotion of exports results in increased production volumes which benefits
downstream industries in animal feeds, hides and skins and soap manufacturing.

Therefore, the livestock industry presents a huge potential and opportunity for trade and investment,
but needs to first of all address efficiency and competitiveness issues. Apart from reducing direct losses
due to pests and diseases, veterinary services exist to manage the sanitary risk which can easily result in
market failure. It is, therefore, important to heed the call to strengthen that service.

30
4.0 Regulations Affecting Livestock Value Chains
This section will look at the key institutions, policies and regulations affecting competitiveness of the
acquisition of inputs, on-farm production, marketing, processing and post processing stages of livestock
and livestock products. It aims to identify key regulatory constraints affecting the different stages of
livestock value chains and offers suggested reforms to improve effectiveness of regulations and
institutions.

4.1 Inputs Related Regulations


Many inputs are necessary in livestock production and feed and genetic resources constitute the most
critical input. Regulations affecting the availability of feed and genetic resources either from local
production or from imports have a significant bearing on cost effectiveness of local livestock production.
Below, some of the regulatory constraints that have been identified by livestock stakeholders to be
counter to achieving competitiveness are briefly described.

4.1.1 Regulations Affecting Locally Produced Raw Material Resources


The bulk of feed raw materials can potentially be produced domestically. Raw materials used by the
feed industry which are partially produced locally include maize, sorghum, sunflower, soya beans and
by-products such as of maize, wheat, cotton seed, soya bean, sunflower and sugarcane processing. The
by-products include maize and wheat bran, oilseed (i.e. cotton, soya bean and sunflower) cake or meal
and molasses.

Regulatory and policy constraints affecting access and cost of locally produced raw materials can be
classified as follows:

 Excessive annual registration fees charged by AMA under Statutory Instrument (SI) 147 of 2012
for buyers of grain and oilseeds, the main suppliers of these raw materials to feed mills.
 Inconsistent application of zero rating for VAT on by-products of milling and crushing used in
feed manufacture.
 Grain Marketing Board (GMB) pricing policy.
 Regulation of imported processed grains.

4.1.1.1 AMA Registration Fees


Before 2012, companies that contracted or bought and sold grains, oilseeds and by-products, only
needed to be registered under the Companies Act. This changed with the gazetting of SI 147 of 2012,
Agricultural Marketing Authority (Registration of Companies and Submission of Returns) Regulations,
2012. This legislation requires all companies that intend to be in the business of buying and contracting
agricultural products to annually register and pay a registration fee of $500 with AMA and submit
periodic returns on products bought and processed and keep records of the same. The SI states that any
company that fails to comply with these requirements would be liable to a fine not exceeding level four
or imprisonment for a period of three months or both. This regulation covers all agricultural
commodities under AMA, apart from those covered by specific regulations such as tobacco
(administered under the Tobacco Marketing Board Act).

31
The scope of the above legislation was further expanded with gazetting of SI 140 of 2013, Agricultural
Marketing Authority (Grain, oilseed and products) By-Laws, 2013 whose stated objectives were to:

a) regulate the participation in the production, buying or processing of any grain (i.e. maize, wheat,
barley, sorghum, rice, pearl millet [mhunga] finger millet [rapoko], ground nuts [nyimo], sugar
beans, cowpeas, Michigan pea beans and sesame), oilseeds (i.e. soya beans, sunflower,
groundnuts) and their processing by-products by producers, buyers or processors; and
b) promote orderly marketing and fair trade practices in the grain and oilseeds industry;
c) promote production of grain and oilseeds, including contract farming; and
d) provide a mechanism for enforcement of contractual obligations to protect the investment of
farmers, contractors and suppliers.

The SI increased annual registration fees as follows:


 Application for registration as a grain industry stakeholder association requires completion of
application form AMAG1 and an annual fee of $500;
 Application for registration as a contractor or processor requires completion of application form
AMAG2 and an annual fee of $1 000 or $2 000 if lodged late;
 Application for registration as a buyer, trader or broker requires completion of application form
AMAG3 and an annual fee of $1 000 or $2 000 if lodged late;
 Though not currently being enforced, application for registration as a grower requires
completion of application form AMAG4 and an annual fee of $1 or $2 if lodged late; and
 Application for registration as a grain service hammer mill requires completion of application
form AMAG5 and an annual fee of $2 or $5 if lodged late.

The regulations and fees noted above have a number of negative impacts on the cost of doing business
in grain and oilseed marketing including:
 Increase in overhead costs for contractors and grain and oilseed buyers and sellers which are
passed on to users of these products, including feed manufacturers. One major stakeholder in
grain procurement incurs $3 500 in annual AMA registration fees as $1 000 is paid to operate as
a trader, $1 000 to operate as a contractor and $500 for each of three warehouses.
 The high registration fees discourage buyers and sellers of small volumes of grain and oilseed to
participate in the marketing system. This has the effect of reducing market access for surplus
producing farmers who are in areas that produce little surplus grain. In addition, this is counter
to Zimbabwe's ZimASSET agenda of encouraging inclusive economic growth.
 The high cost of registration fees also discourage companies from engaging in contract farming
arrangements, contrary to the country's objective of boosting local production of key raw
materials for the feeds industry in order to reduce import dependency.

4.1.1.2 VAT on By-products Used in Feeds


Regulations governing the application of VAT on by-products used in feed manufacture are covered
under SI 273 of 2003, Value-Added Tax (General) Regulations, 2003. The Value Added Tax Regulations
do not list molasses, maize and wheat bran by name as zero rated items. The Regulations indicate in

32
Part 1, Second Schedule, zero rating of the supply of goods consumed or used for agricultural purposes.
One of the goods listed is animal feed as follows:

"Animal feed:
a) goods consisting of: -
i. any substance obtained by a process of crushing, gristing or grinding or by addition to
any substance which possesses or is alleged to possess nutritive properties; or
ii. any condimental food, vitamin or mineral substance or other substance which
possesses or is alleged to possess nutritive properties; or
iii. any bone product, intended or sold for the feeding of livestock, poultry, fish or wild
animals (including wild birds);
b) stock lick or substance which is of a kind which can be and is in fact used as a stock lick, whether
or not such stock lick or substance possesses medicinal properties."

Wheat and maize bran are produced through a process of "gristing or grinding of wheat or maize grain
and are used in making livestock feeds, contributing to energy and protein nutrients. Similarly, soya
bean, sunflower and cotton seed cakes are products of "crushing" of the seeds of these crops and form
an integral part of protein supply in feeds. The Zimbabwe Revenue Authority (ZIMRA) accepts wheat
and maize bran and oilseed cakes and meals as animal feed subject to zero rating under SI 273 of 2003.
However, molasses which is a by-product of ushi g sugarcane and refining to produce table sugar
and used as an important energy source in cattle feeds, is not accepted as qualifying for VAT zero rating
despite it being the main ingredient in the making of "stock lick" highlighted in condition (b) above. The
standard rating (i.e. VAT of 15%) on molasses is therefore inconsistent with the above provisions and
leads to an increase in the cost of cattle feeds.

During 2015, members of the Stockfeeds Manufacturers Association (SMA) used 18,000mt of molasses
in the production of 117 000mt of dairy meals, beef pen feeding meals, dry season cattle maintenance
licks and beef concentrates with a combined value of $32.6 million. Molasses contributed 15% by
volume to all these cattle feeds and thus VAT of 15% on molasses has a significant impact on the cost
structure for the industry. These figures do not reflect direct purchases of molasses from the sugar mills
and distributers by farmers for on-farm feed mixing which is prevalent on most dairy farms and large
scale beef feedlots.

Another problem facing processors of by-product is that some ZIMRA regional managers, despite legal
provisions that specifically zero rates milling by-products used for livestock feed purposes for VAT, have
been levying VAT on maize and wheat bran bought by feed mills. Box 1 indicates the lack of clarity on
VAT on brans based on a survey of members of SMA conducted in October, 2015. (see Box 1 below).

33
BOX 1: Responses on whether or not SMA members are raising or paying VAT on bran sales or procurements (October 2015):

Respondent 1: Milling Company


In May 2014, we had an issue with a customer (stockfeeds manufacturer) we had charged VAT who disputed it on the basis of
the ZIMRA response to your association.

We took the issue up with Mr. M. Chinana at ZIMRA, later Mrs. C. Shumbayawonda and Mr. Madongorere. It took so long to
get a response and when they responded, they did not want to put it in writing on the basis that it was not a blanket exemption
as wheat bran is also sold to non-stockfeed manufacturers and therefore the onus would fall on the seller to prove that they
sold to a stockfeed manufacturer.

From July 2014, we then started charging VAT of 15% only to those customers who are not farmers and stockfeed
manufacturers i.e. just one or two bakeries and here and there as bulk sales, to the stockfeed manufacturers.

We were audited in April 2015 and a penalty was raised on wheat bran sales we had done to stockfeed manufacturers. We
th
appealed on 5 August 2015 and it was acknowledged.

All of a sudden, they then resumed VAT input refunds they had withheld. We have consistently been engaging them for a
declaration on the matter but none has been forthcoming.

We are still pursuing the issue but have continued on the basis of their July 2014 explanations. No VAT charge to stockfeed
manufacturers and farmers. If your organisation could get further clarity on the issue this would be greatly appreciated.

Respondent 2: Feed Manufacturer


We are paying VAT to some suppliers who have been audited by ZIMRA, mostly regional suppliers like Chinhoyi and Kadoma.
They are adamant that they have been penalised.

Harare suppliers and larger millers like National Foods are not charging VAT.

If supplier is charging VAT, we pay; if he is not, we simply leave it.

It is a major problem however and pushes our costs up. We are struggling to get our VAT back from ZIMRA so it creates a cash
flow issue having to pay this extra towards brans.
Respondent 3: Large scale poultry producer with own feed mill
We are paying VAT on procurement of wheat bran and maize bran.

Respondent 4: Out of Harare grain milling company


We charge VAT on the bran we sell, only because no one can give us a straight answer, even ZIMRA themselves.

Respondent 5: Large scale feed manufacturer (Harare)


We are not paying VAT on brans.

Respondent 6: Medium scale feed manufacture


We are importing most of our brans from Malawi and not paying VAT. Recently we have purchased some local brands and have
also not paid VAT. Statutory Instrument 168 of 2012 refers but is not specific.

Respondent 7: Bulawayo based poultry producer with own feed mill


We ha e t ee pa i g a VAT o a s a d ha e ot e eived any directives from ZIMRA.

34
4.1.1.3 GMB Pricing Policy
On 8 August, 2014, MoAMID, through AMA, gazetted SI 122 of 2014, AMA (Minimum Grain Producers
Prices) Regulations, 2014 setting a minimum maize buying price of $390/mt. It was considered necessary
to protect local producers from low prices of locally produced grain, specifically maize. To achieve this
objective, MoAMID of the SI, MAMID also restricted/effected restrictions or banned imported maize
meal and grain from SA, Zambia and Malawi which had surplus grain for export to Zimbabwe at landed
prices ranging from $265 to $310/mt

Stakeholders in the livestock value chain raised a number of concerns including:

a) Import Parity: The price of $390/mt was way above the cost of importing maize from countries in
the region, making Zimbabwe's cost of feeds non-competitive relative to what other regional maize
producers were paying. Based on prices of maize at the time, the landed cost of importing maize
from SA to Harare by road was equivalent to US$312/mt, $292/mt by rail to Harare and $272/mt by
rail to Bulawayo.

b) Regional Producer Prices: The stipulated Zimbabwean minimum producer price exceeds by far
those prevailing in the region. South African and Zambian farmers at the time were receiving
approximately $190/mt and $265/mt for maize, respectively. Thus, Zimbabwean farmers were
being paid more than double the South African producer price and 47% more than Zambian
producers.

c) Severe impact on feed costs and on-farm cost of production: At the time SI 122 was gazetted, feed
processors were purchasing maize from farmers at $320/mt which was already higher than regional
producer prices and close to the landed price of imported maize. Feed manufacturers argued that
raising the procurement price to $390 would lead to cost increases that would induce increases in
on-farm cost of production by as much as US$0.15/kg for pork, $0.08/ kg for beef, $0.13 per broiler
day-old chick, $0.13/kg of broiler meat and $0.30 per dozen eggs. In addition, since 75% of the feed
produced goes into poultry broiler production – in which 35,000 mainly female (60%) small scale
farmers accounting for 52% of production – this sub-sector would be greatly affected by the
increased maize price. The industry estimated that the increases in production costs in the poultry
sector (broilers and egg) would cost all producers nearly $3 million per month20 in lost profit and run
counter to the stated objectives under ZimASSET.

In April 2015, SI 38 of 2015 repealed SI 122 of 2014. However, at the beginning of the 2016 marketing
season MoAMID once again instructed GMB to set their maize procurement price at $390/mt when the
import parity price was between $350 – 360/mt. This resulted in side marketing by producers despite
having been contracted by processors and grain merchants. However, the GMB has been charging its
processing division $300 for the maize it purchased for $390/mt. The difference is being passed on to
Government. There are three major problems with this policy:

20
T. Chamboko and Y. Erasmus(2013). Cost of Compliance with Regulations in the Poultry Sector. Study
Commissioned by USAID-Agricultural Competitiveness Program, Harare.

35
 Because its processed products (maize meal and stockfeeds) are heavily subsidised, the GMB is
able to offer its products at a lower price compared to private millers and stockfeeds companies
- an unfair trading practice;
 The side marketing encouraged by the $390/mt price as well as the economic loss from GMB
under-cutting millers and feed mills discourages private sector engagement in contract farming
activities in an economic environment where bank credit to grain farmers is scarce and
expensive; and
 This creates unsustainable burden on the fiscus who have to foot the grain marketing subsidy on
top of seed and fertiliser production subsidies given to grain farmers under programmes such as
the Presidential Input Scheme.

4.1.1.4 Regulation of Processed Grain Imports

Zimbabwe is a net importer of wheat by-products because of decreased local milling of flour, leading
to higher costs
Increased flour imports have reduced local availability of wheat bran, a by-product which is essential in
the manufacture of stockfeed. To satisfy local demand of bran, Zimbabwe imported 18 600mt of wheat
bran during 2014 mainly from Malawi, Mozambique and Zambia (see Table 4.2). However, 3 000mt was
exported to SA due to a seasonal glut. Thus, the net wheat bran imports amounted to 15 600mt. If the
100 000mt of imported flour had come from locally milled grain, this would have yielded 16 500mt of
bran, making the country more than self-sufficient in wheat bran. Imported bran is expensive, costing an
average of $165 per tonne, including transport costs. Locally milled bran saves $30 per tonne in
addition to creating local employment in the milling sector. The reduced price of bran would lower the
cost of feed manufacture. In 2014, members of SMA used 55 000mt of wheat bran, valued at $9 million.
A saving of $30/ mt in the cost of bran would have reduced the cost of the manufacture of feed by $1.64
million, which, passed on to livestock farmers, would reduce the cost of livestock production, rendering
Zimbabwean livestock products more competitive.

Table 4.2: Wheat Bran Production and Trade in 2014: Zimbabwe

Exports (X) Imports (M) Trade Balance (X-M)


Trading Partner mt $'000 mt $'000 Mt $'000
South Africa 2, 921 395 - - 2, 921 395
Malawi 16, 781 2, 579 (16,781) (2, 579)
Mozambique 1, 096 334 (1,096) (334)
Zambia 750 154 (750) (154)
Total 2, 921 395 18, 627 3, 067 (15, 706) (2, 672)
Source: COMTRADE Database, UN-STATS

Regionally, Mozambique, Malawi, Zambia and SA have encouraged local milling of wheat as Table 4.3
shows that imported wheat four contributed 2% or less to total flour supply with the rest coming from
locally milled locally grown or imported wheat grain. In contrast, close to 42% of total wheat flour used

36
in Zimbabwe is imported. The low volume of milling flour may explain why Zimbabwe has the highest
price of wheat bran of the five countries as Figure 4.1 shows. The high cost of wheat bran - a key input
into feed manufacture - leads to non-competitiveness of Zimbabwe's livestock sector in addition to
worsening trade balance.
Table 4.3: Wheat flour imports as percent of a country's to supply of wheat flour: 2014
Imported wheat flour Imported flour as % of
Country (mt) Locally milled flour (mt) local flour supply
Zambia 57 227,439 0.03%
Malawi 690 140,809 0.49%
Mozambique 429 426,781 0.10%
South Africa 49,907 2,609,027 1.88%
Zimbabwe 99,594 140,591 41.47%
Source: UN COMTRADE Database

Figure 4.1

Source: UN COMTRADE Database

The above analysis supports the view that Zimbabwe should work towards developing a policy that
ensures all wheat is imported in its raw form as other countries in the region are doing. The aim is to
achieve zero imports of wheat flour and Zimbabwe has to increase the import of wheat grain and/or
boost annual wheat production to 255 000mt. Such a policy will reduce import bill of flour from US$105
million to US$92 million, based on 2014 figures when the average price of wheat grain was US$360/mt
and flour prices were $550/mt. As a result of adopting the 'import wheat grain only or boost local
production' policy, the country will likely save US$13 million in addition to boosting milling capacity
utilisation from 41% to 70% with the employment gains this entails.

Zimbabwe has the unenviable position of having the highest price of wheat bran in the region. A spill-
over effect of the above policy is that Zimbabwe will become a net exporter of wheat bran. The
transformation from a net importer to a net exporter of wheat bran will see local bran prices decrease
by an estimated $30 per tonne, putting the country at par with Malawi in terms of price of bran. This will

37
reduce the cost of feeds and make the country more competitive in livestock products. The surplus bran
can be absorbed by SA which, because of its large livestock industry, has excess demand, earning the
country much needed foreign currency.

4.1.2 Regulations Affecting Imported Feed and Genetic Resource Availability


Due to the current low production of most feed raw materials such as maize and soya bean, hatching
eggs and lack of production capacity for raw materials including minerals and vitamins, Zimbabwe has
been heavily reliant on imports. However, regulations governing imports have increased the cost of
doing business for the feeds sector. To import raw materials, companies have to obtain approval from a
multiplicity of institutions governing importation, some with conflicting objectives. These include AMA,
Department of Veterinary Services (DVS), Economics and Markets Division (E&M) (Control of Goods Act)
and the National Biotechnology Authority (NBA) for GMO-free certification. GMO certificates are also
required for some raw materials that do not have internationally traded GMO positive varieties. The
lengthy process to obtain permits leads to a breakdown in the supply chain.

4.1.2.1 High costs of registration with multiple agencies


Prior to 2012, feed manufacturers only needed to be registered under the Fertilisers, Farm Feeds and
Remedies Act [Chapter 18:12]. The Act requires that feed manufacturers pay an annual registration fee
of $200. In addition, any new feed formulation sold by a company had to be registered with the
Fertilisers, Farm Feeds and Remedies Institute. However, after 2012 feed manufacturers who import
some of their raw materials need to be registered with two extra agencies, AMA and NBA. Under SI 147
of 2012 and SI 140 of 2013, manufacturers have to register with AMA and pay an annual registration fee
of $1 000. NBA charges $500 annual registration fee for importers of raw materials that need
verification that they are GMO-free. Although the National Biotechnology Act empowers the Minister to
charge fees and levies to raise money for a Bio-safety Fund, this has to be through a statutory
instrument requiring stakeholder consultations (see Box 2 below). No such SI exists empowering NBA to
charge fees. Feed manufacturers have noted that these extra registration fees are excessive and more
than twice the annual fees charged under the Fertiliser, Farm Feeds and Remedies Act by DR&SS, an
institution that provides direct services for the feeds sector. In addition, NBA also charge for issuing
certificates allowing importation of raw materials and a fee of $40 is applicable for anything under 5
000mt or $50.00 for anything up to 10 000mt. It is unclear why AMA, which falls under MoAMID, should
be issuing a letter of support for the importation of raw materials when several institutions under
MoAMID are already involved in issuing certificates to import. DVS issues a veterinary import permit at
a cost of $10 per permit, Plant Protection Unit also charge $25 per permit while E&M issues the final
import permit at a cost of $70 per permit. It therefore appears that AMA is merely duplicating services
offered by sister organisations within MoAMID, adding to bureaucracy and the cost of compliance for
importers of raw materials.

38
Box 2: National Biotechnology Authority Act [Chapter 14:31](No. 3 of 2006) Part VIII - Levies
Section 49 on Imposition of levies:
"(1) The Minister may, with the approval of Minister responsible for finance and subject to
subsection (3), by statutory instrument, impose one or more levies on producers, processors and
additionally, or alternatively, buyers of any product of biotechnology that is produced in Zimbabwe."
Section 50 on Withdrawal, suspension or increase of levies
"Without derogation from section 21 of the Interpretation Act [Chapter 1:01], the Minister, in
consultation with the Authority, may, by statutory instrument —
(a) withdraw any levy; or
(b) suspend any levy in whole or in part; or
(c) increase the rate or incidence of any levy;
and section 49(3) shall apply to a statutory instrument increasing the rate or incidence of any levy."
Section 51 on Consultation required for imposition, withdrawal, suspension or increase of levies
"Before publishing a statutory instrument in terms of section 49 or 50, the Minister shall cause the
Authority to consult any organisations of producers, processors and buyers of product of biotechnology
who will be affected by it."

4.1.2.2 Delays in obtaining import permits


Of concern to importers in the livestock industry, especially since 2014, has been increasing delays in the
processing of import permits that disrupts production.

Hatching egg import permit delays


The poultry sector has been the best performing livestock sector in Zimbabwe since 2008. 70% of broiler
day-old chicks are absorbed by the small-holder sector where demand is seasonal, picking up from the
end of the rains and peaking at the start of the rains to coincide with the Christmas market. The
smallholder sector accounts for nearly 50% of the layer day-old chick demand.

However, since 2012, poultry breeders who produce their own hatching eggs (to produce commercial
day-old chicks) have been unable to keep pace with demand for both broiler and layer hatching eggs
and have had to rely on imports of hatching eggs from breeders in SA and Malawi to satisfy the local
market. As table 4.4 below shows, demand for broiler hatching eggs grew from 87 million in 2013 to
102 million in 2014 and 103 million in 2015. Imported broiler hatching eggs accounted for 9% of
demand in 2013, 20% in 2014 and 25% in 2015. For layer hatching eggs, demand dropped from 11
million in 2013, to 10 million in 2014 and 9 million in 2015. But imports accounted for 1%, 6% and 30%
of total demand in 2013, 2014 and 2015, respectively. Decreased breeder production is largely because
two companies are no longer in the business.

This shows the high dependency of the poultry industry on imported hatching eggs. Permits are only
issued to a limited number of hatcheries registered with the Poultry Unit of DLVS. However, in order to
budget for increased imports, hatcheries have to place weekly orders six months in advance with

39
external suppliers for hatching eggs. Delays in processing of permits therefore increases the risk of local
hatcheries not being able to satisfy their contractual obligations with suppliers, leading to losses due to
breach of contract. The largest hatching egg import agent for the local poultry industry has experienced
delays of a month to six weeks at MOAMID to process Control of Goods (CoG) permits. Up to December
2014, CoG permits took as few as 3-5 days to process. Eggs or breeder chicks cannot be imported until a
veterinary permit has been issued by DVS after which the CoG permit is issued. The DVS permit takes
less than a week to process and is valid for three months. The current mismatch in expiry dates
between the Veterinary Health Import Permit and CoG Import Permit is severely restricting the ability of
hatcheries to import hatching eggs to meet demand for day old chicks.

Table 4.4: Increasing Importance of imported hatching eggs in Zimbabwean poultry production

2013 2014 2015


Broiler Hatching Eggs
Produced (million) 79.1 81.9 76.7
Imported (million) 7.9 20.1 25.9
Total (million) 87.0 102.0 102.7
% Imported hatching eggs 9% 20% 25%
Layer Hatching Eggs
Produced (million) 10.7 9.8 6.3
Imported (million) 0.2 0.6 2.6
Total (million) 10.8 10.4 8.9
% Imported hatching eggs 1% 6% 30%
Source: Zimbabwe Poultry Association

Grains and Premixes

In the last quarter of 2015, the process of obtaining import permits was made more cumbersome.
Previously, an importer of grain, oilseed cake or premixes first applied for a Veterinary Health Import
Permit from DVS. After obtaining this the importer then applied for a Control of Goods Permit at the
Economics and Markets Division (E&M). After assessing the application the E&M forwards their
recommendation to the Permanent Secretary, MAMID for approval and signature. The new process for
application is as follows:

 The importer submits a letter of request to DVS for a Veterinary Health Import Permit;
 The Principal Director, DLVS recommends this application to the Secretary, MoAMID;
 The Permanent Secretary, personally, authorises this application and refers it back to DVS;
 DVS then issue the Veterinary Health Import Permit;
 This permit is then submitted to E&M, MoAMID for assessment of the application for the
Control of Goods Permit, and then re-submitted to the Permanent Secretary;
 The Minister of Agriculture, personally, signs this permit;
 The importer can then submit both permits to import goods.

40
The circuitous route to obtain permits takes much more time and is also subject to extended delays
especially if the Minister is out of the office. As a result of these delays, most external suppliers and
transporters will only start to fill orders or reserve transport space once the permits have been issued so
that the supplier does not have to hold product indefinitely and the transporter is not held up at the
border.

Dairy

According to participants in the dairy industry who import powdered milk, the delays in processing
permits are proving very costly due to new South African regulations that require the permits to be in SA
at least 7 to 10 days before the arrival of the shipment. The South African Customs and veterinary
regulations require the original Zimbabwean permit to be lodged with the shipment documents prior to
discharge at Durban otherwise a transit permit will not be issued. The delays result in demurrage being
charged in Durban at a standard charge of $1 000 per day per container as they cannot be offloaded.

4.1.2.3 GMO free certificates for products without internationally traded GMO
varieties
When the NBA started implementing the regulation to prevent the importation of GMO positive raw
materials, the focus was only on maize and oilseeds and their products. However, the list of products
that need GMO-free certification has been expanded to include products which have no known traded
GMO varieties and the inclusion of wheat grain and wheat bran among these products has generated
concern among participants in the livestock value chain. Importers of these products are now required
to register with the NBA for $500 and obtain a GMO-free certification from a reputable laboratory in the
source country. This is unnecessarily costly and adds to the cost of production in the feed and livestock
industries. At the present moment, no genetically modified wheat is being grown anywhere in the
world. Plans to introduce GM wheat in North America were abandoned in 2004.21 In 2002, Monsanto,
the world's leading agro-biotech enterprise, submitted an application to the United States and Canada
for the approval of an herbicide resistant, genetically modified wheat cultivar. Two years later,
Monsanto withdrew its application after many farmers feared that their products would be rejected by
markets in Europe and Asia, where views toward GMOs are more skeptical. Concerns about export
markets overpowered potential advantages offered by herbicide resistance.

Thus wheat bran imports should not be among products that require a GMO-free certificate.

4.2 On-farm Production Related Regulations


There are many regulations affecting livestock production. Livestock value chain participants have
raised particular objections to regulations under the Environment Management Act [Chapter 20:27]
which provides for the sustainable management of natural resources and protection of the environment
and the prevention of pollution and environment degradation. Subsidiary regulations under this act
include:

21
http://www.gmo-compass.org/eng/grocery_shopping/crops/22.genetically_modified_wheat.html

41
1) Environment Management (Effluent and Solid Waste Disposal) Regulations of 200722;
2) Environmental Impact Assessment and Ecosystems Protection Regulations23;
3) Air Pollution Control Regulations24; and
4) Environmental Management (Hazardous Substances, Pesticides and other Toxic Substances)
Regulations25.

The regulations applicable to beef, poultry, pig and dairy value chains are the Environment Management
(Effluent and Solid Waste Disposal) Regulations of 2007. According to these regulations, no person shall
dispose of waste or effluent into a public stream or any other surface or ground water, whether directly
or through seepage, except under a license.

An applicant shall submit an application for a blue, green, yellow or red license together with the
prescribed fee to the Agency. If the applicant does not know which class of license to apply for, the
appropriate fee for the issue of a yellow license shall be submitted, pending determination. Upon
receiving an application, the Agency may, after inspection as it deems fit, issue one of the following
licenses:
Blue: in respect of disposal which is considered to be environmentally friendly;
Green: in respect of disposal which is considered to present a low environmental
hazard;
Yellow: in respect of disposal which is considered to present a medium environmental
hazard;
Red: in respect of disposal which is considered to present a high environmental
hazard.

The cost of testing samples to determine the class of license is borne by the applicant and is $200 per
quarter. The applicant delivers the samples to the laboratory and in order to obtain a laboratory
number, makes payment at the EMA Head Office, then returns to the laboratory to show proof of
payment.

Table 4.5 shows the registration and monitoring fees set by EMA (quarterly discharge levy and
administration fee).

Table 4.5: Annual Fees for Effluent and Solid Waste Disposal

Regulatory cost Effluent Disposal Solid Waste Disposal


Annual registration fee (per year) $32 $32

Monitoring fees (per year)

22
Statutory Instrument 6 of 2007
23
Statutory Instrument 7 of 2007
24
Statutory Instrument 72 of 2009
25
Statutory Instrument 12 of 2007

42
Blue $80 $80
Green $155 $155
Yellow $300 $300
Red $585 $585

Discharge levy (per quarter)


Blue $80 $160
Green $155 + 0.0075 x $310
cubic meters of
effluent

Yellow $300 + 0.015 x cubic $600


meters of effluent
Red $585 + 0.030 x cubic $1200
meters of effluent
Red License Penalty fee 50% of Discharge levy + Monitoring Fees +
Registration fees
Administration Fees 5% of all the above fees for each type of license

Under the Environmental Management (Hazardous Substances, Pesticides and Other Toxic Substances)
Regulations26 of 2007, no person shall use herbicides, pesticides, fungicides or any toxic substances for
commercial agriculture or public health pest control or veterinary vector control without a license from
EMA. The regulations require submission of an application and payment of the prescribed fee for
storage and use of hazardous substances for green, amber and red classes at $457, $525 and $672,
respectively. Since practically all crop and livestock farmers store pesticides or veterinary vector control
products they are required to register and pay fees. In addition, to transport more than 200 litres of
fuel, permits from EMA cost $200.

The "Offences and Penalties" section of the EMA Act on agricultural waste specifies that no person shall
dispose of agricultural waste directly into water and disposal of such waste to any part of the
environment is prohibited except under a waste disposal license. It further states that any agricultural
waste which is not purely organic, but has added chemicals, will be classified as hazardous substances.
Any person who contravenes this section of the regulations shall be guilty of an offence and liable to a
fine not exceeding level fourteen ($5 000) or to an imprisonment for a period not exceeding five years or
to both such fine and imprisonment.

The Act also further stipulates that any land user shall put in place appropriate fire prevention measures
on their land and any person who contravenes this section will be liable to a fine not exceeding level
eight ($500) or an imprisonment not exceeding one year.

26
Statutory Instrument 12 of 2007.

43
The penalties under the Environmental Management (Hazardous Substances, Pesticides and other Toxic
Substances) Regulations of 2007 also include a fine not exceeding level fourteen ($5 000) or
imprisonment for a period of one year or to both such fine and imprisonment.

4.3 Livestock Marketing Related Regulations


A number of regulatory constraints affect the marketing of livestock and products.

 Rural District Council Levy: In the majority of cattle dependent districts, Rural District Councils
(RDC) have been charging a levy of 10.5% on all live cattle sales. Not only is the charge excessive
but the rationale behind the charges has been questionable. RDC levies have also encouraged
illegal livestock movements to evade taxation, leading to increased risk of an outbreak of
disease.
 Livestock Clearance and Movement Controls: Cattle farmers and traders also incur significant
costs to navigate complex clearance procedures. Proof of ownership is required by police, and
results in involvement of third parties such as headmen and other witnesses.
 Lack of commercialisation of small stock partly due to taxation: Currently, sheep and goat meat
is subject to VAT of 15% when meat such as beef and chicken is not. Table eggs has just been
moved from zero rating to VAT to VAT exemption which precludes producers from claiming VAT
on inputs into their production process. This is counter to commercialisation of these livestock
species which are more prevalent in low income smallholder farming areas.
 Most cattle commercially traded on local markets are from smallholder farming areas
dominated by small framed indigenous breeds: The current carcass grading system based on
large framed exotic breeds unfairly discriminates against cattle from the smallholder farming
areas leading to artificially low producer prices.

4.3.1 Rural District Council Marketing Levies


In 2006, the Ministry of Local Government, Urban and Rural Development (MoLGURD) issued a circular
suggesting that RDCs charge 10.5% of the agreed price of cattle traded at Council auctions as a levy to
the Council. Farmers' unions and the Zimbabwe Association of Abattoirs have argued against the levy
on the grounds that it is excessive, leading to poor viability of livestock farming, and that the money
raised by the levy is not being applied to help the growth of the livestock sector. Also, basing the levy on
the value of an animal effectively punishes farmers who sell good quality animals.

In 2013, MoLGURD drafted model by-laws to be adopted by all RDCs to charge 10.5% on all livestock
sales from each district. A number of RDCs, some without passing necessary by-laws, have implemented
the proposal. The proposed levies have also been expanded to include cattle marketed through direct
buyer-farmer negotiations instead of just being applied to cattle traded at Council operated auctions. In
addition, some RDCs require buyers of cattle to register for a fee of $250 per quarter in order to be
allowed to buy cattle in the district. Table 4.6 below gives a breakdown of the composition of the levy.

44
Table 4.6: Proposed Levies on Cattle Traded at RDC Auctions
Institution Levy (% of Auction Price)
Council 6
Livestock Production and Development 3
Auctioneer 1.5
TOTAL 10.5%

Stakeholders in the cattle value chain have registered their strong objections to the proposed by-laws as
they argue that such a policy, in addition to reducing the viability of cattle production by communal
farmers, will negatively affect the orderly marketing of cattle in the country.

To clearly see the impact of the above proposed policy on the cattle sector, how cattle are currently
being traded in the rural areas needs to be understood. As Table 4.7 shows, most live cattle are
currently being sold through private buyer-farmer negotiations. In 2012, only 7% of cattle sold were
through auction sales and the rest were sold through private treaty. Trends show that since 2009, the
proportion of cattle being sold through auctions has declined from 11% to 7% in 2012. Though data for
2013 and 2014 is not available, it is believed that the proportion of cattle sold at auctions during this
period is still less than 15% of slaughters in registered abattoirs.

Table 4.7: Small and Declining Proportion of Cattle Sales through Auction

2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

Abattoir Cattle No. 128, 414 229, 677 261, 424 256, 753 260, 514 246, 522
Slaughters
CC Sales No. 8, 949 9, 997 12, 084 10, 584
Ave Price $ 1.24 1.47 1.66 1.72
% Sales 7.0 4.4 4.6 4.1
Communal Auctions No. 5,097 12,146 11,332 7,493
Ave Price $ 0.95 1.17 1.24 1.21
% Sales 4.0 5.3 4.3 2.9
Total Auction Sales No. 14, 046 22, 143 23, 416 18, 661
% Sales 10.9 9.6 9/0 7.3
Non-Auction Sales No. 114, 368 207, 534 238, 008 238, 092
% Sales 89.1 90.4 91.0 92.7
Source: Department of Livestock Production and Development, Meat Graders

A key flaw in the proposed by-laws is that private negotiated sales which are currently being levied do
not benefit from the services in the model by-laws. These sales are not conducted at Council sales pens,
are not managed by auctioneers, nor do they use grading services provided by Meat Graders from DLPD.
Thus, private negotiated sales are levied for services that are not rendered.

45
Stakeholders point out that the predominance of private treaty sales is a reflection of weaknesses in the
current auction system and the high taxation imposed on auction trade. Private buyer-farmer sales are
not ideal as they:

- Impose a burden on farmers who are not usually skilled negotiators compared with experienced
full-time buying agents and traders and lead to sub-optimal prices;
- Impose time and travelling investments by buyers in clearing cattle for movement as this is done
at the selle s ho estead i stead of at e t all lo ated au tio pe s;
- Encourage buyers to engage in corruption and bribing of officials to shortcut the clearance
procedures; and
- Buyers generally incur excessive aggregation costs to buy adequate numbers of cattle for
transporting out of communal areas.

The most efficient way to trade cattle is through auction sales. However, a number of constraints are
currently hindering the use of auctions for live cattle sales and spurring the growth of private treaty
sales. Chief amongst these are the excessive RDC levies being charged and which MoLGURD is
proposing to increase and broaden. There is irrefutable evidence that increasing levies causes a
reduction in auction sales. A good example is the closure of the CC Sales auction market in Headlands
which used to sell 250 beasts per month. Other constraints include the poor state of repairs of access
roads and most rural sale pens.

Stakeholder consultations convened by the Livestock and Meat Advisory Council in February 2013 in
Harare noted more pointed reservations about the proposed harmonised model by-laws. The concerns
include the following:

- The proposal by MoLGURD does not attempt to reduce levies. In fact, by standardising them for
the whole country, levies will be increased in those districts currently charging lower levies;
- The proposal does not justify through a cost-benefit analysis, the size of the proposed levies;
- The levies are unfair for cattle farmers, most of whom are found in low potential agro-ecological
regions. There are no RDC levies on other agricultural commodities;
- Buyers of cattle will pay VAT of 15% on monies generated by RDC levies and auctioneers
commission (i.e. 15% of [6% to RDC plus 1.5% to auctioneers] = 1.125%). This effectively passes
on the cost of VAT to buyers. However, producers will ultimately pay the cost as buyers will
offer lower bids;
- Stakeholders question why RDC and DLPD levies should be based on a percentage of the value
of an animal sold. This effectively penalises sellers of good quality cattle. For example, an
animal sold for $500 attracts a combined RDC and DLPD levy of $45 compared with $22.50 for
an animal valued at $250. The services provided by the RDC and DLPD are the same regardless
of whether or not the animal is of poor or good quality. A fairer taxation system will be a
constant dollar denominated charge per animal;
- Stakeholders also question the rationale behind the levy of 3% charged by DLPD. This levy was
introduced in 2006, when DLPD classified and determined the minimum bid prices for each
grade of animal as a way to protect farmers under conditions of hyper-inflation. This service is

46
no longer required and merely inflates levies to the detriment of buyers and, ultimately, cattle
farmers.
- Finally, stakeholders lamented the number of fees and levies across the whole value chain,
seriously eroding competitiveness and threatening their existence. Levies range from land tax,
DLVS permit and DLPD grading fees as well as fees set by the AMA, EMA and National Social
Security Authority as well as ZIMRA tax obligations, coupled with RDC fees and levies. The whole
fee structure is disproportionate to the services being offered and is contributing to the current
distressed state of the livestock industry and agricultural sector.

There are also broad-based economic implications of the current cattle marketing levies. The
application of the by-laws subject cattle meant for on-farm livestock investment to the levy, including
herd building by newly resettled farmers and cattle bought by farmers for value-addition through
feedlot operations. This is counter to the objectives of ZimASSET of economic growth and value addition
with negative impacts on local (district) economic development. It is also pertinent to note that
currently, 90% of cattle entering the market are from the small holder sector where farmers typically
own herds of 12 animals and only sell one or two head each year.

A secondary impact has been an increase in operations of unscrupulous traders who use bribes to avoid
paying levies and facilitate illegal cattle movements, creating a break-down in disease and stock theft
control. The current FMD epidemic spreading across the southern parts of the country are partly
blamed on such illegal movements of cattle. Reasonable auction fees charged by RDCs would encourage
the resuscitation of regular rural livestock sales which will have many beneficial impacts, including
better monetary returns for the producer and improved livestock movement controls (disease and
theft). A small commission charged on large volumes of animals will increase income to service
providers, including RDCs.

Proposed Cattle Marketing and Taxation

Stakeholders are not averse to paying a levy as long as they are reasonable and are applied to improving
the production and marketing of cattle. Indeed, the Rural District Council Act (particularly Sections 96
and 97) provides for the collection of levies to support livestock related investments as outlined in the
Schedule appended to the Act. These include investments among others, in control of the spread of
diseases, dip tanks and water sources. However, in designing local council policies, there is need to take
cognisance of broader national economic development goals of poverty alleviation, employment
creation and value addition as espoused in the ZimASSET economic blue-print.

Stakeholders in the cattle industry have tabled the following proposal on cattle levies:

 A levy based on a flat fee per animal traded at auctions, in the amount comparable with
similar levies in neighbouring countries such as Botswana, Zambia and Namibia who
draw a significant amount of their processed beef from the smallholder sector.
Marketing levies in these countries cost $2 per head. A similar fee is proposed for
Council services provided at auctions.

47
 Charge a fixed development levy of $2 per head for cattle sold to abattoirs for slaughter
but no charge for cattle sold to farmers for their herd building investments.

The above system, applied countrywide, includes a number of advantages:


- Cattle are not subject to double taxation when they are destined for farms and then later sold to
abattoirs. This supports the ZimASSET objectives of local value-addition;
- More auction sales will be encouraged as RDC levies will be reduced and based on a lower flat
fee per animal which will minimise illegal cattle movements and corruption.

4.3.2 Livestock Clearance and Movement Controls


Cattle and pig farmers and traders incur significant costs to navigate complex clearance procedures
when animals are sold. The Animal Health (Movement of Cattle and Pigs) Regulations of 1984 are the
principal regulations governing the movement of cattle. Depending on the purpose, these regulations
require that all movement of animals be accompanied by a movement permit from DLVS. In some cases,
a pre-movement inspection is required before a permit is issued, whilst in other cases, no inspection is
necessary. The movement permit is issued by an authorised official from DLVS and costs $5 per lot as
does the pre-movement inspection. This cost affects all animals that are marketed, whether for
slaughter at an abattoir or that are moved from one area to another after being sold. Besides the direct
cost of the permit, veterinary offices sometimes request fuel to carry out the inspections.

Anti-Stocktheft Regulations note that cattle may only be moved between 6.00am and 6.00pm and
stipulate the requirement for police clearance before animals are moved. While this is free, producers
incur the costs of travel to and from the police station to collect officers to clear the animals before they
are moved to market27. The distance varies according to the location of the farm from the police station.
The Cost of Compliance Study estimates the average distance travelled to and from the police post and
place of animal exchange for verification of ownership as ranging between 20 and 60km per trip. After
clearance has been obtained, the producer then returns to the police station in order for the form to be
stamped.

In the case of pig movement, the veterinary movement permit is issued by DLVS at a cost of $10 per lot.
These costs escalate rapidly as in general, large scale commercial piggeries deliver animals to markets at
least once per week. Whilst there is no need for police clearance for movement of pigs from large scale
commercial farms who have African Swine fever certification, it is required when moving pigs from
smallholder areas. The process is similar to the clearance procedure for moving cattle.

The main problem increasing the cost of compliance arises from a lack of a national livestock
identification and traceability system (LITS).

27
This depends on the availability of the officers designated to perform the task as the producer has to wait if no
officers are available.

48
LITS as a way to solve marketing constraints

Zimbabwe has a history of a national livestock identification and traceability system which was limited
to the catchment areas for cattle that supplied beef destined for the EU market. The Zimbabwe Cattle
Traceability Scheme, managed by the Livestock Identification Trust, was established in 1999 following
stakeholder meetings to ensure that Zimbabwean beef exports would meet EU requirements of
traceability from farm of origin. At that time, most cattle supplying the formal local and international
beef market emanated from the Large Scale Commercial Farming sector. Following the implementation
of the Fast Track Land Reform Programme, there have been significant changes in the beef value chain.
Most of the cattle destined for the formal market now originate from the communal and small scale
farming sectors where livestock identification has not firmly taken root either due to lack of awareness
or inappropriateness of identification technologies. Furthermore, outbreaks of FMD in August 2001 led
to the loss of international beef export markets which had hitherto acted as the major push factor for
the adoption of a sophisticated identification and traceability system. Apart from disease control, the
major impetus for LITS in Zimbabwe has been increased stock theft and the need to improve the
processing of movement permits.

There is renewed interest to revive LITS in a form that meets the expectations of all stakeholders. With a
small grant from the EU, stakeholders have discussed developing LITS in Zimbabwe and have agreed on
the broad outline for programme. The proposed system builds on already existing legal instruments: the
Brands Act, managed by the Ministry of Home Affairs and SI 35 of 2003, managed by MoAMID (see
Figure 4.2 below). The Brands Act requires that livestock owners register a personal brand that is
applied at specified places on the right side of the animal. Under the current legislation, this is a
voluntary requirement and stakeholders have suggested that it be made compulsory. Though not
currently being enforced, SI 35 of 2003 requires that animals be branded on the left side with a
veterinary brand code specifying dip-tank of origin for cattle in smallholder farming areas or farm of
origin for A2 and commercial farms. Farmers are required to either have dip-tank herd information
cards (for smallholder farmers) or livestock stock cards (for A2 and commercial farms). Stakeholders
have suggested that this information be captured electronically into a central registry. When ownership
changes, stakeholders recommended that a secure identification tag be applied by local veterinary
officers with details of the transaction captured on the movement permit as well as on the registry of
animals held by DVS. These records are then used to update the central registry. Finally, stakeholders
suggested that all cattle owners be issued with a cattle ownership identity card linked to the DVS central
registry and bearing a picture of the owner, his/her brand as well as the veterinary brand code.

49
Figure 4.2

There are a number of advantages of the proposed system including:


 Because the system depends on a hot iron brand, it is accessible and cheaper for poor livestock
farmers. The visibility of brands also makes it easy for police or veterinary inspectors to identify
animals. The more expensive identification tags are only required when animals move out of
the area of origin or exchange ownership. Thus cattle buyers would be responsible tagging the
cattle.
 The combination of veterinary geographic location code (dip-tank or farm of origin), a personal
brand and livestock owner identification cards will identify cattle to the place of origin as well as
to who owns the cattle. This removes the costly need to have Anti-Stock Theft police involved in
ascertaining ownership prior to the exchange of livestock.
 Linking this to the issue of cattle movement permits enables traceability of animals from farm of
origin to destination (other farms, auctions, feedlots, abattoir, shows etc).
 Identification will also aid recovery of stray or stolen animals by farmers.
 When disease outbreaks occur in a particular area, the veterinary authorities can more
effectively control movement out of that area, preventing the spread of disease to clean areas.
 Finally, creating a database of ownership and records of transfers also helps authorities with
livestock population numbers and how they are distributed across the country.

50
The above system would greatly reduce the cost of compliance with movement permits and help speed
up the trade in cattle. In addition, it will also be easy to upgrade the system to individual animal
identification, often required for international trade in livestock products.

4.3.3 Lack of commercialisation of small stock partly due to VAT taxation


Inconsistencies in the application of VAT disadvantages some livestock proteins relative to others and
reduces incentives too full commercialisation of the affected value chain. This has affected sheep and
goat meat as well as table eggs.

Standard rating of VAT on meat of sheep and goats


In 2015, the population of goats and sheep was 4.05 million and 460 000, respectively. However, very
few sheep and goats enter the formal meat market and in 2015, only 19 410 goats and 6 460 sheep
were slaughtered in abattoirs monitored by DLPD (see Table 4.8 below). As a result, the contribution of
these two species to the value of the formal livestock protein market was only 0.12 %. Most sheep and
goats are traded outside the formal marketing channels and are subject to low prices and high
transactions costs.

Table 4.8: Recent Trends in Livestock Protein Production and Value

2012 2013 2014 2015


Beef Number 257,050 261,020 247,220 257,530
Value ($) 106,267,000 122,826,000 $110,676,000 $123,612,000
Goats Number 9,810 11,490 13,070 19,410
Value ($) 343,000 321,000 347,000 411,000
Sheep Number 5,250 5,200 7,340 6,460
Value ($) 210,000 208,000 326,000 246,000
Pigs Number 122,510 145,830 123,760 140,050
Value ($) 24,747,000 28,780,000 $22,719,000 $28,394,000
Dairy Litres 55,929,000 54,665,590 55,479,120 57,544,840
Value ($) 24,614,000 24,680,000 $24,966,000 $28,513,000
Broiler Kgs 98,000,000 119,000,000 114,000,000
Value ($) 284,200,000 332,010,000 305,520,000
Eggs Dozen 51,000,000 49,000,000 53,000,000
Value ($) 79,356,000 82,516,000 80,136,000
Total Value $ 540,371,000 573,560,000 566,832,000
Sheep and Goats as % of
Total Value 0.10 0.12 0.12
Source: ZIMSTAT Fourth Quarterly Digest of Statistics - 2015; Zimbabwe Poultry Association

One of the main factors discouraging abattoirs from buying and slaughtering sheep and goats for the
formal market is that meat from these two species are subject to VAT. This is despite the fact that meat

51
from chicken, pigs and beef cattle are zero-rated for VAT purposes. This puts meat from sheep and
goats at a disadvantage in the retail market and works counter to commercialisation.

Commercialisation of sheep and goats is important because most of these animals are in smallholder
farming areas where the majority of poor live and creating viable markets for sheep and goats will assist
in poverty alleviation. In addition, the land reform programme has reduced the size of farms, making
husbandry of smaller animals particularly attractive for beneficiaries and there has been increased
interest in farming small ruminants as shown by the formation of goat breed associations and the
import of semen from Boer goats. To encourage commercialisation of small ruminants, meat from
sheep and goats needs to be zero rated in line with other meat products.

VAT Exemption of Table Eggs

The table egg value chain is affected differently by VAT regulations. SI 9 of 2016, Value Added Tax
(General) (Amendment) Regulations, 2016 (No. 40) which came into effect on 1st February 2016
transfers table eggs from zero-rated to VAT exempt as follows:

"Exempt supplies are supplies of goods and services that are not subject to Value Added Tax
(VAT) incurred on goods and services acquired. Supplies so exempted may not be claimed as input
tax credit. Traders who exclusively provide exempt supplies are, therefore, not required to be
registered for VAT purposes".

The VAT exemption affects producers for whom the sale of eggs represents more than 10% of their total
income and the effects of the exemption are as follows:

1. The affected producer will no longer be able to claim input tax on all direct purchases relating to
table eggs. The producer will also be prevented from claiming full VAT in indirect purchases
relating to the production of table eggs. Input tax claims for indirect purchases will be limited to
the extent to which they relate to zero rated/supplies taxed at 15%. The balance cannot be
claimed and is disallowed for tax purposes. Consequently, possible tax repayments to producers
are reduced, and the net VAT due to tax authorities will increase. However, table egg customers
will now face price increases as producers will not be able to absorb the extra cost of unclaimed
input tax. Prices are already under pressure and such an increase will only serve to disadvantage
already strained customers, or will further reduce margins and corporate taxes that may have
been paid to the tax authorities.

2. Producers will not be able to claim input tax that has resulted from VAT charged on capital
expenditure. As in (1) above, this will apply to asset purchases that directly and indirectly relate
to the production of table eggs. Further, tax authorities now require producers to repay any
VAT that was claimed on asset purchases that took place between 2009 and 2016. This
retrospective payment relates to VAT claimed on assets directly or indirectly related to the
production of table eggs. Producers do not understand the rationale behind the change and
believe that the legislation should be prospective rather than retrospective with regards to this
repayment. Further, there is no indication as to whether producers will be able to claim this tax

52
back through capital allowances, as the cost of these assets will be increased as a result of the
VAT adjustment.
3. Finally, producer accounting systems are not geared to deal with the change in input tax
calculations and the change came without any warning. Input tax on indirect supplies will need
to be calculated manually as accounting systems presently do not allow producers to implement
this new regime based on the way they have been set up, and accounting software developers
are yet to provide producers with solutions to help in this regard. Manual calculations are
subject to errors and inconsistencies, and will also tie up resources that need to be used
elsewhere in accounting departments. More time is needed to prepare and check producer
returns with these extra computations, a process that producers would not have had to go
through if the product had remained zero rated or attracted VAT at 15%.

For the above reasons egg producers suggest that table eggs should remain zero rated for VAT as the
case with other livestock products such as milk, broiler meat, pork and beef.

4.3.4 Unfair Cattle Carcass Grading Scheme


Most cattle commercially traded on local markets are from smallholder farming areas dominated by
small framed indigenous breeds. The current carcass grading system based on large framed exotic
breeds unfairly discriminates against cattle from the smallholder farming areas leading to artificially low
producer prices.

The main indicator used in the cattle carcass grading scheme that has attracted objections from both
farmers and up-stream industry players is the fleshing index. Use of the old fleshing index based on
carcass weight to length ratio started in the early 1970s and was based on the dominant commercial
breed of the time, the Hereford. The fleshing index derived from these measurements was meant to
predict the proportion of "flesh" in a carcass.

However, the breed composition in Zimbabwe has changed dramatically since the late 1970s with the
introduction of the Brahman, the larger continental breeds (e.g. Charolais and Simmental), and the
increasing commercial production of the indigenous cattle (Mashona, Nguni and Tuli). Research by
Division of Research and Specialist Services (DR&SS between 1987 and 1995) clearly established that
with this wide range of breeds of very different sizes, fleshing index based on weight-to-length ratio as
originally developed in the 1970s is a very poor predictor of the proportion of "flesh" in a carcass. It is
therefore no longer appropriate and should not continue to be used as an important factor in classifying
and grading beef carcasses and especially as a basis of paying producers.

The main weaknesses of the fleshing index as observed from the research within DR&SS can be
summarized as follows:

 The current fleshing index, measured as carcass weight to length ratio (kg/cm), is largely a
measure of scale (i.e. a function of size) because the relationship between carcass weight and
length is non-linear. This means that large breeds always have higher fleshing scores than
smaller breeds, even though the large breeds do not necessarily have a higher proportion of

53
"flesh" in the carcass. Though Hereford, Brahman and Simmental steers are heavier and have
higher fleshing indexes, they had significantly lower proportions of saleable meat in their
carcasses compared with Mashona steers. In terms of carcass grading and pricing, therefore,
large breeds have an unjustified double advantage; they are paid better for their heavy
carcasses and also better for their higher but largely meaningless fleshing indexes.

 Large animals within a breed, sex or age group also have higher fleshing indexes than smaller
animals because of the non-linear relationship between carcass weight and length explained
above. The present carcass classification and grading system, therefore, promotes the
production of large, old and fat animals. This is against all norms of good animal husbandry:
production of older animals reduces turnover and increases production risks because market
animals are kept longer on the farm. Secondly, production of older and fatter animals is
biologically and economically less efficient, especially given that feed or grazing is the major
limiting resource in beef production.

 It is apparent from the two points above that the present fleshing index works against the
production of indigenous and more efficient animals. It also works against the promotion of the
small indigenous breeds which have been shown by research in Zimbabwe, and in Southern
Africa generally, to be much more productive than the exotic meat breeds. All this is happening
after the land reform programme and indigenous livestock should be expected to play an
increasing role in agricultural production in view of their numerical dominance and superior
productivity. The present fleshing index therefore works against the country's best interest, in
promoting greater productivity from the use of the more efficient animals or breeds.

The weaknesses of the fleshing index are generally well known by meat graders and abattoir operators.
Since 2015, stakeholders in the livestock value chain through a committee, (including meat graders,
abattoir operators and farmers) have been engaged in discussions to reform the system. The committee
has recommended that the fleshing index be removed in the beef carcass classification and grading
system because it is serving no-o e s interest in the livestock industry and it is no longer included in
carcass grading in other countries in the region. Carcasses should be graded mainly on the basis of the
remaining classification parameters - weight, age and fat cover. A revised SI on beef carcass
classification and grading was drafted in April 2016 to put these reforms into motion but there has not
been much traction in adopting these proposals by MoAMID.

4.4 Processing Related Regulations


The major regulations negatively impacting upon operations of processing plants include: conflict
between VPH and public health departments of local authorities who both require that meat be
inspected and charge inspection fees. Similar conflict exists between EMA and local authorities. Abattoir
operators are required to register and pay registration fees with multiple authorities including EMA,
AMA, VPH, as well as local authorities.

54
4.4.1 Environmental Management Agency Regulations
As the case with large scale dairy, piggeries and poultry producers, livestock processing plants including
abattoirs and milk processors are required to register, pay annual registration fees and pay quarterly
discharge fees to EMA (see Table 4.5 above). In addition, EMA issues emission licenses for air pollution
processes that are prescribed under SI 72 of 2009. As with effluent disposal, air pollution licenses have
four levels based on the concentration of the emission and the mass flow. The annual registration fee
for the license is $32. An inspector has to access the pollution site for purposes of inspection and
collecting samples and a farmer has to pay an annual monitoring fee depending on the license band. The
fees are noted below:
Blue License $100.00

Green License $145.00

Yellow License $280.00

Red License $555.00

During the year, environmental fees are paid quarterly depending on the license band and quantity of
emissions released into the atmosphere. Table 4.9 summarises the fees applicable under the Air
Pollution Control Regulations.

Table 4.9: Fees Payable by Licenses under Air Pollution Control Regulations of 2009

Annual Registration Fees $32


Annual Monitoring Fees:
Blue $100
Green $145
Yellow $280
Red $555

Quarterly environment fees for each license band and quantity of emissions
License band Volume of emissions discharge per mt per quarter
< 5 mt > 5 but > 50 but < > 100 but > 200 mt
< 50mt 100 mt < 200 mt
Blue $100 $145 $280 $555 $1 110
Green $145 $280 $555 $1 110 $2 000
Yellow $280 $555 $1 110 $2 000 $4 500
Red $555 $1 110 $2 000 $4 500 $9 000
5% administration fee shall be charged on all fees
Source: SI 72 of 2009

A number of livestock sector value chain participants have reported that EMA has been charging
pollution charges on factory equipment such as diesel powered generators and forklifts. Other
regulatory charges include the testing of exhaust emissions at a cost of $150 per quarter, the results of
hi h a e e ui ed EMA as pa t of thei o ito i g. If a o pa disputes the Age s de isio , a
fee of $240 is paid in order to lodge an appeal to the Minister. A duplicate license costs $150.

55
For example, a dairy processing plant in the yellow license category incurs the following regulatory
charges:
a) Receiving bay effluent: Annual registration fee: $32
Annual monitoring fee: $300
Quarterly discharge levy: $300; and
Administration fee: 5%.

This is despite the fact that the milk spilt at the receiving bay is channeled to the municipal sewage
treatment plant for a separate fee.

b) Boiler gaseous emissions: Annual registration fee: yellow licence $32;


Annual license monitoring fee: $280;
Quarterly discharge levy: $280; and
Administration fee: 5%.

c) Boiler effluent (that is, waste hot water from the boiler) also incurs regulatory charges
including: Annual registration fee: $32;
Annual license monitoring fee: $300;
Quarterly discharge levy: $300; and
Administration fee: 5%.

These add unnecessary costs to processing plants which, unfortunately, are passed onto consumers,
making milk non-competitive relative to imported milk products. The impact on the cost of production
is significant when it is considered that EMA fees are charged at both the farm and processor level.
Processors are double taxed as they also have to pay discharge fees to municipalities. Innocuous boiler
gaseous emissions are also subject to charges despite there being no proof that such emissions cause
environmental damage. The quantum of the fees has also been questioned by stakeholders. Worldwide
veterinary public health departments are accepted as the competent authorities in registration of food
processing plants. In Zimbabwe, these authorities charge lower fees to inspect and certify plants than
those currently being charged by EMA.

4.4.2 Veterinary Public Health and Meat Inspection Regulations


The cost of compliance at the abattoir level includes Public Health (Abattoir, Animal and Bird Slaughter
and Meat Hygiene) regulations of 199528. The main Act falls under the Ministry of Health which is the
mother body that regulates the Public Health Act. The VPH component on the registration and
inspection of abattoirs falls under the Department of Veterinary Technical Services, DLVS. These
regulations require that all abattoirs are registered by DLVS. The cost of registration is $400 for Grade A,
$300 for Grade B and $200 for Grade C abattoirs. The regulations also specify the requirement for the

28
Published in Statutory Instrument 50 of 1995

56
inspection of carcasses. For cattle, the cost of inspection is $2 per carcass where the throughput is less
than 1 000 animals per month, and $1.50 where the throughput is more than 1 000 animals per month.
However, some municipal councils also charge for meat inspection under the public health regulations
and abattoirs are forced to collect an additional $3 per carcass for meat inspection. For example, in
Masvingo the municipality charges inspection fees of $3 per head while VPH charges $2, a total of $5 per
head in foregone revenue to the farmer. In addition to the inspection, cattle are also graded by DLPD
under SI 182 of 2000 at a cost of $1.00 per carcass. Additional costs at the abattoir level include the
meat release and transfer certificate that costs $2 per truck.

4.4.3 AMA Legislation and Livestock Processing Industries


Besides the requirement to register with the VPH, abattoir operators are now also required to register
with AMA as provided for under SI 147 of 2012 (Registration of Companies and Submission of Returns)
Regulations. The registration fees for Class A and B abattoirs is $1 000 per annum while the registration
fees for a Class C abattoir is $200 per annum. These fees are more than those charged by VPH. The
justification for the fees is that there is need to collect statistics from producers, traders, processors and
retailers. This is despite the fact that the Meat Graders section of DLPD already collects such
information while AMA has not yet produced comprehensive information on slaughter indicators. The
double registrations are unnecessary and merely increase the high cost of production by value chain
participants in the livestock sector at a time when consumer demand has declined.

4.5 Post Processing Regulations


The current $0.75c/kg export tax on exports of raw hides and skins effectively bans their export,
especially as the FOB price is between $0.85 – 0.90/kg. The rationale for the export tax has been to
encourage local beneficiation of hides. However, tanneries have been offering uneconomical prices for
locally produced hides, causing a huge stockpile and spoilage of hides at abattoirs, a significant loss to
the local economy.

The Animal Health Act discourages use of slaughter by-products in feed mixes, although worldwide
blood, feathers and other abattoir waste are considered high quality feed raw materials.

Government has also stifled investment in post processing of meat through excessive duties on raw
material such as mechanically deboned meat.

4.5.1 Taxation of Raw Hides Exports


I late , )i a e u eiled its leathe st ateg do u e t e titled "The )i a e Leathe “e to
Strategy: 2012-2017". The broad thrust of the strategy has been to increase local value-addition through
a stepwise increase in the proportion of raw hides and skins that are exported as beneficiated products.
The key instrument in achieving this objective was to impose a 25% quota in exports with the rest being
reserved for local tanning industries. Any hides that are not taken up from the 75% reserved for the
local industry can be exported.

However, on 1st January 2015, an export tax of 15% was imposed on the gross value of raw hides and
skins on exports above the allocated 25% tax free quota. In the Mid-Term Fiscal Policy Review delivered

57
by Hon Chinamasa at the beginning of the third quarter of 2015, the restrictions on raw hides exports
was further tightened as the Minister proposed to extend export surtax on the 25% export quota of raw
hides and skins, with effect from 1 October 2015. In addition, the export surtax on all exports of hides
and skins was modified to 15% of FOB value or US$0.75 per kg, whichever is higher.

The Zimbabwe Association of Abattoirs, the major producers of raw hides and skins, are of the opinion
that the policy changes outlined above severely affect their economic viability and are being taken
advantage of by tanners as further elaborated below.

Problems with the Current Policy


The new raft of restrictions on exports of hides and skins comes at a particularly difficult time for the
industry as there has been a crash in the prices of international wet-blue hides accompanied by an even
more severe crash in local raw hide prices.

Local tanneries have maintained profitability by offering abattoirs below export parity prices. However,
high processing cost structures in the tannery sector has meant that profits from tanning have been
declining. This has led to low demand for hides by tanners and an increase in stocks of hides at
abattoirs. The $0.75/kg export surtax makes it uneconomic to export the accumulated hides, increasing
the risk of hides spoiling, representing a loss in potential export earnings for the nation. These
observations are elaborated upon below.

Crash in international wet-blue and raw hide markets accompanied by an even more severe crash in
local hide prices
Records of local marketing and exports of raw wet salted hides and wet blue hides kept by abattoir
operators in Bulawayo indicate the general decline in hide prices throughout the year (see Figure 4.3).
Wet blue prices obtained by Bulawayo Abattoirs for their toll tanned hides declined from $2.20/kg in
April to $1.35/kg in December. Realisation from exports of wet salted raw hides declined from $1.40 in
April to $0.85 in December.

However, the data also shows that prices offered by local tanners have, on average, been $0.26 cents
lower than export parity price of raw salted hides. Currently, tanneries are offering $0.55 - 0.60
cents/kg. This implies that abattoirs have effectively been subsidising tanners.

58
Figure 4.3: Bulawayo Abattoirs Hides Prices - 2015

$2,50

$2,00
HIDES PRICE/KG

$1,50

$1,00

$0,50

$0,00
Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
Wet Salted Export Price $1,40 $1,40 $1,40 $1,25 $1,20 $1,10 $1,10 $0,80 $0,80 $0,85 $0,85
Wet Salted Local Price $1,10 $1,10 $1,00 $1,00 $0,85 $0,85 $0,85 $0,65 $0,60 $0,65 $0,60
Wet Blue Price $2,20 $2,20 $2,20 $2,10 $2,00 $1,90 $1,70 $1,60 $1,60 $1,45 $1,35
Source: Bulawayo Abattoirs records

The information provided by Bulawayo Abattoirs generally tallies with records provided by South African
Revenue Authorities (SARS) in unit values of wet blue and raw hides imported by South Africa from
Zimbabwe in the first 10 months of 2015 (see Figure 4.4) which show a general decline in both export
parity prices of wet blue and raw hides.

59
Figure 4.4: FOB Price of Zimbabwean Wet Blue and Salted Hides exported to
South Africa based on SARS data
$3,00

$2,50

$2,00
$/kg

$1,50

$1,00

$0,50

$-
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct
Wet Blue HS 41041990 &41041190 $2,43 $2,34 $1,91 $2,04 $2,06 $2,08 $2,05 $1,82 $1,62 $1,78
Wet Salted HS 41012090 $1,46 $1,23 $1,32 $1,37 $1,36 $1,20 $1,12 $1,04 $0,69 $0,76

Source: South Africa Revenue Services http://tools.sars.gov.za/tradestatsportal/data_download.aspx

Squeezing tannery profits


The low international prices of wet blue hides have led to reduced profitability of tanning as it costs
$0.50 to tan a kilogram of raw hide. A number of tanneries have been charging $0.55/kg to toll tan raw
hides to wet blue. Bulawayo Abattoirs estimate that the average weight of hides produced in their
abattoir is 24 kilograms. Thus, on average, it costs $12 to tan a hide.

The other key cost element is the acquisition of raw hides. During tanning to wet blue, a raw hide loses
weight from 24kg to 20kg per piece. Thus, revenue for the tannery producing wet blue for export is the
export parity price of wet blue multiplied by 20kg. Profit per hide is therefore the revenue from wet blue
sales, less the cost of acquiring the raw hide and the tanning cost of $12 per hide.

Figure 4.5 summarises profits per hide based on prices offered by local tanneries compared to profits if
abattoirs were being offered export parity prices for their hides. The information indicates that
tanneries are making profits based on prices they are offering abattoirs. However, if they were offered
export parity prices, tanners would only have made a profit in two of 11 months in 2015. Tanners are
only making a profit because they are offering non-competitive prices to abattoirs. Even based on the
local prices being offered, trends indicate that since mid-year, tannery profits have been declining.

60
Figure 4.5: Profits per hide using local tannery prices vs using export parity prices
- Bulawayo Abattoir records
$10,00

$8,00

$6,00

$4,00

$2,00

$0,00
Feb.15 Mär.15 Apr.15 Mai.15 Jun.15 Jul.15 Aug.15 Sep.15 Okt.15 Nov.15 Dez.15
($2,00)

($4,00)

($6,00)

($8,00)

Profit/Hide with tanning(local prices) Profit/Hide with tanning(Export parity prices)

Source: Own computations based on Bulawayo Abattoirs price trends

Low uptake of raw hides by tanneries and increase in stocks at abattoirs


The Zimbabwe Association of Abattoirs conducted a survey of member abattoir operators including
Surrey Abattoirs, Sabie Meats, MC Meats, Bulawayo Abattoirs, Pama Meats, Binder Abattoirs, Circle Y,
West Acre and Outback Safaris. Together, these operations account for 13 790 hides per month
produced in formal abattoirs or 69% of formal cattle slaughters.

The survey shows that in November 2015, abattoirs were holding 23 816 raw salted hides in stocks
which amounts to 173% of average monthly hide production. This indicates enormous difficulties in
selling hides to the local tannery market. The problem was more severe for large operators relative to
small operators. Bigger operators, which together accounted for 73% of hides produced by sampled
operations, were holding more than double (206%) their monthly salted hides production in stocks
compared to 86% for the smaller producers.

Thus, smaller operators have been better able to off-load hides to the local market although they have
also expressed delays in offloading hides. They noted that it was taking as long as 6 weeks to find
buyers and an extra 2 to 3 weeks before being paid, putting severe strain on cash flows. In addition,
while export buyers have typically provided transport from the abattoirs as well as salt, local tannery
buyers have required abattoir operators to provide their own salt and deliver raw hides to tanneries.

Hides cannot be off-loaded to international raw hides markets due to the $0.75/kg export surtax on
raw hides
The accumulation of raw hides at abattoirs has not been helped by the recent surtax on exports which,
due to the rapid decline in export parity prices of raw hides, means that there is a virtual ban on exports

61
of raw hides. Abattoir operators cannot economically offload excess stocks on international markets
while local tanneries are agitating for further price reductions to ensure they remain profitable.

As Table 4.10 shows, between February and September 2015, the export tax on raw hides was 15% of
export parity price. The $0.75/kg export surtax introduced in the Mid Term Fiscal Policy Review
Statement makes the effective taxation level in October and November 2015 greater than 88% of value.
Exporting raw hides in October and November meant abattoirs received only $0.05 and $0.10/kg,
respectively. This is obviously sub-economic for abattoir operators.

Table 4.10: Effective Export Taxation Rates in 2015


Month Wet salted hides Export price wet salted Export surtax as % of raw hide
export parity price ($) after surtax ($) export parity price
before surtax
February 1.40 1.19 15
March 1.40 1.19 15
April 1.40 1.19 15
May 1.25 1.06 15
June 1.20 1.02 15
July 1.10 0.94 15
August 1.10 0.94 15
September 0.80 0.68 15
October 0.80 0.05 94
November 0.85 0.10 88

The accumulation of hides at abattoirs which tanners only take up at lower than export parity prices
puts undue economic strain on abattoir operators. Traditionally, the fifth quarter (offal and hide) covers
the processing costs to operators. Under-pricing of hides forces abattoirs to lower their offer prices for
cattle to farmers, the real owners of cattle hides.

Rethinking the Current Policies


Abattoir operators express support for local value addition in the leather sector. However, this has to be
done in a fair manner for all participants in the value chain. The tannery sub-sector should not be
developed by taxing abattoirs and farmers who produce the key raw materials for the industry.

In summary, the following is occurring due to the current policies:

 On top of the current low international hide prices, the surtax of $0.75c/kg translates into an
export rate of nearly 90% which effectively amounts to a ban on exports;
 Banning exports leaves abattoir operators at the mercy of tanneries who are taking advantage
of the power conveyed by the export ban to offer prices lower than export parity;

62
 Cost structures in the local tanning industry are proving non-competitive and they are only
profitable by under-pricing local hides;
 The current low uptake of hides by tanners coupled with closing the export market due to the
surtax has led to wastage and loss of hides; and
 Revenues generated by the raw hides export tax is not being channelled into developing the
leather value chain.

Given the above problems, the following policy changes are suggested:

 Rescind the surtax of $0.75/kg as it is not viable. It is suggested that it be replaced with an
export surtax of 15% and 10% on both raw and wet blue hides, respectively and a special tax of
15% on imports of leather products;
 Ensuring adequate supply of hides to local tanneries through a determined quarterly export
quota that reflects effective demand by tanneries;
 The funds raised by the taxes should be deposited into a Leather Development Fund, managed
by a Committee of value chain stakeholders as is the case with the Dairy Revitalisation
Programme.
 Key investments for the Fund should be to reduce the cost of production in the tanning industry
as well as improving the quality of hides.
 Tanners note that 60% of hides are good enough for the international wet blue market. Thus,
the 25% export quota is too small to clear all hides produced in the country. The export quota
should therefore be increased to 40% and there should be no restrictions on exports where local
tanners fail to take up hides offered at export parity price by abattoirs;
 There is need for clear performance targets for tannery development as well as timelines for
suppression of exports of raw hides in order to encourage tanneries to establish themselves and
compete with international players without further assistance from Government;
 Finally, there is need for greater transparency in the issuance of export permits. To counter
abuse, there is need for all export permits to be shared by stakeholders and for regular (at least
monthly) reconciliation of permits issued and records of actual cross border flows of hide
exports.

4.5.2 Utilisation of livestock processing by-products as feed resources


Proteins are the most expensive component of feed manufacture. During 2015, stockfeed
manufacturers spent close to $96million on protein raw materials (Table 4.11). $84.2 million was spent
on plant-based protein raw materials including soya bean, cotton and sunflower cakes. However, plant-
based proteins tend to lack essential amino-acids such as methionine and lysine which are crucial to
optimal growth in pigs and poultry. These amino acids have to be supplemented by inclusion of either
animal based proteins rich in these amino acids or synthetic forms. In 2015, $11.6 million was spent on
either synthetic methionine and lysine or imported meat and bone meal (MBM) and fish meal. These
imports could have been avoided if the country utilised its abattoir wastes as raw material protein in
feeds.

63
Table 4.11: Protein Raw Materials Quantities and Value Utilised by Feed Mills - 2015

mt Price ($/mt) Value $


Methionine 396 5 065 2,005,740
Lysine 324 2 257 731,268 $2,737,008
MBM 9,480 744 7,053,120
Fish meal 1,200 1 544 1,852,800 $8,905,920
Soy meal 117,204 660 77,354,640
Cotton cake 11,184 375 4,194,000
Sunflower cake 5,532 484 2,677,488 $84,226,128
Total 145,320 95,869,056
Source: Stockfeeds Manufacturers Association of Zimbabwe

In the past, CSC had rendering facilities which processed blood meal (BM) and MBM which went into
feed manufacture. Years of under-investment and depressed liquidity have resulted in drop i the C“C s
throughput to less than 2 000 animals per month and stoppage of rendering activities. Unfortunately,
private abattoirs are not permitted to process MBM and BM due to stringent EU conditions that still
prevail in Zimbabwe. What this has meant in practice is that valuable raw materials are wasted, forcing
stockfeed manufacturers to increasingly rely on importation to fill the livestock protein raw material
supply gap. The potential of the rendering industry is significant given the huge growth in the poultry
industry. 40 000mt of broiler meat was produced in formal poultry abattoirs during 2015 and could
have potentially generated 2 000mt of BM and 3 400mt of feather meal.

Therefore, domestic processing of livestock by-products is patently necessary in order to reduce current
wastages and environmental pollution and to expand employment opportunities. Livestock production
and processing can also be a route to the development of rural agro-industries and stem the rural to
urban migration.

4.5.3 VAT on Mechanically Deboned Meat


Meat processing industry is a high growth industry making use of by-products of the abattoir industry,
including fats and trimmings to make sausages, tinned products and polonies. Mechanically deboned
meat (MDM), a product of deboned chicken production for the European and American markets, is a
cheap extender used in processed foods. In general, it constitutes 30% of the raw materials used by the
meat processing industry. However, current imports of MDM attract a duty of 40%, similar to duties
applied on most finished food products. Applying such punitive duty on a raw material makes processed
products non-competitive relative to imports from South Africa. It is important to note that South
African meat processors also import their MDM raw material supplies as they do not have the scale of
economies to produce it. Stakeholders suggest that the duty charged on imports of MDM be reduced
from 40 to 5% with stringent caveats to prevent the abuse of MDM in the form of direct retailing to
consumers, which pose a health risks.

64
5.0 Conclusions and recommendations
This review identifies a multitude of regulatory constraints and offers a number of
recommendations for the country to attain its national economic and livestock sectoral goals.

5.1 Broad Policy Recommendations


Zimbabwe is now operating in a vastly different farming landscape compared to pre-2000 because of
the wide-ranging land reform programme. This calls for a very different livestock policy which
emphasises greater intensification and diversification into species that do not require a lot of land.
Value chain stakeholders welcome the recognition of livestock as an important sub-sector through the
creation of a separate Deputy Minister's post within MoAMID and the development of a value-chain
focused livestock policy with wide participation of stakeholders. However, this new policy framework
has yet to be formally adopted by government and accompanying strategies have not yet been
developed to implement the policy. As the review of key regulatory constraints shows, a multitude of
regulations exist that go against the attainment of goals in the livestock policy.

Growth of some small livestock species is also being hampered by lack of policy alignment between
agricultural and environmental ministries. This applies to fish and quail farming where the two
ministries are at odds regarding which should regulate the sub-sector. Most fish farming involves pond
culture where farmers buy fingerlings and feed them to market weight. This is similar to broiler
production where farmers buy day-old chicks and feed them to market weight. The Ministry of
Environment, Water and Climate has regulations that guide catcher fisheries which are different to pond
fish farming. Similarly, quail farming involves breeding of exotic quail birds for meat and eggs. The quail
species utilised by farmers are not related to wild quail found in Zimbabwe and there is no risk of cross
breeding between the species. For these reasons it is recommended that quail and pond fish farming be
managed under MoAMID to avoid conflicting regulations.

5.2 Livestock input regulations


Improving the competitiveness of the livestock sector requires that Zimbabwean products are produced
in a cost effective manner. The review shows that regulations exist that unnecessarily increase the cost
of acquisition of raw materials. Those affecting access to locally produced feed raw materials include a
liberal processed grain import policy; GMB pricing policy; AMA registration requirements and VAT policy
on by-products used in feeds. The study recommends the following:

 MoIC and MoAMID should discourage the importation of flour to boost local milling capacity,
encourage contract farming of wheat, and improved availability of brans at reasonable prices to
feed plants.
 The GMB pricing policy for maize discourages contract farming arrangements as farmers side-
market their maize to the GMB. The study recommends to either let GMB buy at going market
prices of set a GMB floor price mid-way between Zambian producer price and landed price of
Zambian maize into Zimbabwe.

65
 The high AMA annual registration fees without apparent benefits to traders in raw material are
imposing an unnecessary cost burden, which are passed onto feed mills. The study recommends
removal of AMA annual registration fees.
 There is need to foster clarity regarding VAT on wheat and maize brans which are key raw
materials in feed manufacture. These products are not consumed directly in end-markets but
are used as raw materials for stockfeeds. At a meeting held in December 2015, ZIMRA
acknowledged that brans used for the manufacture of stock feeds are zero rated and agreed to
publish a communique clarifying this issue. To date, this communique has not been issued and
some industries are being obliged to pay VAT on brans. The study recommends clear regulatory
notice shared with all regional ZIMRA officers and by-product manufacturers (millers, oilseed
expressors and crushers) on zero-rated by-products for feed manufacture.
 VAT is being levied on molasses a key cattle feed raw material. Molasses needs to be zero rated
like other by-products used in feeds (e.g. soya bean meal, maize bran and wheat bran). This is
already provided for in the VAT Act.

There are a number of constraints for importing raw materials. Importers are required to register with
the AMA and pay annual fees and with the NBA if imported products are subject to GMO-free
certification. The current import permit application is cumbersome leading to delays.

 There seems no basis for AMA to licence annually feed manufacturers and commodity traders. It
is proposed feed manufacturers and raw material importers be exempt from these taxations to
reduce the cost of feeds
 The study suggest removing requirement for annual registration fee while NBA continue to
charge the per shipment processing fee. In addition, there is need to remove wheat grain and
bran from list requiring GMO-free certificate
 There is need to streamline the import permit process. If CoG permits used to take only 5 days
in 2014 there is no reason why we should be taking up to a month.

5.3 Farm related regulations


Sustainable agriculture requires that production processes do as little damage to the environment as
possible. Thus there is need for environmental safeguards to ensure sustainable agricultural
development. However, a number of EMA regulations do not adequately take the Zimbabwean context
into account. Case in point are the regulations on emissions control. According to farmers, effluent
from farming processes such as dairy, piggeries and poultry houses are not environmentally bad but
contribute to crop nutrition in the form of manure, some of which is re- cycled to produce on-farm feed
(maize grain, soya bean, maize silage etc). The scale of production among on Zimbabwean farmers is
very small compared to countries such as Europe or the United States. At current scales of production,
all effluent and solid wastes can be absorbed by the on-farm environment with little escape to
constitute pollution. EMA regulations appear to be based on intensive production in developed
countries, most of which are in temperate climates where on-farm environments are unable to absorb
wastes generated by livestock production. Also of note is the low usage of mineral fertilisers in
Zimbabwe which makes crop farming an environmental bad through excessive mining of soil nutrients. It
is recommended that EMA stops levying farmers based on how much effluent or solid wastes are

66
produced by their livestock operations and, instead, provide extension on proper ways to turn these
wastes into valuable crop nutrition resources to enhance on-farm productivity.

Farmers also object to the need for registration, annual and monitoring fees for using pesticides and
agrochemicals or for carrying more than 200 litres of fuel. Farmers argue that no modern commercial
farming can occur without these inputs. The prudent intervention which EMA can provide is education
on the proper storage and use of such products.

Where farmers are in agreement with EMA is the need to encourage erection of fire guards and punitive
penalties for starting fires which reduces the availability of grazing during the dry months. These
regulations contribute directly to productivity in the livestock sector.

5.4 Marketing related regulations


The review highlighted cases where excessive taxation within livestock markets is reducing the incentive
for commercialisation and the lack of supportive institutions is causing increased transactions costs and
disincentives for producers.

An example of excessive taxation is the RDC levies in livestock marketing. The stated purpose of levying
is to sustain the provision of services to farmers. However, if levies are too high (and in some instances,
amount to 10.5% of the purchase value of a beast), perverse outcomes ensue, such as the deliberate
evasion of formal cattle sales which encourages illegal movements and counteracts disease control
measures. It has been noted that differential rates are being charged for the sa e se i es ‘DC s. I
addition, the collection of the levy is not uniform at all slaughter points, and consequently hampers the
orderly marketing of cattle and meat products. The study recommends RDCs charge a levy based on a
flat fee per animal traded at auctions, in the amount comparable with similar levies in neighbouring
countries such as Botswana, Zambia and Namibia who draw a significant amount of their processed beef
from the smallholder sector. Marketing levies in these countries cost $2 per head. A similar fee is
proposed for Council services provided at auctions. In addition, it is recommended for RDCs to charge a
fixed development levy of $2 per head for cattle sold to abattoirs for slaughter but no charge for cattle
sold to farmers for their herd building investments.

Another example of excessive taxation is the standard rating (i.e. 15%) for VAT purposes of sheep, goat
and rabbit meat. Other meats (beef, broiler and pork) and milk products are zero rated for VAT
purposes and meat from sheep and goats, predominately owned by poor households in smallholder
farming areas, is relatively more expensive compared to the other livestock proteins. The transfer of
table eggs from zero rated to VAT exemption early in 2016 has meant producers can no longer claim
VAT on inputs used in egg production as producers of milk, broiler meat and beef which are currently
zero rated. These regulations are counter to commercialisation of these livestock species which are
more prevalent in low income smallholder farming areas. There is need to zero rate sheep and goat
meat and table eggs for VAT purposes to foster competitiveness of these livestock products and
encourage their commercialisation.

67
Transactions costs in livestock trade are eating into returns from livestock production and trade. The
review identifies two key institutional limitations that are leading to increased transactions costs and
acting as disincentives within the livestock sector. Lack of a simple livestock identification and
traceability system that is accessible to smallholder farmers not only makes it costly to exchange cattle
but makes it difficult to control livestock movements for disease control and to identify cattle to owners
in the case of theft and recovery. DLVS, livestock commodity associations, unions and the ZRP are
currently discussing a framework for a simple livestock identification and traceability system. This needs
to be supported and implemented by Government to reduce the transactions costs of livestock trade.

A second improper institutional arrangement acting as a disincentive to cattle farmers is the outdated
carcass classification and grading system which penalises good quality beef from indigenous small
framed cattle breeds. Not only does this lead to poor prices for cattle farmed by smallholders but it
discourages the keeping of indigenous breeds that have been proved to be the most fertile and adapted
to local conditions, especially given the worsening weather conditions due to climate change.
Stakeholders have discussed and agreed upon a carcass grading system that does not penalise farmers
of small framed indigenous breeds which needs to be formalised and implemented by the MAMID.

5.5 Processing related regulations


Prior to 2012, abattoirs and milk processing plants were only required to register with the VPH and pay
annual inspection fees of $300 for class A, $200 for class B and $100 for class C abattoirs. Inspections of
abattoirs and milk processor ensure that they are compliant with hygienic slaughter protocols to ensure
safety of livestock products for consumers. However, post 2012 primary processing plants are now also
required to register with AMA as provided for under SI 147 of 2012 (Registration of Companies and
Submission of Returns) Regulations. Registration fees for Class A and B abattoirs are $1 000 per annum
while the registration fees for a Class C abattoir are $200 per annum. These fees are more than those
charged by the VPH, an institution that provides a public service. AMA fees are not linked to any service
provided by the institution. It is recommended that statutory Instrument 147 of 2012 be repealed by
AMA to reduce the regulatory burden it has imposed on the processing industry.

From 2007 onwards, processors have been subjected to an array of registrations with EMA which
requires annual registration and monitoring fees as well as quarterly disposal fees under SI 7 of 2007
(effluent and solid waste disposal) and SI 72 of 2009 (air pollution). A small dairy processor needs to pay
at least $4 500 per year in registration, inspection and disposal fees. This adds to fixed costs and makes
processed products non-competitive. Livestock industry stakeholders argue that this policy which
advocates payment for the right to pollute does not solve pollution problems. They prefer that EMA
work together with industry on safe ways to dispose of waste. Abattoirs have invested in waste disposal
structures under the Animal Health Act while milk processors are also required to have acceptable waste
disposal structures under the Dairy Act. There is need therefore for EMA to work with Dairy Services
and DLVS to avoid duplication. Only processors who do not adopt safe ways of handling waste should
be required to pay punitive penalties.

68
Public Health (Abattoir, Animal and Bird Slaughter and Meat Hygiene) regulations of 1995(SI 50 of 1995)
require that all abattoirs are registered by DLVS. The cost of registration is $400 for Grade A, $300 for
Grade B and $200 for Grade C abattoirs. In addition, abattoirs pay $2 per carcass as inspection fees.
The DLPD's Meat Graders under SI 182 of 2000 also charge $1.00 per carcass for grading. However,
some municipal councils also charge for meat inspection under the public health regulations implying
double taxation. In Masvingo the municipality charges inspection fees of $3 per head while VPH charges
$2, a total of $5 per head in foregone revenue to the farmer. There is therefore need to rationalise
inspection fees. It is recommended that MAMID and Ministry of Health and Child Care agree on a policy
that in abattoirs under DLPD inspection regime, municipality should not be allowed to also charge for
the same services.

Besides the requirement to register with the VPH, abattoir operators are now also required to register
with AMA as provided for under SI 147 of 2012 (Registration of Companies and Submission of Returns)
Regulations. The AMA registration fees for Class A and B abattoirs is $1 000 per annum while the
registration fees for a Class C abattoir is $200 per annum. These annual registration fees are more than
those charged by VPH for little to no services rendered to abattoirs. VPH fees cover services of
inspection of facilities to ensure that products coming from plants are safe for the market. AMA
justification for the fees is that there is need to collect statistics from producers, traders, processors and
retailers. This is despite the fact that the Meat Graders section of DLPD already collects such
information while AMA has not yet produced comprehensive information on slaughter indicators. The
study concludes that the double registrations introduced by AMA are unnecessary and merely increase
the high cost of production by value chain participants in the livestock sector at a time when consumer
demand has declined. To improve competitiveness of livestock value chains there is need for AMA to
reduce or eliminate the AMA annual registration fees.

5.6 Post processing related regulations


The review revealed that a number of policies are hindering the full realisation of value in the livestock
value chain. For instance, the current policy to encourage local beneficiation of hides and skins through
punitive taxation of raw hides exports has discouraged the collection of hides from rural butcheries and
led to a huge stockpile and spoilage of hides. In another example, strict controls on the use of rendered
abattoir wastes such as blood, feathers and bone trimmings in stockfeeds at a time when significant
costs are being incurred to import animal protein raw materials for feed manufacture, has stifled
investment in value addition by rural based abattoirs and increased pollution. Trimmings and fats from
abattoirs are raw materials in processed meats production. However, an imported product -
mechanically deboned meat (MDM) - is a key input in this production process. Current high duties on
MDM are hindering value addition in this sub-sector.

In the 2015 Mid-Term Fiscal Policy Review Government with effect from 1 October 2015 imposed an
export surtax on all exports of hides and skins at the rate of 15% of FOB value or US$0.75 per kg,
whichever was higher. Due to current low international hide prices, the surtax of $0.75c/kg translates
into an export tax rate of nearly 90% which effectively amounts to a ban on exports. However, the local
tanneries have been unable to absorb all hides on offer due to under-capitalisation and abattoirs are

69
being offered very low prices. This has led to spoilage of hides and a loss to the national economy. It is
suggested that Government rescinds the surtax of $0.75/kg and replace it with an export surtax of 15%
and 10% on raw hides and wet-blue tanned hides, respectively, and a special tax of 15% on imports of
leather products. The funds raised by the taxes should be deposited into a Leather Development Fund,
managed by a Committee of value chain stakeholders as is the case with the Dairy Revitalisation
Programme. There is also need to ensure adequate supply of hides to local tanneries through a MoIC
and MAMID determined quarterly export quota that reflects effective demand by tanneries.

Mechanically deboned meat (MDM), a product of deboned chicken production for the European and
American markets, currently attracts a duty of 40%, similar to duties applied on most finished food
products. Meat processing industry is a high growth industry making use of by-products of the abattoir
industry, including fats and trimmings to make sausages, tinned products and polony. MDM, a cheap
meat extender is included at 30% in such processed foods. The current punitive duty on a raw material
makes local processed products non-competitive relative to imports from South Africa. It is suggested
that the duty charged on imports of MDM be reduced by ZIMRA from 40 to 5% with stringent caveats to
prevent the abuse of MDM in the form of direct retailing to consumers.

In the past, CSC had rendering facilities which processed blood meal (BM) and meat and bone meal
(MBM) which went into feed manufacture. Years of under-investment and depressed liquidity have
resulted in drop in throughput and stoppage of rendering activities. But private abattoirs are not
permitted to process MBM and BM due to stringent EU conditions that still prevail in Zimbabwe. In
2015, $11.6 million was spent either on synthetic amino acids methionine and lysine, or imported meat
and bone meal (MBM) and fish meal. These imports could have been avoided if the country utilised its
abattoir wastes as raw material protein in feeds. The potential of the rendering industry is significant
given the huge growth in the poultry industry. Extra benefits include the reduction in waste from
processing plants. There is need for the DVS to revise its guidelines for abattoir waste rendering in line
with FAO minimum standards that allows cheap and safe transformation of abattoir wastes into
valuable feed raw materials by private abattoirs.

Conclusion

The Government should engage with private sector associations and individual companies in a
substantial dialogue to reduce these constraints on growth in the livestock sector, which is a significant
source of livelihood for large sections of the country. Resolving these issues can provide a boost to
industry, households, and local and national budgets as inefficiencies are worked out, local production
volumes increase, and more dealings are conducted through formal channels.

70
ANNEX: Summary of regulatory constraints, impacts and suggested reforms

A. Input Related Policy Constraints


A1: Constraints to locally produced livestock inputs

Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms


AMA 1) Increase in overhead cost for contractors Remove all annual registration fees
Excessive annual registration fees charged and grain and oilseed buyers and sellers
by the Agricultural Marketing Authority which are passed on to users of these
(AMA) under Statutory Instrument 147 of products including feed manufacturers.
2012 for buyers of grain and oilseeds, the 2) The high registration fees discourage small
main suppliers of these raw materials to volume buyers and sellers of grain and oilseed
feed mills; and SI 140 of 2013. Annual to participate in the marketing system.
registration fees demanded by the two SIs 3) The high registration fees also discourages
include $1000 to operate as a trader, $1000 companies from engaging farmers in contract
to operate as a contractor and $500 farming arrangements.
operate a warehouse.
VAT 1) Standard rating of molasses for VAT 1) Zero rate molasses used for stock
Inconsistent application of VAT zero rating purposes leads to an increase in the cost of feed manufacture
for by-products of milling and crushing used dairy and beef pen fattening feeds 2) Clear regulatory notice shared
in feed manufacture. 2) Application of 15% VAT on zero rated by- with all regional ZIMRA officers and
1) 15% VAT on molasses is inconsistent with products, though it can be claimed later by-product manufacturers (millers,
SI 273 of 2003 which zero rates agriculture against income tax leads to liquidity problems oilseed expressors and crushers) on
processing by-products used in animal for feed manufacturers zero-rated by-products for feed
feeds. manufacture
2) ZIMRA regional officers sometimes
standard rate soya bean cake/grain bran
contrary to SI 273 of 2003
MoAMID Price policy 1) The high prices have led to side-marketing Either let GMB buy at going market
MoAMID has been setting GMB pricing to GMB by contracted maize farmers, leading prices or set a GMB floor price mid-
grain at greater than import parity while to discouragement of contract farming. way between Zambian producer
GMB has been charging less than import 2) Low prices charged to GMB milling and price and landed price of Zambian
parity price to its processing divisions feeds divisions give them an unfair advantage maize into Zimbabwe
over private processors.
3) Subsidizing farmers by paying greater than
import parity increases government
expenditure
MoIC and MoAMID on Flour Imports Excessive imports of processed flour at the MoIC and MoAMID should
Government allows 4,000 MT of flour to be expense of raw grain has reduced capacity discourage the importation of flour
imported each month for blending utilisation in the milling industry, and starved to boost local milling capacity,
purposes. However, these limits have feed mills of by-products leading to high cost encourage contract farming of
routinely been exceeded of by-products and hence feeds wheat, and improved availability of
brans at reasonable prices to feed
plants

71
A2: Constraints to accessing imported livestock inputs

Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms


AMA registration fees 1) the AMA annual fees are $600 more than There seems no basis for AMA to
Despite being required to register as feed annual registration with Farm Feeds and licence annually feed
manufacturers under the Farm Feeds and Remedies Institute; manufacturers and commodity
Remedies Act, feed manufacturers who 2) AMA's role in raw material importation is traders. It is proposed feed
import some of their raw materials have just to provide a letter of support. There manufacturers and raw material
been since 2013 required to also register seems to be duplication in the role since the importers be exempt from these
and pay annual fees of $1000 under AMA's Economics and Markets Division in the taxations to reduce the cost of
SI 140 of 2013 MoAMID also scrutinises import application. feeds

NBA for GMO certification In addition to the excessively high annual The study suggest removing
The National Biotechnology Authority (NBA) registration fees, importers also need to pay requirement for annual registration
charges an annual registration fee of $500 for certification of shipment in the country of fee while NBA continue to charge
for importers of commodities that are origin which leads to high cost of imported the per shipment processing fee. In
subject to GMO-free certification. Though raw materials. When one adds the extra cost addition, there is need to remove
provided for in the NBA Act there is no of registration with AMA and Farm Feeds and wheat grain and bran from list
Statutory Instrument to support the Remedies Institute these multiple annual fees requiring GMO-free certificate
regulation. In addition there is a fee add significant amounts to fixed costs of feed
payable for each shipment. Wheat grain manufacturers. Also of concern is the
and bran are among commodities that unnecessary costs borne by importers wheat
require a GMO-free certificate though there grain and bran which do not have GMO
is no commercial GMO wheat under varieties currently in commercial production.
production in the world.
MoAMID for CoG permit For example the largest hatching egg import There is need to streamline the
Importers of hatching eggs, grain, soya agent for the local poultry industry has import permit process. If CoG
meal, wheat and maize bran, minerals and experienced delays of a month to six weeks at permits used to take only 5 days in
vitamins, powdered milk, breeder day-old MOAMID to process Control of Goods (CoG) 2014 there is no reason why we
chicks, breeding animals and semen need permits. Up to December 2014, CoG permits should be taking up to a month.
to obtain an import permit. To obtain a took as few as 3-5 days to process. Delays in
permit as required by the Control of Goods processing of permits therefore increases the
Act, importers have to get approval from risk of local hatcheries not been able to satisfy
numerous agencies including DVS, NBA, their contractual obligations with suppliers,
AMA, E&M, Plant Protection, and MoAMID. leading to losses due to breach of contract.
The time taken to get final permit is
currently as long as --- weeks.

72
B: Farm level regulatory constraints
Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms
EMA: Environment Management (Effluent This regulation affects the cost of production The scale and intensity of livestock
and Solid Waste Disposal) Regulations of in livestock enterprises such as poultry, production in Zimbabwe are not at
2007(SI 6 of 2007) require farming piggeries, dairy and pen-feeding operations a level that precludes transforming
operations that generate effluent and solid without contributing to environmental waste from production into
waste to register and pay an annual benefits since most wastes and effluent is valuable fertiliser inputs into crop
registration fee of $32; an annual used as fertiliser on farm. production which is an
inspection fee ranging from between $80 environmental 'good' rather than a
and $585 depending on assessed badness 'bad'. Thus penalties for creating
of the waste and a quarterly discharge fee an environmental are unwarranted.
based on estimated amount of waste What is required instead is
discharged with a minimum of $80 per extension on effective ways of
quarter. harnessing the fertility value of the
wastes
EMA: Environmental Management Since practically all crop and livestock farmers No modern productive farming can
(Hazardous Substances, Pesticides and store pesticides or veterinary vector control proceed without safe use of
other Toxic Substances) Regulations (SI 12 products and have to transport fuel for their veterinary vector control. Rather
of 2007) requires a person using herbicides, tractors they are required to register and pay than add costs to farm operations
pesticides, fungicides or any toxic the exorbitant fees and this increases the cost there is need to draft protocols on
substances for commercial agriculture or of livestock production. To put this into good agricultural practices on the
public health pest control or veterinary perspective the required annual fees are correct handling, storage and
vector control to have a license from EMA greater than revenue from sale of one steer handling of these essential
at an annual fee of between $457 and $672 which for a small scale emergent commercial chemicals.
depending on assessed toxicity of the farmer is a significant dent into profitability
agents used. In addition it requires farmers
who transport more than 200 litres of fuel
to obtain annual permits from EMA at a
cost of $200.

73
C: Regulatory constraints affecting marketing of livestock
Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms
Rural District Councils Not only is the charge excessive but the There is need to charge a levy
In the majority of cattle dependent rationale behind the charges has been based on a flat fee per animal
districts, Rural District Councils (RDC) have questionable. Though the guidelines seem to traded at auctions, in the amount
been charging a levy of 10.5% on all live imply the charges should be on cattle traded comparable with similar levies in
cattle sales. at council operated auctions, the current neighbouring countries such as
practice is to charge all cattle traded even Botswana, Zambia and Namibia
through private negotiation. RDC levies have who draw a significant amount of
also encouraged illegal livestock movements their processed beef from the
to evade taxation, leading to increased risk of smallholder sector. Marketing
an outbreak of disease. Charging levies on levies in these countries cost $2 per
farmer to farmer trade for herd building are head. A similar fee is proposed for
also taxed which discourages livestock Council services provided at
restocking investments. auctions. In addition, it is
recommended to charge a fixed
development levy of $2 per head
for cattle sold to abattoirs for
slaughter but no charge for cattle
sold to farmers for their herd
building investments.
DLVS and ZRP Cattle farmers and traders incur significant DLVS, livestock commodity
Zimbabwe does not have a comprehensive costs to navigate complex movement permits associations, unions and the ZRP
and functional livestock identification and and clearance procedures. This lowers profits are currently discussing a
traceability system to management cattle from sales of animals. framework for a simple livestock
movements and proof of ownership. Proof identification and traceability
of ownership is required by police, and system. This needs to be supported
results in involvement of third parties such and implemented by Government
as headmen and other witnesses. to reduce the transactions costs of
livestock trade
VAT regulations (MoFED): Standard rating of Sheep and Goat meat and There is need to zero rate sheep
Currently, sheep and goat meat is subject to the transfer of table eggs from zero rated to and goat meat and table eggs for
VAT of 15% when meat such as beef and VAT exemption increased the cost of these VAT purposes to foster
chicken is not. livestock products compared to milk, broiler competitiveness of these livestock
SI 9 of 2016, Value Added Tax (General) and beef which are currently zero rated. This products and encourage their
(Amendment) Regulations, 2016 (No. 40) is counter to commercialisation of these commercialisation
instituted in February 2016 transfers table livestock species which are more prevalent in
eggs from zero-rated to VAT exempt. low income smallholder farming areas.
DLPD Carcass Grading System Most cattle commercially traded on local Stakeholders and the DLPD have
In Zimbabwe carcass grading and markets are from smallholder farming areas drafted a grading system that
classification is still based on the old system dominated by small framed indigenous removes the bias on small framed
developed in the 1970s which was based on breeds. The current grading system unfairly adapted breed in the country. This
large framed exotic breeds that dominated discriminates against cattle from the system needs to be implemented
commercial cattle marketing at the time smallholder farming areas leading to by Government.
artificially low producer prices.

74
D: Regulatory constraints affecting processing of livestock
Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms
EMA: Environment Management (Effluent The regulation is currently being applied on discharge There is need to rationalise
and Solid Waste Disposal) Regulations of of abattoir wastes, boiler gaseous emissions from the conflict between Animal
2007(SI 6 of 2007) processing that generate heating fuel discharges and boiler waste water. The Health Act provisions, EMA
effluent and solid waste to register and pay problem with this regulation is that solid waste and and Municipal bye-laws to
an annual registration fee of $32; an annual effluent discharge is also covered under the Animal avoid overlapping taxation.
inspection fee ranging from between $80 Health Act which specifies the kind of investments
and $585 depending on assessed badness that need to be put in place for safe disposal of wastes
of the waste and a quarterly discharge fee (basis for registration by the VPH) as well as municipal
based on estimated amount of waste bye-laws when waste are discharged into sewer
discharged with a minimum of $80 per systems (subject to charges by municipalities). There
quarter. thus double taxation. In addition, waste boiler waster
is a benign waste with no effect on the environment.
EMA: EMA issues emission licenses for air This regulation has been applied on processing plants This levy on factory fuel
pollution processes that are prescribed that have forklifts and generators - a necessity for powered vehicles and
under SI 72 of 2009. Annual registration most livestock processing plants due to erratic power generators needs to be
fee - $32; annual monitoring fee - $100-555 supply. Processors are therefore being punished for removed as it constitutes a
depending on toxicity; and quarterly poor electricity service provision. Government double taxation as well as
discharge fee based on estimated amount through its taxation on fuels and vehicle registration punishment for failures by
emitted(minimum $100 per quarter) already has a carbon tax that levies emissions. These other service providers to
levies therefore constitute a double taxation on provide clean energy.
abattoirs.
Veterinary Public Health and Meat There is double taxation in for meat inspection in There is need to rationalise
Inspection Regulations places such as Masvingo. In Masvingo the municipality inspection fees. In abattoirs
Public Health (Abattoir, Animal and Bird charges inspection fees of $3 per head while VPH under DLVS inspection
Slaughter and Meat Hygiene) regulations of charges $2, a total of $5 per head in foregone revenue regime, municipality should
1995(SI 50 of 1995) require that all to the farmer. not be allowed to also
abattoirs are registered by DLVS. The cost charge for the same
of registration is $400 for Grade A, $300 for services.
Grade B and $200 for Grade C abattoirs. In
addition, abattoirs pay $2 per carcass as
inspection fees. The DLPD's Meat Graders
under SI 182 of 2000 also charge $1.00 per
carcass for grading. However, some
municipal councils (e.g. Masvingo) also
charge for meat inspection under the public
health regulations.
AMA AMA annual registration fees are more than those The double registrations are
Besides the requirement to register with charged by VPH for little to no services rendered to unnecessary and merely
the VPH, abattoir operators are now also abattoirs. VPH fees cover services of inspection of increase the high cost of
required to register with AMA as provided facilities to ensure that products coming from plants production by value chain
for under SI 147 of 2012 (Registration of are safe for the market. AMA justification for the fees participants in the livestock
Companies and Submission of Returns) is that there is need to collect statistics from sector at a time when
Regulations. The registration fees for Class producers, traders, processors and retailers. This is consumer demand has
A and B abattoirs is $1 000 per annum while despite the fact that the Meat Graders section of declined. To improve
the registration fees for a Class C abattoir is DLPD already collect such information while AMA has competitiveness of livestock
$200 per annum. not yet produced comprehensive information on value chains there is need
slaughter indicators. to reduce or eliminate the
AMA registration and
annual fees

75
E: Regulatory constraints affecting post processing of livestock products
Regulatory Constraint Nature of impact on livestock sector Suggested reforms
Export tax on raw hides exports(MoFED) Due to current low international hide prices, It is suggested that Government
In the Mid-Term Fiscal Policy Review the surtax of $0.75c/kg translates into an rescinds the surtax of $0.75/kg as it
delivered by Hon Chinamasa at the export tax rate of nearly 90% which effectively is not viable and replace it with an
beginning of the third quarter of 2015, amounts to a ban on exports. However, the export surtax of 15% and 10% on
Government with effect from 1 October local tanneries have been unable to absorb all both raw and wet blue hides,
2015 imposed an export surtax on all hides on offer due to under-capitalisation and respectively and a special tax of
exports of hides and skins at the rate of abattoirs are being offered very low prices. 15% on imports of leather products.
15% of FOB value or US$0.75 per kg, This has led to spoilage of hides and a loss to There is also need to ensure
whichever was higher. the national economy. adequate supply of hides to local
tanneries through a determined
quarterly export quota that reflects
effective demand by tanneries.
The funds raised by the taxes
should be deposited into a Leather
Development Fund, managed by a
Committee of value chain
stakeholders as is the case with the
Dairy Revitalisation Programme.
Duty on MDM imports(MoFED) Meat processing industry is a high growth It is suggested that the duty
Mechanically deboned meat (MDM), a industry making use of by-products of the charged on imports of MDM be
product of deboned chicken production for abattoir industry, including fats and trimmings reduced from 40 to 5% with
the European and American markets, to make sausages, tinned products and stringent caveats to prevent the
currently attracts a duty of 40%, similar to polony. MDM, a cheap extender is included at abuse of MDM in the form of direct
duties applied on most finished food 30% in such processed foods. The current retailing to consumers.
products. punitive duty on a raw material makes
processed products non-competitive relative
to imports from South Africa.
Processing by-products of livestock In 2015, $11.6 million was spent on both There is need for the DVS to revise
processing(DLVS) synthetic amino acids methionine and lysine its guidelines for abattoir waste
In the past, CSC had rendering facilities or imported meat and bone meal (MBM) and rendering in line with FAO
which processed blood meal (BM) and meat fish meal. These imports could have been standards that allows cheap and
and bone meal (MBM) which went into avoided if the country utilised its abattoir safe transformation of abattoir
feed manufacture. Years of under- wastes as raw material protein in feeds. wastes into valuable feed raw
investment and depressed liquidity have The potential of the rendering industry is materials by private abattoirs
resulted in drop in throughput and significant given the huge growth in the
stoppage of rendering activities. But poultry industry. Extra benefits include the
private abattoirs are not permitted to reduction in waste from processing plants
process MBM and BM due to stringent EU
conditions that still prevail in Zimbabwe.

76

You might also like