Unit 11
Unit 11
FUNCTIONS*
Structure
11.0 Objectives
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Convex Set and Convex Functions
11.2.1 Convex Combination and Convex Sets
11.2.2 Convex Sets, Convex and Concave Functions
11.3 Concave and Convex Functions and their Characteristics
11.3.1 Concave and Convex Functions
11.3.2 Point of Inflection
11.4 Quasi-Concavity and Quasi-Convexity
11.5 Economic Applications of Convexity and Concavity
11.6 Let Us Sum Up
11.7 Answers to Check Your Progress Exercises
11.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
• describe certain important geometric properties of Convex sets;
• understand the relation of a convex set with Convex and Concave
functions;
• explain concave and convex function along with their characteristics;
• define the concept of Quasi-Concavity and Quasi-Convexity; and
• discuss some Economic applications of Convexity and Concavity.
11.1 INTRODUCTION
In the previous Unit, while discussing higher order derivatives, we discussed
concave and convex function. We saw that concave and convex functions are
defined in terms of their second-order derivatives. This unit carries forward
that discussion of concavity and convexity. But along with functions, this unit
carries the discussion forward to the case of convex sets. We will learn to
appreciate the importance of convexity, although the crucial importance of
convexity in Economics will become apparent to you only in the units on
optimisation. In this unit we will focus on the idea that concavity and convexity
are to do with the shapes that certain functions have. We shall see that
concavity and convexity of functions are features decided by the second order
derivatives of functions. We shall be relating the concept of convexity also to
the related but rather important concept of quasi-concavity. Throughout, we
shall also be describing some important economic applications of convexity.
We shall take functions, mainly from Microeconomics since you have a course
on Principles of Microeconomics in this semester, and see which of the
The definition of a convex set implies that the intersection of two convex sets
is a convex set. More generally, the intersection of a family of convex sets is a
196 convex set.
Anything that is hollow or dented, for example, a crescent shape, is non convex Concave and Convex
Functions
(Refer figure 11.1). In Figure 11.1 (a), the set Q is convex, since for this, all the
points of any line segment joining any pair of points of the set (here, v0 and v1)
will lie inside the given set Q. Whereas, in 11.1 (b), we have a non-convex set
R. In set R, not all the points of the line segment joining any pair of points of
the set (here, v2 and v3) lies inside the set R. Trivially, the empty set is convex.
Q R
v1
v3
v0 v2
Figure 11.1
For a concave function, the set below the function must be convex. Also, the
inequality in the expression above is reversed in the case of a concave function.
This we will see in more detail in subsequent sections.
197
Single-Variable
Optimisation
f (x) y = f (x)
Q
P R
x1 x0 x2 x
Consider the diagram above. For the function y = f(x), let f be a differentiable
convex function, and suppose x1<x2 and 0 <α <1, so that xo = α x1 + (1 − α ) x2 .
Now, let points P,Q, R and S in the xy-plane be defined as in the above figure.
Since f is convex, R cannot lie above S; therefore the slope of the chord PR
cannot be more than the slope of the chord PQ. This inequality holds even as α
tends to 1, in which case R approaches P along the curve and the slope of PR
approaches the slope of the curve at P. Hence the slope of the curve at P will
be less than the slope of the chord PQ. Thus,
f ( x2 ) − f ( x1 )
f ′ ( x1 ) ≤
x2 − x1
198
If f is a differentiable concave function, then Concave and Convex
Functions
f ( a + h ) ≤ f ( a ) + hf ′ ( a )
Let us, by way of preamble, mention that convex and concave functions have
to do with the second derivative of functions. So as background let us recall
dy
that if we have y = f(x) as a function, then f ′( x ) = is also a function of x.
dx
Now if we take the derivative of f ′(x ) then it is a derivative of the first
derivative of y and is called the second derivative of y. It is denoted in several
d (dy / dx) d [ f ′( x)] d 2 y
different ways: or or 2 or f ′′( x ) .
dx dx dx
Just as the first derivative is a function whose derivative can be found (called
the second derivative), the second derivative, too, is a function whose
derivative can be found (and is called the third derivative, denoted by f ′′′(x ) .
If the first two derivatives of a function exist, we say that the function is twice-
differentiable. Twice-differentiable functions are very useful in Economics.
Let us consider a function f (x) = x2. Its first derivative is 2x and the second
derivative is 2. In the domain x< 0, we have f`′(x) = 2x but since x < 0, 2x< 0.
So in the domain x< 0, f (x) = x2 falls. As x increases, the slope falls in absolute
value which means that since the slope is negative, the value of the slope is
actually increasing in x. Thus the second derivative is positive. We state that a
200
twice differentiable function f (x)is convex if, at all points on its domain, Concave and Convex
f ′′( x ) ≥ 0 . A twice differentiable function f (x) is strictly convex if f ′′(x ) > 0 , Functions
except possibly at a single point. For example, consider the function f (x) = x4.
It’s second derivative is 12x2, which is positive for all x except x = 0 where the
second derivative becomes zero.
Now consider the function f (x) = 10 – x2. We see that the first derivative is –
2x and the second derivative is – 2. Thus this function is decreasing in x for all
x> 0 and is increasing in x for all x< 0. The slope, however, is falling for all
values of x. This means that when f`′(x) > 0, it is becoming less steep, while
when f`′(x) < 0 the function is becoming more steep in absolute value, but the
slope is becoming more negative. Since the function f (x) = 10 – x2 has a
negative second derivative, it has properties that are opposite of those of a
convex function. It is a concave function. A twice differentiable function f (x)
is concave if f ′′( x ) ≤ 0 on all points of its domain. Also, a twice differentiable
function f (x) is strictly concave if f ′′( x ) < 0 on all points of its domain except
possibly at a single point.
Two points can be made here. First, a linear function, since it has a second
derivative equal to zero, satisfies the condition for both a convex function as
well as a concave function. Secondly, since multiplying by – 1 reverses an
inequality, we could say that f (x) is concave if – f (x) is convex, and that f (x) is
strictly concave if – f (x) is strictly convex.
201
Single-Variable ii) f ′′(a ) ≤ 0 implies that the function changes at a decreasing rate as the
Optimisation
function passes through point a and the function is concave from below at
the point x = a.
The numerical value of f ′′(a ) shows how quickly the change in the value of
f(x) changes and how great is the curvature of the curve y = f(x)at the point x =
a.
11.3.2 Points of Inflection
The functions which we study in Economics sometimes have the property that
they are convex in some part of the domain but concave in other parts. Such
points where a function changes from being concave to being convex, or from
being convex to being concave, are called inflection points. The curve changes
from one side of the tangent to the other side of the tangent. In short, x = k is an
inflection point, if f ′′( x ) changes sign at x = k. We call the point [k, f(k)] an
inflection point on the graph.
The first is a necessary condition for a point of inflection, and the second is a
sufficient one.
If f(x) has a third derivative then an alternative criterion can be given in terms
of the third derivative. If f ′′′(k ) is negative at a point where f ′′(k ) = 0 then
f ′(x ) is maximum at x = k (note that we are not saying that f (x) is maximum
but that f ′(x ) is maximum). If the third derivative is positive, then f ′(x ) is
minimum at x = k.
202
Concave and Convex
11.4 QUASI-CONCAVITY AND QUASI- Functions
CONVEXITY
Let us now discuss the concept of quasi-concavity and quasi-convexity. In next
section, we will get to know the application of concavity and convexity of a
function in Economics. Before that we discuss here a weaker requirement for
several Economic situations. This condition is called quasi-concavity and
quasi-convexity. Quasi-concavity and quasi-convexity, just like concavity and
convexity, can be either strict or non-strict. What do quasi-concavity and quasi-
convexity mean? Let us look at it geometrically:
Let x and y be two distinct points in the domain of a function f, and let the
segment xy in the domain of the function give rise to the arc CD on the graph
of the function. Suppose point D is higher or equal in height to point C. Then
the function is said to be quasi-concave if all points on the arc CD (other than
C and D) are higher than or equal in height at point C. The function f would be
a quasi-convex one if all points on the arc CD are equal to or lower in height at
point D. The function f would be strictly quasi-concave (quasi-convex) if all
points on the arc are strictly higher than point C (lower than point D). We may
state here that any strictly quasi-concave (strictly quasi-convex) is quasi-
concave (quasi-convex) but the converse is not true. Usually, a quasi-concave
function that is not concave has a shape like a bell or like a portion of a bell,
and a quasi-convex has a shape like an inverted bell. A concave function is a
little like a dome and a convex function like an inverted dome.
( )≥ ( )⇒ [ + (1 − ) ] ≥ ( )
A function is quasi-convex if and only if, for any distinct points x and y in the
convex set domain of f, and for 0 < λ < 1,
f ( y ) ≥ f ( x ) ⇒ f λ x + (1 − λ ) y ≤ f ( y )
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
ii) ( )=5 −7
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
iii) ( )=
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
2) Describe the concavity and/or convexity of f(x) = 7 − 42 + 12 +
97 over its domain?
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
3) The notion of Quasiconcavity is weaker than the notion of Concavity, do
you agree?
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
4) For what value of pand q will the graph of the function given by
f(x) = px3 + qx2 pass through (−1, 1) and has an inflection point at x = ?
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
……………………………………………………………………………..
204
Concave and Convex
11.5 ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF Functions
CONVEXITY AND CONCAVITY
In Economics, convexity is one of the most important mathematical properties.
For example, in utility maximisation problems, an optimal basket of goods
occurs where the consumer's convex preference set is supported by his budget
constraint. For a given utility function, and any reference bundle X (x, y),
where x and y are the two goods— the set of all the bundles which are at least
as good as bundle X, is usually assumed to be the upper level set which is the
convex set. This upper level set consists of the consumer’s indifference curve
(IC) and all the set of x and y lying above it (Refer shaded region in Figure
11.3). This assumption of convexity simply means that consumer attains higher
utility from consuming a convex combination of two goods than the extreme
bundles, that is, if consumer is indifferent between bundles A and B then she
prefers the average bundle C, given by A + (1 − ) B for ∈ [0, 1]to either A
or B. Convex preferences results in ICs which are convex to the origin. By
convexity, C = A + (1 − ) B lies on a higher indifference curve, for ∈ [0,
1].
y
A Consumer’s upper-level
C Convex Set
If the preference set is convex, then the consumer's set of optimal decisions is a
convex set, for example, a unique optimal basket (or even a line segment of
optimal baskets). If a preference set is non-convex, then some prices produce a
budget supporting two different optimal consumption decisions (for instance,
happens when consumer faces a choice between two substitutes). The
indifference curve (IC) shows different combinations of two goods, here x and
y, giving equal level of satisfaction (or utility) to the consumer. Notice it is
downward (negative) sloping and convex-shaped. Slope of an IC is the
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)— the rate at which a consumer is willing
∆! #! $%&
to trade good x for good y, MRS = or or , where MUx and MUy refer
∆" #" $%'
to the Marginal utility from consumption of additional units of good x and
(% (%
good y, respectively, [MUx = (" and MUy = (! , for a utility function U(x, y)]
(refer Figure 11.4).Downward or a negative slope of IC implies that an increase
in consumption of one good must be accompanied by decrease in consumption
of another good, so as to keep the satisfaction level constant.
Good y
Good y
∆+
MRS = P
∆,
∆+ Q
R
∆x
IC IC
0 Good x 0 Good x
Q = f (L)
L0 L (labour)
207
Single-Variable
Optimisation
Good y
A
11 B
10 C
8
D
5
PPC/PPF
0 1 2 3 4 Good x
Figure 11.7: Production Possibility Curve
This was the first of the two units in this fourth Block of your present course.
The Block is on single-variable optimisation, and this unit has concepts and
ideas to help you prepare for the next unit on optimisation methods.
The current unit discussed in detail the very important concept of Convex Sets
and Convexity. Applications of Concave and Convex functions occur
frequently in Economics and are a foundation for optimisation, which is a
central and recurrent idea in Economics.
The unit began by explaining the idea of a convex combination and then used
that to introduce you to the concept of a convex set. The unit then moved to a
description of the relationship between a convex set and a convex function. In
the next section a calculus based discussion of convex and concave functions
using second derivatives was presented. It was seen that convex and concave
functions can be either increasing or decreasing. The conditions and criteria of
convex and concave functions were presented. This section also presented a
discussion of inflection points which are points at which the second derivative
is zero, and the curvature of the curve changes from convex to concave, or
vice-versa.
2) Although convex functions and convex sets are related concept, they are
also distinct concepts. In describing a function the word convex denotes
how the curve or surface bends itself, that is it talks about the bulge. In
the context of a set, the word convex specifies how the points in the set
are ‘stacked’ together, that is how dense is the set.
3) A convex function is a function with the property that the set of points
which are on or above its graph is a convex set. In terms of the definition
of a convex set that we just saw, a function is a convex function if it has
the property that the chord joining any two points on its graph lies on or
209
Single-Variable above the graph. For a function that is convex, the set above the function
Optimisation must be convex.
ii) Yes, MRS is diminishing for this utility function. Hint: MRS =
$%& !
⟹ " . As we move down the IC, that is, as consumption of good
$% '
x increases, the denominator gets bigger and MRS decreases.
2) The indifference curve for such an individual would bend away from the
origin and not towards it, that is, it will be concave-shaped instead of
convex. MRS is no longer diminishing along the indifference curve, that is,
the indifference curve exhibits increasing MRS.
3) Refer section 11.5 and answer.
210