Lance Taylor - Structuralist Macroecnomics - Applicable Models For The Third World-Basic Books Inc (1983)
Lance Taylor - Structuralist Macroecnomics - Applicable Models For The Third World-Basic Books Inc (1983)
Lance Taylor - Structuralist Macroecnomics - Applicable Models For The Third World-Basic Books Inc (1983)
Lance Taylor
ISBN O-MbS-DflEB^-M
Structuralist
Macro¬
economics
APPLICABLE MODELS FOR
THE THIRD WORLD
Lance Taylor
□3A3
Structuralist Macroeconomics
Structuralist
Macroeconomics
Applicable Modelsfor
the Third World
Lance Taylor
Taylor, Lance.
Structuralist macroeconomics.
Bibliography: p. 220
Includes index.
1. Underdeveloped areas—Mathematical models.
2. Macroeconomics. I. Title.
HC59.7.T372 1983 339’.0724 82-72408
ISBN 0-465-08239-4
Acknowledgments
Appendix 123
Notes 209
References 220
Index 227
*
Acknowledgments
MOST scholarly books are pastiches of other people’s works. This one is
no exception, and draws heavily on studies by people from many different
parts of the world (though not from different time periods since most of the
research on formal structuralist models has taken place during the past
three or four years). I am particularly grateful to the following people:
Edmar Bacha, Francisco Lopes, Eduardo Modiano, Andre Lara-Resende,
and Persio Arida at the Pontifical Catholic University (PUC) in Rio de
Janeiro; Alejandro Foxley, Jose Pablo Arellano, and Rene Cortazar at
CIEPLAN in Santiago; Alain Ize and Nora Lustig at El Colegio de Mexico
in Mexico City; J0m Rattsp at the University of Trondheim; Hiren Sarkar
at the National Council of Applied Economic Research in New Delhi; Jack
Duloy, Sweder van Wijnbergen, Alan Gelb, Wafik Grais, P^adeep Mitra,
and Desmond McCarthy at the World Bank; Youssef Boutros-Ghali at the
International Monetary Fund; Frank Lysy at Johns Hopkins; Jere Behrman
and Ed Buffie at the University of Pennsylvania; Graciela Chichilnisky at
Columbia; Carlos Diaz-Alejandro at Yale; Bill Gibson at the University of
Massachusetts in Amherst; Steve Marglin at Harvard; Eliana Cardoso at
Boston University; Amitava Dutt, Paul Krugman, Rudi Dombusch, Emma
Rothschild, and Dick Eckaus at MIT. Cohorts of students at PUC, MIT,
El Colegio de Mexico, and in seminars at various other places suffered
through successive elaborations of the models here; they paid back their
tormentor for his “minor slips” in turn. My wife, children, and pets pro¬
vided the appropriate quantum of distractions from the algebra. Linda
Dorfman did a super job of typing. My thanks to them all.
Structuralist Macroeconomics
1
The Structuralist
Perspective
A
m JL N ECONOMY has structure if its institutions and the behavior of
its members make some patterns of resource allocation and evolution sub¬
stantially more likely than others. Economic analysis is structuralist when
it takes these factors as the foundation stones for its theories.
According to this definition, North Atlantic or neoclassical professionals
do not practice structuralist economics. Their standard approach to theory
is to postulate a set of interlocking maximization problems by a number of
“agents” and ask about the characteristics of the solutions. Institutions are
conspicuously lacking in this calculus, as is recognition that men, women,
and children are political and social as well as economic animals. Noneco¬
nomic, or even nonmaximized, forces affecting economic actions are ruled
out of discussion. Moreover, allowable economic actions are curiously cir¬
cumscribed. For example, markets are almost always postulated to be price¬
clearing when it is patently obvious that many functioning markets are
cleared by quantity adjustments or queues.
In applied economics, this theoretical cabala breaks down, as it must. But
the impact of the theory on the practitioner remains strong. If markets are
routinely supposed to clear by price, then getting the prices right or, more
grandly, assuring a Pareto efficient allocation, becomes an obsession. If
4 Structuralist Macroeconomics
chapters 2 through 10. Most of what one learns from the analytical models
that is of practical or policy use is summarized in chapter 11. The reader
mainly interested in inquiring if formalized structuralist macroeconomics
is of any earthly use is encouraged to jump directly there.
of income and saving and consumption behavior. Some gain and others lose
when the macro situation changes; the losers may try to regain their eroded
position by forcing further changes in macro variables over time. One
example is workers who find their real incomes decline when prices rise to
bring macro balance under conditions of fixed output in some sectors. They
press for higher wages, and in so doing find that their claims for real income
conflict with those of capitalists, the government, foreigners, or other
groups in the system. From this process of conflicting claims, inflation,
perhaps linked with more severe social disruption, is an inevitable result.
Most structuralist theories of inflation (certainly the ones in this book)
proceed along these lines. They can be made subtle when it is recognized
that the relative bargaining strength of capitalists and workers changes with
the situation of the economy—workers may be in a position to obtain higher
real wage gains when employment is high or inflation accelerates. Such
assumptions underlie the profit-squeeze theories of cyclical adjustment that
appear in the medium-run models presented below.
Foreign trade enters this interplay in several ways. The open economy
must adjust so that two balances are satisfied:
1. The trade deficit (foreign saving) must equal investment minus national saving.
2. The trade deficit must also equal the sum of imports (capital, intermediate, and
consumer) and net interest payments on debt, minus exports and other net
current foreign exchange receipts such as emigrant remittances.
Different models can be constructed around the two variables that adjust
to assure these relationships hold. The growth rate, capacity utilization, and
the trade deficit are possible accommodating variables among macro quan¬
tities, while the exchange rate and the price level (implicitly, the income
distribution) play the same role in the price system. Some pairs of adjusting
variables are more plausible candidates in the context of development eco¬
nomics than others. The choice defines the structure one chooses to impose
for analyzing a particular policy program. Selection requires a judgment
from outside the model about the key forces that make the economy oper¬
ate. Returning to a point made earlier, postulating maximizing behavior on
the part of all agents suppresses the need to judge.
Money and financial variables affect the real side of the economy along
with trade. Investment responds to the interest rate as well as to the profit
rate (or the income distribution) and capacity utilization. But interest pay¬
ments also enter firms’ prime costs if they are required to pay in advance
for labor and intermediate inputs. Facing poorly articulated transport and
commercialization networks and financial systems with a low degree of
The Structuralist Perspective 7
Topics covered in the chapters unwind more or less in the order just set
out. Chapter 2 takes up quantity, price, and competitive import adjustment
toward macro balance in a one-sector model. Comparative static exercises
center around currency devaluation (which can prove “stagflationary,”
with price increases and output contraction at the same time) and income
redistribution. A digression shows that neoclassical formulations give essen¬
tially the same results as in the simpler models used here, except when
macro causality is set up to let saving determine investment. Then the
substitutability assumptions at the base of neoclassical models have an
important role to play. Finally, a profit-squeeze business-cycle theory is
proposed as a first extension of the analysis toward the medium run.
Chapter 3 is devoted to a pair of fixprice/flexprice models, with price¬
clearing agricultural and infrastructure sectors in order. Industry is the
quantity-clearing sector in both models. The effects of big investment
pushes, food consumption subsidies, and other matters are discussed in the
first agriculture/industry system. The second model focuses on the absorp¬
tion problems of a mineral exporting economy. Both theoretical specifica¬
tions underlie chapter 4, where an empirical computable general equilib¬
rium model for India (with two price-clearing and three quantity-clearing
sectors) is used to illustrate the vagaries of short-run adjustment in practice.
Financial markets are introduced in chapter 5. The public can hold three
assets: money in the form of bank deposits; loans to firms to finance working
capital; and a collection of nonproductive assets called “gold.” A reduction
in money supply increases the interest rate on loans to firms and thus the
cost of working capital. A sharp enough increase can drive up the price level
from the side of cost-push—monetary contraction can be inflationary in the
short run. Similarly, attempts to draw deposits toward the banking system
can lead to a contraction in rentiers’ desired volume of productive loans to
firms instead of holdings of gold. The outcome is once again stagflation.
Orthodox financial policy can easily prove counterproductive. This lesson
is extended to the long run in chapter 6, where it is shown across different
steady states that slower money growth can lead to faster inflation, a lower
growth rate of output, and a more unequal income distribution. The skele¬
ton key to these unusual results is again interest rate cost-push resulting
from restrictive monetary policy.
Chapter 7 addresses open economy problems of stabilization and growth,
using the two balance equations described above. These are first interpreted
in terms of the development economists’ familiar two-gap model (due fun-
The Structuralist Perspective 11
damentally to Hollis Chenery) and then put through adjustment paces. The
chapter also discusses the roles of foreign interest payments and an export
push in affecting internal and external balance.
One of the specifications in chapter 7 is short run, with the trade deficit
and the level of economic activity responding to investment demand (or the
capital stock growth rate), the exchange rate, and other variables. This
description of the real side of the economy is combined with financial
markets in chapter 8 to inquire about the effects of revising the rate at which
the nominal exchange rate is depreciated in a crawling peg. Recent or¬
thodoxy recommends that the rate of crawl be slowed as an anti-inflationary
device. This policy is shown to have strongly destabilizing tendencies in the
long run. The chapter closes with a review of how the gap equations in
chapter 7 plus the monetary system’s accounting identity (money supply
= bank credit to the private sector -f bank credit to the government +
foreign reserves) are applied in practical economic work by agencies such
as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund.
Chapter 9 takes up longer-term patterns of growth and income distribu¬
tion in two two-sector models. The first extends the agriculture/industry
model of chapter 3 to discuss food-price inflation and its real effects in
steady state. The second model shows how policies aimed at income redis¬
tribution may accelerate growth in an economy with “wage” and “luxury”
good industries.
Chapter 10 turns to international issues in a long-term context, where the
“South” is assumed to export a price-clearing commodity for which the
income elasticity of demand in the “North” is less than one. The North
exports investment goods and luxuries to the South. It is shown that growth
in the South is largely dependent on what happens in the North in these
circumstances, and that a productivity increase in its export industry will
generate adverse shifts in its terms of trade, available saving, and rate of
growth. This last finding is a classic structuralist result.
Finally, as mentioned above, chapter 11 summarizes policy conclusions.
Adjustment
Mechanisms—
The Real Side
M
AVA ACROECONOMICS begins with the notion that the value of
saving generated by all participants in the economy must by one means or
another come into equality with the value of investment in the short run.
The investment decisions are typically made by public authorities, the
managers of firms, and the families that choose to construct new housing.
In a capitalist system, saving comes from financial institutions (insurance
companies, pension funds, and so forth), retained earnings of firms (over
which managers exercise partial control), the public sector’s budget surplus,
households, and foreign institutions that lend money to accumulate “our”
country’s financial obligations or cover its deficit on foreign trade. These
accounting truisms are repeated here to emphasize one point: the groups
making saving and investment decisions only partly overlap; hence, there
must be mechanisms that affect their behavior to bring their totals of saving
and investment into accord. In any functioning economy, of course, adjust¬
ment occurs in many ways at the same time. The art of macroeconomic
modeling is to pick out the dominant changes for more careful, at times
Adjustment Mechanisms—The Real Side 13
Through manufacturing and related activities account for far less than
one-half of total value added and an even smaller share of employment in
most developing countries, they play a central macroeconomic role. The
industrial sector often grows faster than the rest of the system, and is more
14 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where P is the sector’s output (or producer) price; r is the markup rate,
w is the nominal wage rate; b is a labor-output coefficient (the inverse of
average labor productivity); e is the exchange rate or price of the local
currency in terms of foreign currency (for example, ten “locals” trade for
one dollar, and e — 10); PJ? is the foreign currency price of imported
intermediates; and a0 is the intermediate import-output coefficient. Another
decomposition of price, useful later on, is:
Adjustment Mechanisms—The Real Side 15
Here, the term in brackets is value-added per unit output, in turn separated
into wage and nonwage components wb and r(wb + eP$a0) respectively.
Value-added plus intermediate imports per unit output (ePJa0) sum to the
price level P.
Assume that the value of physical capital (plant and equipment) owned
by industrial firms is PK. A rigorous justification would be that there is just
one type of industrial product that can be used as an intermediate, a final
consumption good, and fixed capital: the amount K serving as capital is
valued at the current producer price P. Nobody seriously believes such
stories but many economists still find it convenient to work with profit rates
of the form:
PX — wbX — eP$aoX
PK
In this ratio, the numerator is total industrial sales PX (when the output
flow is X), less wage and intermediate import costs. Dividing this measure
of total profits by the value of capital stock gives the profit rate r. After
substitution from (2.1), r can be rewritten as
t X T
r —-= -u (2.3)
1 + t K 1 + r
C + I + E - X = 0 (2.4)
That is, wage earners consume all their income, while a share, s„ of profit
income is not consumed, or saved. This formulation leaves out whatever
saving workers may undertake; however, much of their accumulation ulti¬
mately goes to finance housing and purchase of consumer durables and can
be left out of a model focused on industrial investment demand. Saving from
profits will be undertaken both by firms (retained earnings) and those
presumably well-off households that receive significant amounts of property
income. Depending on accounting conventions, in many countries surpluses
of public enterprises would also contribute to the profit-based saving
flow.3
Substitution of (2.5) into (2.4) and manipulation based on the cost decom¬
position (2.2) give the equation:
In words, saving per unit of capital in the economy is the sum of saving from
profits srr and the nonconsumed flow of income resulting from intermediate
imports (f>r/r. Total saving is exhausted by capital stock growth g and net
exports of home-produced goods as a fraction of capital stock, e.
To close out a description of the macroeconomy, we have to write down
demand functions for investment and net exports. Export demand e can
most usefully be held constant for the moment. Investment demand can be
expressed as:
6 — z0 I Z |' I ~
, 1 + T
— Zq + Z1 -(- -Z 2 (2.7)
The theory underlying the equation in the first line is that there is some base
level z0 of public and private investment that is unaffected by current
economic conditions—in the traditional phrase, z0 reflects the “animal
spirits” of private corporate managers and public enterprise functionaries.
Investment will rise with both the profit rate r and the index of capacity
utilization u as indicators of future profitability. The variable u resembles
an accelerator term in investment demand functions; econometric evidence
suggests that the accelerator coefficient z2 is likely to exceed the profit rate
coefficient z, in (2.7). The second line in this formula uses (2.3) to reduce
investment behavior to a function of the profit rate and the markup r.
Equation (2.6) is drawn as the “Saving supply” curve in figure 2.1, under
the assumption of an exogenously fixed level of net exports. Even if invest¬
ment demand g is zero, domestic saving is required to finance the corre¬
sponding trade surplus. The intercept of the saving supply curve on the r-
axis represents the profit rate that will generate the needed saving flow.
The “investment demand” schedules in the diagram correspond to (2.7),
with two different levels of the animal spirits parameter z0. In the middle
quadrant, capacity utilization and the profit rate are related positively
according to (2.3) until a capacity limit u is reached. Thereafter, capacity
use stays constant while profit rate increases are accompanied in the bottom
quadrant by a falling real wage to or w/P:
= w_= » = * - 4> (2 8)
P (1 + T)(wb + eP%a q) (1 + r)b
Macro Equilibrium with Capacity Adjustment (Point I) and Forced Saving (Point
II)
the economy reaches full capacity, further increases in the profit rate can
only come from a higher markup rate and a falling real wage. In formal
terms, transition to full capacity imposes an additional restriction on the
macro system. It can only be met by an additional dependent variable, and
the obvious candidate is the markup rate. As described in detail below, a
rise in r drives up the price level P, which in turn limits demand to the
available capacity level UK.
Now consider the investment-saving equilibrium points in figure 2.1. At
point I, the growth rate is g(, the profit rate is r,, and there is excess
capacity since u i lies below u. Any small increase in investment (or export)
demand could be met by increased capacity use at a constant real wage co.
Adjustment Mechanisms—The Real Side 19
^7
at
=/[£ + €- (t ‘<f> + O'*]
— f\z 0 + € + (2.9)
(Zl + iT^) “ (7 + *')
where/(0) = 0 and the first derivative of /is positive. The profit rate (and
capacity utilization) will be constant when commodity excess demand is
zero and saving equals investment, but will rise when excess demand is
positive. The adjustment is stable if the derivative of / with respect to r is
negative, so that a rising r will drive excess demand back toward zero. It
is easy to verify that this will be the case when the slope of the investment
function is less than that of the saving function, as shown in figure 2.1.
At point II, the saving-investment equilibrium occurs at full capacity u.
As argued above, the markup rate and real wage are endogenous in this
situation. Any increase in animal spirits or exogenous investment z0 will
create excess demand for output that can only be reduced by rising price
level P and markup rate r. From (2.8), there will be a falling real wage a).
Since the propensity to consume from wage income exceeds that from
profits, total consumption will be reduced and excess demand driven back
to zero. This is a forced saving adjustment, of the type emphasized by
Kalecki and Kaldor.5 Note that its efficacy requires a constant money wage
w in (2.8), or at least wage increases that lag prices. Forced saving is
impossible when (1) saving propensities of workers and profit recipients (or
of all groups) are the same, or (2) wages (or all nominal payment flows) are
instantaneously and fully indexed to price increases. In an economy with
a plausible set of medium-term contract obligations, behavioral parameters
and apparatus for class repression, these conditions will not be satisfied and
forced saving is a viable adjustment mechanism.6
To give a formal version of the adjustment, note from (2.3) that at full
capacity the profit and markup rates are linked by the equation (1 -f t)/t
= u/r. Substitution into (2.9) then gives the profit rate response to excess
demand as:
For a plausibly high saving rate, df/dr < 0, and the forced saving adjust¬
ment will be stable.
So far, the variable e, representing net exports as a share of capital stock,
has been held constant. Moreover, little would be changed if net exports
adjusted according to a rule such as e = e(eP%/P), where P* is the foreign
currency price of “our” exports. This equation simply states that exports
are an increasing function of the ratio between the price at which they can
be sold and the domestic producer price. Depending on the circumstances,
export price responsiveness may or may not be macroeconomically impor¬
tant, but it does not modify the adjustment mechanism underlying figure
2.1 in any essential way.
Adjustment can be affected, however, if net exports are treated as com¬
pletely endogenous. Assume that the economy is at full capacity and, more¬
over, that workers can muster sufficient power to stabilize the real wage at
level ci>2 in figure 2.1. At full capacity, the profit rate will then be fixed at
r 2 and saving supply (per unit of capital) at g2. How could a further increase
in investment demand be accommodated? Figure 2.2 illustrates one means
—an upward shift in the saving function mediated by falling net exports.
FIGURE 2.2
Macro Adjustment by Reduced Net Exports at Full Capacity Utilization and a
Fixed Real Wage
Adjustment Mechanisms—The Real Side 21
As € declines for a given profit rate r, (2.6) shows that more saving is made
available to finance investment demand. The saving supply curve shifts up
while the country’s foreign trade surplus declines (or its deficit increases).
“Foreign saving” provides the means for the economy to move its equilib¬
rium from II to III while the real wage stays fixed.
Evidently, other saving flows could be made endogenous to satisfy a
similar function. Changes in the public sector surplus by continuously
adjusting tax or subsidy rates are examples. As we will see in subsequent
chapters, such adjustments almost always have monetary repercussions that
may not be easy to control. But along with variations in capacity use and
forced saving, endogenous shifts in the levels of foreign or public sector
saving are an important adjustment device.
FIGURE 2.3
Effects of a Reduction in the Markup Rate r
dr r
(<t> ~ z2)
dT At7
Adjustment Mechanisms—The Real Side 23
and
where A = (t~'4> + 5,) — [z, + r_1(l -f r)z2] is positive from the overall
stability conditions.
These equations show that the growth rate will increase with a decline
in r so long as the saving rate sr exceeds the import cost share <f>. The
conclusion is that profit and growth rate increases are more likely conse¬
quences of a reduction in the markup rate when the economy is not highly
dependent on intermediate imports. Otherwise, the profit rate could easily
fall, as illustrated in figure 2.3. Note also that capacity utilization increases,
though this change could go in either direction as well. In the diagram, a
reduction in markups gives rise to faster growth, more capacity utilization,
and a higher real wage (bottom quadrant). At the same time, the profit rate
falls. Resistance on the part of capitalists toward such a policy would be
likely.
This model is often interpreted the other way round, with a high markup
presented as the root cause of economic stagnation—low capacity utiliza¬
tion and slow growth. This line of thought has been frequently repeated in
India, as in the following quotation from Deepak Nayyar:7
Clearly, a large proportion of the demand for industrial products originates from
a narrow segment of the population. However, manufactured goods sold to the
relatively few rich can use up only so much, and no more of the capacity in the
intermediate and capital goods sector. Only a broad-based demand for mass con¬
sumption goods can lead to a full utilization of capacity . .. but that in turn requires
incomes for the poor. Thus an unequal income distribution operating through
demand functions might well restrict the prospects of sustained industrial growth.
The simple model used here does not capture Nayyar’s intersectoral nu¬
ances, but does reflect his emphasis on lagging aggregate demand. Indeed,
with a low enough intermediate import share, even capitalists might benefit
from the sort of income distribution he implicitly favors. Such a condition
may hold in India. Also, as shown in chapter 9, effects of the type discussed
here carry over to a multisectoral macro model.
To pursue this theme further, one might ask about the consequences of
income redistribution under full capacity use. Since r is an endogenous
variable when there is full capacity, income shifts via forced reduction in
markups are not feasible. To explore other devices we can use the price
decomposition:
24 Structuralist Macroeconomics
rP
P = wb H-b eP *a o (2.10)
u
which follows from (2.2) using the substitution rPK = r(wb + eP*a0)X
for total profits. Equation (2.10) can in turn be solved as:
wb + eP^a o
r = u
P
FIGURE 2.4
Effects of a Devaluation (an Increase in the Exchange Rate e)
on the “Trade deficit” axis, the devaluation does lead to balance of pay¬
ments improvement, at least in terms of foreign prices. However, the deficit
in domestic prices (the foreign price deficit multiplied by the higher ex¬
change rate e) may get larger. As discussed in chapter 8, the higher deficit
can lead to contraction in the money supply, which will strengthen the
effects being discussed here.
Empirical evidence suggests that the output contraction and adverse
income redistribution from devaluation illustrated in figure 2.4 may be
fairly common; however, much depends on the export response. To get a
formal expression, let 17 be the elasticity of exports with respect to their
relative profitability, viz:
dE (eP\/P)
d(eP*E/P) E
Using this elasticity, one can show that, leaving aside changes in invest¬
ment (z, = z2 = 0), the response of output to devaluation is given by:
From this expression it is easy to see that output expansion requires the
export elasticity to satisfy the condition:
eP*E (eP*aoX/PX)
17 >- (2.11)
P E/X
However, riding out the contractionary phase may not be easy. The ex¬
pected tenure of finance ministers who devalue is often very short.9
The effects of devaluation at full capacity can vary, depending on the
specific assumptions about the responses of different classes of income
recipients that one chooses to make. When u is fixed at u and the markup
rate is endogenous, the saving supply and investment demand functions
(2.6) and (2.7) can respectively be written as:
and
Suppose that the domestic price level P is held constant when e is raised
so that the nominal devaluation is also “real.” Then the relative cost of
imported intermediates (eP*a0/P) will go up while the return to exports
(eP*E/P) will rise. The change in the bracketed term on the right side of
(2.12) can, in principle, take either sign, but a “successful” devaluation
would improve the trade balance and lead it to increase. It is easy to see
from (2.12) and (2.13) that the outcome would be a higher capital stock
growth rate g and profit rate r (so long as the basic stability condition
sr > z, is satisfied).
What about real wages? The cost decomposition (2.10) can be restated
as:
The model sketched so far has scant possibility for substitution of labor
and capital, capital and imports, and other such trade-offs that neoclassical
economists adore. The omission stems in part from a desire to simplify—
fixed coefficients and markup pricing permit easy algebra and diagrams that
emphasize directions of causation underlying macro adjustment paths. At
the same time, the basic neoclassical hypotheses of perfect competition,
facile substitution of production inputs, and all the rest lack credibility in
industrial economies, let alone the Third World. Finally, a neoclassical
formulation adds little to what has already been said, except under strong
additional hypotheses. Demonstration of this last point is the purpose of
this section.
To begin, note that the standard story about substitution in production
can be closely mimicked with the apparatus already developed. The key
neoclassical hypothesis is that the rate of profit should rise with the output-
capital ratio. This relationship is already built into equation (2.3) for a fixed
markup rate r. Making r a nonlinearly increasing function of output (there
is conflicting econometric evidence on this idea10) would not change the
fundamentals of macro adjustment as previously analyzed. However, there
would be a blending of the two first adjustment mechanisms described
above. That is, there would be forced saving from the increasing markup
even before high levels of capacity utilization were reached, whereas if the
function r = t(X) were made steep near “full capacity,” the kink in the
capacity utilization function of figure 2.1 and the abrupt switch between
Keynesian and forced saving adjustment regimes would not show up. For
applied models, smoothing out adjustment processes in this way is often
convenient—it helps prevent the numbers coming out of the computer from
taking disconcerting jumps. One strength of neoclassical formulations
comes from the fact that they have a lot of smoothness built in.
To illustrate smooth adjustment in more detail, it is simplest to work with
a model in which there are no intermediate imports, so that only labor and
capital enter as production inputs. Suppose further that there is an econo¬
mywide constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function of the
form":
X = ) BtL(<r_,)/<r + B*A'(<r-,Vo'}a/<<r“,)
(2.14)
and
K
(2.15)
~X
That is, the intensity of use of each factor is a decreasing function of its real
cost to the producer.
To fit these relationships into a macro model, assume in the neoclassical
spirit that there are no differences in saving parameters between recipients
of wage and profit incomes. Then the value of consumption is given by:
PC = (1 — s)PX
g + a - s = 0 (2.16)
<r/(cr— 1)
L
(2.17)
~K
Capital Stock
Growth Rateg
Saving
Supply
Investment
Demand
Employment-Capital
Ratio L/K Profit Rate r
Capacity
Utilization
Output-Capital
Ratio u
FIGURE 2.5
Macro Equilibrium When There Is a CES Production Function (cr < 1) and
Producer Cost Minimization
1. The profit rate r is set in the macro equilibrium condition (2.1t>) when exports
and the growth rate are predetermined variables.
2. The output-capital ratio follows from (2.15) and the labor-capital ratio from
(2.17).
3. Solving (2.14) and (2.15) for the real wage w/P gives:
w L
P ~ ~K r
(2.18)
=
r A
and
g = (r '4> + sr)^-
A
where
A = t-1<{> + sr — h > 0
The profit-squeeze story depends on the notion that r falls when employ¬
ment and labor militancy are high. The labor-capital ratio L/K is equal to
bu. Let the labor supply consistent with high employment be L—in the
Marxist idiom the reserve army of the unemployed would shrink toward a
low level as L rose toward L. Let X = L/L and k — K/L. Then by easy
substitution:
Assume that the markup rate varies over time according to the rule
k = (dk/dt)/k = K - t
and
K = (dK/dt)/K = g
— abk(du/dr) —abu
, (2.21)
k(dg/dr) 0
The key linkages underlying the stable adjustment are the positive associ¬
ation of capacity utilization with the markup rate due to
<t>(g* ~ z0)
T —
Z\g* - s,ig* - z0)
Pn = (1 + r)wb„ (3.1)
where r is the markup rate, w is the money wage, and b„ is the labor-output
ratio.
The agricultural sector, by contrast, is resource-limited: supply does not
respond to price or other incentives in the short run.2 For purposes of
formal modeling, land can be assimilated with capital so that sustained food
output increases can only come from investment activities such as land¬
clearing, mechanization, and works for irrigation. Available employment
opportunities are limited by capital in the A-sector in terms of full-time
equivalent jobs. For macroeconomic purposes here, we do not go into
Adjustment Mechanisms — Two-Sector Models 39
details about how full-time jobs may be split among numerous family
members and employed workers. Also, no distinction is drawn between
food sector capitalists and employees. All income flows go to “peasants,”
who are assumed to share common saving and consumption functions.3
In formal terms, agricultural output is determined by available capital
stock:
Xa = aKa (3.2)
and
EDa = Ca + E — Xa (3.6)
and
EDn = C„ + Ia + /„ - Xn = C„ + / - Xn (3.7)
where E stands for net exports of food, and 1 is investment demand (the
sum of sectoral investment demands /„ and Ia, on the assumption that
capital goods are produced only in the N-sector).
The conditions for macro equilibrium in the economy are EDa =
EDn = 0. One can multiply (3.6) by Pa and (3.7) by Pn, sum the equations,
and simplify to get the investment-saving balance:
As in the last chapter, investment and net exports are financed in equilib¬
rium by domestic saving, the sources this time being agricultural and profit
incomes.
Rather than express all variables as growth or profit rates, it is simplest
in the present model to work out adjustment processes in terms of “level”
variables of the form presented so far. The price Pa rises when there is
excess demand in the food market, while X„ balances the N-sector. The
formal specification depends on the excess demand functions, which can be
written in detail as:
and
dXn
f[EDn(Xn,Pa)]
dt /
and
—~ = g[EDa{Xn,Paj\
dt
where the functions / and g satisfy /(0) = g(0) = 0 and have positive first
derivatives. These derivatives only describe speed of adjustment (which is
presumably fast since we are dealing with a short-run model). Stability itself
depends on the properties of the Jacobian matrix of the excess demand
functions, which can be written as:
(1 - a)yaXa - 0
-[1 - (1 - a)yn]
ay nP„ ay„P„X„
Stability analysis follows the usual procedures.4 To check the trace condi¬
tion, note that the bracketed term in the northwest is one minus the propen¬
sity to consume nonagricultural products from nonagricultural income,
which will be a fraction. Similarly, the term in the southeast (aside from the
minus sign) is proportional to the propensity to consume food from nona¬
gricultural income, also a fraction. Both terms are clearly negative, and so
is the trace (their sum). The determinant of the Jacobian is:
ay nP„ (1 - a)yaXa - 0
A = r-[l - 0 - a)7.] ~ (3.11)
(1 - a)yaXa - 0 p
Pn[\ - (1 - a)yn\ °
must be satisfied. But note that when excess demand for the nonagricultural
product is zero, then from (3.9) Xn is given by:
42 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Note: The shifts in the Agricultural market lines represent increased net exports or lower production
in the agricultural sector.
To see how the system works, begin with the excess demand function for
the N-sector, equation (3.9). Demands are from investment / and nona-
gricultural and agricultural incomes. An increase in the agricultural price
reduces real incomes in the N-sector while it increases those of agricultural¬
ists. Thus, a rise in Pa causes demand for X„ from N-sector incomes to fall
(from both income and substitution effects) and demand from A-sector
incomes to rise. The former effect is likely to dominate when Engel effects
are strong, leading to a relatively large real income loss in the N-sector as
Pa goes up. In the algebra, a large value of 0 is what matters since this
parameter represents the portion of food demand that is insensitive to
changes in incomes and prices. In formal terms, 0 > (1 — a)yaXa is the
condition for X„ to respond negatively to Pa, as can be seen directly from
(3.12). The two possible cases are illustrated by the “Nonagricultural mar¬
ket” schedules in figure 3.1, with the upper diagram showing what happens
when Engel effects are strong.
The analysis of food market equilibrium is simpler. As (3.13) shows,
X„ will be an increasing function of Pa so long as food output Xa exceeds
the sum of marginal food demands from farmers (ayaXa), the constant
demand level 0, and net exports E. Equation (3.13) is graphed as “Agricul¬
tural market” schedule in figure 3.1.
diagram). Otherwise, both Pa and Xn will rise in response to the higher net
exports.
This result can be used to illustrate institutional responses in several
countries. When Engel effects are strong, nonfarmers would benefit in two
ways from lower net food exports (or higher imports)—the food price would
be lower and there would be a higher level of N-sector economic activity.
Under such circumstances, a political coalition in favor of gaining easy
access to imports could form. Examples might be the groups favoring repeal
of the Com Laws in England in the last century, or nationalistic supporters
of low-cost Japanese acquisition of rice from Taiwan and elsewhere before
World War II. By contrast, export promotion might well be favored politi¬
cally when Engel effects are not important at the macroeconomic level, and
the lower diagram of figure 3.1 applies. Exports would stimulate both farm
prices and industrial activity in this case, perhaps characteristic of food
exporters such as the United States in recent years.
These examples are implicitly based on the notion that the volume of
agricultural trade is controlled by the government, perhaps through a state
trading corporation. In fact, regulation of both internal and external com¬
merce in food products is the rule in most countries because of the ex¬
tremely low demand and supply elasticities that characterize the market in
the short run. Low elasticities naturally give rise to large fluctuations in
food prices and quantities offered for sale, which governments do their best
to avoid by regulatory maneuvers.5
If, improbably, free trade in food products were allowed, then the domes¬
tic price Pa would in principle be determined from the world market. Food
traders could make a profit by importing for domestic resale until such time
as the internal price came down to the world level. In practice, such conver¬
gence to the “Law of One Price” may be glacial, but the assumption is often
maintained in theoretical discussions.6
If Pa as determined by the world market increases from an initial equilib¬
rium position in figure 3.1, then adjustment would occur by a clockwise
rotation of the agricultural market schedule as net food exports go up. It
is easy to see from the excess demand function (3.10) that the immediate
export response would be given by:
- aya) - 0 - E]
Note that this response will be weak insofar as net surplus production
beyond fixed food demands (the term in brackets) is small. Indeed, one
Adjustment Mechanisms—Two-Sector Models 45
could imagine cases in which this surplus would be negative, for example
when the propensity to consume food from food producer’s incomes (aya)
is high. The particular model developed here does not have a solution with
positive values of Xn and Pa under these circumstances, and other models
are unstable. Nonetheless, a perverse or very weak export response to world
price increases has often been pointed out in the literature as a serious policy
problem confronting such food exporters as Argentina or Thailand.7
Turning to other experiments, note that increased investment demand
will shift up the intercept of the nonagricultural market schedule in figure
3.1, driving up both X„ and Pa. A push toward more rapid growth should
then be accompanied by a shift in the terms of trade toward agriculture.
This possibility is of considerable historical interest, for example, in the
rapid growth spurt experienced by the Soviet Union in the first five-year
plan between 1928 and 1932. During that period, the share of investment
in national income rose from 14.8 percent to 44.1 percent, and national
income itself rose by 60 percent. By the end of the period, the investment
share in national income was more than twice as big as that of agricul¬
ture.
The traditional interpretation is that much of the increment in savings
necessary to support the extra investment came from the agricultural sector.
However, the above comparison of the income shares of investment and
agricultural value-added shows that the role of agriculture as a savings
source cannot have been great. Rather, the terms of trade shifted strongly
in favor of food producers (from 100 in 1928 to 164 in 1930 and 130 in
1932), and real urban wages dropped by about 50 percent. The resulting
forced savings on the part of workers supported much of the investment
effort. At the same time, Stalin’s dekulakization campaign generated an
ample supply of displaced agricultural labor for employment in urban
industries—in many ways capacity limitations on industrial output could
be broken by (inefficient) use of raw labor.
This interpretation of Soviet experience is broadly consistent with the
model at hand, where an investment push is bound to raise the agricultural
terms of trade.8 Other historical conjunctures would be interesting to ex¬
plore.
A more contemporary policy issue regards consumer food subsidies,
which have been installed in a number of poor countries. They satisfy
political necessity to pacify urban workers’ pressures to maintain their
living standards, but also are often criticized by international agencies as
being “distortions” leading to improper resource allocation. It is reasonable
to ask about the macro implications of modifying subsidy policies.
46 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Note: A reduction in agricultural supply reduces both demand for nonagricultural output and potential
saving from the sector, leading Pa to rise and X„ to fall.
ture is (saxa — E)Pa, shown in the southwest quadrant. For overall equilib¬
rium, both excess demand for the nonagricultural commodity and econo¬
mywide excess demand (investment minus saving) must be driven to zero
at Pa and Xn. In the diagram, adjustment occurs via upward or downward
shifts of the X„ demand function in the northeast quadrant.
Now consider a food supply shortfall, or a fall in Xa. For a given Pa, both
farmers’ demand for X„ and their supply of saving will decline. In the
diagram, the schedules in both the northwest and southwest quadrants
rotate toward the Pa axis, and the outcome is a higher Pa and lower Xn.
The sort of supply shock shown in figure 3.2 can easily set off a burst of
inflation if money wages respond to the rising agricultural price and drive
up N-sector costs in turn. A sequence of such shocks could keep inflation
going if, for example, population growth runs ahead of the growth rate of
agricultural supply. This sort of inflationary process is discussed formally
in chapter 9.
Two final exogenous shifts of interest are increases in the urban nominal
wage w and the markup rate r. Observe from (3.12) and (3.13) that the
48 Structuralist Macroeconomics
The sort of model used for agriculture and industry in the previous
sections can be extended to deal with many other economic structures in
which prices vary to clear some markets and output movements clear
others. In this section, we sketch a model in which intermediate inputs play
a crucial role. The economy in question exports a fixed quantity of a
commodity, such as a mineral, which requires nationally produced nonim¬
portable intermediates like transport services, energy, and other infrastruc¬
ture. These “universal” inputs are assumed to be in fixed supply, and feed
either mineral production or another “manufacturing” sector with markup
pricing. Mining itself typically generates only modest wage flows that lead
to demand for manufactured goods since export profits come in the form
of foreign exchange. If mineral output expands it will pull intermediates
from use in manufacturing on the one hand, and generate demand for
manufacturing output on the other. In addition, there can be cost-push
price increases in manufacturing if the intermediate goods price rises to
clear that market. The final outcomes for manufacturing prices, exports (if
Adjustment Mechanisms—Two-Sector Models 49
In this equation, the markup (at rate r) is taken on wage cost per unit output
wbn, cost of the universal intermediate Puaun, and imported intermediate
costs eP$a0n. The input-output coefficients bn, au„, and a0„ are assumed
constant in the short run.
On the demand side, assume that Engel elasticities are unity. To save
notation, all profits will be assumed to be saved and all wages spent on
consumption. Then the consumer demand functions for N-sector outputs
will be
and
where it is assumed that the same wage w is paid in all three sectors.11 The
coefficient a will presumably be positive but small, as much less than
one-half of consumer spending goes toward energy, transport, and other
products from the U-sector. In these equations, the contribution of the
mineral sector to consumption demand is likely to be low since only wage
income is consumed. (The share of mining wages in the total across the
economy might be as low as 5 percent.12) In practice, some share of the
export receipts from mining will go to the national government, and will
be spent. This important potential source of demand is left out in the present
formulation, which concentrates on short-run responses.
50 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Cn 4~ E -f- G — Xn — 0
and
Cu + ounXn + aumXm 4- 0/ — Xu — 0
(1 - a)w
[bnXn + buXu -f bmXm\
(1 + T)[wbn + Puau„ + eP*a0n]
eP*
+ 6 + €o + *i
(1 4- r)[wbn 4- Puaun +
- X, = 0 (3.16)
and
Adjustment Mechanisms—Two-Sector Models 51
+ aumXm 4- 0/ — Xu = 0 (3.17)
The adjusting variables are X„ for (3.16) and Pu for (3.17).13 The equa¬
tions are written out in all their glory to illustrate the fact that inclusion
of intermediate inputs in a model substantially complicates its accounting.
Compared to (3.9) and (3.10) for the agriculture/industry model, these
excess demand functions both have more entries and (more importantly) are
nonlinear. Because the intermediate price Pu enters into the determination
of the N-sector price P„, terms in products or quotients of Pu and manufac¬
turing output Xn are unavoidable in (3.16) and (3.17).
Even without writing the Jacobian, it is straightforward to see that (3.16)
gives a negatively sloped relationship between Pu and X„. Excess demand
for manufacturers falls when Xn rises (more supply) and also when Pu goes
up (less consumer and export demand from intermediate cost-push into a
higher Pu). Hence, the two adjusting variables must trade off inversely in
the (Pu, X„) plane. By contrast, an increase in X„ generates more consumer
demand for the U-sector in (3.17), which must be limited by an increase in
Pu. A positively sloped curve results.
The two schedules are shown in figure 3.3. The shifts are due to an
FIGURE 3.3
Response of the Mineral-Exporting Economy to an Increase in Mineral Output
Note: The intermediate price rises and manufacturing output can shift either way.
52 Structuralist Macroeconomics
awL{\ — a)wbn
awbm + aumPu
[(1 - a)wL + t,eP*nXn}(\ + r)aun (3.18)
Manufacturing
w w
(Pny~a(Pu)a (^«)aKl + r)[wbn + eP*a0n + Puaun]Y~a
54 Structuralist Macroeconomics
so that the real wage falls when Pu goes up. On the saving-investment side
of the model, the corresponding increase in real profits underlies a forced
saving macro adjustment process. Setting out the details is left to the reader.
The derivations are tedious, but follow directly along the lines of the models
already described.
Though there are striking exceptions (mostly in the Persian Gulf), min¬
eral-exporting countries by and large suffer from balance of payments pres¬
sure. The historical sequence is that after an initial phase of building up
foreign exchange holdings when mineral wealth arrives, pressures to in¬
crease imports rise and the corresponding coefficients shift up. The govern¬
ment learns that it can finance more spending on N-sector goods by holding
foreign exchange in the form of central bank reserves and creating national
money against that base.15 The outcomes in terms of the model sketched
in last section are relatively high levels of G, (1 — 0), and a0„. The balance
of payments deficit in terms of dollars becomes:
€o —(1 + T)aun
e
(3.20)
Short-Run Adjustment
in Practice
The data base for the India model (and all the others) is arranged in the
form of a social accounting matrix, or SAM. The Indian SAM is described
in section 4.1—it amounts to a blown-up version of the accounting relation¬
ships developed above. Section 4.2 sets out the equations for the model,
which are closely linked to the structure of the SAM. A brief discussion of
how values are assigned to the parameters appears in section 4.3. Section
4.4 describes the numerically calculated Jacobian of the Indian model’s
excess demand equations. This leads to the analysis in section 4.5 of a
number of comparative static exercises with the model, as parameters or
exogenous variables are perturbed to shift it away from its base solution
(which is described by the SAM). The emphasis is on the role that different
adjustment mechanisms play in this applied model. Conclusions are sum¬
marized in section 4.6.
Immediately below the input-output flow table are blocks giving sources
of household and government revenues, sources of foreign commodities (or
uses of foreign exchange for imports), and taxes and subsidies. All the
accounting in these rows is in current Indian price terms except the import
row, where purchases are valued in c.i.f. border prices (multiplied by the
rupee/dollar exchange rate). Differences between prices of imports at the
border and the prices at which they are sold internally are captured in
entries in the tax and subsidy rows of the SAM.
The first five column sums give the cost structures of the producing
sectors, exhausted by intermediate purchases, payments to the government
and households, import costs, and indirect taxes less subsidies. By the
standard SAM accounting rule, these column sums must equal the corre¬
sponding row sums, which represent total sales by the sectors.
To the right of the input-output matrix are blocks for uses of resources.
The household sector purchases outputs of the sectors, saves, receives subsi¬
dies, and pays direct taxes. The government also buys commodities on its
current account (its capital expenditures are in the investment column), and
60 Structuralist Macroeconomics
saves and pays subsidies. In the investment columns appear outlays for
gross fixed capital formation and stock changes—their total is of course
balanced by the sum of the entries in the saving block. Exports (positive)
and competitive imports (negative) are valued in border price terms. The
difference between border and internal prices of exports is made up in the
export subsidy column. Exports less competitive imports comprise sources
of foreign exchange; the other major sources are remittances from emigrant
workers that go into household income, and foreign saving, which comes
into the economy on foreign capital account to balance the current account
deficit.3
Table 4.1 is the numerical SAM for our Indian model.4 Some of its details
are worth pointing out. Note first that income flows to households are split
three ways. Agricultural households in row 6c get income from the first two
sectors, while income generated in nonagriculture goes to wage-earning and
nonwage-earning households. The nonagricultural households get govern¬
ment wage, transfer, and interest payments (column 7) and emigrants’
remittances (column 9a). Note also that government revenues in row 7
include income from public sector production activities outside of agricul¬
ture.
Household uses of income appear in column 6. Only totals are shown in
the matrix, though in the model described below distinct consumption
patterns are postulated for agricultural and nonagricultural households.
Note the entry with negative value —545 in row 11. This represents subsi¬
dies to food consumption; along with producers’ subsidies signed with a
minus in columns 1-3, it is offset by the government’s total subsidy outlay
of 1327 in column 7.
Besides its production activities, the government’s revenue sources in row
7 include indirect and direct taxes (columns 11 and 12). The sources of these
taxes appear in rows 12 and 13. All direct taxes are assumed to be paid by
households (2941 in column 6), whereas the indirect tax burden falls on
production and sales in the nonagricultural sectors. Government uses of
funds appear in column 7.
Transactions with the rest of the world are recorded in row 9 for imports
and columns 9a and 9b for exports and competitive imports. The negative
entries for the latter in the commodity balance rows 1 through 5 are offset
by a positive total of 3782 in row 9, so that the column 9b sum is zero. Most
competitive imports come into the manufacturing sector. Besides exports
and remittances, the other source of foreign exchange include 1800 as the
current account deficit or foreign saving in row 8. Household saving is
22637 and government current saving is 2980; their total of 27417 is equal
to investment demand, or the sum of the column totals 8a and 8b.
04 v© vo m T*
O Tf —< oo
a 11 oo
CM
m
v©
04
O m
m
S *->
*—< o-
m m
«—ii
On
O'
vO
ON
m o4 — vo 3 04 04 -
m 04
& *
QK
■'T
ON
o
^ £
je K
8.1
%
I I I
II
I4
04
O' O'
Ss 04
3
!
A Social Accounting Matrix for India, 1980-81
"IS ac
tog
rS -3
o s;
c „
TABLE 4.1
?5 g ON Tf OO
8
» ? 5 On
Tt-
mm
3 O' —*
04
O
ON
*1!
<3
O' —
m oo
04 oo 3
s<s,
Os 04 m oo
O oo
ir\ m
3
On
04
rj-
OO
On
—■ On
All values are in crores (ten million rupees) at current prices.
to
3I SI & Tt O OO «—• vO
^ o s:4 on
On
m
OO 04
^g^ o
to «B
m m 04 04
S''S.'S
2 S' c O O vo
04 vo
O oo
04 m
m oo ON ^ ^ O
cI 3 04
■5S 3
rf m *—'
■*t
04
■<t
04
VO
O'
04
.£ C
60^53 O' ON
0^3
•O O Q O' o
O m
•§ e 3
r>j ^0
On
OO
^
—
—'
«—'
O
O-
04
•“1 ''T
^^ a
<u
00 6
3 5 c o
C
3 •5 G q c "§ + X
'g o .2C OG «u «oo *73
5 XI 3 x o. 2 o
oo
CO 1 ££> <23 jg op -a 00 co 3 <u
£ , x
X
c
S E S c a E5 3
.2 § v
60
2
g O T CO « O B
x> P-
I § e ° g- s 3 UJ
^ e
£ O *5 2 *5 e
<U
<u Z
(/)
S Z c < .S vg £
£ O .£ o W Cl, w 5 H o
H
O
Z
—■ 04 m & OO O' O «—< 04 m
62 Structuralist Macroeconomics
With its double-entry bookkeeping, the SAM provides a data base around
which it is easy to construct a general equilibrium model. The SAM in fact
represents the base solution of the model since, as we will see in section 4.3,
the parameters of its equations are calculated to make their numerical
solution agree with the SAM. Of course, one has to first produce a SAM
to be able to follow this procedure.
Fairly complete recipes for constructing social accounting matrixes are
available in the literature, so there is no need to go into great detail
here.5 The usual approach is to begin with an input-output table, the
national accounts, and information from a household survey on patterns of
consumer spending. In general outline, the following steps will produce the
matrix:
1. Sectoral levels of value-added from the input-output and national accounts data
must be made consistent, typically by adjustment of both.
2. Next comes disaggregation of the value-added totals into income flows to house¬
hold and government sectors to be distinguished in the analysis. For example,
sectoral value-added in the Indian SAM had to be split among the entries in rows
6a, 6b, 6c, and 7 of table 4.1, following national accounts and other information
about the functional distribution of income.
3. The national accounts will give a control total for household saving. Savings
levels from the different income recipient classes (H of them) have to be estimated
to satisfy this total, typically on the basis of cross-sectionally estimated saving
parameters.
4. After taxes and saving are subtracted from household incomes, one is left with
H totals for values of household consumption by income recipient class. If there
are N sectors in the economy, the input-output table gives N totals for consump¬
tion of the different sectoral outputs. One thus has the row and column sums
(perhaps after correction for consumer taxes and subsidies) for the N X H matrix
of values of household consumption by type of product and income recipient
group. Subject to these control totals, the matrix has to be filled in. One typically
begins with existing estimates of household expenditure patterns, then modifies
them until the control totals are satisfied. The computations can either be done
informally or with a matrix-balancing computer algorithm such as the procedure
called RAS.6
5. Input-output and foreign trade information can be utilized to fill in the rest of
the sectoral final demand columns and the import row. Government fiscal data
usually suffice for the tax, subsidy, and government expenditure accounts. The
final check on filling in the matrix is that saving supply should equal investment
demand. After enough informal reconciliations between inconsistent data sources
are made, overall balance can usually be worked out.
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 63
With the SAM constructed, the next step is to set out equations for the
model around it. The Indian model is based on the notion that the two
agricultural sectors are price-clearing, while output levels vary to satisfy
demand in the rest of the economy. Much literature in India points to an
“infrastructure bottleneck,” which suggests that sector four might best be
treated as price-clearing subject to fixed supply (like the U-sector in the
model of sections 3.3 and 3.4). However, numerical results show little
demand variation for sector four, so it was deemed simpler to treat it as
quantity-clearing to avoid complications in the model solution algorithm
described below.
The model’s equations appear in table 4.2 and the variables and parame¬
ters are described in table 4.3. The equations are set out in blocks, to be
described in succession.
Block I contains input-output balances, which set demand (to the left)
equal to supply for the five sectors. The entries correspond to the first five
rows of the SAM, with the convention that base-period prices for sectoral
outputs are all set to one. Note in equation (4.1) an entry (GPX — FA ,
— FN i) that reflects government food market interventions described
below. Also, in (4.3) national production of intermediate inputs to sectors
one and two is pegged at the level Xf. This quantity represents an exoge¬
nously specified level of fertilizer output. The balance of fertilizer demand
(«31*, + anX2 — X/) is assumed to be met by imports.
Block II contains an equation making accumulation of private food
stocks an increasing function of the market food price. The equation is
included in an attempt to capture the macroeconomic effect of food stock
speculation, which is often pointed out as a possible source of inflation in
India. Equation (4.6) gives a positive feedback from a rise in the food price
to increased stock accumulation and hence to a still higher price. The
practical importance of this potentially destabilizing demand response is
discussed below.
Block III has equations defining agricultural and wage incomes Ya and
YValue-added in the two agricultural sectors is calculated in (4.7) to give
Ya. Note that farmers pay a regulated price Pf for their fertilizer inputs.
The government also gives them a guaranteed “procurement price” P* for
a fixed quantity GP \ of food sales (the procurement). Production above the
procurement level (Xx — GP ,) is sold at the market price P,. The govern¬
ment’s accounts for this complex set of food market interventions are set
out below.
TABLE 4.2
Equations for the India Model
A 5, = ASK/V/’ir* (4.6)
„ (1 4- r4Xl 4- f4)
l3* — . ... . [ .IL ai*Pi + ai*Ps + **'4^4 + aMeP04(1 - '04)] (4.17)
1 - (1 4- t4)(1 4- '4)044 /-i
„ (1 4- T,X1 + ty) *
P> = . ... , Iz a»pi + ‘*'3*5 + a0}eP$,(l - /os)] (4.18)
1 - (1 + Ts)(l + t,)a„ ,-1
Da = (1 - M (4.23)
-
Da = 2 ©W (4.25)
1=1
D„ m X ©7^, (4.26)
/=1
C, = C| + FA, + C? + FN x (4.37)
X, - X, == 0, / = 1 and 2 (4.42H4.43)
X. Governmental Balances
TABLE 4.3
Symbols for the India Model
I. Sectors
1. Food agriculture
2. Other agriculture
3. Manufacturing industries
4. Intermediate production (energy and transportation)
5. Services
e — exchange rate
R — remittances
Lg — government employment
TR — transfer payments
P* — border prices of intermediate imports, / = 1.5
t0i — subsidy rates on intermediate imports, f = 1 , . . . , 5
sub 3 — subsidy rate for manufacturing industries
t4 — markup rate in sector 4
ti — indirect tax rates, /' = 3,4,5
DEP — total depreciation
<#> — share of depreciation for government capital
GRi — government profits from enterprises, i = 3,4,5
tz — tax rate on profit income
FA | — food distribution under rural food-for-work program
FN i — food distribution in ration shops, “issue”
Pi — issue price
C0 — consumption of imported goods
P*c — border price of consumption imports
P*f — border price of fertilizer imports
P* — border price of sectoral exports, / = 1.5
A", — capital stock in sector i, = 3 and 5
GINT — government interest payments
Xj — fixed output levels, / = 1,2
IV Parameters
V. Initial Values
D„ required to pay for the base-level purchases. Both price and income
responsiveness of consumption are summarized by these parameters.
In the Indian context, further complications come from the facts that
agricultural families receive food-for-work cereal donations at zero price in
quantity FA ,, while nonagricultural families can get an "issue” of grain
(total quantity FN,) at a subsidized price P, in the largely urban ration
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 69
shops. Working through the utility maximization that underlies the LES
when these food subsidies are included in budget constraints gives the
demand equations that appear as (4.27)-(4.36). Adding the subsidy quanti¬
ties gives sectoral consumption levels in (4.37)-(4.41). Finally, note back in
equation (4.1) that the net change in the government’s food stocks is given
by its procurement GP, less food-for-work distribution FA , and the ration
issue FNX.
So far, we have described 41 equations in 43 variables (that is, all the
endogenous variables in section II of table 4.3 except T'nd, GREV, GEXP,
and DEF, which are described below). The two equations of block IX that
specify that demand less the fixed supply for each agricultural commodity
must equal zero serve to close the system. Thinking in terms of excess
demand functions shows how it can be solved. An algorithm contains the
following steps:
1. Guess sectoral output levels X\.X5 and a trial pair of prices P ^ and P2 for
the agricultural sectors.
2. Calculate nonagricultural markup rates and prices from the equations in block
IV (incorporating the feedback from price levels to wage rates in equations
(4.8)-(4.12) when it is assumed to apply).
3. Using the trial values of prices and outputs, calculate wages and wage and
agricultural incomes in block III, variable costs per unit output in block V, and
profit income in block VI.
4. Calculate sectoral levels of consumer demand from blocks VII and VIII, and the
foodstock change from block II.
5. Add up totals of sectoral demand, using the expressions to the left of the equality
signs in equations (4.1)-(4.5). If any sectoral demand level differs from its corre¬
sponding trial value by more than a prespecified tolerance, set the trial value equal
to the demand level and go back to step 2. Continue until demand levels are very
close to trial output values for all sectors.8
6. Check if output levels X i and X2 are very close to the prespecified agricultural
supply levels Xi and X2. If not, modify the prices P, and P2 and return to step 1.
Continue until excess demands for the agricultural products are effectively equal
to zero.9
direct tax receipts, indirect taxes [calculated in (4.44)], and revenues from
enterprise. The first two terms in equation (4.46) for current expenditure
GEXP are costs of food-for-work and ration shop food subsidies; the cost
differential associated with grain procurement, (P, — P*) GPU follows.
The next terms represent purchases of sector outputs from the development
budget (P GS ) and current outlay accounts; then come two terms captur¬
5 5
ing the effects of the fertilizer subsidy. The following five terms, respec¬
tively, represent wage payments to functionaries, transfers, depreciation on
government capital stock, government interest payments, and the subsidy
to manufacturing industry.
The next term is the sum of export subsidies in the five sectors and merits
some commentary. The law of one price is not imposed in the model; as a
consequence domestic and border prices of commodity exports may differ.
The price differential creates an income gain or loss to be absorbed by
someone in the system. In practice, both firms and the government will
share the benefit or burden, but in the Indian institutional context where
the government actively subsidizes exports, it is appropriate in a simplified
model to give it the full role. The penultimate term in (4.46) shows that the
government pays a variable export subsidy to firms, so that they can sell at
the same price both internally and externally. This outlay, of course, repre¬
sents government dissaving, and plays a role in the model’s overall adjust¬
ment to equilibrium. (A corresponding entry, which should appear for
variable tariffs on competitive imports, is omitted since its magnitude is
likely to be small.) The final term shows that the government also subsidizes
intermediate imports, at fixed sectoral rates t0r
Equation (4.47) defines the trade deficit in rupee prices. Because taxes or
subsidies on competitive imports are not included in the specification, they
enter the definition of the deficit DEF at internal prices (first term to right
of the equality sign). The other terms are at border prices multiplied by the
exchange rate e, and represent items of foreign commerce already de¬
scribed.
The saving-investment balance (4.48) is of standard form. Saving to the
left of the equals sign comes from households, the government current
account, and the trade deficit. Investment on the right includes capital
formation and stock changes. The other item is the government’s net stock
acquisition GP\ — FA 1 — FN,, valued at the market price Px.
As in all the models of this book, the saving-investment balance is not
an independent restriction; for that reason it is equation number 48 in a
system of 47 endogenous variables. However, it provides a convenient
numerical check on the computer solution of a model like the one here. In
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 71
solving the India model, tolerance limits were set to make saving equal to
investment to five or six significant figures. This degree of precision assures
that the algorithm to solve the model will generate a balanced SAM; it is
well beyond the accuracy of the data at hand.
4.3 Parameterization
5. The other parameters in the table were estimated more or less ad hoc for the India
model, again subject to sensitivity analysis and the results of formal statistical
estimation.
6. The initial values of the variables of the model either can be read directly from
the SAM or else follow from simple manipulations (like dividing sectoral gross
output levels by total variable costs to get markup rates). Again, accounting
consistency permits straightforward computation of the long list of symbols in
table 4.3.
TABLE 4.4
Main Parameters of the Model
3 0.1466 0.1243
4 0.3066 0.10157
5 0.50158 0.06987
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 73
TABLE 4.5
Response Matrices for the India Model
Pi Pi x3 X4 x5
demand with respect for goods from sector three (industry and construc¬
tion), and the inverse of the Jacobian.12
An increase in any one of the five adjusting variables will reduce excess
demand in its corresponding sector—that is, the meaning of the negative
entries along the main diagonal of the Jacobian. Note, however, that there
are strong feedbacks from some sectors to others. The most important
example is the coefficient in row one, column two. Its value of 0.5 comes
directly from the parameter value of 0.3081 for the marginal propensity to
consume m\ pointed out in connection with table 4.4 above. The linkages
go as follows:
Along similar lines, there are strong demands from all other sectors for
sector three, and from sectors three and four for sector five. Perhaps surpris¬
ingly, not much additional demand for infrastructure services from sector
four is generated by price or quantity increments in the other sectors. The
Jacobian replicates the finding mentioned earlier that output in the infra¬
structure sector is relatively independent of activity in the rest of the econ¬
omy.
In algebraic terms one can write the response of the endogenous variables
to a change in investment demand for sector three products as follows:
1
_1
jn dp1 0 0
dX 3 + dh — 0
dXA 0 0
_1
3
y 51 0 0
1
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 75
where they,* are the elements of the Jacobian. From this formulation it is
evident that the column sums of the Jacobian (multiplied by minus one)
provide a differential form of the saving-investment balance in the model,
that is
The numerical matrix in table 4.5 shows that a unit increase in P, generates
0.231 units of saving, and so on.13 All saving responses are positive except
for P2 ■ The increase in demand for food and other products that a rise in
this price generates actually reduces saving overall. Such an effect could
potentially make the excess demand functions unstable, but it is not strong
enough to do so in the present model.14
The elasticity matrix shows how prices and quantities respond in relative
terms to an increase in investment demand. Since the rise in investment first
affects sector three, its own elasticity of 2.716 is the largest in absolute terms
in the matrix, as might be expected. The elasticities for the prices are in
general less than for the quantities, basically because consumers’ price
elasticities of demand for food are fairly small, as shown in table 4.4. The
consequence is that wide swings in prices as equilibrium shifts may be
expected. This observation is verified by the inverse of the Jacobian (with
all entries multiplied by minus one) in table 4.5. It shows that all the
endogenous variables will respond positively to an increase in any sector’s
demand. The elements in the first two rows giving price responses are large,
especially in comparison to the initial normalization of both prices at unity.
The direct and indirect elasticities of the endogenous variables to an in¬
crease in sector three investment demand (calculated from the third column
of the inverse Jacobian matrix) are: Pu 3.557; P2, 3.123; X3, 0.819; X4, 0.62;
X5, 0.602. The fivefold difference in magnitude between price and quantity
elasticities comes from the economics of the system. The price-clearing
agricultural sector plays a major role in the Indian economy, and is charac¬
terized by inelastic supply and low elasticities of demand. Hypersensitive
prices are the structural outcome.
76 Structuralist Macroeconomics
In this section, trial variations in parameters and data for the India model
are described, with emphasis on its adjustment mechanisms. We first take
up how the system responds to changes in investment demand, coupled with
foodstock speculation, partial wage indexation, rising markup rates, and
variations in the level of agricultural supply. Next comes an analysis of the
possible effects of devaluation, followed by a discussion of how the govern¬
ment might adjust its food procurement policy to compensate for output
fluctuations in sector one. Results from the model, including a demand-
supply balance for money, are given in section 5.5.
Table 4.6 shows how the system responds to an increase in investment
demand for products of sector three from 2.3186 to 2.41 hundred billion
rupees (about 4 percent). The rise in aggregate demand is reflected in
increases of both agricultural prices and nonagricultural levels of output,
as shown in the second column of panel A of the table. The arc elasticities
of response are close to those calculated from the Jacobian in table 4.5, and
the output multipiers are^3, 3.335; X4, 0.281; X5, 1.743. These values are
consistent with the usual Keynesian “leakages” from the income-demand
linkage through saving and intermediate imports, coupled with the feed¬
back of increases in agricultural prices to demand for nonagricultural pro¬
ducts.
Panel B of table 4.6 shows how saving flows adjust to meet higher
investment demand. The value of investment rises from 2.7417 to 2.928
hundred billion rupees. This increase reflects both the greater quantity of
capital goods demanded and the rise in the sector three price (due to
cost-push of intermediate inputs purchased from agriculture) from 1.0 to
1.0318. As shares of investment we have the following changes in sources
of saving:
TABLE 4.6
Effects of a Four-Percent Increase in Investment Demand for Sector Three
Products
C. Income Shares
Investment Increase Coupled With
Only Foodstock Rising
Base Investment Price Wage Markup
Run Increase Responsiveness Indexation Rates
profits stays about constant, while the output increases in the nonagricul-
tural sectors draw in more intermediate imports and drive up the trade
deficit’s share.
Both price and quantity changes enter into the adjustment. In distribu¬
tional terms, the outcome in panel C of table 4.6 is an increase in agricultur-
78 Structuralist Macroeconomics
alists’ share of income, and a fall of that of wage earners. In relative terms,
profit incomes hold roughly stable.
These patterns change when additional price and quantity reactions are
introduced into the system, as shown in the other columns of the table. The
columns headed “Foodstock price responsiveness” show what happens
when the speculation parameter crs in equation (4.6) is changed from zero
to one. There are sharper price increases, and some output response in the
nonagricultural sectors. More forced saving occurs at the expense of work¬
ers, and the income distribution shifts further toward agriculture.
In practice, partial indexation of urban wages in India to price increases
within the year appears to be the rule. The columns headed “Wage indexa¬
tion” show what happens when 20 percent of the increase in the consumer
price index as calculated in (4.8) is passed along to nominal wages in
(4.9)-(4.12). Not surprisingly, the effect is inflationary. Moreover, workers
lose from the indexation, as their income share falls from 0.3545 when
investment increases without indexation, to 0.3479. The reason is that food
supplies are assumed fixed, so that an initial increase in demand resulting
from higher money wages has to be cut back by still sharper food price
increases. The outcome is an additional shift of the income distribution
toward agriculture and a lower real wage. Profit recipients gain from bigger
markups on higher nominal variable costs.
The columns headed “Rising markup rates” summarize the effects of
raising the parameters <x3 and <x5 from zero to 2.0 and 1.5, respectively, in
equations (4.14) and (4.15). With these changes in specification, markup
rates rise along with the output-capital ratios in sectors three and five,
essentially reflecting demand-pressure on prices.15 Once again, price in¬
creases go beyond those induced by a simple increase in investment demand.
In panel C of table 4.6, it can be seen that the distributional effect favors
agriculturalists and harms wage earners; the profit share as usual holds
steady.
Each of the three shifts in the specification—foodstock speculation, wage
indexing, and markups rising in response to demand—is mildly inflationary
taken by itself, adding 5 percentage points or so to the average 14 percent
rise in agricultural prices caused by higher investment demand. However,
when the three effects are put together, the feedbacks between them are
extreme.
The agricultural prices rise by 64 and 49 percent, as shown in the “Infla¬
tionary effects” column in panel A of table 4.7. There are also substantial
increases in sectoral outputs, and the income distribution swings 7 percent¬
age points toward agriculture.
Short-Run Adjustment in Practice 79
TABLE 4.7
Effects of an Investment Increase Linked with All
Inflationary Mechanisms and Either Increased Imports of
Sector Two Commodities or Supply Response in Sectors
One and Two
C. Income Shares
Agric.
Base Inflationary Increased Supply
Run Effects Imports Response
These shifts are too large to be credible, but do reflect the model’s (and
to a degree the Indian economy’s) sensitivity to the agricultural sectors.
However, they are easily moderated by supply changes. In table 4.7 two
options are presented. First, “Increased imports” columns show the effects
of raising competitive imports into sector two from 0.0035 to 0.0235 hun¬
dred billion rupees (about 0.75 percent of initial supply). Second, the “Agri-
80 Structuralist Macroeconomics
cultural supply response” columns show what happens when output during
the year in each of the agricultural sectors rises in the response to higher
prices. The supply elasticities were set at values 0.1 and 0.2 in sectors one
and two, respectively, on the notion that there is likely to be somewhat less
market sensitivity for the staple commodities produced by cereal growers.
For short-run elasticities these values are perhaps on the high side, but were
chosen to reflect as much stabilization from supply response as might
reasonably be expected.
In both cases, the price increases are greatly moderated, as one could
already anticipate from the large entries in the northwest comer of the
inverse Jacobian matrix of table 4.5.16 Both import manipulation and farm¬
ers’ price-responsiveness (as well as other policies such as changes in pub¬
licly held foodgrain stocks) have very important macroeconomic effects in
the model. This observation also applies to the real economy of India.
Turning to another topic, we examine the effects of a 15-percent devalua¬
tion of the rupee in table 4.8. Three simulations are given, with elasticities
of export volumes from all sectors with respect to the exchange rate as¬
sumed to be zero, 0.5, and 2.0, respectively.
When there is no export response, the model follows the contractionary
devaluation scenario of chapter 2. Devaluation drives up the costs of inter¬
mediate imports, which are directly transmitted to higher prices of nona-
gricultural products. Real wages fall, pulling down aggregate demand. The
outcome is reduced production in the quantity-adjusting sectors, and lower
agricultural prices. There is an overall inflationary push, despite the reduc¬
tions in F, and P2.
Increased nominal values of exports and remittances and the reduced
volume of intermediate imports dominate higher import costs, so that the
trade deficit in rupee terms declines (panel C).17 At the same time, the
nominal value of investment demand rises along with nonagricultural
prices. The required saving comes mainly from the government (panel B)
as its nominal export subsidies fall. The net increase in saving from govern¬
ment and the trade deficit is (0.2247 — 0.1357) + (0.1539 — 0.1800) =
0.0629. As discussed in section 5.5, where money is brought into the present
model, the outcome is a reduction in money creation by 0.0629 as well. At
a time when devaluation is driving up nonagricultural prices, money supply
drops with a contractionary effect on output and growth. Finally, note that
devaluation shifts the income distribution slightly away from agriculture
(panel D) as the sector’s prices fall.
When exports respond to the exchange rate, the contractionary effects
vanish. Already an exchange rate elasticity of 0.5 induces enough export
TABLE 4.8
Effects of a Devaluation by Fifteen Percent
Export Export
Base No Export Response Response
Run Response Elast = 0.5 Elast = 2.0
C. Trade Balance
Export Export
Base No Export Response Response
Run Response Elast = 0.5 Elast = 2.0
D. Income Shares
Export Export
Base No Export Response Response
Run Response Elast = 0.5 Elast = 2.0
C. Income Shares
Output Output
Base 3.6% Up 4- Procur. 6.6% Up 4- Procur.
Run Sector I Increase Sector 1 Increase
grain price resulting from higher output can either stimulate or cut back
on demand for nonagricultural products. Farmers’ income drops as their
output price declines sharply in the face of increased supply, while the real
purchasing power of incomes generated in nonagricultural sectors goes up.
Demand for nonagricultural products will rise or fall, depending on how
these opposing income changes balance out.
In the India model, falling cereal prices slightly retard demand for sector
three products (industry) and stimulate it for sector five products (services).
At the same time, the income distribution swings against agriculture and
in favor of wages and profits. All prices fall as foodgrain output rises, due
to consumer demand and input-output linkages in the system.
The policy variable that the Indian government uses to stabilize the
economy against food output shifts is procurement. The government has to
honor the procurement price, which, with its initial value of one, lies above
the market price in both cases of output increase shown in table 4.9. The
“procurement increase” columns show what happens when the government
buys enough grain to hold the market price steady at its initial (normalized)
value of one. There is overall expansion, and government saving increases
in nominal terms despite its outlays to buy grain.
Varying procurement to stabilize prices makes GP\ almost an endoge¬
nous policy variable. When procurement is treated in this fashion, it is
natural to ask about trade-offs between the amount of government pur¬
chases required to hold market food prices constant and the level of produc¬
tion. Figure 4.2 depicts the iso-price relationship between GP] and output
Xt. The graph is essentially linear, and shows that a procurement increase
of about three billion rupees’ worth of grain will counteract a production
increase of ten billion. Procurement appears to be an effective price stabili¬
zation instrument in India.18
84 Structuralist Macroeconomics
FIGURE 4.2
Levels of Grain Production and Procurement That Maintain the Market Price at
Its Initial Level
4.6 Conclusions
the current period’s price level, as in table 4.7. Equally, saving rates could
be made dependent on income levels, or real investment might be assumed
to fall if prices go up (on the hypothesis that investment outlays are planned
in nominal, not real, terms).19 Some of these changes would make the
specification more neoclassical, as discussed in section 2.3; others would
depend on policy judgment. But all of them amount to ways of sweeping
innumerable microeconomic feedbacks to the macro system into a tidy pile;
they add little to our understanding of how the system operates in the first
place.
5
X = aK (5.1)
in which i is the daily interest rate, and w, and w,+T are wages at the
beginning and end of the period. If the money wage stays constant (w, + r
= wt), then evidently Cost = Lw,iT. Alternately, if the wage is perfectly
indexed to expected inflation and the nominal interest rate is equal to some
real rate j plus inflation (z = j + tt), then we have:
L = bx = baK (5.3)
Substitution of (5.3) into (5.2) gives an expression for the profit rate as:
(1 -f 0 wb
r = a (5.4)
~~P
Evidently, r rises with the price level but falls with both the interest rate
and the money wage. Inverting (5.4) gives:
aw( 1 + i)b
(5.5)
(a - r)
so that the maximum profit rate is the output-capital ratio a, reached when
the real wage falls to zero.
Equilibrium excess demand for output must be zero:
C + I + G - X = 0
PC = (1 + i)wL + (1 - s)rPK
Substitution of this expression into the excess demand equation and ma¬
nipulations such as those in chapter 2 give the investment-saving balance as:
g -f ya — sr = 0 (5.6)
90 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where g — I/K is the growth rate of capital stock (and output) and y =
G/X is the share of government demand in output.
Together with (5.4), equation (5.6) determines the equilibrium price level
P. To get a final expression for P, a theory of investment must be added
to the demand side. As before, returns to investment are measured by the
profit rate r. A new feature is the cost of tying up resources in physical
capital measured by the alternative uses to which they could be put. Since
capital formation is a long-term process, the real interest rate / — 7r is
the appropriate cost concept. The simplest formulation makes the growth
rate of capital depend on the difference between profit and real interest
rates, or5
p _ _ (5 - h)aw( 1 + i)b _
(5.8)
[s - (h + y)]a - g0 + h(i - n)
[s — (h + y)]o - g0 - h( 1 + tr)
For given values of the other parameters, this expression shows that work¬
ing-capital cost-push makes dP/di positive when the expected inflation rate
7T is relatively low. With more inflation, forced (dis) saving from reduced
investment demand may come into play strongly enough to make the
derivative negative. For future reference, note that simple manipulation
makes the condition (s — h)abw > Ph a requirement for working-capital
cost-push to dominate.6
Before going on to discuss money and finance, we can derive two addi¬
tional results from the saving-investment balance. First, P is a function of
i and tt from (5.8), and the profit rate r follows from (5.5). From (5.7),
investment demand thus depends only on i — it. Going through the algebra
shows that the growth rate is given by the expression:
Money and Other Assets in the Short Run 91
sg o + hya — sh(i — n)
g = ---—^-- (5.9)
s
s — h
So long as s > h (the effect on saving of profit rate increases exceeds the
effect on investment—the standard stability condition), then an interest rate
increase unambiguously reduces the rate of growth.
The second result is simply a closed form expression for commodity
excess demand, which is:
(s - h)a{ 1 + i)wb
---h(t - tt)
+ go — [s — (y + h)]a = 0 (5.10)
Excess demand on the left side of the equality is a falling function of P. This
effect represents the forced saving adjustment mechanism. Discussion of
how excess demand responds to interest rate changes can safely be post¬
poned until after details of the financial market are set out.
up” restriction that the value of assets should equal wealth puts strong
restrictions on portfolio choice, as we will see later on in this chapter.
Hence, selection of assets to be included in a formal model is not trivial,
even if one residual, such as the “bond” of traditional macro theory, is
included to absorb all the slack.
For the present, we will distinguish three sorts of assets held by persons.
The first is money, conventionally held in the form of deposits with banks.
The second takes the form of loans to firms, which in turn borrow from both
banks and the public to finance fixed and working capital needs. (Firms are
assumed not to sell equity, for the simple reason that stock markets are at
best a decoration in most poor lands). Finally, the public is assumed to hold
a congeries of assets such as currency, precious objects, and land and real
estate, which we call “gold.” This gold has its price fixed by simple market
clearing and has no value in use. This asset specification is set up to empha¬
size the differences between wealth held with banks, or the formal financial
system, and that held (perhaps with some sacrifice of liquidity) beyond the
bankers’ and tax collectors’ view. Of our three assets, deposits are fully
“monetized” or “intermediated” and gold is not. Loans to firms are some¬
where in the middle. Informal credit markets are widespread in most coun¬
tries, are often competitive and agile, and provide an area in which to hold
resources besides a mattress or a hole in the ground or the banks. They also
play an important macroeconomic role, as we will see shortly.
The balance sheets for the assumed financial system appear in table
5.1.8 At the bottom, the public holds its wealth in the form of bank deposits
Dp, loans to firms Lp, and gold. The fixed gold stock is Z. its price is
Pz and the value of gold holdings is P,Z. At the top of the table, the central
bank holds government fiscal debt F as its only asset. The corresponding
liability is commercial bank reserves H, which in the table’s simplified
accounting scheme are equivalent to the money base, or high-powered
money.
The commercial banks have as assets their reserves, plus loans or net
credit to the private sector. For simplicity, all credit is assumed to go to
firms (in volume Lh). Bank liabilities are deposits held by the public and
firms (respectively DP and Df). Firms receive loans both from banks and
the public, while their assets are their bank deposits and the value of their
fixed capital PK. After cancellation of all items entering on both sides of
the accounts, wealth W turns out to be equal to H + PK + P,Z, or the
sum of the money base and the values of capital and gold. Consolidation
of the bank’s account shows that H + Lb = Dp + Dfi or outstanding
credit to the government and firms just equals the money supply. These
Money and Other Assets in the Short Run 93
TABLE 5.1
Financial Balance Sheets
Assets Liabilities
Central Bank
Commercial Banks
Firms
Public
Df = wbaK — H -\- Lb — DP
where the second equality follows from the consolidated balance sheet of
the banking system.
The next assumption is that banks don’t hold excess reserves and that
the banking authorities enforce a reserve requirement of the form H =
lx(Df + Dp), with ju, < 1. (We could alternately—and realistically—assume
that the authorities restrict bank credit Lb to a given level and get essentially
94 Structuralist Macroeconomics
the same results.) Finally, assume that the public’s demand for deposits
takes the form DP — i|/(/', id, tr, ttz)W, where W is total wealth and the
arguments of the function v|> are discussed in more detail below. In effect,
the public is assumed to keep a fraction ij/ = DP/W of its wealth in the
form of bank deposits, providing liabilities for the banking system to trans¬
form into loans to firms. From the equation for Df just above, excess
demand equilibrium for these loans becomes:
wbaK — (5.11)
Deposits DP\ id — 7r
Gold Z: 7TZ — 7T
moment, so that the interest rate and gold price adjust to bring demands
in line with supply. The excess demand balances (5.11) and (5.12) are
brought into equilibrium in markets for loans and gold. When excess de¬
mands for these two assets are zero, then excess demand for money (by
Walras’s Law) will be as well.
The sensible way to figure out how a model with three assets works is to
attack it by stages. In this section, we follow this strategy by leaving gold
out. The relevant equations are commodity excess demand (5.10) and loan
market excess demand (5.11), dropping the terms tt2, Pz and Z. For a fixed
nominal wage w these equations constitute an equilibrium system for the
commodity price level P and nominal interest rate /. The growth rate g
follows as a dependent variable from (5.9). For the moment the hypothesis
of static expectations is maintained, so that expected inflation tt is a prede¬
termined variable.
The Jacobian for (5.10) and (5.11) takes the form:
—a (s — h)awb
--h
P P
tyK i|f,W
where:
This long expression represents the excess of saving over investment when
the profit rate takes its maximum value a, and in practice will be positive.
Along with the condition i|/, < 0 (demand for deposits declines when the
interest rate on loans rises), a > 0 assures that the trace of the Jacobian
will be negative.
The determinant is:
To check the stability condition A > 0, observe that the slopes of the excess
demand functions for commodities and loans respectively are:
dP ($ — h)awb — hP
di p a
and
dP _ vj/,TF
(5.16)
~di\.i|)K
Since \|/, < 0, the loan market equilibrium derivative is positive. The
detailed explanation depends on the peculiarities of the asset structure set
out in table 5.1, but would go through in its essentials under other specifica¬
tions. In the present model, the immediate impact of an increase in the price
level is to raise the value of firms’ physical capital PK. With an agile equity
market, this capital gain would soon pass through into an increase in
price/earnings ratios on common stock. When equities are not widely
traded (the assumption underlying table 5.1, and the truth in most poor
countries), the assumption has to be that sooner or later firms will put their
windfall gains to use by demanding more loans. Bank lending is limited by
the reserve requirement; hence, public lending LP must rise. The requisite
resources are drawn into the loan market by an increase in the interest rate
and a reduction in bank deposits as determined by vjb-
In macro equilibrium, comparison of (5.15) and (5.16) with (5.14) shows
that the determinant A will be positive when the slope of the loan market
schedule from (5.16) exceeds the commodity market slope (5.15). In con¬
nection with (5.8) it was already noted that this latter relationship between
P and i can have either a positive or negative slope, depending on whether
cost pressure or investment demand reduction from a rising interest rate is
stronger. Macro instability occurs when working-capital cost-push is force¬
ful enough (or expected inflation it low enough) to make the curve repre¬
senting commodity market equilibrium steeper than the curve for the mar¬
ket for loans.
Figure 5.1 illustrates determination of short-run equilibrium, when the
price level rises in response to higher interest costs. Adjustment dynamics
are shown by the small arrows. In the upper quadrant, output is in excess
demand below the commodity market curve and loans are in excess demand
to the left of the loan market schedule.
Money and Other Assets in the Short Run 97
FIGURE 5.1
Determination of Short-Run Equilibrium When the Only Assets Held by the
Public Are Bank Deposits and Loans to Firms
Note: There is assumed to be a strong effect of the interest rate on the price level via working-capital
costs.
The main comparative static result is that the loan market curve will shift
to the right either when there is monetary contraction or when the money
demand function x)/ shifts autonomously upward.10 The outcome will be a
rise in the interest rate i and declines in investment demand and the growth
rate g. In a more complete model with variable capacity utilization, the
story would be similar but slightly more complex. A rising interest rate
would reduce investment demand through (5.9). At the same time, it would
be reasonable to postulate an aggregate supply function of the form
X = X[P/{ 1 + /»]
At the initial price level P, an increased i would lead to cost pressures that
would induce producers to reduce their output X. If supply went down
more than demand, the resulting aggregate excess demand would lead to
a rising price along the lines of figure 5.1. Thus, monetary contraction
would not only slow growth and drive up prices, but also reduce output and
employment in the short run. The possibility that stagflation may result
98 Structuralist Macroeconomics
from economic stabilization policies that restrict the money supply has been
heavily emphasized in macro-policy literature in developing countries in
recent years.11
A second comparative static exercise of interest has to do with changes
in the expected inflation rate n. In equation (5.8) an increase in n will
reduce the real interest rate and stimulate investment demand, shifting up
the commodity market market curve in figure 5.1. For a given price level,
the loan market curve has to shift to the right, with a higher value of i
countering the increase in 7r to maintain equilibrium in (5.11). The outcome
is a higher level of P—an increase in inflationary expectations drives up
aggregate demand and the current output price. A similar linkage will turn
out to be important in the long-run stability analysis under rational (not
static) expectations about inflation that appear in chapter 6. But before
going on to ask how well short-run results carry over into longer periods,
we turn to the next section for a description of the macro system when there
are assets besides money and loans to firms.
such as “gold.” In the former case, the deposit rate strategy could easily
backfire, as we demonstrate shortly. This possibility perhaps explains why
generously offered advice from flying experts about interest rate policy in
the Third World has been almost universally declined.13
The model with gold is based on the three excess demand functions
(5.10)—(5.12). For the record, one can write out the comparative statics of
a change in the deposit rate in the following matrix equation form:
a B
0 dP 0 0
~P ~P
£K £,W (1 - g)z
*t3
^3
0
Pz _ N
1
I
The symbol a has been defined in (5.13), B stands for (s — h)awb — Ph,
and the subscripts / and d respectively denote partial derivatives with
respect to the interest rate on loans to firms and the deposit rate.
The standard conditions for stability of a three-dimensional system like
(5.17) are that the trace of the Jacobian should be negative, the sum of the
three second-order principal minors (or 2 X 2 determinants linking each
possible pair of excess demand functions) should be positive, and the third-
order determinant should be negative. Both trace and second-order condi¬
tions follow easily when i|/, < 0 and £, <0, or an increase in the interest
rate on loans pulls wealth holding away from both bank deposits and gold.
After some manipulation, the third-order determinant can be written as:
di (XZtV _ y\ \
[(1 - 0v|fd + iJ/0]
t y i /r ,
(5.19)
did TP7P
di / o [7 « > 3+ ©
100 Structuralist Macroeconomics
H — wbaK
U < H + PK
in which the right side is certain to be less than one. Under these cir¬
cumstances, financial liberalization will not bring good results, at least un¬
der the standard assumption that financial assets are gross substitutes, or
H'rf >
The difference between the two extremes hinges on the degree of financial
intermediation that the commercial banks can legally provide. The informal
market operates with no reserve requirement, channeling resources toward
firms with great efficiency. By contrast, a fraction of each new deposit in
the commercial banks goes to reserves and cannot be loaned out. Thus,
unless banks largely draw hoarded assets into deposits when id goes up, the
overall effect of reform can be stagflationary.14
Money and Other Assets in the Short Run 101
These effects can be illustrated in a diagram if we first solve for the price
of gold by eliminating the wealth variable (tV = H + PK + PzZ) from
(5.11) and (5.12):
^ (H/fx) — wbak
(5.20)
vj7[ Z
Clearly, Pz falls as Z rises with unit elasticity. But the sign of its response
to interest rate changes is ambiguous since both and i|/( are negative. If
|£,-/£;| > then the derivative dPz/di will be negative. Again, the
assumption is that the public is loath to hold gold when returns to alterna¬
tive assets rise.
Plugging PzZ from (5.20) back into (5.11) allows a solution of the system
in the variables i and P alone. For the case of a positive response of the price
level to the interest rate due to working capital cost, the comparative statics
are shown in figure 5.2.
FIGURE 5.2
Effects of an Increase in the Deposit Rate When Increased Deposits Come Mainly
from Gold Holdings and a Rise in the Interest Rate Drives Up the Price Level by
Working-Capital Cost
102 Structuralist Macroeconomics
The deposit rate increase pulls resources into the banking system, having
the same impact as an increase in the money supply. The loan market
schedule shifts to the left. At the same time, if the saving rate goes up in
response to a rise in id, there will be less demand pressure at a given interest
rate and the commodity market schedule shifts down. The outcome will be
lower prices and interest rates, coupled with faster growth. The financial
reform package works well, with the only untoward consequence being a
possible rise in the price of gold in response to the interest rate changes.
Gold speculation resulting from strong expectations about a rise in its price
could be destabilizing in the medium run, as discussed further on.
If the loan market curve in figure 5.2 were shifted to the right instead
of to the left, it would correspond to a situation in which the deposit rate
increase mostly pulls asset demand from loans to firms. If, in addition, the
saving rate response to id is weak (a small downward shift in the commodity
market schedule), the outcome would be a higher price level and slower
growth. In this case, as in the monetary contraction discussed in connection
with figure 5.1, orthodoxy gives rise to stagflation in the short run.
Finally, figure 5.3 illustrates monetary contraction, or a deposit rate
FIGURE 5.3
Effects of an Increase in the Deposit Rate When Increased Deposits Come Mainly
from the Public's Loans to Firms and a Rise in the Interest Rate Reduces the
Price Level by Decreasing Investment Demand
Money and Other Assets in the Short Run 103
increase with stable gold demand in the case when the price level responds
negatively to the interest rate. The result is more traditional in that growth
slows and prices fall.
These outcomes suggest that simple pronouncements about financial pol¬
icy don’t make much sense, even in poor countries where financial markets
are not notably complex.
Moreover, it is easy to spin out disquieting medium-run asset market
scenarios set off" by short-run events such as depicted in figure 5.2. For
example, an increase in the deposit leads the interest rate i and output price
P to fall and the gold price Pz to rise. Suppose that expected price changes
7r and ttz follow in the same direction. Then the returns to holding deposits
and gold (respectively id — tt and itz — ir) will rise relative to the return
to loans (/ — 7r). The corresponding attempts to shift portfolios toward
money and gold could lead to an accelerating gold price increase and shifts
away from loans and (perhaps later) money. The final outcome could be
rising interest rates and finally economic collapse as working capital finance
dried up. Such unstable expectational bubbles are not easily ruled out when
there are three assets on the scene.15
Even leaving aside unstable dynamic stories, there is quite a lot else that
can happen in the economy as the results of these last two sections are
extended toward the medium run. But the lesson remains that if assets held
as gold, land, or other hoards are not easily relinquished when bank deposit
rates go up, then aggressive interest rate policy will do little good for the
economy in the short to medium run.
TABLE 5.2
Equations to Put Money in the India Model
TABLE 5.3
New Symbols for Putting Money in the India Model
I. Endogenous variables
III. Parameters
TABLE 5.4
Effects of Contractionary Monetary Policy and Devaluation in the India Model
Incorporating Money
Agr. sav. 0.5373 0.5723 0.5370 Dom. inv. 2.3186 2.3998 2.3692
Wage sav. 0.6414 0.6478 0.6463 Imp. inv. 0.1211 0.1211 0.1393
Prof sav. 0.5325 0.5773 0.5388 Pr. stocks 0.4048 0.4272 0.4127
Trade def. 0.1800 0.1962 0.1554 Gov. stocks -0.1028 -0.1028 -0.1028
Gov. sav. 0.1357 0.1368 0.2260
Deprec. 0.7148 0.7148 0.7148
C. Income Shares
Base Mon.
Run Policy Deval.
Money, Inflation,
and Growth
varies to alter the real interest rate i — P and drives investment to equality
with saving. As in most Marxian models, investment is finally determined
by saving, but with the particularly un-Marxian rationale, expectations
twist. How this saving-investment adjustment is linked with financial mar¬
kets is described in section 6.1.
With wage and inflation dynamics set up in the first two sections, the
story about transitions between steady states is told in section 6.3, when
money and loans by the public to firms are the only assets in the system.
The possible role of “gold” and other extensions are briefly sketched in
section 6.4, while an appendix contains the mathematical underpinnings of
some of the analysis that is done graphically in the body of this chap¬
ter.1
and
where the actual inflation rate P replaces the expected rate tt in the invest¬
ment demand term h(i — P) and the money demand function v)/(i — -Pi-
Adjustment stories in perfect foresight models are often farfetched, per¬
haps justly so in light of the incredibility of the hypothesis itself. In the
present model, R and V are given at any point of time from dynamic
processes to be described below. Hence we need two variables to adjust
“within the moment” to assure that (6.1) and (6.2) are satisfied.
Look first at the market for commodities. If the price-wage ratio R rises
from an initial equilibrium level, the macroeconomic outcome is an incipi¬
ent excess of saving over investment (given that capitalists’ saving rates
exceed those of workers). In an agile financial market, one might expect the
real rate of interest to fall, to stimulate investment demand, and to restore
equilibrium. This bit of entelechy can occur through either a decrease in the
nominal interest rate / or an increase in the inflation rate P. Assume the
latter, that inflation accelerates when there is initial excess saving supply.
Then if the interest rate goes up when there is excess demand for loans in
(6.2), we have a locally stable short-run adjustment process. Financiers are
assumed to sense potential imbalance in commodity markets and adjust
their inflation expectations and thus the cost of borrowing rapidly enough
to prevent disequilibrium from actually coming about.2
This short-run market balance can be perturbed by shifts in the state
A
demand effects are more important, the equilibrium (i,P) locus will have
a positive slope.
Comparative statics of the dominant working-capital case are shown in
figure 6.1. In the upper diagram an increase in V, the ratio of money to
FIGURE 6.1
Comparative Statics of an Increase in the Money-Capital Ratio V (Upper
Diagram) and Price- Wage Ratio R (Lower Diagram) When an Interest Rate
Increase Drives Up the Price Level through Higher Working-Capital Costs in the
Short Run
capital stock, requires a lower real interest rate to maintain money market
balance; for a given P, i must decrease. After commodity market reactions
are taken into account, a rise in V is associated with a lower interest rate
and a higher rate of inflation.
In the lower diagram of figure 6.1, we see that an increase in the price-
wage ratio R is associated with a higher interest rate at a given inflation rate
Money, Inflation, and Growth 113
in the commodity market (as just discussed). In the loan market, an increase
in R raises the value of the term (R /fx)V = H/jjlwK or the degree of
monetization measured in wage units. Once again the real interest rate must
fall, so the loan market curve shifts to the left. A higher price-wage ratio
is associated with faster inflation, but an ambiguous shift in the rate of
interest.
Figure 6.2 shows what happens when investment demand responses dom-
inate the interest rate effect. In the upper diagram, an increase in the
money-capital ratio reduces both the interest and inflation rates. The lower
A
Suppose there is ongoing price inflation at the rate P, where as usual the
A
FIGURE 6.3
Variations in the Real Wage over Time When There Are Periodic Money Wage
Adjustments with an Ongoing Price Inflation at Rate P and the Target Wage Is
0)*
Money, Inflation, and Growth 115
There is a cycle between the values o>* and a)*e~^x, which is of course
repetitive when the inflation rate stays constant.
Over time, the average real wage to is given by:
If we let PX = p, then from PHospitaPs rule one can easily show that
co approaches co* as p approaches zero, that is, the average wage becomes
the target either when inflation falls to zero or when there is instantaneous
indexing. Similarly, one has:
a co co*
ap p2
But since ep = l-t-p + p2/2 + ..., this derivative is negative for p >
0. The real wage declines when either the inflation rate is higher or the
indexing period gets longer. If the period is one year, the following numbers
illustrate the impact of increases in the inflation rate on the real wage (and,
for later reference, its inverse or the price-wage ratio):
Annual
Inflation Real Price- Wage
Rate Wage Ratio
and so on. In countries where 100-percent wage indexing has been applied,
such uniformity is not observed.4 However, we will assume that strictly
uniform wage adjustment exists to make analytical discussion of the dynam¬
ics of inflation easier.
Equation (6.3) is a relationship between the average real wage and infla¬
tion that would hold at all times if the economy’s wage indexing rules were
followed exactly. It summarizes institutional arrangements that give equi¬
librium on the supply side of the labor market (with “supply” referring not
to the number of people seeking jobs, but rather to the real wage consistent
A #
with indexing rules when the inflation rate is P). By inverting the equation,
the supply side value of the price-wage ratio R s can be written as:
P\
Rs = (6.4)
g>*(1 _ e-K)
The derivative of Rs with respect to both the inflation rate P and the
indexing period X will be positive. The second derivative is also positive, or
A
When the labor market is tight, R lies below Rs, and w > P. Restated in
terms of R, this out-of-equilibrium adjustment rule becomes:
Note from (6.4) that Rs is a function of P, while from (6.1) and (6.2) P is
determined by R and V Hence, (6.5) is a shorthand representation of how
R evolves over time as a function of itself and V We have one of the two
differential equations for the state variables that we require.
The other equation can easily be written as:
A A A A
V — H — P — K (6.6)
For the moment, assume that the growth rate of the money base (H) is
exogenous. Equations (6.1) and (6.2) give P and i, while (5.9) gives K (or
g) after the current inflation rate is substituted for the expected rate tt. In
effect, V becomes a function of R and V. Given equations (6.5) and (6.6),
the next step is to consider their stability as represented by the Jacobian
matrix:
'dV/dV a V/dR"
dR/dV dR/dR
— or + -
so that stability occurs if the term in the southwest corner is not too strongly
negative. The rationale goes as follows:
1. In the southeast of the Jacobian, begin by observing from figures 6.1 and 6.2 that
a reduction in the price-wage ratio R pulls down the inflation rate in the short
run, unless investment demand is highly sensitive to real interest rate changes.
But then from (6.4) the price-wage ratio consistent with the wage indexing goes
up. Workers’ nominal wage demands moderate since the difference between the
current real wage and the target declines (as also would the level of employment
in a more realistic model with variable capacity utilization). If money wage
growth slows sufficiently, R = P — w will rise. Hence, the derivative dR/dR
takes a negative sign. From (6.5) it is clear that this result depends on a large
118 Structuralist Macroeconomics
A A
The overall stability condition is that the slope of the locus of points along
which V = 0 should be less (more negative) than the locus along which
R = 0 in a diagram with V on the horizontal axis and R on the vertical.
An increase in the rate of growth of the money supply (H) shifts the V
— 0 locus to the right—either the inflation or growth rate has to rise to meet
the steady growth condition H = P + K, and either shift is associated with
increased monetization V for a given price-wage ratio R.
If stability is assumed, figure 6.4 illustrates the dynamics in the dominant
working-capital case. The adjustment involves a gradual increase in V and
a decline in R from the model’s initial equilibrium at A. Since at the new
steady state at B the labor market will be in equilibrium, (6.4) shows that
the inflation rate P will be lower. Also, since H = P + K the growth rate
will be higher. Compared across steady states, faster money growth leads
to lower inflation, more rapid capital stock growth, and a higher real wage
when interest rate increases drive up working-capital costs. The faster
Money, Inflation, and Growth 119
FIGURE 6.4
Adjustment between Steady States under Rational Expectations in an Economy
Where an Interest Rate Increase Drives Up the Price- Wage Ratio from Working
Capital Cost-Push in the Short Run
Note: Faster money growth gives lower inflation, an increased real wage, and faster output growth.
Note: Faster money growth gives higher inflation, a reduced real wage, and faster output growth.
120 Structuralist Macroeconomics
monetary expansion permits more rapid growth and less inflationary cost
pressure in the long run.
Details of the transition between steady states depend on the specific
dynamic assumptions of the model. In the case at hand, when money
growth is jumped up from an initial steady state, V or H/PK will start to
rise while R is momentarily stationary. The implication from figure 6.1 is
that inflation will speed up. Thereafter, R will begin to fall (as it would with
monetary expansion in the static expectations story of figure 5.1) and the
inflation rate will follow. The adjustment pattern for “half-cycle” conver¬
gence as assumed in figure 6.4 will be initial acceleration and then decelera¬
tion of P. There could be further oscillations with the adjustment trajectory
spiraling in toward point B, but it is convenient to assume them away.
Adjustment in the alternative commodity market case in which an inter¬
est rate reduction drives up the price-wage ratio by increasing aggregate
demand is shown in figure 6.5. As usual, the results are more traditional:
an increase in the growth rate of money base leads to higher steady-state
inflation by driving up the price-wage ratio R. The money-capital ratio
A
V rises as well, so that the real interest rate i — P will fall. From (5.9)
investment demand will be stimulated, so that the growth rate goes up in
this case as well. There is not a sufficient fall in the interest rate to allow
real wages to rise. Forced saving supports faster growth in the long run.
These results are fairly straightforward extensions of the short-run analy¬
sis of section 5.2, to a situation where plausible price and wage dynamics
apply. With volatile rational expectations built into the specification, the
model’s stability properties are bound to be tenuous, as indeed they are. If
there is stability, it comes from two linked relations. First, a rise in the
price-wage ratio R (or a fall in the real wage) is linked to a faster inflation
A
hypothesis makes sense under the circumstances in which the central bank
has both monetary and nonmonetary assets in its portfolio and can sell them
back and forth (typically in open market or foreign exchange operations)
with other agents in the system. Strictly speaking, such maneuvers are ruled
out here by the balance sheets of table 5.1. Indeed, since there are no taxes
in the model, monetary expansion is determined by the needs of government
finance: dH/dt = PG. Plugging this expression in to the rest of the equa¬
tions shows that the growth rate of money base is given by:
H = 1 (6.7)
ju, v|(R + ba
A A
Bringing gold into the system means that another asset market and state
variables have to be considered. Define the state variable as U = PzZ/
PK, or the value of gold holdings relative to the capital stock. The short-run
equilibrium conditions incorporating gold become:
for gold. Stability analysis could be done as before, by inverting (6.8) and
(6.9) for P and Pz and then substituting the resulting expressions into
differential equations for the state variables U and V. We forego the gory
details and make only brief comments on the nature of steady-state equi¬
libria.
122 Structuralist Macroeconomics
£ = (l - £) - ^ yaR
n v|//? + (1 — i)ba
Note that a rise in the deposit rate id increases v|/ and reduces £, so that its
effect on money growth is ambiguous. However, enthusiasts for financial
liberalization presumably suppose that the effect of the change in v|/ would
be stronger, so that money growth falls. In the case where aggregate de¬
mand effects from interest rate changes dominate, figure 6.5 shows that
inflation would drop off and the real wage would rise, but the growth rate
would decline. A strong saving response to higher deposit rates could
salvage the growth rate, although empirical evidence suggests little to hope
for on this score. The story in figure 6.4 (dominant working-capital effects)
is worse, for there the inflation rate would rise and real wage decline in the
long run.
The conclusion is that unless coupled with expansionary monetary policy
from some other source (perhaps a reduction in reserve requirements),
financial liberalization will do little to benefit economic performance in the
medium run. Moreover, it may not even lead to an increase in financial
depth, as measured by the ratio H/PK. Simple manipulation of (6.8) and
(6.9) shows that this variable can easily move in either direction across
steady states.
A final question might be raised regarding the two aggregate demand
cases so scrupulously distinguished in the analysis: Which one really mat¬
ters in a given economy over a given time span? Regarding timing, invest¬
ment demand responses to interest rate changes may take longer to build
up than working-capital costs. The implication is that the effects shown
in figure 6.5 (faster money expansion increases both inflation and growth)
will hold in the longer run, although one could scarcely be sure. In any
case, which effect dominates is an empirical matter that remains to be
explored.
The evidence from a few econometric studies seems to show that the
working-capital channel is the one that matters in the short run in develop¬
ing economies, while traditionally Keynesian responses are more important
in the longer run.5 Proponents of deposit rate increases might draw support
from these conclusions since their nostrum works better just under such
circumstances. Nonetheless, the situation remains complex—too complex
for any simple policy prescription along financial liberalization (or other)
lines to be worth serious thought.
Money, Inflation, and Growth 123
Appendix
A more formal stability analysis for the model of this chapter is straight¬
forward, but tedious to work out. A sketch begins with solving the commod¬
ity market demand-supply balance (6.1) for the interest rate,
_ A \R - B
B - A2R
which will generate a positive value for i so long as both R and B are
positive. The sign of the derivative depends on A \ — A 2 or [5 — (y + h)]
A
A further step in solving (6.1) and (6.2) for i and P is to rewrite the latter
equation as:
R V/y, — ba
i — P — A (6.11)
R(V + 1)
where A is the inverse function of ij/ and has a negative first derivative. It
A
is easy to show that the real interest rate i — P must fall in the loan
market when either the price-wage ratio R or the degree of monetization
V goes up. Let A* = AV[R(V + l)]2 < 0, where A' is the derivative
of A. Then for reference the expressions for the partial derivatives of
(6.11) are:
(6.12)
124 Structuralist Macroeconomics
and
— = A *ba(V + 1) (6.13)
dR
Solving (6.10) and (6.11) for i and P is straightforward. The results are:
and
When both commodity and loan market equilibrium are taken into ac¬
count as in these equations, di/dR still has an ambiguous sign. The positive
effect comes from the bracketed term multiplying R in (6.14). Equation
(5.13) shows that the bracket just equals a > 0. The negative effect comes
from the derivative of A with respect to R, as previously discussed. The
corresponding partial derivative makes di/dV clearly negative.
Recall that the term [(5 — h)ab — hR] in (6.15) is positive when an
increase in the interest rate drives up prices, and negative otherwise. Under
A
is more important. The same effects go into dP/dR, for which the formal
expression is:
bP_
[a - 8A*ba(V + 1)] (6.16)
Jr
where:
8 = (s — h)ab — hR
V = (.* +,U£
\ss —
- h )
'.V/ji — ba
[ 1R(V + 1)
- i(V,R)
sg o + hya
+ H (6.18)
s — h
and
R = <M* - (6.19)
{shab + 8) • A*Rba(V + 1) — a
effect, the northwest term will be negative. Since aRs/dP > 0, the south¬
west term will be negative when a — 8A*Rba{V + 1) is strongly positive.
A
But from (6.16) this condition just means that dP/dR should be large. The
trace condition for stability will be satisfied for 8 > 0 under these condi¬
tions. Higher inflation or stronger investment demand would make 8 < 0,
but by continuity of the functions stability should still be observed for values
of 8 not far below zero.
The determinant of the Jacobian is proportional to the quantity:
A*R ^1 — + 8
126 Structuralist Macroeconomics
dRs
A
a < 0
dP
dRs
A
dP 1
Trade Balance
Complications
a UITE A LOT has already been said about the commodity trade
entry in the balance of payments. Recall the contractionary devaluation tale
of chapter 2, the travails of agriculture and mineral exporters in chapter 3,
and the empirical wrinkles of chapter 4.
Perhaps surprisingly, trade poses still more riddles, especially about di¬
rections of causality in the macro economy. There are two key equations
for what orthodox theorists call internal and external balance, but about a
half dozen potentially endogenous variables enter into them. Hence, infor¬
mation beyond the equations must be used to specify chains of economic
causes and the corresponding adjustment processes. There is no reason to
expect the model to be the same for all countries or all times.
Section 7.1 sets up internal and external balance equations, or the saving
gap and trade gap as they are known in the development literature. Section
7.2 explains the disequilibrium two-gap planning model interpretation of
the balances, as well as two equilibrium adjustment processes for the rate
of growth. The first has investment determined from saving, while competi¬
tive imports vary to close the balance of trade. The second, more realistic
for application in poor countries, has growth fixed by available capital goods
imports, while the income distribution changes to equilibrate saving supply
128 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where /**() is the world price of intermediate imports and a0 is the corre¬
sponding input-output coefficient. The money wage is w and the labor-
output ratio is z. All wage income is consumed, and a share 5 of profits is
saved, so that the value of consumption is given by:
where B is the deficit in dollars.1 Insertion of (7.2), (7.3), and (7.4) into (7.1)
gives a condition for zero excess demand of the nationally produced good:
Equations (7.5) and (7.6) represent internal and external balance of the
economy, respectively. Two variables must adjust to assure the balances
hold in equilibrium. Various stable marriages are discussed in the following
two sections. In preparation, we follow our usual strategy of dividing (7.5)
and (7.6) by the value of capital stock, PK, to restate them as:
ST
[0 + (1 - ®)qPf]g-« - qb = 0 (7.7)
1 + T
and
is almost always positive for poor countries: net capital inflow (or the trade
deficit) is less than the value of capital goods imports.3 From (7.8) the
condition A > 0 implies that [q(P*a0 — e,P*) — e0]w < 0- The interpreta¬
tion is that exports exceed intermediate imports, or that the country runs
a surplus on current trade to pay for the portion of its investment imports
not financed from abroad. This sort of trade surplus strongly influences
external adjustment in a semi-industrial country, as will be discussed in
detail shortly.
dg _ _ <7
g
qP*(\ - 0)
from (7.8).
Trade Balance Complications 131
The internal balance slope is less than the one for external balance. A unit
increase in b permits g to go up by more along (7.8) than (7.7) because only
a portion of the commodities required for capital formation is supplied from
foreign trade. This distinction is illustrated by figure 7.1.4
Capital Stock
Growth Rater? External Balance
Internal Balance
or Saving Gap
FIGURE 7.1
External Balance (Trade Gap) and Internal Balance (Saving Gap) Trade-Offs
between the Trade Deficit and Capital Stock Growth
dm
Fm[qb - qP* (1 - 0)g - qP$a0u - m\ (7.11)
~dt
The nominal exchange rate is assumed constant and since there is free
foreign trade the law of one price applies: P — eP*. The markup rate is
determined from (7.2), and the economy is supposed to operate at full
capacity so the u is fixed. (Flexible wages and free capital-labor substitution
may be postulated to back this hypothesis up.) Finally, the allowable trade
deficit b is set by capital market conditions from abroad.
Under all these assumptions, it is easy to see that (7.10) and (7.11) define
a stably adjusting system in g and m. The economics is simple. A unit
increase in b, the trade deficit relative to the capital stock, generates enough
saving to raise the growth rate by q/[Q + (1 — Q)qP* ], from (7.10). But
from (7.11) the extra growth uses only P* (1 — 0) in imports of capital
goods, and the rest of the increment in foreign resources can go to competi¬
tive imports m. What happens when b is reduced and m tends to fall below
zero is left unexplained.
This story clearly focuses on the saving gap—conditions of productivity
and thrift within a country and capital donors’ largesse abroad provide the
saving that determines g. Then competitive imports adjust to keep trade in
balance. The two-gap dilemma is dissolved by free trade. Not surprisingly,
neoclassical trade theorists are the principal exponents of the foregoing sort
of model.6
Trade Balance Complications 133
and
Markup Rate
Note: The dashed lines show the effect of an increase in the intermediate import price, or an "oil shock."
saving exceeds that provided by a higher deficit alone, and r must rise. In
an alternative specification with capacity utilization as the adjusting vari¬
able, a larger deficit would permit both higher output and faster growth.
As a final exercise, consider what happens under an “oil shock” or
increase in the intermediate import price P* in the two specifications. When
growth is saving-determined in (7.10) and (7.11), it is easy to see that a rise
in P* will cut back on both g and competitive imports m. Figure 7.2 shows
what happens in the forced saving model. The higher import bill represents
additional savings so that for a given r, growth will be slowed from the trade
gap, or that schedule shifts leftward. The outcome is a lower markup and
(from arguments similar to those above) slower growth. In an output¬
adjusting model, capacity utilization would decline from lower aggregate
demand, as in the model of contractionary devaluation of chapter 2. A
lower markup is how the system adapts to fixed capacity utilization.
Regrettably, taxonomy runs rampant in this discussion of the two-gap
model; it often does when foreign trade is the subject at hand. The differ¬
ences in response are substantial enough to suggest that one should be quite
clear about causal linkages in the system before jumping into policy advice.
From a structuralist perspective, a model on which income distribution or
level of output bears the brunt of adjustment looks decidedly more relevant
than one in which freely adjusting foreign trade smooths all external shocks
away. But as we see in the following section, there are further possibilities.
Trade Balance Complications 135
Why can’t the exchange rate vary to smooth the two-gap kink away? If
not constrained by the asset market (see chapter 8), in principle it can bear
some part of macro adjustment. But even in commodity markets there are
limits—no plausible exchange appreciation is going to turn Kuwait into a
net importer. Moreover, the macro correlates of exchange rate adjustment
may not be pleasing. To see why, consider a model in which capacity
utilization rises in response to excess commodity demand in (7.7) and the
exchange rate goes up when there is excess demand for dollars (a positive
left-hand side) in (7.8). The growth rate, the markup, and the trade deficit
are assumed to be fixed. This specification is not greatly different from that
of the mineral-exporter model of chapter 3, and addresses the same issues
discussed there.
The details of this model closure show up in the total differentials of
equations (7.7) and (7.8):
ST h
du —q(\ + r)a0h
1 + T <1
+
h
3
o
+ dg - db = (7.14)
q( 1 - &)P* q_ 0
With e0 < 0 (elastic exports, again) the trace of the Jacobian matrix
multiplying du and dq will be safely negative. The same condition assures
a positive determinant A:
hz srue0
A =-
ug (1 + r)q
136 Structuralist Macroeconomics
h + ®g
-q du
u
e0u
-•*
—\
©
"0
1
y
q
du u
— = — - P*a0u) + sP%a0u]
dq 0g
FIGURE 7.4
Effects of an Increase in the Real Exchange Rate q on Capacity Utilization and
the Trade Deficit When Devaluation Is Expansionary (Upper Diagram) or
Contractionary (Lower Diagram)
the internal balance or saving gap equation (7.15) will be less negative than
that of the external balance or trade gap (7.8). In (7.15) an increase in
q raises capacity utilization u at a given trade deficit b when h > 0. Under
this condition, along with e0 < 0, a higher q reduces the deficit for a given
level of u in (7.8). The outcome is shown in the upper diagram of figure 7.4
—capacity utilization goes up and the deficit falls. For e0 > 0, b can rise
along with q, as shown in the lower diagram. Devaluation under such
circumstances may worsen both the trade deficit and the level of economic
activity.
If we banish the lower diagram by assumption, then this last model is
quite standard—the exchange rate does the usual things and higher capital
stock growth stimulates aggregate demand. Note, however, that from (7.15)
the profit rate (1 — coz — qP*a0)u initially falls when q goes up. Hence,
140 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where i is the (real) interest rate on F If reserve changes are zero, then in
the overall balance of payments the current account B will have to be offset
by increases in F, or capital inflows:
—B -f — = —B + gfF = 0 (7.18)
Equations (7.17)-(7.19) can be combined with (7.1) and (7.2) to give new
versions of the internal and external balance conditions (7.5) and (7.6).
Assume that / is constant so that gf = g, where g is the growth rate of
capital stock. Division of these new balance equations by PK (the value of
capital stock) then permits them to be stated as:
and
internal balance, the growth rate is independent of the export share, but its
derivative with respect to / is given by:
142 Structuralist Macroeconomics
The term in the numerator after the first equality is the difference between
the ratio of net exports to capital stock and the interest costs on capital
goods imports. This expression represents the recurring foreign exchange
surplus that can be generated by putting foreign debt to use for capital
formation. Countries without good export prospects could find this surplus
negative; the implication is that they would be unlikely to have access to
capital markets in the first place. For present purposes we assume the
numerator positive so that an increase in debt permits faster growth along
the trade gap, but bear in mind that some economies may not be so for¬
tunate.13 The expression after the second equality shows that having a
growth rate less than the real interest rate on one’s loans may be a sign
of this sort of international impoverishment (under our standard assump¬
tion that financial capital inflows do not pay for physical capital imports:
PH\ -&)>/).
Suppose that the country passes this means test and is eligible for interna¬
tional loans. How does their presence affect the relative slopes of the trade
and saving gaps? Recall from the discussion of figure 7.1 that the trade gap
is usually assumed to be steeper, because the denominator in the term after
the second equality in (7.23) is less than the denominator in (7.22). Note
now, however, that if the interest rate i is high relative to the growth rate
g, the usual condition can reverse and the derivative in (7.23) can be less
than that in (7.22). The reason is that interest charges add to the current
account deficit one-for-one, while they only reduce national saving by the
fraction s. On a long-term basis, an increase in a country’s creditworthiness
as demonstrated by a rise in / may add more to its national saving than to
its available foreign exchange. The effect on the economy would be contrac¬
tionary—in a model with output adjusting to national excess demand, the
Trade Balance Complications 143
There is a final observation on the role of exports in all the models of this
chapter: there is no very clear linkage between the net export share and
other variables of interest, such as the rate of growth. A country at neoclas¬
sical full employment would demonstrate a negative relationship between
exports as a fraction of potential output and the capital stock growth rate.
Physical resources for higher investment would have to be diverted from
net sales abroad, and the foreign deficit would have to increase to provide
the saving counterpart of increased investment demand. If there is spare
capacity, on the other hand, higher exports can stimulate growth, as in the
Hobson-Luxemburg theory of imperialism discussed in chapter 10. And, of
course, there may be shifts between regimes from time to time.
All this stands in sharp contrast to recent statistical exercises in which
GNP growth is supposed to be monotonically related to the (average or
marginal) export share or to the growth rate of exports.14 First note that
a positive relationship between GNP growth and the growth of exports
would simply reflect a constant export share. The resulting regression coeffi-
144 Structuralist Macroeconomics
An additional point to note is that the crawling peg models really depend
on the two-gap (or internal and external balance) specification of chapter
7, plus the accounting identity for the banking system that says that the
money supply must equal the sum of banks’ foreign assets and their domes¬
tic credit to the government and private sector. The two accounting gaps,
or balances, and the money identity also underlie other approaches to
macro analysis in the Third World. The practice of agencies such as the
World Bank and International Monetary Fund is discussed in section 8.4.
TABLE 8.1
Balance Sheets for the Open Economy Model
Assets Liabilities
Central Bank
Commercial Banks
Bank reserves H
Loans to firms L Deposits from the public D
Loans to public (1 - B )PzZ
Firms
Loans from banks L
Physical capital PK
Net worth N
Public
exchange for domestic deposits. The total of bank and private holdings (or
V) can only change over time through a current account deficit or surplus.
As in table 5.1, the central bank also holds government debt F, which
sums with eR to give high-powered money H. Along with H, the assets of
the commercial banks are loans to firms L, and loans to the public (7 — B)
PzZ. Regarding the latter, the hypothesis is that, as in chapter 5, the public
holds a nontradable asset, gold (or perhaps more realistically, “land”).
Under existing financial customs, when people acquire Z, they finance a
fraction (1 — B) of the purchase with bank loans. Think of mortgages.
Hence, bank assets include outstanding loans of this type, (1 — B)PzZ. The
public holds the balance, BPzZ. Individuals also have deposits D, a banking
system liability.
The consolidated balance sheet of the central and commercial banks takes
the form:
eR + F + [L + (1 — B )PzZ] = D (8.1)
In words, money supply D is the sum of foreign assets of the banking system
(eR), bank credit to the government (F) and bank credit to the private
sector [L + (1 — B)FzZ]. The definitional decomposition of money supply
into the credit items of the left-hand side of (8.1) is the basis of the “financial
programming” exercises of the International Monetary Fund, as discussed
in section 8.4.
The treatment of firms’ assets differs somewhat from that in chapters 5
and 6. Working capital and associated cost-push are left out for simplicity.
Also, in the absence of an active equity market, firms are assumed to own
themselves. In practice, in poor countries a very restricted part of the
population plus the government will control most enterprises using large
amounts of physical capital, so this assumption is not so far-fetched as it
seems. Its implication is that PK—the value of capital stock—is the total
of firm assets, while their liabilities are loans from banks (L) and net worth
(N). The bank credit finances a fraction a of investment spending; hence,
in the notation of chapter 7, loan demand Ld is:
and
W = D + eJ + B PzZ
W = --- (8.6)
ja(l - 0 + X(1 - &
Wealth is higher, the higher is the share of assets held in gold (|) and the
lower in foreign exchange (X). The impact of a rise in the reserve require¬
ment ju is to reduce wealth by cutting banks’ credit creation. If gold is
ignored (£ = 0) then (8.6) becomes:
eV + F
W = (8.7)
i - iK1 - p)
which shows that W rises as more deposits are held (higher i|/) and as the
reserve requirement is lower.
Using (8.6) and a bit more manipulation, one can derive an expression
for loan supply to firms as:
150 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Available loans rise along with the total primary financial assets (eV +
F), but otherwise depend in a complex way on the workings of the financial
system, as illustrated by the expression after the first equality. For future
reference, all the interactions are boiled down into a single credit multiplier
<f> in the second expression.
When there is no gold, (8.8) simplifies dramatically to the equation:
<Ki - m)
V (eV + F)
1 - ij>(l - p)
The arguments of i|/ are i — tt and ne — 7r, with positive and negative
partial derivatives, respectively. Now suppose that the government pro¬
mises to slow the crawling peg, and is believed. Then ire will fall and i|/ will
rise as wealthholders shift toward domestic assets by trading in foreign
currency at the bank. There is credit multiplication, and the loan supply to
firms goes up. Our first conclusion is that in a very simple financial model,
slowing the crawl with credibility will lead to domestic credit expansion.
When gold enters the picture, the wealthy have another option. After
they convert their foreign holdings to national deposits, they can turn
around and take out loans to finance gold purchases. If the initial deposits
are relatively small (or are restricted by regulations on capital inflow) and
the private loan demands large, then loans to firms will be cut back. Con¬
traction of economically productive credit follows in wake of the slower
crawl.
To see the details, assume that di, = —yd\, with 0 < y < 1. The new
parameter y is the fraction of their reduction in foreign exchange holdings
that members of the public direct toward gold. Its magnitude will depend
on both asset-holders’ behavioral patterns and the institutional restrictions
that the authorities place on the exchange market (for example, minimum
maturity requirements on foreign loans, interest rate premia, and so forth).
Differentiation of (8.8) shows that loan supply to firms will contract when
the following condition is satisfied:
PT + 0 - p)
Foreign Assets and the Balance of Payments 151
B < + (A + £)
poses that prices are determined neither from markup rules as in chapter
2 nor from trade arbitrage between domestic and competitively imported
goods, which would enforce the Law of One Price. Under either hypothesis
the price would be fixed in the short run, and changes in money or credit
supply would spill over into the balance of payments, as in the International
Monetary Fund financial programming models discussed in section 8.4. The
IMF in fact follows what is usually called the monetarist approach to the
balance of payments, and our determination of the price level here by
internal monetary conditions would be considered heretical (but perhaps
acceptable to monetarists if current account foreign transactions are as¬
sumed constricted by protection). Be that as it may, we are after a structur¬
alist story under circumstances where money creation may be inflationary
in any case.
With the price allowed to vary, it is reasonable to assume that it will
increase when there is an excess supply of loans in (8.9), in a case of financial
credit chasing producer’s goods. With a pegged nominal exchange rate at
any point in time, this adjustment amounts to postulating that the real
exchange q — e/P will rise with loan excess demand. The process will be
locally stable when 0 > 0, or some share of investment demand is satisfied
with goods produced at home.5
Suppose that loan supply (f> goes up with the slower crawl. Then the
alternative adjustment mechanisms would lead to either lower interest rates
and faster growth, or rapid price increases and exchange appreciation
(lower q) after the policy shift. Alternatively, if loan supply goes down, the
outcome could be high interest rates and investment stagnation, but a drop
in inflation and real devaluation (with a consequent push to exports). De¬
pending on interest rate restrictions, market dynamics, and other considera¬
tions, a combination of interest rate and price response could of course
happen. By and large, the symptoms of credit expansion were observed
during stabilization attempts in Argentina, Uruguay, Israel, and Spain in
the late 1970s, but the reverse was true for Chile.
the latter, so assume that the price level (or real exchange rate) varies to
assure loan market equilibrium in (8.9), while the interest rate is held
constant by bank regulation. The capital stock growth rate g is supposed
fixed for the moment, from singularly stable investment demand. Finally,
the national component of the money base is ignored. In table 8.1 F is set
to zero and the central bank’s only assets are foreign reserves eR. Similarly,
the term (F/P) disappears in (8.9).6
The second model closure in section 7.3 now comes into play since it
shows how b (the trade deficit divided by the capital stock) is determined
by g and the real exchange rate q. This information is of interest since total
foreign assets held by the central bank or the public can only change from
the trade account:
where
which determines a q consistent with steady state. The minus sign on the
left side implies that 17 < 0. Since the model omits foreign aid, emigrant
154 Structuralist Macroeconomics
remittances, and similar transfers from abroad, the only way the home
country can maintain a growing money supply is to run a trade surplus.
Now add two more pretty incredible assumptions. First, expected infla¬
tion rates in the prices of commodities and gold (v and tt2) are static.
Second, all agents really believe that the authorities will stick with their
announced exchange rate crawl, so that ne = e is given.
If e is reduced under these circumstances, the “normal” response in (8.9)
is that (f> should rise. Then the real exchange rate has to appreciate from
(or drop below) its steady-state value q to maintain equilibrium in the loan
market. Since 017/3q < 0, the trade surplus will diminish, and V/K will
fall over time. The real exchange rate will gradually rise back toward q,
implying that price inflation P will be slower than the crawl rate e. The
dynamics are shown in figure 8.1. The “loan market” schedule in the
FIGURE 8.1
Adjustment of Foreign Asset Holdings to a More Slowly Crawling Peg under
Static Expectations
Note: The supply of loans to firms rises when the crawl is slowed. When the policy shift is (credibly)
announced, the real exchange rate jumps down from A to B, and than gradually rises from B to C as
domestic inflation declines below the rate of crawl.
diagram corresponds to (8.9). The initial steady state is at point A, with the
exchange rate q determined from the “ V = g" line corresponding to (8.11).
A decline in the crawl rate e increases loan supply <$>qV/K. At the initially
given level of V/K, the real exchange rate must shift down to maintain loan
market equilibrium—q jumps from A to B as the loan market schedule
adjusts. The trade deficit worsens, and q gradually rises back to q at point
C, with a lower steady-state foreign exchange/capital ratio V/K.
Foreign Assets and the Balance of Payments 155
P, and 7tz = Pz. If we ignore details of the gold market to keep the problem
tractable, then we can look at dynamics in (8.9) with the arguments of tf>
restated as / — e + q, q, and Pz — e + q. These substitutions transform
(8.9) into an implicit differential equation for q as a function of q, with e
as a shift variable. In the case when a slower crawl boosts loan supply, the
first partial derivative of <j> will be positive and the second, negative (with
absolute magnitude smaller than the first, from an assumption that assets
are gross substitutes). An increase in q will drive up <f>, and from (8.9) will
reduce q. Inverting this relationship makes q a declining function of q, or
(8.9) defines a locally stable adjustment process of adjustment for the real
exchange rate.
The dynamics of adjustment for (V/K) and q are shown in figure 8.2.
FIGURE 8.2
Adjustment of Foreign Asset Holdings to a More Slowly Crawling Peg under
Rational Expectations
Note: The supply of loans to firms rises when the peg is slowed.
156 Structuralist Macroeconomics
FIGURE 8.3
Adjustment of Foreign Asset Holdings to a More Slowly Crawling Peg under
Rational Expectations When the Supply of Loans to Firms Rises
Note: The adjustment process demonstrates a saddlepoint instability. To reach the trajectory converging
stably to C, the real exchange rate must jump from A to B immediately when the crawl is slowed.
the one linking points B and C converges to a steady state. The other paths
diverge in a speculative bubble of some sort. If, after the crawl is slowed,
the government, speculators, or the gods assure that the real rate jumps
from A to B, then there will follow steady appreciation, trade surpluses, and
convergence to point C in the long run. Otherwise, the clock just unwinds.
Foreign Assets and the Balance of Payments 157
Like the analysis of chapter 6, figure 8.3 suggests that one should take
long-run arguments involving formation of expectations with a grain of salt.
Real people are always capable of changing their minds and mucking up
the model makers’ conceits. Even when they aren’t supposed to be following
acrobatic saddlepaths to steady state as in figure 8.3, sensible folk revise
expectations in response to both economic and noneconomic information.
Their changing opinions can substantially alter the policy regime. For
example, politically powerful groups, such as Argentine exporters, found
scant profits during the course of a stately real devaluation along the lines
of figures 8.1 and 8.2. Use of an overvalued peso in an attempt to control
inflation led inevitably to a squeeze on local industry. Capitalists revolted,
there was a run on the peso, and a maxidevaluation was the final result.
Monetarist rationalization of a slow crawling peg was faulty—it buckled
under current account duress.
Besides these exchange rate effects, monetarist stabilization is prone to
other ills. Working capital cost-push along the lines of chapters 5 and 6
could be added to the present analysis, with predictable but relevant re¬
sults.7 A more interesting twist can be based on the observation that in both
Argentina and Uruguay a slower crawl was initially followed by an invest¬
ment boom and a rapid approach to full employment. Thereafter, the
economy went in a cyclical trough and recession accompanied the export¬
ers’ blues.8
The initial investment burst follows naturally from (7.15), where initial
appreciation of the real exchange rate can be seen to lead to an increase in
the profit rate (1 — o)z — qP*a 0). Higher investment demand would be
a natural consequence. Thereafter, profit squeeze along the lines of section
2.4 could set in, acting together with lagging exports to exacerbate a reces¬
sion. The reader is encouraged to work out the details.
(8.1). Note that these equations are virtually accounting identities. Working
with the simplest possible models is the professionals’ stock in trade.
Most policy-related work with the balance or gap equations is based on
using them independently to get alternative predictions of the trade deficit
for a given rate of growth (or the other way round). The parameters in
these computations are usually derived by a combination of guesswork
and simple regression equations between such variables as intermediate
imports and GDP. The regressions may be run over time spans of a very
few years because those are the statistical degrees of freedom that the data
permit.
If the two gaps or trade deficits come out about the same in the projec¬
tions, then at least that bit of consistency is something to rely on. It can be
tested by alternative specifications of input coefficients, saving rates (includ¬
ing that of the government, omitted for simplicity from the models here),
capacity utilization, and the rate of capital stock growth. Evidently, (7.7)
and (7.8) will yield determinate solutions for b and g. The question is
whether these projections are consistent with available finance for the trade
deficit, aspirations about growth and income distribution, anticipated
changes in the real exchange rate, world prices, and the parameters. The
equations are useful devices for organizing country experts’ thoughts
around these issues. The widely used RIMSIM, or Revised Minimum Stan¬
dard Model of the World Bank (unfortunately undocumented in the aca¬
demic literature), amounts to (7.7) and (7.8) programmed out in enormous
national and capital payment (interest and amortization of loans) account¬
ing detail. Its simulations often seem to call for cutting imports (and capac¬
ity utilization) or maintaining profits. But such results may not be surpris¬
ing when coming from an institution that makes shibboleths of a virile
balance of trade and fast growth.
The Fund and the central bank governors it monitors go through similar
exercises on the basis of (8.1), but with conclusions even more predictable
than those of planning ministers and the World Bank. The IMF model can
be interpreted as an applied version of monetarist balance of payments
theory (though chronologically it came well before the academic explosion
of the 1970s) and as such is documented in the journals.9
Fund-style financial programming adds the familiar equation of ex¬
change,
DV = PX (8.12)
eR + F + LP = D (8.13)
/
in which LP is total bank credit to the private sector. The other new symbol
is V (redefined from last section), the velocity or turnover rate of money:
_ Value of transactions PX
Money stock D
Two-Sector Models
of Inflation, Distribution,
and Growth
T HE MODELS of the last four chapters went into great detail regard¬
ing finance and the balance of payments but said nothing about how link¬
ages between sectors may affect the pattern of economic growth. In this
chapter, the emphasis switches to intersectoral complications, under the
hypothesis that money and trade adjust to whatever happens in the real
domestic economy. Postulating “passive money” under inflation has a long
tradition in structuralist macroeconomics, and is adopted here to keep the
discussion within bounds.1 A foreign sector could be added to the chapter’s
two models without much difficulty, but again to keep things relatively
simple this extension is left for the interested reader to pursue.
The first two sections are devoted to interactions between a food-produc¬
ing sector and the rest of the economy, along the lines of chapter 3. In
section 9.1, a model is set up to describe inflation resulting from conflicting
claims to product between workers and profit recipients under conditions
of lagging food supply. (The assumption of passive or accommodating
162 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where Xda is the current level of demand for food, Xa is supply, and B„ is
a constant describing speed of adjustment. Equation (9.1) says that the food
price responds to the value of excess demand Pa{Xda — Xa)—little would
change in the analysis if it were assumed to respond to demand volume
Xda — Xa instead. Finally, food supply Xa is assumed fixed, as in chap¬
ter 3.
The price Pn in the nonagriculture sector is determined by a markup
Pn = (1 + T)wbn (9.2)
where r is the markup rate, w the money wage, and bn the labor-output
ratio. There is spare capacity, and output Xn rises to meet excess demand:
Again, the demand level Xd follows from aggregate income and prices.
Two-Sector Models of Inflation, Distribution, and Growth 163
P = PaaPnx~a (9.5)
The weighting parameter a is usually taken as the food share in the con¬
sumption budget in some base year.
To make use of (9.5), add a definition of the agriculture/nonagriculture
terms of trade cf>:
<f> = ~ (9-6)
*n
Then if the real wage is defined as &> = w/P, it is easy to show that
In words, the real wage is a decreasing function of the terms of trade cf>, the
markup rate r, and the labor-output ratio (inverse of productivity) b„.
The next step is to build this trade-off between the real wage and terms
of trade into a model of inflation when claims to food output exceed the
available supply. The approach here differs somewhat from the profit-
squeeze dynamics of chapters 2 and 6, which amount to a fairly complex
(though realistic) theory of how worker-capitalist conflict can underlie a
cyclical approach to steady-state growth under inflationary conditions.
Here the emphasis is on inflation resulting from workers’ attempts to main¬
tain their real consumption standards when food is a major component of
their expenditure basket. The appropriate hypothesis is that if the real wage
falls below some target level a>*, then workers push for increases in the only
price over which they have any influence, the money wage. But from (9.7)
the real wage target co*, can be used to define a target terms of trade, <f>*.
164 Structuralist Macroeconomics
where price inflation Pn follows from (9.2). This equation asserts that wage
and price inflation are more severe when the terms of trade shift in favor
of agriculture. For many developing countries, (9.8) appears to be an accu¬
rate rule.3 Putting it together with the rest of the model leads to an expres-
A A A
FIGURE 9.1
Determination of the Equilibrium Nonagricultural Output Level and Terms of
Trade in a Model Where Inflationary Pressure Arises from a Low Real Wage
Two-Sector Models of Inflation, Distribution, and Growth 165
exceeds demand above the market equilibrium line. Finally, the vertical line
at <j>* indicates the level of terms of trade at which there is no wage inflation.
The next step is to characterize the locus “(f> = 0,” along which the terms
of trade stay constant. To begin, suppose the economy is at point A, where
<f> = <f>* and Xdn = X„. However, investment exceeds saving, so that from
(9.9), the terms of trade will rise (as illustrated by the arrow). At B, by
contrast, cf> < 0 since investment equals saving and the nonagricultural
market is in equilibrium, but (f> > <f>*.
With opposite directions of motion for <f> established at A and B, it is easy
to imagine moving along the line between them to some intermediate point
Q at which <f> = 0. Here the wage push from high terms of trade is just offset
by excess demand for food and <p stays constant.
Much the same analysis can be applied along the “/ — S” locus to get
another stationary point for <f>. At C, cf> is rising since there is excess food
demand (which follows from (9.4), where I — S = 0 and there is excess
nonagricultural supply). Hence, there will be a point R between B and C
at which <f> is constant. Connecting Q and R is the curve “<j> = 0” for stable
terms of trade. To its left <J> rises and to its right cf> falls.4
Given this adjustment dynamics, it is clear that there is a stable equilib¬
rium at Q, with the nonagricultural commodity market in balance and
unchanging terms of trade. However, as argued above, there will be excess
food demand, and from (9.1) the food price Pa will rise at a constant rate.
Given the constant terms of trade, w and Pn will increase at the same speed
as well.
The model thus generates persistent inflation. Of course, if workers were
willing to accept a lower target wage, the rate of price increase would be
reduced. In figure 9.1 <f>* would rise and Q would shift to the right, lowering
excess demand. For typical levels of living in poor countries, such meekness
on the part of labor is improbable, unless imposed. Without wage repres¬
sion, a more promising policy is to increase food supply. The impact would
be to shift the “/ — S” locus down and B to the left. Point Q would also
shift left, lowering the rate of wage inflation. Extra food could come from
imports or (better) more efficient agriculture. Land reform has often been
proposed to this end.5
Finally, note that the present model at best applies to the short run since
it generates persistent macro disequilibrium. In any functioning economy,
the observed market responses would be reductions in food stocks and
queues. The latter might persist, but stock reduction, imports, and similar
adjustments guarantee that the national accounts will never register an item
for “excess demand.” If only for this trite statistical reason, the model
166 Structuralist Macroeconomics
would be difficult to fit to data. In practice one would have to assume that
the food price responds much more rapidly to excess demand than does the
money wage to shortfalls of the real wage below its target. In symbols, Bfl
would be much larger than B* and the stable inflation point Q would be
close to the macro equilibrium B in figure 9.1. Having gone this far, it is
simpler to assume that the food price varies to clear the market in the very
short run (say a period of days), while wage inflation persists until the real
income shortfall is closed, as in (9.8). With a homogeneous model like the
one developed in chapter 3, prices would also increase at the same rate as
the wage. Long-run policies that may affect rates of both price and output
increase are discussed in the following section.
and
PaXa Pa
a
In the definition of ra the assumption that labor and capital incomes are not
separated in agriculture is maintained, so that the profit rate can be deter¬
mined on the basis of the total value of output PaXa. With a fixed output-
Two-Sector Models of Inflation, Distribution, and Growth 167
capital ratio a in the food sector, ra turns out to be proportional to the terms
of trade <f>. As we will see shortly, high agriculture profits and inflation go
hand in hand.6
With this much notation set out, the investment-saving and food market
balances can be written as:
and
1 + T ®/Ka
-o.y„r„ + \ra (1 - aya) = 0 (9.11)
T a
Besides the N-sector markup rate t, the parameters carried over to these
equations from chapter 3 include a and 0 from the demand functions (3.4)
and (3.5), and the consumption propensities ya and y„ defined in connec¬
tion with (3.3). Two new symbols are X = Ka/K„ and € — E/Ka. The first
measures the relative size of the two sectors, while e indicates the impor¬
tance of agricultural exports relative to the sector’s capital stock.
Equations (9.10) and (9.11) almost describe a tractable growth model, but
two simplifications are still required. First note that if 0 is constant, then
the ratio Q/Ka will steadily decline as the economy expands. Since 0 > 0
when food demand is income inelastic, a decreasing ratio of 0 to Ka means
that Engel effects become less important as growth proceeds. On the other
hand, a steady state can never be reached so long as &/Ka is changing. For
that reason, it is simplest to set 0 to zero and assume that demands for both
goods have unit income elasticities. This is standard practice in growth
models. A more realistic alternative (which the reader might want to pur¬
sue) would be to assume that 0 grows at a constant rate to represent
population pressure.
The second simplification is to set the two sectoral saving rates equal:
sa = s„ = s. This assumption is mostly adopted to shorten lengthy alge¬
braic expressions and could be relaxed.
We first describe how the economy behaves in steady growth, and then
briefly discuss stability. At the steady state, set ga = gn — g. Then (9.10)
and (9.11) can be solved to get the two sectoral profit rates as:
1 + X a[l + (1 — s)r]_
r, g (9.12)
X A
168 Structuralist Macroeconomics
and
where
Note that ra declines and r„ rises as X (or Ka/Kn) goes up. A shift in
capital stock toward agriculture lowers the profit rate there and raises
returns in the nonagriculture sector. We will shortly specify an investment
function that responds to a difference between the two profit rates strongly
enough to drive them to equality. When ra = r„ — r at steady state, the
corresponding value of X is given by:
q[l + (1 - *)t]
(9.15)
t[1 + a(l - s) — (e/a)]
FIGURE 9.2
Determination of Steady-State Values of the Profit Rate r and Capital Stock
Ratio X for a Given Food Sector Growth Rate g
Note: There will be wage inflation from low real purchasing power of workers when r lies above r*.
r[l - (e/a)] + a_
r -:-S (9.18)
Note that when e/a = 0 (no food exports), then r — g/s. More generally,
(9.18) is a standard formula for forced saving models, showing here that the
170 Structuralist Macroeconomics
profit rate must rise to generate additional saving when investment demand
to support faster agricultural growth goes up. This result carries directly
over to steady-state growth from the short-run models of chapter 2.
The lesson of (9.18) is that an increase in the saving rate s will permit
a lower long-run profit rate and less inflation when the economy is limited
by growth (and investment requirements) in one sector. Public sector in¬
vestment financed by taxes on profits could do the trick. More rapid agricul¬
tural expansion, on the other hand, would worsen inflation by putting
pressure on profits and the terms of trade. The profit rate would fall with
faster food supply growth only if it came from an increase in agriculture’s
output-capital ratio when exports were positive. Under the circumstances,
the export effort would be less costly in terms of domestic resources and
inflation would drop off.
A final policy to be considered is reduction of the markup rate r, for
instance, from industrial price controls. From (9.7), any target real wage
would be consistent with higher terms of trade, hence r* in figure 9.2 would
shift up. This change might or might not be offset by other macro impacts
of a change in t. In section 3.2, it was observed that the agricultural price
Pa can respond either way to a higher markup in the short run. Differentia¬
tion of (9.18) shows that the same conclusion carries over to the steady-state
profit rate. With high enough saving rates, a fall in r will reduce r. If
agriculturalists and profit recipients save a lot, then a reduction in the
markup that the latter receive will permit a lower profit rate and less
inflation in a resource-limited long run. A plausible justification for urban
price controls could be developed along these lines.
Results of the same type as those just developed carry over into other
models with one fixed-price and another flexible-price sector. For example,
one can extend the analysis of internal and external diversification of the
mineral exporting economy of chapter 3 in fairly straightforward fashion
to the long run. This story is not pursued here to save space. Rather, the
discussion in section 2.2 of the possible expansionary effects of income
redistribution is extended to an economy with two sectors, respectively
producing wage (subscript w) and profit recipients’ (subscript p) goods.7
A system in which food or intermediate input shortages are not restrictive
is assumed; hence, there is excess capacity and markup pricing in the two
sectors according to the rules:
Two-Sector Models of Inflation, Distribution, and Growth 171
/
and
Pp = (1 + Tp)wbp (9.20)
For simplicity, workers in both sectors are assumed to receive the same
wage w. However, markup rates and labor-output ratios can differ. As
discussed below, employment and distributional impacts of policy changes
depend crucially on intersectoral variation in these parameters.
All wage income goes to consumption, while a proportion s of profits
(from both sectors) is saved. Workers devote a fraction aw of their con¬
sumption spending to the wage good and (1 — aw) to the more luxurious
commodity; profit recipients follow the same pattern but with a parameter
ap. The names of the sectors already imply that aw > ap. Finally, the
P-sector is the only one to produce capital goods. The W-sector can be
imagined as making food products, clothing, and so forth, while the P-
sector provides cars, consumer and producer durables, and services catering
to high-income tastes. (In a poor country, the latter would range from
domestic servants to good restaurants to high tech health care supply.)
To set out balance equations, let X now stand for the ratio of W-sector
to P-sector capital (X = Kw/Kp) and define sectoral profit rates as:
(9.21)
and
(9.22)
1 + tw Pp Kw
The price ratio Pw/Pp in (9.22) is required to put profit rates on a common
base. As discussed in chapter 4, one can always measure quantities of goods
in such units as to set base year prices to one. We assume therefore that
PJPp = 1.
With this notation, one can immediately set down the saving-investment
balance as
where gw and gp are growth rates of capital stocks in the two sectors. The
172 Structuralist Macroeconomics
condition that excess demand for the wage good is equal to zero takes the
form:
The last term introduces a tax/transfer policy variable that can be used to
redistribute income. A nominal amount T is taken from profit recipients’
consumption spending (as by a consumption tax) and transferred to wage-
earners. The equation shows that as T rises in relation to the P-sector
capital stock, then demand for wage goods will go up.
In the very short run, sectoral capital stocks are fixed and X is predeter¬
mined. If, for simplicity, we assume that investment demand levels gw and
gp are constant, then (9.23) and (9.24) can be solved for rw and rp. Sectoral
outputs will, of course, be proportional to the profit rates, from (9.21) and
(9.22). After the algebraic dust settles, the solutions turn out to be:
£*X gp
rP =
A - £ (9.25)
1 + A
and
1 g»X + gp
= + { (9.26)
X(1 + A)
where
and
T and £), rp will fall and rw will rise. If L is total employment, one can write
out an expression for its level as:
1 -
L — bwKw r,p
(9.29)
174 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Here, z0w is a base rate of growth for which entrepreneurs aim. They
respond to higher profits with a coefficient zlw and to capacity utilization
according to z2w. As noted with chapter 2, the capacity utilization effect
amounts to an accelerator term in investment demand. Econometrics sug¬
gests that z2w > zlw.
Capitalists making luxury goods follow basically the same pattern; hence,
their investment demand is:
1 + TB
SP — zop + •ip 4- z T-P ' rP = z0p + <f>prp (9.30)
As it turns out, most of the action in the model depends on the difference
between and <f>p, which empirically likely sectoral distinctions in
markup rates (or shares of profits in value-added) will make nonzero even
if all investment demand parameters are the same. To save space, we thus
set zoh. = z0p — Zo in what follows.
It is easy to solve (9.29) and (9.30) for profit rates in terms of growth
rates. Substitution into (9.25) and (9.26) then gives expressions for growth
rates only:
<f>w /£»X + gp
- Zo — (9.31)
(1 + A)X V ~
and
&P ( g^ 4 gp ^ _
gP ~ Zo (9.32)
1 + A \ ~
<K
X = (9.33)
hA
Even at steady state, (9.31) and (9.32) form a nonlinear system in g, A, and
£. Resorting to total differentiation shows that A will rise in response to an
increase in £. Across steady states, a transfer from profit to wage incomes
will shift the structure of production toward wage goods. This is a direct
analog of the short-term result in the last section.
Regarding growth, the situation is more complex. One can show that the
derivative of the steady-state growth rate is:
Clearly, dg/dB, can have either sign. From (9.33) it will be negative when
the existing steady-state capital stock ratio Kw/Kp is less than one. A
relatively small W-sector (in these terms) will occur if A is larger than one
and the investment response of P-sector captitalists to higher profits is as
strong as the response of their colleagues in the W-sector. The implication
is that an income transfer toward wage recipients will make the growth rate
fall. Or, the other way round, policies aimed at worsening the income
distribution might stimulate long-run growth.
Evidently, a serious empirical question is involved in these results. It was
already noted in chapter 2 that Indian economists, in particular, have
argued that stagnation can result from an unequal income distribution. By
contrast, one can find Latin Americans asserting that deteriorating equity
goes hand in hand with faster growth.9 Cumulative processes of the type
illustrated here clearly underlie these judgments, and it would be interesting
to explore empirically whether they are valid or not. Unfortunately, this
task would not be easy since specification and estimation of investment
functions at a sectoral level is very hard to do.
The final matter to be discussed is stability of the steady state. Again
setting £ to zero for simplicity, one can solve (9.31) and (9.32) for the
growth rates. Since A — gw — gp, substitution shows that the growth of
the captial stock ratio (around an initial steady state) is
[(1/X) + 1] - „ Vo + x>
(1 + A )s
where
(9.34)
176 Structuralist Macroeconomics
Trade Patterns
and Southern Growth
Consumption patterns differ in the two regions, but in the North the
Engel elasticity for the South’s export is less than one. The South is also
dependent on the North for supply of its capital goods; that is, technology
for production of commodities viable under the existing trade regime re¬
quires capital inputs traceable only to the North. The amount of Northern
financial capital transferred to the South (that region’s trade deficit) is
assumed to be determined by political factors, and is fixed in the short run.
(Alternately, capital flows responding positively to interest rate differences
between the regions and negatively to their own volume, or “lender’s risk,”
could be postulated without changing the model’s basic results.)
Finally, there is a third region in the system selling an imported interme¬
diate input to the North at a nominal price of its own choosing. Part of the
proceeds from sales of the intermediate flow back to the North as export
demand. A rise in this price is a stylized version of an oil shock.
All these assumptions go together to give conclusions that are very
strong, viz
1. There are not enough degrees of freedom in the international system to allow the
South to choose its own growth rate or terms of trade. Macro equilibrium is
determined by saving and investment functions in the North, plus its determina¬
tion of the magnitude of capital flows.
2. A productivity increase, or an oil shock by itself, will reduce aggregate demand
in the North, leading to slower growth in both regions and a fall in the South’s
terms of trade. In the medium run, the nominal wage rate in the North might
be expected to rise following either event, to restore aggregate demand. Any
inflationary impact would be beneficial to the South.
3. Faster capital flows from North to South stimulate the latter’s growth rate and
terms of trade; however, the quantitative response may be small. Capital flows
stimulate Northern capacity utilization and output growth. These responses fol¬
low from determination of output by aggregate demand in the North (the Hob-
son-Luxemburg theory of imperialism) and the role of surplus labor and capital
inflows in shaping saving supply in the South.
4. Productivity increases in the South will reduce its terms of trade and growth rate
so long as the North’s Engel elasticity for consumption of Southern exports is less
than one. Such impoverishing effects of technical change are often invoked in
structuralist discussions of the terms of trade, as several authors have pointed
out.2
5. In steady state, the Southern growth rate remains determined by the Northern
rate, and the response coefficient is equal to one. A perturbation to steady state,
such as an oil shock or a Northern productivity increase, will reduce the coeffi¬
cient, so that Southern growth will lag. The South carries a major share of
worldwide economic adjustment costs.
The reasons why these conclusions arise are singled out in the formal
discussion, which begins in section 10.1 with a description of growth in the
Trade Patterns and Southern Growth 179
North. Section 10.2 discusses growth in the South, and section 10.3 takes
up interactions of the two regions in terms of the system’s equations for
excess demands. Section 10.4 is devoted to comparative dynamics, and
section 10.5 concludes with a few additional observations and sketches
directions for further research.
The strategy will be to set up a model in which the North grows along
lines sketched for the industrial economy in chapter 2, while surplus labor
characterizes the South. In addition, the North purchases an intermediate
imported input from a third party, “OPEC”. The three countries are linked
through trade and transfers and have their own behaviorally determined
demand and supply patterns.
The natural way to describe the North is as a Keynesian economy in
which firms are on their labor demand curve and labor can be hired as
necessary at the current nominal wage (with workers drawing on knowledge
that real wages have increased with productivity over time.) There is excess
capacity and markup pricing according to the rule:
The first term on the left of (10.2) is saving generated by Northern produc¬
tion, and the second term is the trade deficit. The two sources of saving sum
to the value of investment, PnIn.
This expression can be simplified if we define rn, the Northern profit rate
on capital, as
Saving supply in the North is proportional to the profit rate r„, with a
Trade Patterns and Southern Growth 181
coefficient determined by the North’s saving rate sn and net savings gener¬
ated by imports from OPEC. The saving is used to finance growth of capital
stock at rate gn and also net exports to the South (measured relative to
capital stock).
To determine macro equilibrium in the North, investment demand must
balance with saving supply. If investment rises with the profit rate, then the
demand function can take the form:
gn = go + hr„ (10.5)
Solving (10.4) and (10.5) together determines the growth and profit rates
g„ and rn. The resulting equilibrium will be stable under Keynesian output
adjustment in the North if investment responds less strongly to the profit
rate than saving, or s„ + r -1 <f)S0 — h > 0. A graphic presentation appears
in the right-hand quadrants of figure 10.1. The northeast quadrant shows
FIGURE 10.1
Determination of Macroeconomic Equilibrium under Trade between the North
and South
Note: The shifting schedules depict the response of the system to an “oil shock.
182 Structuralist Macroeconomics
With its large subsistence sector, the South will have a labor supply
function elastic to the real wage. Moreover, labor supply conditions will
determine wages in the medium run, precisely because there is no history
of rising real income to induce workers to be somewhat tolerant of employ¬
ment lapses from time to time. To keep to simple formulations, we will
assume that the South’s real wage is constant in terms of its own product
—there is an infinitely elastic labor supply.
To explore the implications of surplus labor, we must specify conditions
Trade Patterns and Southern Growth 183
of production in more detail. There are two key assumptions. First, capital
scarcity is the rule in the South, so that there is full capacity utilization (as
opposed to determination of output from the demand side in the North).
That is, Southern output Xs is proportional to the capital stock, Ks:
Xs = aKs (10.6)
The second assumption is that capital goods are imported. This polar case
in effect amounts to saying that all capital takes the form of “machines” that
are made only in the North. Our main results remain valid if part of capital
(“construction”) is Southern-made, but the algebra becomes cumbersome
enough to be left out.
With a fixed real wage and capital valued at the Northern price Pn, the
Southern profit rate rs can be written as:
The term in parentheses on the left of (10.8) is Northern demand for the
South’s exports, and the other term shows consumption from labor income.
These two sources of demand exhaust the value of Southern output, PSXS.
Equation (10.8) determines the South’s price level (and its terms of trade
Ps/P„) from Northern aggregate demand, Xn. From (10.7) the South’s
profit rate becomes:
(1 - wsbs)a ByXn
(1 - wsbs)Xs - 0 Pn
(1 - wsbs)Xs Byu ^
(10.9)
(1 - wsbs)Xs - 0 P,
184 Structuralist Macroeconomics
into (10.9). A higher value of <f> (the share of imports in Northern variable
costs) reduces the slope of the schedule relating rs to u. An increase in the
Northern wage rate wn following a rise in productivity or the price of oil
will reduce cf> and benefit the South. However, such a response in the North
is always in danger of being cut off by anti-inflationary moves.
Perhaps surprisingly, an increase in Southern productivity also cuts back
on the Southern profit level (and export terms of trade) for a given level of
Northern capacity utilization u. This effect shows up algebraically in a
positive derivative of the expressions for rs in (10.9), with respect to the
labor-output ratio bp when 0 is greater than zero. Inelastic Northern
demand for the South’s export leads to a fall in its profit rate when bs
declines due to a productivity gain. Adverse effects of technical progress on
the South’s terms of trade (and, as we shall see, growth) are a staple
component of structuralist doctrine. They come out clearly from the de¬
mand conditions facing Southern exports in the model here.4
The final task is to determine the growth rate in the South. Sources of
saving are from income of capitalists and the North’s trade surplus PnZ,
which serves as a source of foreign saving for the rest of the world. We
assume that only a fraction t of this capital inflow is in fact invested, the
rest feeding into consumption imports from the North.5 On these hypothe¬
ses, the South’s saving-investment balance becomes:
where gs is the growth rate of Southern capital stock (or Is/K,). This
equation appears as the "Saving supply” curve in northwest quadrant of
Trade Patterns and Southern Growth 185
figure 10.1. It shows that Southern growth increases with the profit rate
rs and the Northern trade surplus z (though the quantitative importance
of the latter is attenuated by the consumption leakage parameter t).
(ByX„
+ + wsbsXs — Xs = 0 (10.12)
V Ps
1. When not offset by wage increases, Northern productivity growth or an oil shock
will reduce growth and profit rates in the two regions, and the North’s output-
capital ratio will fall.
2. An increase in Northern net exports to the South raises output, growth, and the
profit rate in the North. It also increases the South’s terms of trade, profit rate,
and growth rate, but the quantitative responses will depend on the North’s
marginal propensity to consume Southern goods (B) and the share of capital
inflows to the South that is actually saved (t). Both parameters may be small.
3. A productivity increase in the South will reduce the region’s terms of trade, profit
rate, and growth.
Other exercises could be pursued, but these suffice to illustrate the short-
run workings of the model. To close off the analysis, we turn to growth
analysis in steady state.
tions we can solve (10.4) and (10.5) to get growth and profit rates in the
North as:
(s„ -h T 'fojgo
(10.14)
sn 4- T~'(f)s0 — h
and
_go_
rn (10.15)
s„ + r~'(f)s0 — h
From (10.9) and (10.3), the South’s profit rate rs is determined by r„ in the
expression:
where it may be recalled that X is the ratio of capital stocks, K„/Ks. Finally,
note that when there are no capital flows the growth rate in the South is
given by:
The capital stock ratio X is the variable that adjusts to generate steady
states. It satisfies the simple differential equation:
dX W x
— = Mgn - gs)
dt
s„ + T~'(f>S0
X* = (10.18)
5sB[t-'(1 - <f>) + (1 - -O]
188 Structuralist Macroeconomics
With this expression in hand, it is easy to characterize the steady state. First
insert (10.18) into (10.16) to get the South’s steady-state profit rate:
S„ + T-'(j>S0
rc = ---r.
The implication is that profit rates are not equalized. Rather, if the North¬
ern saving rate sn exceeds the Southern rate ss, then the South’s profit rate
will be higher than the North’s (even ignoring the saving generated from
intermediate imports). This finding is generally in line with the stylized
facts.
Second, from (10.4) and (10.17), the two growth rates are related as:
* - - ♦) + (■ - O l
Sn + T-'<f)S0
When X takes its steady state value X*, this expression reduces to gs =
g„. But suppose that the steady state is perturbed by an oil shock or a
Northern productivity gain. The import cost ratio <p will rise, and from
figure 10.1 or equation (10.14), the Northern growth rategn will fall. Since
the coefficient in (10.19) tying gs to g„ declines as well, Southern grow'th
is doubly hurt in the short run. In the longer run, (10.18) shows that the
steady-state capital stock ratio X* must rise in response to the lag in South¬
ern growth. The final outcome is a new steady state at a lower growth rate,
but with the South having carried the brunt of the adjustment cost.
The conclusion is that growth in the North serves as a locomotive for the
South—equation (10.19) assures that fact. However, the locomotive loses
traction whenever Northern productivity or the real cost of intermediate
imports goes up. Any time either event occurs, the coefficient relating
gs to gn becomes less than one. Even in terms of growth rates, conjunctural
perturbations help assure that parity between the two regions is indefinitely
postponed.
Trade Patterns and Southern Growth 189
The foregoing results are quite striking, and should serve as a useful
purgative for anyone who is sanguine about benefits to the South from the
international economic system as presently arranged. Moreover, the analy¬
sis can be extended along several lines.
Can the framework here be broadened to deal with other issues in the
international order? One possibility is to consider dualities within the dual
regions of the present model. In the North, for example, a number of writers
have pointed to an emerging dichotomy between human service and envi¬
ronmentally oriented sectors with high income elasticities of demand on the
one hand, and the more traditional industrial sectors on the other. Within
the South, this same sort of industry is dual to the rural/agricultural sector
in ways that are illustrated in chapters 3 and 9. Addition of another com¬
modity to each country (nontraded services in the North, industry in the
South) would permit discussion within something like the present model of
such issues as to how sectoral polarities within each country are (or are not)
mutually reinforced through the system of international trade. Exploration
of such dualities has long been the stock in trade of dependency theorists;
there is no reason why mainline economists shouldn’t learn something from
it as well.
Finally, both the present model and dependency theory reach strong
conclusions about what is in store for the South. It is caught in a web of
economic restrictions from which the exits are difficult and few. Realign¬
ment of export patterns to more “modern” products, reduction of the need
for imported capital goods, elimination of surplus labor—these changes are
as difficult as they are essential to a more equable alignment of international
growth. The North will not willingly yield the upper hand. Internally
oriented policy and great self-reliance might enable the South to seize it in
the fullness of time.
11
Policy Lessons
There are two justifications for monetary contraction, which get muddled
in minds of practitioners of applied orthodoxy who jet out to the Third
World. The first is based on the hoary equation of exchange from the
quantity theory of money, which states that the value (price times quantity)
of transactions in the economy is proportional to the money supply. If the
quantity of transactions or output stays constant, then a smaller money
stock ought to be associated with a lower price level. On this rationale,
cutting the money supply or at least its growth is a key anti-inflationary
move.
Open economy monetarism retains the hypotheses of the equation of
exchange and stable output (or, effectively, full employment) but adds the
notion that the price level is determined in the short to medium run either
from competition of imported goods or from labor and intermediate import
costs, that is, the levels of the wage and exchange rate. The IMF couples
these assumptions with the balance sheet identity for the banking system
—any rise in the money supply (the banks’ main liability item) must be
balanced by increases in loans to the government or private firms, or else
by higher foreign exchange reserves (banks’ loans and foreign exchange
holdings are their principal assets). Monetary restriction takes the form of
ceilings on credit to the government and private sector; the main benefits
are supposed to come in the form of higher foreign reserves, not lower
prices.
To apply the open economy monetarist model in detail, first make projec¬
tions of output and the price level; then you have money demand. Put limits
on government and private borrowing from the banking system. From the
banks’ balance sheets, the change in foreign reserves “must” be determined
as a residual item. Or, in other words, if domestic borrowing from the
banking system is restricted, then the balance of payments will improve.
This reasoning persuades many, and is certainly neat—causality runs
crisply from monetary restraint to lower prices and better external bal¬
ance. 1 Doubts can be raised, but necessarily center on inelegant details such
as the likely effects of monetary contraction in practice.
Policy Lessons 193
There is little room in the monetarist model for devaluation. The ex¬
change rate may enter into import costs and the price level, but otherwise
is singularly absent from the accounting. To give devaluation a macro role,
two additional relationships have to be considered: internal balance or the
saving gap, and external balance or the trade gap. Details appear through¬
out this volume, especially in chapter 7.
Internal balance says that investment demand must be met by saving
from the government, private citizens, and foreigners. Foreign saving is
equivalent to a current account deficit, with the corresponding capital
account surplus representing an increase in foreigners’ saving in the form
of claims on “our” national wealth. External balance says that the current
account deficit is equal to imports of intermediate, capital, and consumer
goods plus interest payments less exports and net foreign remittances.2
These balances represent two restrictions on the macro system—there have
to be two corresponding endogenous variables. Candidates on the side of
real magnitudes include investment demand (or output growth), the level
of economic activity as a determinant of intermediate imports and national
saving, and the current account deficit itself. Possible endogenous prices are
the exchange rate and the aggregate price level (and implicitly the distribu¬
tion of income if the money wage is fixed). Different models follow from
different hypotheses regarding which variables are exogenous and which are
194 Structuralist Macroeconomics
The effects of any macro policy are complicated by the fact that in
many developing countries distributional and price interactions between
sectors are complex. The paradigm case is an agricultural (or food) sector
for which the market is cleared by a varying price coupled with a non-
agricultural sector in which output responds to demand. We can begin to
understand this system by looking at how income effects influence con¬
sumer decisions.
In the market for food, an increase in nonagricultural output and income
will raise demand. If supply is fixed or not very price elastic, the incipient
demand increase will have to be cut back by a higher price. Since demand
for food consumption is not elastic, the increase may be sharp.
In the market for nonagricultural products, things are harder to figure
out. A rise in the agricultural price, on the one hand, will increase farmers’
incomes and their demand for industrial products. By hypothesis, for a
generally oligopolistic industrial/service sector, the demand increase will be
met by increased supply.
On the other hand, an increase in food prices will reduce real income
elsewhere in the economy (bread or rice becomes more expensive and your
overall purchasing power falls), leading to less buying of nonagricultural
products by nonagriculturalists. Hence, demand for nonfood products can
either rise or fall with the food price. Consider the two possibilities in an
economy where policy is suddenly redirected toward an increase in agricul¬
tural exports.5
Farmers’ income would rise with the policy change; it cuts internal
supply and drives up agricultural prices. If demand for nonagricultural
products is dominated by rural income, there would be an export-induced
boom. By contrast, if the initial real income loss in the nonagricultural
sector is the dominant effect, demand for industrial products would fall and
recession would result. In the first case, the food price increase is likely to
be large since demand is price inelastic; in the second case, the real nona¬
gricultural output loss could be serious. Agricultural exporters are perched
on a knife-edge. Devaluation or other stimuli to exports do not ease their
balancing act.
The same line of reasoning applies to cutting food subsidies, another
orthodox policy move. Demand for food products will fall, leading to a
decline in either imports or the internal producer’s price (or both). There
may be a spillover into demand for nonagricultural goods, leading to overall
output contraction. Once again, a foreign balance improvement is obtained
at the cost of reduced economic activity and a price-induced shift in the
196 Structuralist Macroeconomics
income distribution against the poor, who devote a large share of their
spending to food.
These two examples plus others presented in section 3.2 show that the
terms of trade between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors are in
principle highly sensitive to attempted policy changes. Given that food
products make up a large share of total production and consumption activ¬
ity in poor countries, the consequent shifts in income distribution and
resource allocation could be expected to be large. In practice, violent re¬
sponses are not frequently observed. The reason is that governments almost
always intervene in food markets, separating and stabilizing consumer,
producer, and import prices to try to maintain or at most marginally alter
the status quo among the interest groups involved.6
This policy stance responds to the structure of a poor economy in which
price formation and output responses vary significantly across sectors. This
sort of problem is less serious in a more homogeneous developed country.
Simple attempts to alter the terms of trade by shifting food subsidy rates
or enacting agricultural export promotion schemes are bound to have gen¬
eral equilibrium effects that will call forth reaction on the part of groups
that get hurt. In some circumstances, such policy changes might be sensible;
they are just extremely difficult to apply.7
real rates are common in advanced economies, but have been pointed to as
a “distortion” ripe for liquidation in the Third World. The current rate of
inflation provides a convenient benchmark against which to measure what
the nominal interest rate “should” be.
What are higher interest rates supposed to achieve? One benefit, long
term at best, would be increased use of the banking system and greater
financial intermediation. More financial depth would permit open-market
operations and other flexible regulation policies and undoubtedly is a goal
to be pursued, but is not relevant in a stabilization context. What is relevant
is the notion that interest rate increases will raise saving rates and available
deposits in the banking system. If, as in neoclassical growth theory, the
extra saving gets translated automatically into higher investment, the econ¬
omy can be boosted painlessly onto a faster growth path.
It is argued in chapter 2 that the world probably does not operate neoclas-
sically—an ex ante increase in saving is more likely to lead to economic
contraction than a sudden investment spurt. Nonetheless, let us assume for
discussion that saving does rise with increases in bank interest rates, but that
investment demand is interest-sensitive as well. The question becomes:
sensitive to what interest rates? In many countries, the relevant rates would
appear to be the ones ruling in informal financial markets. Except for the
largest, both industrial and agricultural firms have recourse to informal
lenders instead of the banking system for their finance. Curb and village
credit markets are often efficient and well tailored to the needs of small
borrowers. Not surprisingly, the interest they charge is also quite high.
Now assume that bank deposit rates are increased, and in fact more
deposits come in. What is their origin? One possibility is a reduction in
informal lending, and a second is a drawing-down of hoards of gold, idle
balances, and sales of real estate and similar goods. If the latter occurs, there
will be a transfer from productively useless to useful assets. Bank lending
can increase, investment demand be stimulated, and working-capital costs
fall—all in all a favorable outcome.
The other story is more grim. If higher deposit rates induce moneylenders
or their backers to pull resources out of informal markets and put them in
banks, there can easily be an overall credit contraction because reserve
requirements or credit ceilings in official institutions are bound to be more
strict than those along the curb. The outcome could be working-capital
cost-push and a decline in investment demand and the level of economic
activity—stagflation once again. Under these circumstances, the increase in
ex ante saving would only make things worse.
Which outcome is more likely can only be judged by informed observers
198 Structuralist Macroeconomics
in a specific country; broad generalizations are beside the point. The impor¬
tant conclusion is that the existing financial structure can frustrate simplis¬
tic attempts at reform by “getting the interest rate right.” A second observa¬
tion is that even if the policy is successful it will work only by getting the
financial system tail to wag the capital formation dog. Directly stimulating
investment and technical progress would be a straighter route to sustained
economic growth.
Besides revising interest rates, recent orthodoxy has focused its attention
on the market in foreign assets and the role of the exchange rate in influenc¬
ing portfolio choice. To set the stage, consider an economy where the
authorities have been steadily devaluing the nominal exchange rate in a
“crawling peg” at a rate more or less equal to the difference between the
domestic and foreign rates of inflation.
Such policies were first introduced in Latin America in the 1960s. As
discussed in chapter 8, their rationale was to keep the real return to export
activities stable, and to preclude speculation against a maxidevaluation such
as occurs in a fixed-rate exchange regime.8
More recently, a third justification for a crawling peg has been proposed.
If the crawl is slower than the actual rate of inflation, it can dampen
expectations and gradually direct the economy toward an equilibrium with
stabler prices.
When crawling pegs were slowed in practice during the 1970s, the shift
came as part of a package involving reduction of restrictions on both foreign
trade and international capital flows. The results were unexpected.
First, foreign-held capital came streaming toward the domestic banking
system, which at any time had to trade national currency for dollars at the
ruling exchange rate. Slowing the speed at which the local exchange rate
was raised in periodic minidevaluations reduced the short-term return to
holding assets abroad, which can be written as foreign interest rate +
expected depreciation of national currency — expected foreign inflation
rate. So long as asset-holders continued to believe that the slower crawl
would be followed, they had strong incentives to repatriate wealth held in
dollars.
Second, the capital inflow led to substantial credit expansion by the
banking system as new deposits were lent out. The jump in money and
Policy Lessons 199
Table 11.1 presents in summary form the judgments one can reach about
the effects of orthodox stabilization policies taken one by one. The results
are decidedly a mixed bag. Moreover, it is easy to show with simulation
models, such as the one in chapter 4, that often unfavorable effects are
TABLE 11.1
Likely Effects of Orthodox Stabilization Policies
Improve Improve
Maintain Balance of Reduce Income
Output Payments Inflation Distribution
Monetary contraction
a. Working capital important - + — -
b. Otherwise — + + +
Devaluation — initially + — —
-I- later
Commodity price reform
(especially food) — + + -
Higher interest rates
a. Draw resources from idle
balances + ? + ?
b. Otherwise — ? — ?
Slower crawling peg -)- initially -f initially — ?
— later — later
Export push (at excess capacity) + + — —
202 Structuralist Macroeconomics
1. The terms of trade between agriculture and industry or (not the same thing)
traded and nontraded goods are less free to vary in some structural situations than
others, with consequent effects on sectoral growth and income distribution.
2. The income distribution itself may affect patterns of commodity demand, and
through induced sectoral investment the long-term growth prospects of the econ¬
omy.
3. The rate of inflation, rate of growth, and income distribution all interact in
complex fashion under different monetary growth rules and fiscal policy regimes.
Policy Lessons 203
4. Poor countries as a group may find their possibilities for autonomous develop¬
ment circumscribed by their dependent position in the international system.
One final topic is the position of poor countries as a group in the interna¬
tional system. Aggregating all the Third World together is perilous—pre¬
cisely the point of the previous discussion is that there is great structural
diversity in underdevelopment. Nonetheless, for the grand view one has to
work with grandly aggregated models. One such is presented in chapter 10.
Following structuralist tradition, it tries to spell out the essential asymme¬
tries in the international roles of rich and poor countries (or “North” and
“South”), underlining the barriers that hinder the latter group’s overall
growth. The key assumptions go as follow:
1. The North grows in Keynesian fashion, with excess capacity that can be reduced
by brisker export sales to the South. When saving equals investment in macro
equilibrium, the North’s growth rate, profit rate, and output level are all deter¬
mined. By contrast, investment and growth follow from available saving in the
South, where output is constrained by supply conditions as opposed to demand
in the North. Surplus labor fixes the South’s real wage.
2. Consumption patterns differ in the two regions, but in the North the Engel
elasticity for the South’s export is less than one. The South is also dependent on
the North for supply of its capital goods. As discussed in section 11.3, the amount
of Northern financial capital transferred to the South (that region’s trade deficit)
is likely to be less than the value of capital goods imports. The actual magnitude
is assumed to be determined largely by political forces, and is fixed in the short
run.
3. Finally, there is a third region in the system selling an imported intermediate
input to the North at a nominal price of its own choosing. Part of the proceeds
from sales of the intermediate flow back to the North as export demand. A rise
in this price is of course a stylized version of an oil shock.
1. There are not enough degrees of freedom in the international system to allow the
South to choose its own growth rate or terms of trade. Macro equilibrium is
determined by saving and investment functions in the North, plus its determina¬
tion of the magnitude of capital flows.
208 Structuralist Macroeconomics
The reasons why these conclusions arise are singled out in the formal
discussion of chapter 10, but their implications for the South seem clear.
Poor countries are caught in a web of economic restrictions from which the
exits are difficult and few. Realignment of export patterns to more ‘‘mod-
ern” products, reduction of the need for imported capital goods, elimination
of surplus labor—these changes are as difficult as they are essential to a
more equable alignment of international growth. Autonomous development
of the South may well require an inward-looking strategy delinked from
Northern pressures to the maximum possible extent. South-South trade and
relaxation of NIC restrictions on imports from their poorer neighbors
would help greatly toward these ends. But in the final analysis, each country
has to go it alone and make its own way out of the structural cage it is now
within. The failure of the New International Economic Order negotiations
of the 1970s showed how tightly Southern countries are bound. The suc¬
cesses will come only when they break their constraints.
Notes
Chapter 1
1. The terminology is due to Hicks (1974). For additional references, see chapter 3.
2. Commodities imported in “non-competitive” or “complementary” fashion cannot be
produced domestically within a reasonable time period (for example, a year) or without
unreasonable changes in existing techniques. “Competitive” imports are made up of
commodities that are (or can easily be) produced at home.
Chapter 2
1. Good references on the microeconomic rationale for markup pricing are Sylos-Labini
(1979) and Kalecki (1971a). A useful discussion is given by Lara-Resende (1979), while
Ros (1980) provides econometric justification in the case of Mexico.
2. More detail on input-output accounting is given in chapter 4 and Taylor (1979). When
intermediate input prices can vary, further complications are added to the adjustment
process, as illustrated in chapter 3.
3. Public sector enterprises fit uneasily into standard accounting categories but generate a
substantial cash flow. They are handled explicitly in an illuminating study of Brazil by
Wemeck (1980).
4. Or at least output variation is the main adjustment mechanism in Keynes’s General
Theory (1936). Previously, he had concentrated on forced saving type adjustments in the
Treatise on Money (1930), as discussed below.
5. See Kaldor (1955). Forced saving is the main adjustment process in Keynes’s Treatise on
Money (1930), where its continual replenishment of profit flows is likened to the biblical
parable of the widow’s cruse. Lopes (1977) gives a nice synthesis of the arguments
involved.
6. Note that in practice the government may serve as another important source of forced
saving. If tax receipts rise along with the price level P but government spending is fixed
by the budgetary process in nominal terms, then government saving will increase. This tax
effect is present in countries like the United States, where income is withheld during the
210 Notes
year, but may work the other way in many developing countries where taxes on incomes
earned in one year may not be collected until the middle of the next.
7. This quote is from a political economy analysis in the Indian newspaper, Economic and
Political Weekly (Special Number, August 1978). The model in the text follows Dutt
(1982).
8. Bitar (1979) is a standard economists’ reference on the Allende period in Chile. His and
other evidence shows that GDP rose by about 8 percent in 1971, Allende’s first full year
in the presidency. The major stimuli were income redistribution and higher aggregate
demand. In 1972, limits on both foreign exchange and capacity were reached, and inflation
(fed by full and unlagged wage indexation) accelerated rapidly. Needless to say, substantia]
internal and external political disruption abetted the inflationary process.
9. The notion that devaluation may lead to simultaneous price increases and economic
contraction has appeared for many years in the literature. Early versions in English are
Hirschman (1949) and Diaz-Alejandro (1963), and there are papers in Spanish and Por¬
tuguese as well. Cooper (1971a, b) provided both theoretical and empirical support for the
idea, and discussed the fate of ministers who devalue. The formal model here is similar
to that of Krugman and Taylor (1978).
10. Sylos-Labini (1979) argues that there are at most very weak linkages between markup rates
and capacity utilization in industrial economies; Ros (1980) finds a negative relationship
for Mexico.
11. For details on the CES function collected in one place, see Taylor (1979), Appendix D.
12. Another way of putting this result is that the present model is linearly homogeneous in
P and tv, so the price level will change by the same amount as the wage in percentage
terms, and w/P must stay constant. Adding an additional input such as intermediate
imports would permit the real wage to change when the money wage was modified (even
when the price level is not pegged), but the effect on resource allocation would probably
be weak. For algebra on this point see Taylor and Lysy (1979), who paraphrase the elegant
argument in Keynes’s General Theory (1936), chapter 19.
13. The whole argument in this chapter draws heavily on the literature about how different
schools of economists close their models in different ways, consistent (usually) with their
ideological stance. Sen (1963) is perhaps the first published paper on the topic, while
Marglin (1983) gives it an illuminating and thorough treatment. Note also in passing that
neoclassical full employment can be assured when there is an independent investment
function if both saving and investment are sufficiently responsive to the rate of interest
(introduced as an adjusting variable in the system, distinct from the rate of profit). Since
interest rates presuppose the existence of money and other assets, their analysis is post¬
poned to later chapters. In practice, private saving is not strongly affected by the interest
rate in poor countries, and the classical “loanable funds" adjustment is a weak foundation
upon which to construct a full employment general equilibrium. For evidence, see Giovan-
nini (1982), who severely criticizes regression results by Fry (1980) that purport to show
interest-responsiveness of saving in several Asian economies.
14. The radical story has its roots in the theory of the political business cycle put forth by
Kalecki (1971b), though he argued that capitalists might induce a recession to discipline
labor when there is full employment rather than have their own profits squeezed by
workers’ militancy. Current versions involving a profit squeeze are presented for the
United States by Boddy and Crotty (1975) and for Britain in a longer time frame by Glyn
and Sutcliffe (1972).
15. A complete, useful review of the American evidence is given by Weisskopf (1979).
16. Note the possibility that L > L. at least for some period of time—actual employment can
exceed the “normal" full employment level.
17. References on the stability of differential equations include Hirsch and Smale (1974) at
a fairly rigorous level, Gandolfo (1980), who stresses economic applications, and many
other texts. In this book, only local stability analysis based on the Routh-Hurwitz theorem
is employed.
Notes 211
Chapter 3
1. Sections 9.1 and 9.2 in chapter 9 extend the model further to deal with questions of
inflation and growth.
2. “Short run” in the context of the present model means a period of a year or less, during
which farmers are not likely to switch their patterns of input use markedly in response
to price or other signals. In the longer run, no one denies that farmers revise input and
yield patterns under institutional circumstances that reduce risk and guarantee some
security of tenure. Even so, total aggregate output from agriculture will depend on availa¬
bility of capital, land, and technical change. In a relatively land-scarce economy, a produc¬
tion function specification like (3.2) makes sense.
3. For a version of the model with a class structure in agriculture, see Taylor (1982b).
4. For references on stability of differential equations, see note 17 of chapter 2.
5. For more on the instability of food prices, see the model for India in the following chapter.
6. Reasons why the Law of One Price is frequently violated are reviewed by Kravis and
Lipsey (1977) and Isard (1977).
7. Chichilnisky (1981) gives one such model. In the present version, a full linear expenditure
system (with another constant term for nonagricultural demand corresponding to 0 for
agriculture) would permit existence of the unstable case in which the agricultural market
schedule of figure 3.1 would have a negative slope and cut the nonagricultural market
schedule from above. A rise in food exports would lead to a lower agricultural price in
this case.
8. See Ellman (1975) for discussion of the Soviet first plan experience.
9. Models of the terms of trade between food and nonfood sectors along the lines developed
here show up in various contexts throughout development economics. The behavior of the
large general equilibrium model for South Korea proposed by Adelman and Robinson
(1977) can be understood in terms of the simple model presented here. More interesting
political economy appears in Mitra (1977) and in empirical models developed by deJanvry
and Sadoulet (1983). Okun (1981) gives a lucid presentation of a developed country version
of the model.
10. There is a large structuralist literature about mineral-exporting economies from both Latin
American and Carribbean authors. See, for example, Girvan (1973), Brewster (1972) and
Sunkel (1969). The present formal treatment closely follows Boutros-Ghali (1981).
11. There is usually a wage differential in favor of the mineral sector (perhaps created by the
export companies to maintain a labor queue), which we ignore. For evidence regarding
Jamaica on this matter, see Brewster (1968) and, more generally, Nankani (1979). The
present model ignores the interesting policy question of what happens when the wage
differential is reduced.
12. Or at least 5 percent was the mineral sector wage share in Chile in 1977, according to the
input-output table.
13. It is worth noting that in many countries the production of U-sector products is likely to
be in the hands of public enterprises, which often engage in transactions that are not
rationed by price. If, however, the export sector is given priority when intermediates are
in short supply, then most of the results that follow will still go through.
14. These useful terms are from Boutros-Ghali (1981).
15. A good historical review of such developments in non-Persian Gulf oil exporters is given
by Gelb (1981).
16. Magee (1973) gives a good empirical description of the j-curve.
17. See Cooper (1971a) for statistics regarding the number of finance ministers who fell not
long after effecting a devaluation.
212 Notes
Chapter 4
1. The work reported here draws heavily on joint research with J0rn Ratts0 and Hiren Sarkar
on contructing a macroeconomic model for India. A directly parallel effort for Mexico is
being undertaken by the author with Bill Gibson and Nora Lustig. Models closely related
to the present one are described in McCarthy and Taylor (1980) and Taylor (1979), while
more distant cousins are scrutinized by Dervis, deMelo, and Robinson (1982).
2. Social accounting matrices derive ultimately from the work of Richard Stone at Cam¬
bridge University; see Stone (1966). Expositions of the usefulness of SAMs in developing
countries are given by Pyatt and Thorbecke (1976), Pyatt and Roe (1977), and Taylor
(1979).
3. Note in passing that the same sector can have both competitive imports and exports—this
happenstance is due to aggregation of trade in many commodities over time and space.
4. The SAM in table 4.1 was constructed by a team at the National Council of Applied
Economic Research in New Dehli; see Sarkar and Subba Rao (1981).
5. For applied detail in constructing social accounting matrices, see Pyatt and Roe (1977)
or Eckaus, McCarthy and Mohie-eldin (1981).
6. For discussion of the RAS procedure (due like social accounting matrices to Richard
Stone), see Bacharach (1970).
7. The original presentation of the linear expenditure system is by Stone (1954). A useful
monograph is by Lluch, Powell, and Williams (1977).
8. The output iteration just described amounts to a Gauss-Seidel procedure for solving a
closed Leontief model in which prices are fixed. Convergence will be rapid so long as
“leakages” of income flows to saving (instead of consumer demand) are nonnegligible.
9. The reduced form excess demand equations for sectors one and two with the correspond¬
ing prices as endogenous variables are highly nonlinear; hence a fairly sophisticated
algorithm must be used to find their solution. The solutions described here were obtained
with an algorithm due to Powell (1970). It is no longer state-of-the-art, but has proved
effective in several computable equilibrium models besides the one described here.
10. Taylor (1979) discusses the strengths and weaknesses of using SAMs in applied macro
analysis in developing countries.
11. Taylor (1979), Appendix B, discusses “guesstimation" of LES parameters in applied
models.
12. The Jacobian in table 4.5 is “exact.” An algebraic representation of the Jacobian was
obtained with the symbol-manipulation computer package MACSYMA at MIT; the
numerical version followed from plugging in the base solution parameters and values of
the variables from the SAM. The table 4.5 matrix does not include effects of wage
indexation, rising markup rates, and foodstock speculation as discussed below.
13. In the numerical solutions, initial prices are set to one, while quantities are scaled around
unity by figuring magnitude in units of one hundred billion rupees (instead of crores, or
ten million, as in table 4.1). In practice, computable general equilibrium models seem to
be easier to solve when all variables are normalized around one (or some other convenient
order of magnitude).
14. A quick check shows that all 2 X 2, 3 X 3, and so forth, principal minors of the Jacobian
have alternating signs—these determinants basically show whether or not groups of sec¬
tors taken in isolation show stable adjustments. Somewhat more complicated calculations
show that all eigenvalues of the matrix are negative, as required for stability. Their values
are —0.996, —0.834, —0.701, —0.574, and —0.052. The small magnitude of the last
eigenvalue reflects potentially destabilizing feedbacks between sectors one and two, as
described in the text.
15. The prices of the infrastructure services aggregated into sector four are fixed by the
government; hence, the markup rate is held constant.
Notes 213
16. The Jacobian in table 4.5 underestimates price responsiveness because the inflationary
feedbacks discussed here are not incorporated into its underlying equations. The price
responses in the expanded model are substantially larger than the values shown in table
4.5.
17. As discussed in chapter 2, the local currency trade deficit can move either way after
devaluation. It improves in the India model but deteriorates sharply in the companion
model for Mexico described by Gibson, Lustig, and Taylor (1982).
18. For completeness figure 4.2 shows how procurement would have to fall to compensate for
production decreases (points to the left of the base run.) Numerical results are not
reported, however, since changes in the procurement are not a likely policy under such
circumstances.
19. The extent to which the model needs smoothing depends on circumstances. In the Mexico
model described by Gibson, Lustig, and Taylor (1982), for example, agricultural price
fluctuations are much less brusque than those summarized here. The difference in behavior
probably reflects the reduced role of the agricultural sector in the Mexican economy as
compared to India’s.
Chapter 5
10. The monetary contraction could take the form of a lower value of H in (5.11). Strictly
speaking, there would have to be fiscal policy changes to permit H to vary over time, but
we ignore this complication here. Alternately, the reserve ratio p could be increased or
(in any functioning economy) myriad other instruments could be deployed to induce
monetary tightness.
11. See the references in note 2.
12. The quote is from Kapur (1976), which is more or less the approved formalization of the
institutional and historical arguments presented by McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973).
The general equilibrium asset market model used here of course follows in the tradition
of Tobin (1975). Recent specific applications to poor countries include Krugman (1981),
van Wijnbergen (1983a), and Buffie (1983), all of whom note that changes in the deposit
interest rate can move total private sector credit either way.
13. Argentina in the late 1970s was perhaps the nearest thing to complete credit market
liberalization. The results were disastrous but complicated by volatile capital flows in and
out of the country. See chapter 8 for details.
14. To their credit, McKinnon, Shaw, and their disciples would also push for lower reserve
requirements and loosening of credit restrictions to increase bank intermediation and the
effectiveness of interest rate reform. But these policies would just look like monetary
expansion in figure 5.1. Why bother with the deposit rate incantations?
15. Kindleberger (1978) gives a fascinating history of financial panics from destabilizing
speculation.
Chapter 6
1. The growth model presented here has a fairly complicated history. A first version of the
medium-run forced saving story of section 6.3 appeared in a 1976 first draft of Taylor
(1979), following the institutional analysis of Georgescu-Roegan (1970). Cardoso (1979)
added a monetary adjustment mechanism. The institutionally based wage adjustment is
based on Bacha and Lopes (1983), with mathematical assistance from Sweder van Wijn¬
bergen. Bacha and Lopes also extend the analysis to include the real balance or inflation
tax effects that are part of orthodox monetary growth models. The possibility that faster
money growth may slow inflation in steady states is pointed out by Sargent and Wallace
(1981). Their mechanism is financial market crowding due to government demands for
loans to finance the interest burden of its debt. Working-capital costs give rise to the
“perverse” long-run effect of slower money growth in the present model. This channel has
apparently not been noted before. Finally, for comparison of the wage dynamics adopted
here with more orthodox Marxian model closures, Marglin (1983) is a useful source.
2. The need for such extreme assumptions about investors' perspicacity stems from the way
P behaves in (6.1) and (6.2). Note that partial derivatives of both expressions with respect
to P are positive, ruling out simple excess demand based adjustment hypotheses.
3. The loss of real purchasing power of fixed money wages in the face of inflation is an old
Latin American notion—diagrams similar to figure 6.3 have been around the continent
for decades. The present formalization follows Bacha and Lopes (1983).
4. Chilean labor contracts in the 1960s had their renegotiations spread over a quarter or two
following legislation on government wage readjustments that could be passed anytime
during the first few months of a new year. For details, see Cortazar (1983).
5. Econometric evidence for South Korea and Argentina comes from van Wijnbergen (1982)
and Cavallo (1977), respectively.
Notes 215
Chapter 7
1. Factor income flows are omitted for the moment from (7.4)—repatriated profits from
multinationals or interest on sovereign debt going out and emigrants’ remittances or
intergovernmental transfers coming in. These items are introduced in section 7.4.
2. A wrinkle on (7.5) is that all of the current account deficit (or capital inflows less reserve
changes) may not be saved. Griffin (1970) and Weisskopf (1972) in influential papers both
pointed out that B in (7.5) should be multiplied by a saving share sb < 1. The foreign
exchange inflows not saved would have to be consumed, adding a term (1 - sb)eB to the
right-hand side of (7.3).
3. Evidence that h > 0 can be pieced together from such sources as the World Bank’s World
Development Report (1981).
4. When not all “capital inflows” are saved, as suggested by Griffin (1970) and Weisskopf
(1972), then the saving parameter sb < 1 will multiply q in the numerator of the expres¬
sion for the internal balance slope. The distinction between the two balances becomes even
stronger.
5. Early two-gap formulations are due to Chenery and Bruno (1962) and McKinnon (1964).
The latter paper is the source for figure 7.1. The basic notion of “external strangulation”
from lack of foreign exchange is due to the Latin structuralists; an early exposition in
English is in chapter 9 of Hirschman (1958).
6. The neoclassical case is argued by Bhagwati (1966) and Findlay (1971). It is further
discussed in connection with figure 7.5.
7. This interpretation of the two-gap hypothesis follows Bacha (1983).
8. The condition e0 < 0 resembles Marshall-Lerner restrictions on elasticities in orthodox
balance of payments theory. Dornbusch (1981) gives the canonical explanation.
9. We follow the usual confusing terminology about the exchange rate. Depreciation or
devaluation refers to a rise in q, and appreciation to a fall. When q (or e) rises, then our
country’s real (or nominal) purchasing power abroad goes down; hence, the decline,
depreciation, or devaluation of the local money’s force.
10. Tricks for formally setting up such cumulative processes as mineral abundance giving rise
to slow growth are presented in chapter 9. The obverse story is that a price shock to an
oil importer is likely to reduce u but raise q. The resulting stimulus to domestic activity
may accelerate growth in the long run.
11. In nominal terms, interest payments are a large component of the current account of
countries that borrowed heavily in world capital markets during the 1970s, such as
Mexico, South Korea, and Brazil. Real interest payments are substantially less (the extent
depending on the price deflator subtracted from nominal interest rates to make them
“real”), but still can amount to more than 10 or 20 percent of exports. In what follows,
we implicitly work with a real interest rate /. For more on debt and interest problems,
see Bacha and Diaz-Alejandro (1982).
12. For theoretical discussion of how credit rationing naturally arises in international capital
markets, see Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) and Sachs (1982).
13. Condition (7.23) follows Bacha (1983). At a full capacity level of the output-capital ratio
u, the quantity iP*(l — &)/u becomes a floor level on the export share e. If its value
of € falls below the floor, a country is not likely to get access to foreign commercial loans.
14. For examples, see Michaely (1977) and Balassa (1978).
216 Notes
Chapter 8
1. The name crawling peg was proposed by Williamson (1965). Bacha (1979) gives an
insightful review of the practical effects of a crawl.
2. Diaz-Alejandro (1981) gives an influential survey of the historical and institutional under¬
pinnings of responses in Latin economies to a slower crawl. Reviews of the Chilean and
Argentinian cases are given by Ffrench-Davis and Arrellano (1982) and Frenkel (1982),
respectively. The importance of economists who study real economies is emphasized by
the large number of theoretical papers that these studies stimulated, for example, Buffie
(1981), Calvo (1981), Krugman (1980), Dombusch (1981), van Wijnbergen (1983c), and
the present treatment, among many others. A related issue is switching by nationals
between local currency and readily available dollars. This is an important policy issue in
countries such as Egypt or Mexico; see Boutros-Ghali (1980) and Macedo (1983), or Solis
and Rizzo (1982).
3. The details are a bit different, but the general approach in the following model comes from
Krugman (1981).
4. As pointed out by Dombusch, et al. (1982), currency outstanding from the United States
Federal Reserve Bank is on the order of $500 per American. Even allowing for organized
crime, a large proportion of these dollars must be held by private individuals outside the
United States.
5. An excess of credit is nearly equivalent to an excess supply of money—if the latter drives
up the price level, then so should the former as well. Note from table 8.1 that money supply
Ds = H/p while (ignoring loans for gold for simplicity) loan supply Ls = (1 — p)
H/p. The simplest goods market clearing equation is PI = sPX, and loan demand
Ld = aPI (ignoring imported capital goods). Then Ls — Ld = (1 — p)H/p — PsX
is excess supply of loans. But this expression is proportional to a typical equation for the
excess supply of money of the form D1 2 — kPX where k = as/(l — p) can be interpreted
as an institutionally determined money demand parameter. The money and credit markets
are almost mirror images of each other, especially in an economy with little financial
depth, and one can model price pressures in one as well as the other.
6. This assumption precludes discussion of important questions regarding coordination of
monetary and exchange rate policy; see Krugman (1981) and Dombusch (1980) for
various rules.
7. Van Wijnbergen (1983c) has an interesting model along these lines.
8. Buffie (1981) reviews this cyclical history in Argentina and Uruguay, and presents a model
incorporating traded and nontraded goods and a Phillips curve.
9. The model by Polak (1957) enshrined the IMF approach—this is undoubtedly one of the
most practically important macroeconomic papers written since the Second World War.
The Fund’s nitty-gritty is further displayed by Robichek (1975).
10. Reichman (1978) and Reichman and Stilson (1978) back up the assertions made here in
official IMF publications. Buira (1983) presents a thoughtful synthesis of Fund experience.
Chapter 9
1. The label “passive money” and an interesting formalization appear in Olivera (1970).
2. See Deaton and Muellbauer (1980) for a good discussion of true cost-of-living indexes and
other demand theory concepts.
Notes 217
Chapter 10
1. The model presented here is used in one form or another by Prebisch (1959), Nurkse
(1959), and Lewis (1980). Its political economy is discussed by Taylor (1982a). The
formalization here follows Taylor (1981b). For a more neoclassical presentation see Find¬
lay (1981).
2. Bhagwati’s (1958) model of impoverishing growth (really exogenous technical change) has
been very influential, as evidenced by its transformation of the strange word “immis-
eration” into economic jargon. Bacha (1978) states a similar result in the context of the
debate about unequal exchange, further reviewed by Mainwaring (1980) and Gibson
(1980).
3. The references are Hobson (1902) and Luxemburg (1921). As pointed out by Hirschman
(1976), the philosopher Hegel was an (unlikely?) precursor.
4. More precisely, the terms of trade always shift against the South when its productivity
rises. So much is clear from the excess demand function (10.12), where a decrease in
bs cuts Southern workers’ total demand for their product, and leads its price Ps to fall.
However, the profit rate only falls when Northern demand is inelastic and the fall in price
is more than proportional to the productivity gain. Symmetrically to a productivity gain,
a decline in the Southern wage rate ws also reduces the region’s terms of trade, profit rate,
and growth. Though the mechanisms differ, this is the key result of the Sraffa-type unequal
exchange models of Mainwaring (1980) and Gibson (1980).
5. This hypothesis on saving follows Griffin (1970) and Weisskopf (1972). See also chap¬
ter 7.
6. If the model is extended to include endogenous capital flows, then it will be stable when
the North’s export surplus z adjusts according to a rule such as z = z0 + a(rs — r„).
In this equation, the parameter a measures the response of the level of capital flows to
a profit rate differential, while z0 represents foreign investors’ animal spirits. Adding such
a response function to equations (10.11)—(10.13) complicates the model but does not alter
its essential results. This more market-oriented variant of the political story in the text still
rules out independent Southern investment demand.
218 Notes
Chapter 11
1. For equations describing IMF “financial programming” as just sketched, see section 8.4
here and (in another variant) section 9.2 in Taylor (1979).
2. In most of the following discussion, foreign interest payments and remittances are ignored.
For detail on how the former may upset normal macro relationships, see section 7.4.
3. Chapter 2 gives a rationale for markup pricing rules. Note also that we do not permit freely
varying competitive imports or exports to close the “gap between the gaps” as in tradi¬
tional trade theory. For a justification, see section 7.2.
4. In a representative economy, investment might be 20 percent of GDP, made up in turn
of 60 percent nationally produced goods (construction and simple machinery) and 40
percent imported goods (sophisticated machinery). The capital goods import share in
GDP of 8 percent will exceed the feasible trade deficit for most countries.
5. The policy shift could take the form of devaluation or more sector-specific changes such
as export subsidies or acreage controls. Examples might be Bangladesh emphasizing jute
production as opposed to rice, or the Central American republics pushing bananas and
beef instead of corn and beans.
6. One key reason for these interventions is to avoid inflation. If the real cost of food rises
for groups such as urban workers, they can easily bid up money wage demands, which
in turn can be passed along to further price increases and an inflationary spiral. Models
are given in sections 9.1 and 9.2.
7. In some countries—Egypt is an example—nominal consumer prices of basic food items
have been held constant for years. Consequently, the real food price has dropped steadily
as the general price level has gone up. Such a secular decline in an important price sooner
or later has to be undone, but raising food prices suddenly is political dynamite. One
should have sidestepped the problem by slow and gradual price revisions, as in the
crawling peg exchange devaluation schemes discussed herein.
8. If the exchange rate is fixed when domestic inflation is substantially higher than that of
trading partners, imports steadily become cheaper and exporting less worthwhile. Pres¬
sures toward devaluation grow, and asset-holders begin to put wealth abroad through legal
channels or by overinvoicing imports, underinvoicing exports, and similar illegal devices
if necessary. The capital flight finally forces a maxidevaluation, with the shocks to the
economy discussed in section 11.3. Only the wealthy benefit, by bringing home their assets
and enjoying their capital gain.
9. A profit squeeze and consequent cutback in investment at the height of a boom is a
moderately convincing theory of the business cycle in a capitalist economy. For details,
see section 2.4 and chapter 6.
10. One imaginative—and nameless—structuralist economist fancies that the IMF team ar¬
rives in a country on mission with briefcases full of whips and leather dungarees. Mel
Brooks movies to the contrary, such is not the case. But it is at times difficult to avoid
reading self-righteousness or class bias into orthodox policy moves.
11. For references and models, see chapters 2 and 9. Note that distinct consumption propensi¬
ties between rich and poor for different goods, diverse investment and saving functions
and, more generally, demand composition differentials underlie the discrepant theories
mentioned in the text. It is hard to sort out the theoretically dominant forces underlying
different income redistribution models, let alone their empirical relevance.
12. For details, see sections 3.3 and 3.4.
13. For example, in the numerical model for India in chapter 4, devaluation and an export
push are strongly inflationary because they indirectly and directly generate demand for
products of the supply-limited agricultural sectors.
14. The implicit assumption is that the world capital market effectively imposes credit limits
Notes 219
Adelman, Irma, and Robinson, Sherman. Income Distribution Policies in Developing Countries:
A Case Study of Korea. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1977.
Ahluwalia, Isher J. “An Analysis of Price and Output Behavior in the Indian Economy:
1951-73.” Journal of Development Economics 6 (1979): 363-90.
Atkinson, A.B. The Economics of Inequality. New York and London: Oxford University Press,
1975.
Bacha, Edmar L. “An Interpretation of Unequal Exchange from Prebisch-Singer to Emman¬
uel.” Journal of Development Economics 5 (1978): 319-30.
Bacha, Edmar L. “Notes of the Brazilian Experience with Minidevaluations, 1968-76.” Jour¬
nal of Development Economics 6 (1979): 463-81.
Bacha, Edmar L. “Growth with Limited Supplies of Foreign Exchange: A Reappraisal of the
Two-Gap Model.” Mimeo. Rio de Janeiro: Pontifical Catholic University, 1983.
Bacha, Edmar L., and Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F. "International Financial Intermediation: A
Long and Tropical View." Princeton University: Princeton Essays on International Finance
No. 147 (1982).
Bacha, Edmar L., and Lopes, Francisco L. “Inflation, Growth and Wage Policy: A Brazilian
Perspective,” Journal of Development Economics 12 (1983).
Bacharach, Michael. Biproportional Matrices and Input-Output Change. New York and Lon¬
don: Cambridge University Press, 1970.
Balassa, Bela. “Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence.” Journal of Development
Economics 5 (1978): 181-90.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. "Immiserizing Growth: A Geometrical Note." Review of Economic
Studies 25 (1958): 201-05.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. “The Nature of Balance of Payments Difficulties in Developing Coun¬
tries.” Measures for Trade Expansion in Developing Countries, Japan Economic Research
Center, Center Paper No. 5, (1966).
Bitar, Sergio. Transicion. Socialismo y Democracia: La Experiencia Chilena. Mexico City:
Siglo XXI, 1979.
Boddy, Raford, and Crotty, James. “Class Conflict and MacroPolicy: The Political Business
Cycle.” Review of Radical Political Economics 1 (1975): 1-19.
Boutros-Ghali, Youssef R. “Foreign Exchange, Black Markets and Currency Substitution:
The Case of Egypt." Mimeo. Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Tech¬
nology, 1980.
Boutros-Ghali, Youssef R. “Single Export Systems and the Dependent Economy Model."
“Essays on Structuralism and Development.” Unpublished Ph D. dissertation, Massachu¬
setts Institute of Technology, 1981.
References 221
Brewster, Havelock. “Wage, Price, and Productivity Relations in Jamaica.” Social and Eco¬
nomic Studies 17 (1968): 107-32.
Brewster, Havelock. “The Growth of Employment under Export Biased Underdevelopment.”
Social and Economic Studies 21 (1972): 153-70.
Bruno, Michael. “Stabilization and Stagflation in a Semi-Industrialized Economy.” In Rudiger
Dornbusch and Jacob A. Frenkel (eds.) International Economic Policy: Theory and Evi¬
dence, Baltimore and Washington: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979.
Buffie, Edward. “Price-Output Dynamics, Capital Inflows and Real Appreciation.” Mimeo.
Department of Economics, Yale University, 1981.
Buffie, Edward. “Financial Repression, the New Structuralists and Stabilization Policy in
Semi-Industrialized Economies.” Journal of Development Economics, in press, 1983.
Buira, Ariel. “IMF Financial Programs and Conditionality.” Journal of Development Eco¬
nomics, in press, 1983.
Calvo, Guillermo A. “Trying to Stabilize: Reflections on Argentina.” Paper presented to a
Conference on Financial Policies and the World Capital Market: The Problem of Latin
American Countries, Mexico City, 1981.
Cardoso, Eliana A. “Inflation, Growth and the Real Exchange Rate: Essays on Economic
History in Brazil.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
1979.
Cardoso, Eliana A. “Food Supply and Inflation.” Journal of Development Economics 8 (1981):
269-84.
Cavallo, Domingo F. “Stagflationary Effects of Monetarist Stabilization Policies.” Unpub¬
lished Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University, 1977.
Chenery, Hollis B., et al. (eds.) Redistribution with Growth. New York and London: Oxford
University Press, 1974.
Chenery, Hollis B. and Bruno, Michael. “Development Alternatives in an Open Economy: The
Case of Israel.” Economic Journal 72 (1962): 79-103.
Chichilnisky, Graciela. “Terms of Trade and Domestic Distribution: Export-Led Growth with
Abundant Labor.” Journal of Development Economics 8 (1981): 163-92.
Cooper, Richard N. “An Assessment of Currency Devaluation in Developing Countries.” In
Gustav Ranis (ed.) Government and Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1971a.
Cooper, Richard N. “Devaluation and Aggregate Demand in Aid-Receiving Countries.” In
Jagdish N. Bhagwati et al., Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth: Papers in International
Economics in Honor of Charles P. Kindleberger. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1971b.
Cortazar, Rene. “Employment, Wages and Income Distribution in Chile.” Unpublished Ph.D.
dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1983.
Deaton, Angus, and Muellbauer, John. Economics and Consumer Behavior. London and New
York: Cambridge University Press, 1980.
deJanvry, Alain, and Sadoulet, Elisabeth. “Social Articulation as a Condition for Equitable
Growth.” Journal of Development Economics, in press, 1983.
Dervis, Kemal, de Melo, Jaime, and Robinson, Sherman. General Equilibrium Models for
Development Policy. New York and London: Cambridge University Press, 1982.
Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F. “A Note on the Impact of Devaluation and Distributive Effect.”
Journal of Political Economy 71 (1963): 577-80.
Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F. “Southern Cone Stabilization Plans.” In William R. Cline and
Sidney Weintraub (eds.), Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries. Washington,
D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1981.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. Open Economy Macroeconomics. New York: Basic Books, 1981.
Dornbusch, Rudiger et al. “The Black Market for Dollars in Brazil.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, in press, 1982.
Dutt, Amitava K. “Stagnation, Income Distribution and Monopoly Power.” Unpublished
Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1982.
222 References
Eaton, Jonathan, and Gersovitz, Mark. “Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and
Empirical Analysis.” Review of Economic Studies 48 (1981): 298-309.
Eckaus, Richard S., McCarthy, F. Desmond, and Mohie-eldin, Amr. “A Social Accounting
Matrix for Egypt, 1976.” Journal of Development Economics 9 (1981): 183-203.
Ellman, Michael. “Did the Agricultural Surplus Provide the Resources for the Increase
in Investment in USSR during the first Five Year Plan?” Economic Journal 85 (1975):
844-64.
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo and Arellano, Jose Pablo. “Financial Liberalization and Foreign
Debt: The Chilean Experience, 1973-80.” Mimeo. Santiago Chile: CIEPLAN, 1982.
Findlay, Ronald. “The Foreign Exchange Gap and Growth in Developing Economies.” In
Jagdish N. Bhagwati, et al. Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth: Papers in International
Economics in Honor of Charles P. Kindleberger, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1971.
Findlay, Ronald. “The Fundamental Determinants of the Terms of Trade.” In Sven Grassman
and Erik Lundberg (eds.) The World Economic Order: Past and Prospects. New York: Saint
Martin’s, 1981.
Frenkel, Roberto. “Financial Liberalization and Capital Flows: The Case of Argentina."
Mimeo. Santiago, Chile: CIEPLAN, 1982.
Friedman, Benjamin M. “Crowding-Out and Crowding-In: The Economic Consequences of
Financing Government Deficits.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 3, 593-641,
1978.
Fry, Maxwell J. “Saving, Investment, Growth and the Cost of Financial Repression.” World
Development 8 (1980): 317-27.
Gandolfo, Giancarlo. Economic Dynamics: Methods and Models (2nd revised edition). Am¬
sterdam: North-Holland, 1980.
Garcia d’Acuna, Eduardo. “Inflation in Chile: A Quantitative Analysis.” Unpublished Ph.D.
dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1964.
Gelb, Alan H. “Capital-Importing Oil Exporters: Adjustment Issues and Policy Choices."
World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 475, 1981.
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas. “Structural Inflation-Lock and Balanced Growth." Economies
et Societes 4 (1970): 557-605.
Gibson, Bill. “Unequal Exchange: Theoretical Issues and Empirical Findings." Review of
Radical Political Economics 12 (1980): 15-35.
Gibson, Bill, Lustig, Nora, and Taylor, Lance. “Impactos Distributives de las Politicas del
Sistema Alimentario Mexicano en un Marco de Equilibrio General." Mimeo. El Colegio
de Mexico, Mexico City, 1982.
Giovannini, Alberto. “The Interest Elasticity of Saving in Developing Countries: The Existing
Evidence.” Mimeo. Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
1982.
Girvan, Norman. “Multinational Corporations and Dependent Underdevelopment in Mineral
Exporting Economies.” Social and Economic Studies 19 (1970): 490-526.
Glyn, Andrew, and Sutcliffe, Bob. Capitalism in Crisis. New York: Panthenon, 1972.
Griffin, Keith B. “Foreign Capital, Domestic Savings and Economic Development.” Bulletin
of the Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics 32 (1970): 99-112.
Hicks, John R. The Crisis in Keynesian Economics. New York: Basic Books, 1974.
Hirsch, Morris W. and Smale, Stephen. Differential Equations, Dynamic Systems and Linear
Algebra. New York: Academic Press, 1974.
Hirschman, Albert O. “Devaluation and the Trade Balance: A Note." Review of Economics
and Statistics 31 (1949): 50-53.
Hirschman, Albert O. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1958.
Hirschman, Albert O. "On Hegel, Imperialism, and Structural Stagnation." Journal of Devel¬
opment Economics 3 (1976): 1-8.
Hobson, John A. Imperialism: A Study. London: J. Nisbet, 1902.
References 223
Isard, Peter. “How Far Can We Push the ‘Law of One Price’?” American Economic Re¬
view 67 (1977): 942-48.
Kaldor, Nicholas. “Alternative Theories of Distribution.” Review of Economic Studies 23
(1955): 83-100.
Kalecki, Michal. “Costs and Prices” and “Distribution of National Income.” In Selected
Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy. New York and London: Cambridge
University Press, 1971a.
Kalecki, Michal. “Political Aspects of Full Employment.” In Selected Essays on the Dynamics
of the Capitalist Economy. New, York and London: Cambridge University Press, 1971b.
Kapur, Basant K. “Alternative Stabilization Policies for Less-developed Economies.” Journal
of Political Economy 84 (1976): 777-95.
Keynes, John Maynard. A Treatise on Money. London: Macmillan, 1930.
Keynes, John Maynard. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London:
Macmillan, 1936.
Kindleberger, Charles P. Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. New
York: Basic Books, 1978.
Kravis, Irving B., and Lipsey, Robert E. “Export Prices and the Transmission of Inflation.”
American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 67 (1977): 155-63.
Krugman, Paul. (1981) “The Capital Inflows Problem in Less Developed Countries.” Mimeo.
Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1981.
Krugman, Paul, and Taylor, Lance. “Contractionary Effects of Devaluation.” Journal of
International Economics 8 (1978): 445-56.
Lara-Resende, Andre. Inflation, Growth and Oligopolistic Pricing in a Semi-Industrialized
Economy: The Case of Brazil. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology, 1979.
Lewis, W. Arthur. “The Slowing Down of the Engine of Growth.” American Economic
Review 70 (1980): 555-64.
Lluch, Constantino, Powell, Alan A., and Williams, Ross A. Patterns in Household Demand
and Saving. New York and London: Oxford University Press, 1977.
Lopes, Francisco L. “Lucro, Juros e Moeda: Um Ensaio em Dinamica Keynesiana.” Revista
de Estudos Economicas 7 (1977): 221-51.
Lustig, Nora. “Underconsumption in Latin American Economic Thought: Some Considera¬
tions.” Review of Radical Political Economics 12 (1980): 35-43.
Lustig, Nora. “Characteristics of Modern Economic Growth: Empirical Testing of Some Latin
American Structuralist Hypotheses.” Journal of Development Economics, in press, 1982.
Luxemburg, Rosa. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals, Leipzig: Frankes Verlag, 1921.
Macedo, Jorge Braga. “Currency Diversification and Export Competitiveness: A Model of the
‘Dutch Disease’ in Egypt.” Journal of Development Economics, in press, 1983.
Magee, Stephen P. “Currency Contracts, Pass-Through and Devaluation.” Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity 1 (1973): 303-23.
Mainwaring, L. “International Trade and the Transfer of Labor Value.” Journal of Develop¬
ment Studies 17 (1980): 22-31.
Marglin, Stephen A. Growth, Distribution and Prices: Neoclassical, Neo-Marxian and Neo-
Keynesian Aporoaches to the Study of Capitalism. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1983.
McCarthy, F. Desmond, and Taylor, Lance. “Macro Food Policy Planning: A General Equi¬
librium Model for Pakistan.” Review of Economics and Statistics 62 (1980): 107-21.
McKinnon, Ronald I. “Foreign Exchange Constraints in Economic Development and Efficient
Aid Allocation.” Economic Journal 74 (1964): 388-409.
McKinnon, Ronald I. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1973.
Michaely, Michael. “Exports and Growth: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Develop¬
ment Economics 4 (1977): 49-54.
224 References
Mitra, Ashok. Terms of Trade and Class Relations. London: Frank Cass, 1977.
Morawetz, David. “Employment Implications of Industrialization in Developing Countries.”
Economic Journal 84 (1974): 411-52.
Morley, Samuel. “Inflation and Stagnation in Brazil.” Economic Devlopment and Cultural
Change 19 (1971): 184-203.
Nankani, Gobind. “Development Problems of Mineral Exporting Countries.” Washington
D.C.: World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 354, 1979.
Nayyar, Deepak. “Industrial Development in India: Some Reflections on Growth and Stagna¬
tion.” Economic and Political Weekly. Special Number, Augusto 1978.
Nurske, Ragnar. Patterns of Trade and Development. Stockholm: Almquist and Wicksell,
1959.
Okun, Arthur M. Prices and Quantities: A Macroeconomic Analysis. Washington D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1981.
Polak, J.J. “Monetary Analysis of Income Formation and Payments Problems.” International
Monetary Fund Staff Papers 6 (1957): 1-50.
Powell, M.J.D. “A Hybrid Method for Nonlinear Equations” and “A FORTRAN Subroutine
for Solving Systems of Nonlinear Equations.” In Philip Rabinowotz (ed.) Numerical Meth¬
ods for Nonlinear Algebraic Equations. London: Gordon and Breach, 1970.
Prebisch, Raul. “Commercial Policy in the Underdeveloped Countries.” American Economic
Review 49 (1959): 251-73.
Pyatt, F. Graham and Roe, Alan. Social Accounting for Development with Special Reference
to Sri Lanka. New York and London: Cambridge University Press, 1977.
Pyatt, F. Graham and Thorbecke, Erik. Planning Techniques for a Better Future. Geneva:
International Labor Office, 1976.
Reichman, Thomas M. “The Fund’s Conditional Assistance and the Problems of Adjustment,
1973-75.” Finance and Development 15 (no. 4) (1978): 38—41.
Reichman, Thomas M. and Stilson, Richard T. “Experience with Problems of Balance of
Payments Adjustment: Stand-by Arrangements in the Higher Credit Tranches, 1963—
1972.” International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 25 (1978): 293-309.
Robichek, E. Walter. “Financial Programming Exercises of the International Monetary Fund
in Latin America.” Mimeo. IMF Institute, International Monetary Fund, 1975.
Ros, Jaime. “Pricing in the Mexican Manufacturing Sector.” Cambridge Journal of Eco¬
nomics 4 (1980): 211-31.
Sachs, Jeffrey. “LDC Debt in the 1980’s: Risk and Reform." Mimeo. Department of Econom¬
ics, Harvard University, 1982.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Wallace, Neil. “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic." Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Fall, 1981) 1-17.
Sarkar, Hiren, and Subba Rao, S.V. “Social Accounting Matrix for India for 1980-81." New
Delhi: National Council of Applied Economic Research, 1981.
Sen, Amartya K. “Neo-Classical and Neo-Keynesian Theories of Distribution.” Economic
Record 39 (1963): 54-64.
Shaw, Edward S. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York and London:
Oxford University Press, 1973.
Solis, Leopoldo, and Rizzo, Socrates. “Oil Surplus and Financial Openness: The Case of
Mexico." Mimeo. Santiago, Chile: CIEPLAN, 1982.
Stone, Richard. "Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An Application to the
Pattern of British Demand.” Economic Journal 64 (1954): 511-27.
Stone, Richard. “Multiple Classifications in Social Accounting” and “British Economic Bal¬
ances in 1970: A Trial Run on Rocket.” In Mathematics in the Social Sciences and Other
Essays. London: Chapman and Hall, 1966.
Sunkel, Osvaldo. "Inflation in Chile: An Unorthodox Approach." International Economic
Papers. No. 10 (1960): 107-31.
References 225
Sunkel, Osvaldo. “National Development Policy and External Dependence in Latin America.”
Journal of Development Studies 6 (1969): 23-48.
Sylos-Labini, Paolo. “Industrial Pricing in the United Kingdom.” Cambridge Journal of
Economics 3 (1979): 153-63.
Taylor, Lance. Macro Models for Developing Countries. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979.
Taylor, Lance. “IS/LM in the Tropics: Diagrammatics of the New Strucuturalist Macro
Critique.” In William R. Cline and Sidney Weintraub (eds.) Economic Stabilization in
Developing Countries. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1981a.
Taylor, Lance. “South-North Trade and Southern Growth: Bleak Prospects from a Structural¬
ist Point of View.” Journal of International Economics 11 (1981b): 589-602.
Taylor, Lance. “Back to Basics: Theory for the Rhetoric in the North-South Round.” World
Development 10 (1982a): 327-35.
Taylor, Lance. “Food Price Inflation, Terms of Trade, and Growth.” In Mark Gersovitz, et
al. (eds.) The Theory and Experience of Economic Development: Essays in Honor of Sir W.
Arthur Lewis. London: Allen and Unwin, 1982b.
Taylor, Lance, and Bacha, Edmar L. “The Unequalizing Spiral: A First Growth Model for
Belindia.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (1976): 187-219.
Taylor, Lance, and Lysy, Frank J. “Vanishing Income Redistributions: Keynesian Clues about
Model Surprises in the Short Run.” Journal of Development Economics 6 (1979): 11-29.
Thurow, Lester C. Generating Inequality: Mechanisms of Distribution in the U.S. Econ¬
omy. New York: Basic Books, 1975.
Tobin, James. “Money, Capital and Other Stores of Value.” American Economic Review
(Papers and Proceedings) 51 (1961): 26-37.
Tobin, James. “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory.” Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 1 (1969): 15-29.
van Wijnbergen, Sweder. “Stagflationary Effects of Monetary Stabilization Policies: A Quan¬
titative Analysis of South Korea.” Journal of Development Economics 10 (1982): 133-70.
van Wijnbergen, Sweder. “Interest Rate Management in LDC’s.” Journal of Monetary
Economics, in press, 1983a.
van Wijnbergen, Sweder. “Credit Policy, Inflation and Growth in a Financially Repressed
Economy.” Journal of Development Economics, in press, 1983b.
van Wijnbergen, Sweder. “Capital Flows, the Real Exchange Rate and Preannounced Crawl¬
ing Peg Policies.” International Economic Review, in press, 1983c.
Weisskopf, Thomas E. “The Impact of Foreign Capital Inflow on Domestic Saving in Under¬
developed Countries.” Journal of International Economics 2 (1972): 25-38.
Weisskopf, Thomas E. “Marxian Crisis Theory and the Rate of Profit in the Postwar U.S.
Economy.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 3 (1979): 341-78.
Werneck, Rogerio L. “Rapid Growth, Distributional Equity and the Size of the Public Sector:
Trade-Offs Facing Brazilian Economic Policy in the 1980’s.” Unpublished Ph.D. disserta¬
tion, Harvard University, 1980.
Williamson, John. (1965) “The Crawling Peg.” Princeton University: Essays in International
Finance No. 50, 1965.
World Bank. World Development Report: 1981. Washington, D.C., 1981.
Index
187, 188; and trade balance, 131- in, 65; conclusions on, 84-85; as
35* 139* 141. 142 data base, 62; demand-supply
Short run, 57-113; in agricultural balances in, 64, 73; imports-
sector, 60, 61, 64-66, 68, 72, 78, exports in, 59-61, 66, 79-81; in¬
84; capacity utilization in, 97; come in, 60, 61, 64-66, 68, 76, 81,
commodities in, 102, 112, 113; 82; infrastructure and energy in,
consumption in, 89; demand in, 61; input-output in, 59-69, 73-
64* 73* 95* 99* 106; deposits in, 78, 82; manufacturing sector in,
95, 98-102; exchange rate in, 70, 64-66; numerical results on, 75-
80, 81; exports-imports in, 59-61, 83; price in, 63-69, 73-75, 77,
66, 79-81; gold in, 92-95,98-103; 79-82; profit in, 64-66, 68, 72,
growth in, 90, 91, 95,101, no; and 77, 79, 82; public sector in, bo-
income, 60, 61, 64, 65, 68, 76, 81, 72, 76, 79, 81-84; savings in, 60,
82, 88, 107, no; in industrial 61, 64-65, 67, 68, 77, 79, 81; sec¬
economy, 16-23, 25, 31-33, 174- toral consumption functions in,
76; and inflation, 88, 90, 95, 98, 65; subsidy in, 59-61, 64-66, 69,
no—13; interest in, 86-88, 90, 91, 70; taxes in, 59-62, 64-68, 72;
97, 98,102-6, 108, no—13; invest¬ and utility maximization, 65, 69;
ment in, 86, 87, 89, 97, 98, 104, wages in, 64-68, 76-79
106, 107, no; and labor, 88, 89; Socioeconomic class: conflict, 5, 9,
loans in, 92-97,102,104,105,112, 205-7; and savings, 8
113; money in, 86-108, 112, 113; South; capacity utilization in, 181;
neoclassical approach to, 87; exports-imports in, 180-82, 184;
and North, 185-86; output in, growth in, 182-88; input-output
87-89, 97; policy on, 89, 104-6, in, 180, 183-85; investment in,
202; price in, 63-69, 73-75, 77, 181, 184; labor in, 182, 183; and
79-82, 89-91, 94-99* 101, 103-5, policy, 207-8; price in, 180, 183—
no—13; profit in, 64-66, 68, 72, 85; profit in, 181, 184, 187, 188;
77, 79, 82, 89-91, 99; and ratio¬ savings in, 181, 184-85, 187, 188;
nal expectations, 110-13; savings and short run, 185-86; steady
in, 60, 61, 64-65, 67, 68, 77, 79, state in, 186-88; and trade pat¬
81, 82, 89, 102, 107, ho; and terns, 177-79, 182-89; wages in,
South, 185-86; stagflation in, 86, 177, 182-84
87, 97-98,100,107,108; taxes in, Soviet Union, five-year plan of, 45
59-62, 64-68, 72; wages in, 64- Stagflation, 10; and medium run,
68, 76-82, 88-90, 107, 110-13 109; policy on, 194, 197; in short
Sismondi, 200 run, 86, 87, 97-98, 100, 107, 108
Social accounting matrix (SAM), Stalin, 45
58-83; agricultural sector in, 60, Structuralism, 3—11; analytical
61, 64-66, 68, 72, 78, 84; cereal tools for, 7-9; and economic
stock speculation in, 64; closure structure, 5-7; and neoclassical
234 Index
Taxes: in industrial economy, 21; Wages: adjustments in, 14, 19, 21,
in short run, 59-62, 64-68, 72 57; in agricultural sector, 48,
Technology, 204 162-66; and balance of pay¬
Tobin, James, 8, 9 ments, 159; indexation of, 77, 78,
Trade balance, 127-44; and capac¬ 114, 115; in industrial economy,
ity utilization, 130, 133, 135, 136, 16-31, 170-72; and inflation, 14,
138, 139, 143; and exchange rate, 78; institutional determination
54-55, 129, 130, 132, 135-40; and of, 5; in medium run, 114-22,178;
foreign debt, 140; and growth, in mineral-exporting economy,
129-44; and input-output, 129, 49. 53» 54; and monetary de¬
133, 135-40; and interest, 6, 140- valuation, 27; in North, 178,179,
43; internal and external, 128- 182, 186; policy in, 191, 194, 199,
30, 131, 136; and investment, 6, 203-5, 207, 208; and short run,
128, 142; and labor, 129; and 64-68, 76-82, 88-90, 107, no-
monetary devaluation, 26-27; 13; in South, 177, 182-84; and
policy on, 191; price in, 132, 134, trade balance, 129, 137; see also
i35> 137. 138, 140-42; and profit, Labor
128-29, I33-38. 141; savings in, Walras’s law, 16, 87, 95
131-35. 139. 141. 142; two-gap ap¬ Wealth: forms of, 91-94; identity
proach to, 130-35; and wages, of. 93-95
129,137; see also Balance of pay¬ World Bank, 11, 98, 146, 157, 158,
ments 191
Two-gap model, 10, 127, 130-35
*
*
(continued from front flap)
Structuralist Macroeconomics also considers in¬
come distribution and attempts to alter the struc¬
tural composition of sectoral outputs.