Work 812
Work 812
No 812
Steady-state growth
September 2019
© Bank for International Settlements 2019. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be
reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.
Abstract
We compute steady-state economic growth - defined as the rate
of growth that the economy would converge to in the absence of new
shocks. This rate can be computed in real-time by means of a parsimo-
nious time-varying parameter (TVP) VAR model. Our procedure of-
fers a relatively agnostic estimation of benchmark equilibrium growth
rates. Estimates show that the steady-state GDP growth rate in the
case of the United States declined from just above 3% per year in the
1990s to 2.4% at present. Results for other six advanced economies
and the euro area indicate that the steady-state growth rate, which
is consistent with stable inflation and financial conditions, has been
relatively stable since 2010 in most cases in spite of a recent slowdown
in actual GDP growth rates.
JEL codes: C11; C15; E30; O40.
Keywords: economic growth; financial conditions; inflation; mon-
etary policy; potential output; time-varying parameter VAR; trend
growth.
∗
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Bank for International Settlements or the Bank of Japan. We thank
Claudio Borio, Angelo Fasolo, Andrew Filardo, Wagner Piazza Gaglianone, Marco Lom-
bardi, Dubravko Mihaljek, Benoit Mojon, Hyun Song Shin, Christian Upper and seminar
participants at the BIS for useful comments and suggestions.
†
Monetary and Economic Department, Bank for International Settlements. Central-
bahnplatz 2, 4051 Basel, Switzerland.
1
1 Introduction
point in time? Policy makers are continuously confronted with these ques-
tions. The answer to them is crucial for the appropriate calibration of mone-
tary and fiscal policy. This paper presents a relatively agnostic estimation of
steady-state growth rates can be easily recomputed in real time after each
distortions (see Hamilton (2018)). At the same time, our benchmark growth
rate relies on less a priori theoretical restrictions than the well-known model
of Laubach and Williams (2003) for the natural rate of interest. Further-
more, the allowance for variation of the parameters over time enables the
2
innovations, so that changes in the properties of the shocks are well captured.
We apply our method to assess the steady-state growth rates for seven
OECD countries and the euro area. The estimates show that the steady-
state growth in the case of the United States declined from just above 3%
per year in the 1990s to 2.4% at present. Results for other countries indicate
that the steady-state growth rate - which is consistent with stable inflation
and normal financial conditions - has been relatively stable in most cases in
recent years despite a recent slowdown of the actual GDP growth rates. The
differ on how much they rely on theoretical models. Our approach, which is
and del Negro and Primiceri (2015). Lubik and Matthes (2015) have al-
the natural rate of interest and trend growth rates. Their crucial assumption
is that the output gap is determined by its own lags and the ex ante real funds
rate gap. Holston, Laubach and Williams (2017) discuss how estimates of
that model may vary according to model specification. Our work is inspired
curve.
3
by this evolving literature.
The main advantage of our analysis is that the model parameters are
not assumed to be fixed, but are allowed to vary over time as new data
points come in. In this sense, the approach is far less prescriptive, and the
policies and responses change over time. On the whole, the contribution of
for several major OECD countries and the robustness of these estimates. We
show the differences between real time and full sample estimates and the
concluding remarks.
where ∆ stands for the log change in output, ∆ for the log change in
4
2
conditions; is the time-varying intercept; and 1 and 2 are matri-
ces of coefficients, which are time varying. represents the vector of het-
autoregressive process
= −1 +
= −1 +
where , , and are innovations. In other words, the coefficient vec-
tors are modelled as random walks and the standard deviations are geometric
3
random walks - making it a stochastic volatility model.
2
The selection of variables is such that it allows the model to have one implicit IS
curve, a Phillips curve and a Taylor rule.
3
A more detailed description of the model specification and estimation methodology
5
In what follows, we use the Goldman Sachs financial conditions index or
the 5-year government bond yield as . The latter is preferred to the short-
term policy rate because it better reflects the overall stance of monetary
policy during the recent period of policy rates at or close to the zero lower
bound.
⎡ ⎤
∆
⎢ ⎥ b1 −
b2 )−1b
⎣ ∆ ⎦ = ( −
In what follows, we focus on the benchmark growth rate ∆ .
3 Estimation
To obtain the steady-state growth rates, the TVP-VAR models were esti-
mated for seven OECD countries and the euro area. Estimates were based
on quarterly data. Our benchmark steady state growth rate estimation uses
ness check, we show estimates when the 5-year government bond yield is used
as the variable . Due to the availability of the FCI, the sample period starts
for the TVP-VAR model can be found in Primiceri (2005) and Nakajima (2011).
6
in 1990Q3 and ends in 2018Q4. For Canada, Sweden and Switzerland, the
starting point of sample period varies according to data availability. For the
euro area, time series were taken from the AWM database with the sample
The number of lags of the VAR is two based on the Bayesian Information
Criterion (BIC).
economies and the euro area just before the GFC (2006Q4) and at the end of
our sample (i.e. 2018Q4). Equilibrium growth in the United States declined
from an estimated 2.8% per year in 2006 to 2.4% in 2018. Similarly, in the
United Kingdom it declined from 2.3% per year to 2.0%. Estimates were less
affected by the crisis in the cases of the euro area and Japan, where they
stand at, respectively, 2.0% and 1.2%. Canada and Switzerland also exhibit
a slight decline in the steady-state growth rate between 2006 and 2018.
over time. The solid lines show the mean estimate and the shadow areas
7
Table 1. Steady-state growth rates.
%
2006Q4 2018Q4
United States 2.8 2.4
Euro area 1.8 2.0
Japan 1.1 1.2
United Kingdom 2.3 2.0
Canada 2.5 2.3
Australia 2.7 2.8
Switzerland 2.0 1.9
Sweden 2.2 2.6
Note: 1. For the euro area and Switzerland, 10-year yield is used. 2.
For the euro area, the latest estimate refers to 2017Q4.
Figure 1. Steady-state growth rate (VAR with FCI).
4.0 3.5
3.5 3.0
3.0 2.5
2.5 2.0
2.0 1.5
1.5 1.0
1.0 0.5
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
3.0 4.0
2.5 3.5
2.0 3.0
1.5 2.5
1.0 2.0
0.5 1.5
0.0 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
% Canada % Australia
4.5 4.5
4.0 4.0
3.5 3.5
3.0 3.0
2.5 2.5
2.0 2.0
1.5 1.5
1.0 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
% Switzerland % Sweden
4.0 4.5
3.5 4.0
3.0 3.5
2.5 3.0
2.0 2.5
1.5 2.0
1.0 1.5
0.5 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
Note: For the euro area (up to Q4 2017) and Switzerland, 10-year yield is used. Shadow area indicates 68% confidence intervals.
indicate the 68% confidence intervals. Estimates show that steady-state GDP
growth rate in the case of the United States declined from just above 3% per
year in the 1990s to the current 2.4%. For the euro area, one noteworthy
Large uncertainty in this case hardly comes as a surprise given the shorter
Graph A1 in the Appendix plots the evolution when the 5-year govern-
ment bond yield is used as instead. By and large, the patterns are found
4
to be similar. Further, Graph A2 shows the evolution of the stochastic
volatility of growth shocks. As can be seen in the plots, the financial crisis
5
led to a spike in the volatility of growth innovations in most cases.
It may also be useful to compare the estimates obtained from our methodol-
based estimates of potential growth for the median country in 2006 are ex-
actly equal to the median delivered by the TVP-VAR approach for that
6
year (i.e. 2.3% per year). However, while the median potential output
4
We also find similar patterns and levels when we use the shadow interest rates of Wu
and Xia (2016) for the United States, United Kingdom and the euro area. The confidence
bands are however wider under this choice during the period that interest rates are close
to zero.
5
The exception is Australia, where core inflation increased most after the crisis, to
above 5%. The model considered this unsustainable. The trend growth rate recovered
when core inflation dropped.
6
Based on data from the OECD Economic Outlook no.105, May 2019.
8
growth has declined 69 basis points according to the OECD, our econometric
methodology leads to a reduction of only 10 basis points by 2018 for the me-
dian country. The methodology seems to reflect that higher growth rates are
compatible with stable inflation and financial conditions. We find that the
bulk of the reduction in trend growth rates in most countries predates the
GFC (as can clearly be seen in Graph 1). In the case of the United States,
however, we find that the trend growth rate diminished by a further 40 basis
7
points since 2006.
The current rate of 2.4% for the United States is somewhat higher than
the 2.0% estimated by Holston, Laubach and Williams (2017). Also our
estimate for the euro area trend growth is above theirs. In contrast, the
The estimated steady-state growth rate could be affected by the prior speci-
fication for the innovation variance of the time-varying intercept and the
lagged coefficients 1 and 2 . In the baseline model, we use the inverse
IG(10, 0.0025), (2) IG(50, 0.0025), (3) IG(25, 0.001), and (4) IG(25, 0.005).
7
Put differently, the model does not interpret the financial crisis as a very substantial
change in the transmission mechanism, but it sees it as a large negative output shock.
9
Table 2 reports the posterior means and 68% confidence intervals of the
steady-state growth rate for the Unitest States in 2006Q4 and 2018Q4. The
estimates turn out to be only marginally different, which implies that the
for the other countries and found that the posterior estimates of steady-state
3.4 Real-Time
in each case. In the case of the G-3 economies (the United States, the euro
area and Japan) corrections for steady-state growth rates are generally found
to be modest. For 2016Q4 and 2017Q4, for instance, they are never above
15 basis points. Larger corrections for 2016Q4 are found in the case of the
United Kingdom.
On average, two-years ago real-time steady state growth rates are ad-
basis points. All in all, this assessment suggests that a reasonably reliable
10
Table 2. Prior sensitivity: US steady-state growth rate estimates
%
2006Q4 2018Q4
Lower Mean Upper Lower Mean Upper
Baseline 2.36 2.82 3.24 2.02 2.44 2.85
Prior 1 2.24 2.84 3.37 1.88 2.32 2.77
Prior 2 2.39 2.78 3.16 2.12 2.50 2.87
Prior 3 2.41 2.79 3.16 2.14 2.53 2.91
Prior 4 2.26 2.84 3.37 1.92 2.36 2.79
Note: "Lower" and "Upper" correspond to 68% confidence intervals.
%
2016Q4 2017Q4
United States -0.13 0.10
Euro area -0.11 -0.04
Japan 0.05 0.10
United Kingdom 0.58 0.06
Canada -0.06 0.34
Australia 0.44 -0.01
Switzerland 0.03 0.29
Sweden -0.11 0.01
Note: Real-time estimate less the full-sample (up to 2018Q4). For
the euro area, 2015Q4 and 2016Q4.
4 Concluding Remarks
steady-state growth rate is purely data driven, and does not rely on fixed
coefficients are updated after each new data point. The TVP-VAR based
is that the steady-state growth rate can easily be computed in real time.
The estimates show that steady-state GDP growth rate for the United
States declined from just above 3% per year in the 1990s to 2.4% at present.
In six other advanced economies and the euro area the steady-state growth
rate, which is consistent with stable inflation and normal financial conditions,
has been relatively stable after the crisis in most cases, despite a recent
11
References
Hamilton, J.D. (2018) Why you should never use the Hodrick-Prescott
monetary policy at the zero lower bound", Journal of Money, Credit, and
12
Figure A1. Steady-state growth rate (VAR with 5-year yields).
4.0 4.0
3.5 3.5
3.0 3.0
2.5 2.5
2.0 2.0
1.5 1.5
1.0 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
% Canada % Australia
4.5 4.5
4.0 4.0
3.5 3.5
3.0 3.0
2.5 2.5
2.0 2.0
1.5 1.5
1.0 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
4.0 4.0
3.0 3.0
2.0 2.0
1.0 1.0
0.0 0.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
8.0 5.0
4.0
6.0
3.0
4.0
2.0
2.0 1.0
0.0 0.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
% Canada % Australia
4.5 4.5
4.0
4.0
3.5
3.5
3.0
3.0
2.5
2.5
2.0
1.5 2.0
1.0 1.5
0.5 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
% Switzerland % Sweden
4.0 7.0
3.5
6.0
3.0
5.0
2.5
4.0
2.0
3.0
1.5
1.0 2.0
0.5 1.0
92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18
Note: For the euro area (up to Q4 2017) and Switzerland, 10-year yield is used. Shadow area indicates 68% confidence intervals.
Previous volumes in this series
809 Inflation expectations anchoring: new insights Nikos Apokoritis, Gabriele Galati,
September 2019 from micro evidence of a survey at high- Richhild Moessner and Federica
frequency and of distributions Teppa
808 A disaster under-(re)insurance puzzle: Home Hiro Ito and Robert N McCauley
August 2019 bias in disaster risk-bearing
807 Bank intermediation activity in a low interest Michael Brei, Claudio Borio and
August 2019 rate environment Leonardo Gambacorta
805 Exchange rate puzzles: evidence from rigidly Charles Engel and Feng Zhu
August 2019 fixed nominal exchange rate systems
804 (Un)conventional Policy and the Effective Fiorella De Fiore and Oreste Tristani
August 2019 Lower Bound
803 Determinants of credit growth and the bank José Bustamante, Walter Cuba and
July 2019 lending channel in Peru: a loan level analysis Rafael Nivin
801 The internationalization of domestic banks Paola Morales, Daniel Osorio and
July 2019 and the credit channel: an empirical Juan Sebastián Lemus-Esquivel
assessment
800 Banks’ business model and credit supply in Miguel Biron, Felipe Cordova and
July 2019 Chile: the role of a state-owned bank Antonio Lemus
798 How do bank-specific characteristics affect Carlos Cantú, Stijn Claessens and
July 2019 lending? New evidence based on credit Leonardo Gambacorta
registry data from Latin America