Negotiating International Cooperation by C Ablin
Negotiating International Cooperation by C Ablin
Negotiating International Cooperation by C Ablin
DOI: 10.1017/S0260210503003656
Abstract. Global public goods (GPGs) are vital to human welfare and security worldwide. Yet
often they suffer from under-provision and free-riding, and are not accessible or beneficial to
everyone. They illustrate starkly problems of collective action. This article examines
multilateral negotiations in which countries seek agreement on the terms for collaboration in
providing GPGs. It argues that common obstacles to an effective agreement concern justice
and fairness issues, which arise from the earliest phase when the agenda is set to the final stage
of securing implementation and compliance. Drawing on recent negotiation practice, it
proposes a framework and a set of strategies for how such issues could be tackled.
Why do countries so often fail to cooperate sufficiently on peace and security issues,
even when the consequences are known to harm everyone in the long term? Any
observer of world affairs will have noticed the steady proliferation of problems
which defy unilateral solutions. The 11 September 2001 terrorist attacks in the
United States drew worldwide attention to the urgency of increased collaboration on
a global scale in combating terrorism and its underlying causes. They underscored
once more the significance of preventing nuclear, biological and chemical weapons
from falling into the ‘wrong hands’ through more effective arms control and
disarmament measures. Moreover, there is a host of other issues where, although not
publicised with the horror and drama that terrorist events create, the worldwide
repercussions of states and other players failing to act together are grave. Resource
depletion and environmental hazards such as climate change, poverty and its links to
trade and the finance of economic development, violent conflict and human rights
abuses, and the spread of infectious diseases such as HIV, are among these.
Despite progress and continued efforts, international cooperation to date has been
inadequate to tackle many such problems. Are political leaders blind to the mutual
gains to be reaped, and the dangers to be avoided, through collaboration? Do they
fear exploitation and ‘free riding’, that other parties cannot be trusted? Or cannot
government representatives be expected to look beyond shorter-term domestic
considerations, such as the next election?
When and why international cooperation takes place is among the most funda-
mental questions addressed in the political science and international relations
* The author gratefully acknowledges funding from the Office of Development Studies of the United
Nations Development Programme (New York) for the preparation of this article, and helpful
comments from anonymous referees.
365
366 Cecilia Albin
1
On motivations for collaboration, see K. Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, MA:
Addison-Wesley, 1979); R. Axelrod and R. O. Keohane, ‘Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy:
Strategies and Institutions’, World Politics, 38 (1985), pp. 226–54; L. Gruber, ‘Rationalist Approaches
to International Cooperation: A Call for Theoretical Reorientation’, Working Paper Series, no. 99.14
(Chicago, IL: Irving B. Harris Graduate School of Public Policy Studies, University of Chicago,
August 1999); and L. Gruber, Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational
Institutions (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000). On problems of free riding and
‘cheating’ on contractual obligations, see J. M. Grieco, ‘Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation’ and
‘Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation’, in D. Baldwin (ed.), Neorealism and
Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993). On ways to
encourage compliance and secure long-term benefits of cooperation through international institutions
and regimes, see O. Young (ed.), The Effectiveness of International Environmental Regimes
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1999); O. Young, International Cooperation: Building Regimes for
Natural Resources and the Environment (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1989); S. Krasner (ed.),
International Regimes (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1983); V. Rittberger (ed.), Regime Theory
and International Relations (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1993); and D. Victor, K. Raustiala, and E.
Skolnikoff (eds.), The Implementation and Effectiveness of International Environmental Commitments
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, and IIASA, Laxenburg, Austria, 1998).
2
See I. Kaul, I. Grunberg and M. Sten (eds.), Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the
21st Century (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999).
3
Some literature on international multilateral negotiation does link longer-term cooperative outcomes
to the negotiation process, often using a single case study or issue area. See, for example, B. Spector,
G. Sjöstedt and I. W. Zartman (eds.), Negotiating International Regimes: Lessons Learned from
UNCED (Laxenburg, Austria: International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, 1994); N.
Gallagher, The Politics of Verification (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999); J.
Odell, Negotiating the World Economy (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2000); and J. Sebenius,
Negotiating the Law of the Sea (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1984).
4
‘Global public goods’ here refers to goods (tangible or intangible) which benefit everyone, or at least
more than one group of countries and people. Their benefits are non-rival in consumption and often
non-excludable. ‘Pure’ (perfectly) global public goods as here defined are rare; that is, goods whose
benefits are at once universally accessible or beneficial, non-rival in consumption, and non-excludable.
Other definitions stress, in addition, publicness (understood as broad or representative participation)
in decision-making and publicness (understood as equity) in the distribution of their benefits (see I.
Kaul, I. Grunberg and M. Stein, ‘Defining Global Public Goods’, in Kaul et al., Global Public Goods).
Fairness and international cooperation 367
Private goods – houses, shoes, pillows, milk, train tickets, weapons and so on – are
traded in markets as they have clearly defined owners, are mostly rival in con-
sumption, and can usually be denied to those who lack a right to use or benefit from
them. By contrast, global public goods – such as clean air, a stable climate, good
health and freedom from infectious diseases, the non-proliferation of weapons of
mass destruction, and international financial stability – do not have exclusive owners
and are seldom zero-sum in consumption. Their widespread benefits cross national
boundaries, population groups and even generations, and can rarely be denied those
who decide not to contribute to the supply of the goods themselves. There is then
the problem of motivating collaboration. At the same time, there is collective
dependence on cooperation to ensure adequate provision and management of
GPGs: in most cases they can be created and supplied only through coordinated
action between numerous states and other actors. Negotiations are required to bring
all needed parties into the process.
The obstacles to cooperation which arise at the bargaining table concern disputes
over, among other matters, agenda-setting, negotiation and consultation procedures,
the allocation of the costs and benefits of GPG provision, and the prospect of ‘free
riders’. They all involve essential issues of justice and fairness which is the article’s
second focus.5 They must be tackled if strong cooperative agreements are to result.
A few powerful states can, for example, dominate the negotiation of such agree-
ments. If this marginalises the interests of other parties, collaboration can have
unbalanced and even negative welfare consequences for these. When the beneficiaries
do not depend much on the active involvement of the losers, and the losers will incur
even greater costs if they fail to collaborate altogether, some cooperation may still
take place, largely on the beneficiaries’ terms.6 In other words, the losing parties may
still sign and abide by relevant agreements, as long as they lack better alternatives.
Nonetheless, the expectation or experience of cooperation delivering few benefits or
even losses to some and plentiful gains to others always threatens to erode it. To be
durable, international collaboration has to be mutually beneficial and seen as
reasonably fair by all participants.
How do justice and fairness intervene in deliberations over GPGs? Such concepts
can have many effects upon international negotiations: they may guide the bargain-
ing dynamics – proposals put forward, the exchange and evaluation of concessions,
and the formulation of agreements – and thereby facilitate cooperation. And they
may become subject to negotiation themselves, and cause deadlocks and stalemates
which bring the process to the brink of collapse.7 In the case of GPGs, as discussed
below, a stock of relevant principles now exists which enjoy broad recognition.
However, their exact meaning and application in specific contexts, and priorities
5
‘Justice’ here refers to general standards for allocating collective benefits, opportunities and burdens
among the members of a community. They exist prior to and independently of any situation to be
judged, but their exact meaning in specific contexts is often ambiguous. While justice can be thought
of as a macro-concept, ‘fairness’ exists at the micro-level: It consists of individual notions of what is
reasonable under the circumstances, often in reference to how a principle of justice regarded as
pertinent should be applied. C. Albin, ‘The Role of Fairness in Negotiation’, Negotiation Journal, 9: 3
(1993), pp. 223–44.
6
Gruber, ‘Rationalist Approaches’; Gruber, Ruling the World.
7
C. Albin, Justice and Fairness in International Negotiation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2001).
368 Cecilia Albin
among different principles, are often hotly disputed. This helps to explain why
justice and fairness issues remain so controversial and all too often threaten a
successful cooperative outcome.
We will begin by overviewing why justice and fairness matter in negotiations over
GPGs. The article then moves on to ask what specific justice and fairness issues arise
in negotiations, and suggests criteria for fair negotiation practice: what is fair agenda
setting? How can we recognise a fair negotiation process? What is required of a just
outcome and to what extent do fair agenda setting and fair bargaining contribute to
it? Ongoing debates over many global resources are filled with the language of
ethics. These are not merely rhetorical references, for justice and fairness genuinely
matter. Yet all too often, the meaning attached to these concepts is never specified.
The analysis here hopes to contribute to a debate which can never be resolved until
it is lifted above the multitude of vague demands or assurances about justice and
fairness. The concluding section discusses possibilities for enhancing fairness in
negotiations over GPGs, along the lines here discussed, and argues that doing so is
ultimately in the interest of all parties. All too often, fairness is presented in an
altruistic light which contradicts considerations of self-interest and political reality.
Examples will be drawn from multilateral talks over trade and, to a lesser extent,
reform of the global financial system, nuclear non-proliferation, the global climate,
and air pollution. Unlike so many other GPGs, the international trade regime is
significant in that the vast majority of countries (developed and developing)
recognise it as a top priority concern.8
8
The international trade regime possesses qualities which here define it as a GPG (see note 4 above),
although like most GPGs it is an ‘imperfect’ and not a ‘pure’ one. On the ‘club model’ of decision-
making in the trade regime, see R. Keohane and J. Nye, ‘The Club Model of Multilateral
Cooperation and the World Trade Organization: Problems of Democratic Legitimacy’, unpublished
paper prepared for ‘Efficiency, Equity and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System at the
Millennium’ (Cambridge, MA: John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, 1–2
June 2000).
Fairness and international cooperation 369
• To bring all needed parties to the negotiating table, and keep them there
• To evaluate alternative proposals for an agreement (their terms and prospects)
• To overcome conflicting interests and claims, and reach agreement
• To legitimise the outcome before important constituencies (at home and internationally)
• To help secure the implementation of and compliance with agreements
• To establish and maintain successful cooperation in the long term
difficult fairness issues: the incentives to overconsume and to ‘free ride’ are strong, as
the use of GPGs cannot easily be portioned out nor be denied those who fail to
contribute; the costs of their supply can be very high; and the fair way of dis-
tributing the benefits of GPGs among parties with different needs and requirements
is rarely obvious and always disputed. In other words, there are serious dis-
agreements over the terms of international cooperation. Yet, as GPGs cannot be
produced unilaterally, negotiations must bring all parties to the table and to an
agreement on collaboration, and ensure implementation of it. This can rarely be
achieved without resort to principles of fairness and the expectation of mutual net
gains.
Finally, negotiations over many GPGs are conducted in the shadow of broadly
accepted principles – both substantive ones concerned with outcomes (for example,
‘equitable utilisation of shared resources’, ‘sustainable development’), and processual
or procedural ones concerned with conduct (such as duties concerning exchange of
information and cooperation). They have often been endorsed in earlier multilateral
framework agreements, and provide a broad normative context within which specific
obligations are later negotiated and general standards which negotiators are expected
to observe. Such principles are too vague to stipulate specific measures, so negotia-
tion is still needed to reach agreement on their proper meaning and implementation.
Fairness issues arise as parties consider conflicting ways in which the same principles
can be applied and the impact of each on their own interests.
The international trade regime is a case in point. At its heart lie principles of free
and fair trade specified in the GATT treaties, which inform negotiations within the
World Trade Organization (WTO). Parties have repeatedly expressed their support
for these. The serious disputes concern their implementation and real effects to date.
For example, poor countries may suffer net losses when asked to liberalise and
compete with economically far more advanced states. Many industrialised countries
have retained protectionist barriers in their own markets. These issues evoked
powerful resentments about unfairness already in the Uruguay Round of the GATT
(1986–1993).9 In its aftermath, the World Bank identified Africa as a net loser as its
costs of food imports would rise and prices of its exports fall.10 The street battles
9
Detailed accounts of the Uruguay Round of trade talks and the agreements which resulted from it
can be found in T. Stewart (ed.), The GATT Uruguay Round: A Negotiating History (1986–1992),
Volumes I and II (Deventer, The Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1993).
10
B. Moon, Dilemmas of International Trade (Oxford: Westview Press, 2000).
370 Cecilia Albin
surrounding the 1999 WTO meeting in Seattle again drew worldwide attention to the
reality that the existing trade regime produces both winners and losers, and fails to
spread the income and wealth it generates adequately at all levels from the local to
the global.
Moral ambiguity plagues negotiations over GPGs. We lack one overarching standard
which defines justice and fairness in concrete situations. Moreover, there is no
consensus on priorities among recognised principles. There are usually several conflict-
ing principles on which a cooperative agreement can be based and still reasonably be
considered just and fair. Negotiators, like scholars, thus frequently dispute what
justice and fairness require. Moreover, their perspectives may differ greatly from
what domestic or local constituencies perceive as fair and legitimate. Although
broad international acceptance of many criteria now exists, consensus on which
principles or interpretation of them should rule in specific instances is thus rare.
In order to situate the approach taken here, we will overview current concepts of
justice and fairness and sum up where the practice of these stands today in actual
negotiations. Interestingly, this practice demonstrates a more coherent picture of
what is to be taken as just and fair than do scholarly debates at present.
Competing criteria
Current concepts of justice and fairness fall into several categories. There are those
which assign a particular substantive content to these values and procedural
principles which do not. Approaches can also be distinguished based on their use of
external, internal or impartial criteria. Substantive principles are often specific to
particular issue areas.11 Procedural principles, by contrast, are more generally
applicable and rarely unique to a particular sector. A major one is ‘reciprocity’; that
is, mutual responsiveness to each other’s concessions. The pertinent literature
endorses this principle as intrinsically just or fair,12 and as instrumental in achieving
cooperation.13 Others, further discussed below, include ‘impartiality’, ‘mutual benefit’
and representative forms of decision-making such as voting and decision by con-
sensus.
11
Two exceptions are the principle of differentiating obligations in accordance with economic ability,
and the obligation to comply with freely negotiated agreements, which are more broadly applicable
(see discussion below).
12
A. Gouldner, ‘The Norm of Reciprocity: A Preliminary Statement’, American Sociological Review,
25: 2 (1960); O. Bartos, Process and Outcome of Negotiations (New York: Columbia University Press,
1974); A. Gibbard, Wise Choices, Apt Feelings: A Theory of Normative Judgment (Oxford: Clarendon
Press, 1990).
13
F. Iklé, How Nations Negotiate (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1964); R. Axelrod, The Evolution of
Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
Fairness and international cooperation 371
Current concepts of justice also rely on external principles. These are well-recog-
nised distributive criteria whose general content is independent of any particular
allocation to be judged. Examples are the principles of ‘equality’ (parties should
receive identical or comparable treatment, rewards, and burdens), ‘proportionality’
(benefits and costs should be distributed in proportion to relevant inputs, such as
contributions or assets), ‘compensatory justice’ (resources should be distributed to
indemnify undue costs inflicted on a party in the past or present), and ‘need’
(resources should be allocated relative to strength of need, so that those in most
need receive the greatest share). While relatively clear in concept, all principles pose
problems of application. For example, interpretations of equality vary from ‘equal
shares’, the uniform distribution of resources regardless of differences in
preferences, needs or other considerations,14 to equality of utility, welfare or ‘func-
14
D. Pruitt, Negotiation Behavior (New York: Academic Press, 1981).
372 Cecilia Albin
External
1. ‘Equality’ Requires parties to receive identical or comparable rewards and
burdens.
Internal or contextual
3. ‘Mutual advantage’ Arrangements are just if based on terms which parties themselves
have agreed to honour. They must be mutually beneficial, since
parties strive to maximise their own gains.
4. ‘Reciprocity’ Mutual responsiveness to each other’s concessions. ‘Specific
reciprocity’ entails equal concessions or sacrifices. ‘Diffuse
reciprocity’ involves concessions leading to an agreement which is
considered sufficiently balanced and fair overall.
Impartial
5. ‘Justice as fairness’ Principles of justice are those which parties would select and agree
upon if they were in a ‘fair choosing situation’; that is, ignorant of
their own identity and position.
15
A. Sen, Inequality Reexamined (Oxford: Oxford University Press, l992).
16
D. Gauthier, Morals by Agreement (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986).
17
J. Rawls, ‘Justice as fairness’, Philosophical Review, 67 (1958), pp. 164–94; J. Rawls, A Theory of
Justice (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1971).
18
B. Barry, Justice as Impartiality (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995), p. 51.
Fairness and international cooperation 373
Negotiation practice today portrays greater agreement on the meaning of justice and
fairness than does the scholarly literature. A stock of principles has been generated,
which enjoy broad support and are frequently applied. They reflect the experience of
what negotiators have repeatedly found to be reasonable, even-handed and broadly
acceptable ways forward.
Firstly, justice and fairness are rarely taken to mean identical (equal) treatment or
allocations. These values require proportionality: that parties’ circumstances be taken
into account. In negotiations over GPGs ranging from environmental resources to
free trade, the differentiation of obligations in accordance with economic ability is
commonplace. It often conflicts with the ‘polluter pays’ rule; yet, one participant in
negotiations on air pollution in Europe recalls that there was ‘hardly any debate’
about basing emission reductions on this principle: ‘. . . the differentiation was indeed
considered an issue of justice and fairness’.19 In international trade talks, the poorest
nations are usually asked to remove trade barriers in accordance with level of
development.20
Secondly, fairness is associated with reciprocity and net benefits for all parties:
‘The purpose of any negotiation is to produce . . . reciprocal benefits . . . All parties
feel that they need a balance of concessions...that is, they require reciprocity from
other parties’.21 ‘Appropriate’, not identical, commitments are sought from parties in
light of their different circumstances, to arrive at an agreement considered balanced
overall.22 It means that other principles, such as ‘no harm’ and ‘polluter pays’ in the
environmental area, are acted upon only as far as it is consistent with the overriding
concern about joint net benefits. Thus, rich countries victimised by air pollution,
such as Sweden and Finland, have paid for the adoption of clean technologies in the
poorer countries which are the source of much of this pollution, such as the Baltic
States and Poland, and have gained more from this than undertaking clean-up
efforts at home.23 Notions of justice requiring unilateral resource transfers without
19
Personal communication with Volkert Keiser, head of the Dutch delegation (since 1992) in the UN
Economic Commission for Europe Executive Body and the Working Group on Abatement Strategies,
in writing on 1 October 1997.
20
Personal communication with Karl Falkenberg, First Secretary of the delegation of the European
Community (EC) to the Uruguay Round of the GATT and then Head of the EC unit in charge of
the negotiations on trade in services, on 27 April 1998.
21
Personal communication with Ambassador Richard Self, chief US negotiator on services in the
Uruguay Round, on 29 April 1998.
22
Personal communication with David Hawes, Permanent Representative of Australia to the GATT
and Acting Chair of the Group of Negotiations on Services in the Uruguay Round of the GATT, on
26 March 1998.
23
R. Löfstedt, ‘What factors determine the provision of environmental aid to Eastern Europe: the case
of Sweden’. Paper presented at a conference on ‘Risk and Fairness’ at the International Institute for
Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) (Laxenburg, Austria: IIASA, 20–22 June 1993).
374 Cecilia Albin
return benefits – for example, aid to peoples affected by extreme poverty, natural
disasters, and epidemics – rarely survive political negotiations.
Thirdly, practitioners associate justice and fairness with impartiality. Voluntary
acceptance and the absence of coercion are important. However, to them imparti-
ality also entails balancing different principles and interests.24 A number of principles,
reflecting a wider range of considerations and concerns of parties than a single
criterion can capture, must guide a balanced solution. As noted earlier, several
competing principles can be invoked credibly in most complex international talks. So
balancing different principles is seen as a reasonable way to overcome conflicting
considerations, particularly when none emerges as superior and salient, and formu-
late an agreement which all can accept as evenhanded and fair.
Finally, international negotiators widely support the obligation to comply with
freely negotiated agreements. This is a well-established principle of morality and
international law, although views and regulations differ on circumstances which
justify breaking an agreement. The indivisibility of GPGs makes over-consumption
and under-supply tempting, so the main point here is about intentional ‘free riding’:
some parties can benefit from others complying with an agreement on GPG provision,
while avoiding compliance themselves and maximising their gains. Yet, in the inter-
national community today, adherence to voluntary agreements is expected and
certainly associated with justice.
This stock of principles can be captured in an overarching concept of justice as
the balanced settlement of conflicting claims.25 It recognises that the meaning of
justice and fairness is a complex matter in real international encounters, and that it
is frequently contested for good reasons. A notion of what is right and reasonable in
these common situations of moral ambiguity is therefore essential. In order to
Examples:
• Impartiality (for instance, no coercion, balancing different interests and criteria)
• Reciprocity
• Unequal (differential) treatment of unequal parties
• Representative decision-making
• Net gains from cooperation
• Compliance with freely negotiated agreements
• No free riders
24
Personal communication with Ambassador Ralph Earle, Acting Head of the US delegation to the
1995 NPT Review and Extension Conference, on 30 June 1998; personal communication with Van-
Thinh Tran, Head of the EC permanent delegation to the Uruguay Round of the GATT, on
25 March 1998.
25
C. Albin, Justice and Fairness in International Negotiation.
Fairness and international cooperation 375
Cooperation on peace and security issues (and GPGs specifically) so often fails or is
insufficient, because countries stumble over critical justice and fairness issues when
attempting to negotiate the terms of collaboration. What then are these issues that
have to be tackled? They concern the structure, process, procedures and outcome of
negotiations.
These concern the fundamental conditions and constraints under which the negoti-
ation process unfolds and negotiators operate.26 They can prejudice the talks and the
outcome considerably, particularly for weaker parties. Three issues are especially
important in negotiating GPGs: agenda-setting, parties, and rules.
What issues are placed on the agenda, and how they are ordered and linked,
impact upon the subsequent bargaining and outcome. Negotiators naturally seek
maximum coverage of issues of most interest to themselves, and linkages which can
improve their bargaining position. In negotiations over GPGs, agenda-setting often
raises heated disputes about fairness along the North-South divide. Representatives
of LDCs hold that GPGs of vital importance to their survival and well-being (such
as health and poverty issues, and the finance of economic development) are
persistently neglected, while other GPGs of most benefit to richer states and the
corporate world are imposed and prioritised on the international agenda (such as
nuclear non-proliferation, the environment, and intellectual property rights).
The attempt to launch another round of trade talks at the 1999 WTO meeting in
Seattle fell partly over this issue. Key developed countries (DCs), led by the US,
pushed for electronic commerce, investment policy, and labour and environmental
standards to be placed on the agenda for new talks. LDCs found these areas of little
interest or even potential harm to themselves; for example, labour and environmental
standards linked to trade would discriminate against their goods produced by child
26
J. Z. Rubin and B. Brown, The Social Psychology of Bargaining and Negotiation (New York and
London: Academic Press, l975).
376 Cecilia Albin
labour and by workers without trade unions rights.27 They also held that rich
countries had neglected to open up their markets sufficiently to goods in which
LDCs have comparative advantage, such as textiles and agricultural products. LDCs
insisted on further progress in removing barriers to trade in these products before
new concerns were added to the agenda.
The notion of justice as a balanced settlement of conflicting claims calls for a
broad and balanced agenda which includes, orders and links issues in a way which
takes into account the essential concerns of all parties. It does not cater predomin-
antly to one set of interests at the expense of others. This makes possible a fair
negotiation process as discussed below, and an outcome which all can accept. The
need to get to the table and to an agreement can encourage fairer agenda-setting in
this sense. In the preparatory talks to the Uruguay Round of the GATT, it was
recognised that LDCs had been marginalised in the agenda-setting for earlier
rounds, and that industrialised states had not responded sufficiently to their concerns
in areas such as agriculture and textiles. That Round would have been impossible to
launch without the eventual formulation of an agenda which balanced competing
interests, partly by making progress in talks on services conditional upon progress
on issues essential to LDCs.28 Service sectors of importance to DCs, such as capital
flows, as well as to LDCs, such as labour, also had to be included. Charges of unfair
agenda-setting re-emerged at the 1999 WTO meeting in Seattle but, at a WTO
ministerial meeting in Doha (Qatar) in 2001, governments finally agreed on a more
balanced agenda for a new round of global trade talks.29
Another set of issues concern the parties to the negotiations: their attributes,
representation, and relations between them. Unequal power relations, for example,
raise fairness issues. If sharply unequal parties bargain over GPGs, the process and
its outcome may mirror their respective power or lack of it more than voluntary
agreement, entitlements, contributions or needs. On representation, offering every
party a seat at the bargaining table as far as possible is important: it helps to ensure
that all interests are considered, enhances the legitimacy of the outcome and
facilitates its implementation talks.30 The rise in negotiations over global issues has,
however, raised difficult questions about what fair representation entails. Many
GPGs implicate far more interests and parties than governments, often responding
to constituencies at home and looking to the next elections, can represent. Yet, the
traditional admissions criteria of statehood and sovereignty still prevail in inter-
national negotiating fora, and the participation of non-state actors remains largely
unofficial or ad hoc and subjected to the approval of state delegations.
Justice as a balanced settlement of conflicting claims speaks for a principled and
cautious expansion of the opportunities to participate in negotiations over GPGs. It
should be based on criteria which relate to what parties (state and non-state) can
27
J. Bhagwati, ‘Third World Intellectuals and NGOs-Statement Against Linkage’ (November 1999).
Retrieved from http://www.columbia.edu/~jb38/papers.htm
28
Personal communication with Tovar Nunes, member of Brazil’s delegation to the Uruguay Round
talks on services (from 1988 to 1991), on 7 May 1998.
29
‘Doha WTO Ministerial 2001: Ministerial Declaration.’ WTO Doc. WT/MIN(01)/DEC/1 (Geneva:
20 November 2001).
30
L. Susskind and J. Cruikshank, Breaking the Impasse: Consensual Approaches to Resolving Public
Disputes (New York: Basic Books, 1987).
Fairness and international cooperation 377
It refers to how parties relate to and treat each other during negotiations. It is, in
brief, about fair behaviour. Two matters are important to justice as a balanced
settlement of conflicting claims, and in negotiations over GPGs: fair input and fair
play.
31
Trade and Development Report, 2001 (Geneva: United Nations Trade and Development Conference,
2001).
32
G. K. Helleiner, ‘Markets, Politics and Globalization: Can the Global Economy be Civilized?’, p. 20.
Tenth Raul Prebisch Lecture, Palais des Nations, Geneva, 11 December 2000 (Geneva: United
Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2000).
33
Personal communication with Jayantha Dhanapala, President of the 1995 NPT Review and
Extension Conference and UN Under-Secretary-General for Disarmament Affairs, New York, on 29
June 1998.
378 Cecilia Albin
The first, fair input or fair hearing, refers to parties and issues. Each party should
have an adequate chance to put forward its case and have an input into the process,
from the stage when the problem is framed and options assessed to the point when
the final agreement is formulated. A fair process is expected to consider as far as
possible all affected interests, with a view to their merits rather than existing power
structures. It is to avoid marginalising, or exploiting the absence of, any parties by
settling issues at their expense. Full information about the issues under negotiation is
to be made available to all, and to be considered openly. This may require the
assistance of outside individuals or organisations if participating governments do
not possess enough resources or credibility to gather and present relevant data
impartially.
Fair play means that each party can freely accept or reject proposals, without
being subjected to heavy-handed coercion and threats. Stronger parties refrain from
pressurising the weak and dispossessed into accepting terms which, to impartial
observers, would appear unreasonable or even exploitative. But numerous multi-
lateral framework agreements on GPGs also stress that all participants are obliged
to negotiate ‘in good faith’; that is, genuinely work towards and contribute to a
negotiated settlement. They are expected to reciprocate concessions and balance
different interests. A party cannot pursue its own self-interests in an uncompromis-
ing way that halts the entire process or blocks an agreement to the detriment of
others.
Fair play also requires parties to agree on clear negotiation rules and procedures,
and to respect these thereafter (unless changed subsequently by consensus). This
brings us to procedural fairness, that is, the features of the methods used to arrive at
an agreement.34 They include voting, linkage of issues, mutual reciprocation of
concessions, and decision by consensus. They may be inherently fair or unfair in
some respect (such as, by giving, or failing to give, every party a power of veto or a
vote), or endorsed by virtue of favouring a certain outcome seen as fair (such as one
based on a balance of concessions between parties). Some are adopted during the
bargaining process while others, as discussed above, are agreed in advance as part of
the overall negotiation structure. Minimally they cover two matters: consultation
practices with parties inside and outside the negotiating room, and methods of
decision-making which, whatever their specifics, should be representative and trans-
parent. Ideally, they are more comprehensive and may clarify matters such as: are
the parties expected always to give full (and truthful) information about their
interests, priorities and options? In one argument, lying and other deceptive tactics
are unacceptable unless all parties know and accept that they are part of the game.35
In the Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty (CTBT) talks from 1994 to 1996, Australia
along with 50 sponsoring countries bypassed the Conference on Disarmament and
its consensus rule by submitting the final draft treaty to the United Nations (UN)
General Assembly for approval. The purpose was to prevent India, an opponent to
the draft, from blocking its adoption. Australia defended the action by arguing that
34
The terms ‘process fairness’ and ‘procedural fairness’ are often used interchangeably without making
this distinction, to refer to the negotiation process generally.
35
D. Lax and J. Sebenius, The Manager as Negotiator: Bargaining for Cooperation and Competitive Gain
(New York and London: The Free Press, 1986).
Fairness and international cooperation 379
‘the extension of a national point of view to the point of seeking to prevent others
from acting on theirs’ was unacceptable.36 Yet there were countries other than India
which felt that ‘India was treated unfairly in the CTBT negotiations because a
solution was forced on them that was not forced on anybody else. The rules of the
game were changed. That was unfair.’37 It is at least clear that overriding the
consensus rule made it more desirable and easier for India to reject the final CTBT
with some moral justification.
Negotiations over GPGs frequently take place under framework agreements
which endorse principles of process fairness mentioned here. Yet, their material
impact on outcomes to date has in many cases been disappointing. It partly reflects
the fact that well-to-do countries enjoy advantages in terms of representation (pre-
sence, size, and preparation of delegations); negotiating experience and skills; access
to technical knowledge, information and other support; and sheer weight in inter-
national economic, military or political terms. Some LDCs even lack a permanent
diplomatic presence in important international fora. For such reasons, actual
decision-making power over GPGs can be vested unproportionally in the hands of a
few states, which come to dominate the negotiation process excessively. Other parties
may find few real chances to stand up for their interests and influence the talks on an
equal basis.
The WTO machinery is based on formal decision-making rules which help to
reduce power inequalities between its members. Nevertheless, in practice, the great
number of parties, interests and issues involved in talks under its auspices creates a
need for leadership. Economically more powerful states, well resourced to handle
issues of great technical complexity, frequently end up exercising this function, while
resource-constrained countries find themselves poorly prepared to take an active
part in the consensus-building deliberations. In the Uruguay Round of the GATT
this meant that weak states were periodically marginalised, particularly in important
informal talks taking place outside the official conference rooms. The 1999 Seattle
meeting failed partly because the 135 WTO members, the majority of which are
LDCs, were asked to sign an agreement which only about 25 countries had been
seriously involved in drafting. This small grouping was seen as unrepresentative, and
left LDCs feeling that industrialised states had excluded them and neglected their
concerns. Delegates from both rich and poor countries blamed the US for seeking to
impose an agreement suited to American interests on others, and explained the
failure of the meeting in terms of such methods used.38
Does a negotiation fulfilling the criteria of process fairness here proposed lead to
a fair outcome? There is much empirical evidence to suggest that matters such as
taking all parties and interests well into account, and taking decisions by consensus,
enhance the perception of the outcome being fair and balanced. For instance,
greater participation by LDCs is now seen as essential if reforms of the global
36
R. Johnson, ‘A Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty: Signed but not Sealed’. Acronym Report, no. 10 (May
1997).
37
Personal communication with Don Sinclair, member of the Canadian delegation to the 1995 NPT
Review and Extension Conference, and a ‘Friend of the Chair’ in the negotiations leading to the
CTBT, on 2 July 1998.
38
‘Trade talks failure prompts rethink’, BBC News Online, 4 December 1999; ‘WTO: Who’s to blame?’,
BBC News Online, 6 December 1999.
380 Cecilia Albin
Fair play:
• Freedom of choice and voluntary agreement
• Obligation to negotiate ‘in good faith’, reciprocate and compromise
• Truthful information about positions, interests, alternatives and their implications
• Adherence to agreed rules for the negotiations
financial system are to be credible and effective. So process fairness facilitates, but as
we have seen, cannot guarantee a fair outcome.
This concerns, firstly, the principles guiding the distribution of benefits and burdens in
an agreement. They are the criteria underlying the terms of cooperation over GPGs.
Negotiators who eventually reach a successful agreement usually employ, as we have
seen, a combination of different principles. It is a means to consider more pertinent
factors than a single criterion can capture, to overcome conflicting interests, and to
win the approval and cooperation of all needed parties. The practice is seen as right
and reasonable, not only as required on pragmatic grounds, and corresponds well
with the notion of justice as a balanced settlement of conflicting claims. For example,
the 1994 Uruguay Round agreements or the ‘Final Act’ ended seven years of conflict-
ridden negotiations with a package based on the consideration of all affected
interests. Differential treatment of LDCs to take account of their financial, trade
and development needs (such as more time for compliance and time-limited exemp-
tions from agreed obligations), mutual benefit, non-discrimination, and transparency
were among the principles which were balanced and combined.39
But of concern is also fairness after the agreement, that is, actual implementation
and compliance with its terms and principles, and the soundness of these over time
with changing circumstances. Renewed talks may be needed to combat free riders
and ensure that all parties honour their part of the bargain, or to adjust the original
terms in light of new knowledge and developments. This stage often determines
whether an agreement on paper will actually result in effective – and fair – co-
operation on the ground. Fairness after the agreement is central to the notion of
justice put forward here, and a challenge to achieve regarding GPGs because of the
39
‘The Final Act Embodying the Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations’.
Signed by ministers in Marrakesh on 15 April 1994 (Geneva: GATT (1995) [GATT 94/4]).
Fairness and international cooperation 381
temptation to free-ride. Some states can often escape the duties of cooperation and
yet consume its benefits, at least until those complying find a way to take action or
decide to abandon the agreement themselves.
The objections of LDCs to the trade regime focus on how agreements to date have
supposedly been implemented in favour of industrialised states. They criticise DCs for
being slow and reluctant to carry out their trade liberalising obligations under the
Final Act. They also point to the US and the EU using anti-dumping legislation and
favouring labour and environmental standards in discriminatory ways. Significant
trade barriers certainly remain in areas where LDCs have comparative advantage, such
as agriculture and textiles. Even after the reforms of the Uruguay Round, agricultural
protectionism in high-income countries reportedly caused annual income losses for
LDCs of almost $US20 bn per year. LDCs’ exports of manufactured goods to DCs
are subjected to trade barriers which are four times higher than those applied to
exports from developed states.40 At the 1999 WTO Ministerial Conference in Seattle,
India’s Minister for Commerce and Industry highlighted LDCs’ great concern about
implementation issues, including ‘the non-realisation of expected benefits from
Agreements such as textiles and agriculture’, and held that addressing these effectively
would alone give the WTO ‘an image of fairness and equity’.41
Justice and fairness issues thus figure prominently in bargaining over GPGs, from
the earliest phase when the talks are structured and the agenda set to the final phase
of securing implementation and compliance. Like conflicts of interests, these issues
can undermine the capacity of negotiation to produce acceptable and durable
solutions. They go a long way to explain why countries all too often fail to reach
agreement on GPGs. Ultimately, however, parties depend on large-scale cooperation
in securing the continued provision, management, and benefits of most GPGs. Too
arbitrary or too self-serving proposals and arrangements usually fail to win the
respect and voluntary approval of all parties and their constituencies, and have a
short lifespan. Negotiators are therefore motivated to act and formulate terms for
collaboration based on principles for the allocation of duties, rights, benefits and
costs which everyone can freely accept as reasonable and legitimate – as fair.
The notion of justice as a balanced settlement of conflicting claims offers guide-
lines as to what is required in negotiations over GPGs. For example, the agenda
needs to be set collectively and balance the interests of all parties. Every party, as far
as possible, should have a chance to participate actively in and influence the negoti-
ation process. The voices represented at the table should be expanded in a principled
and cautious way, beyond those of governments and states. Methods employed to
reach an agreement should be inclusive, open and non-coercive. Just agreements not
40
‘Seattle WTO Talks Must Focus on the Poor. [World Bank President James D.] Wolfensohn Calls for
‘Fair and Inclusive’ Round’. News Release no. 2000/115/S (Washington, DC: The World Bank Group,
29 November 1999).
41
Statement by Shri Murasoli Maran, Minister for Commerce and Industry, India, at the Third WTO
Ministerial Conference in Seattle, 30 November 1999, India and the WTO Newsletter
(http://commin.nic.in/doc/wtonovdec2.htm).
382 Cecilia Albin
only deliver real benefits to all participants but also establish a sound balance of
benefits between them (give each its ‘fair share’ of the gains from cooperation);
make demands on individual parties with consideration for their resources and other
relevant circumstances; and balance the two when they seem to conflict. Such agree-
ments combine and reconcile different principles and interests, can be justified on
impartial grounds, win the voluntary approval of parties, require evenhanded imple-
mentation, and ban intentional free-riding on others’ compliance.
Few of these ambitious criteria have been met fully in negotiations over GPGs to
date. What then can be done to promote fair negotiation practice, and thereby better
cooperation? By way of conclusion, we will discuss four sets of strategies.
The first concerns improving negotiating and decision-making methods. This could
go a long way to make the bargaining process over GPGs more inclusive and
efficient. Firstly, in an informal, off-the-record context, parties could prepare for
actual negotiations by engaging in open dialogue and problem-solving over conten-
tious issues. The purpose would be to clarify goals and intentions on all sides;
brainstorm and evaluate possible alternative solutions which may be mutually
beneficial; and, in the process, enhance trust and goodwill. As part of this exercise,
the parties could develop and agree on a set of explicit rules and objectives defining
their understanding of a fair negotiation process and outcome. Subsequent adherence
to these would then be reviewed regularly, when revising and deciding on drafts of a
final agreement and at other critical junctures. A detached party, such as a committee
consisting of subject experts and representatives of the host organisation, could help
participating governments to undertake these reviews impartially and to find ways
out of any disputes.
The observance of agreed criteria of fairness could also be examined across issue
areas at regular intervals. Organisations sponsoring negotiations over GPGs in a
range of areas may be well suited to institute such a procedure; for example, the UN
General Assembly. Such broader reviews acting as ‘watch-dogs’ may reveal patterns
and trends which would not become as apparent on an issue-by-issue basis; for
example, any negligence in the treatment of the priorities and concerns of LDCs or
other parties in global agenda-setting and in the implementation of agreements.
Once formal negotiations are underway methods of consultation and decision-
making need to ensure that all voices are represented and heard – and perceived to
be so. This is a formidable challenge in negotiations over GPGs, which usually
involve well over 100 parties, and takes time and skill. A core steering group
consisting of a limited number of parties almost always needs to be formed to make
agreement possible, but it has to be representative of the larger group.
The so-called ‘Green Room meetings’ with a small number of delegations which
the US chair of the WTO meeting in Seattle held over three days became seen as
unfair and undemocratic. By contrast the Indian chair of the 1995 NPT Review and
Extension Conference, which lasted nearly a month, created a group of 25 countries
representing all main positions and interests, to test ideas and proposals and draft
the principles of an agreement. This method, combined with the chair’s determin-
ation and leadership to reach an evenhanded outcome, ‘allowed a solution to be
worked out in a smaller group and to be accepted by a larger group’.42 That larger
42
Communication with Dhanapala.
Fairness and international cooperation 383
group, the 175 participating states, then adopted the NPT extension decision by
consensus, not by majority vote as stipulated in the Treaty, which boosted its moral
authority and legitimacy. The US chair of the WTO meeting in Seattle argued that
the world organisation had outgrown the consensus rule.43 This case points to its
continued potential value, however, if enough time is allowed to reach that con-
sensus. Whatever methods of decision-making are used, they need to be represent-
ative and transparent in order to win respect and approval.
Providing training, research and technical support, and policy advice to disadvant-
aged parties is another way to promote fairness. These are crucial means to strengthen
their individual and collective capacity to look after their interests in view of new
developments, formulate effective positions, and influence negotiations. Such support
could be provided prior to and during formal talks, and to individual countries as
well as coalitions. Of course, the more LDCs can develop common positions among
themselves before they begin to bargain with DCs, the more successful they are likely
to be. Effective reform of the world’s monetary and financial system, for example,
depends extensively on whether LDCs can act collectively on their shared objectives.
It also depends on preparing LDCs better for and increasing their participation in
negotiations, with the assistance of DCs.44
The establishment of the Agency for International Trade Information and Co-
operation (AITIC) independently of the Bretton Woods institutions, the WTO’s
provision of trade policy courses and other initiatives have begun to prepare LDCs
better for taking a full part in trade talks, and for intervening effectively before critical
decisions are taken. In short, training and support are vital to ensure that the
principles and rules of the trade regime are interpreted and implemented in an even-
handed way, and deliver real benefits to all its members. The President of the World
Bank appeared to recognise shortcomings on this front when stating that ‘[i]t makes
no sense to urge poor countries to reform their economies, to urge them to compete
and “pay their way in the world”, while denying them the means to compete’.45
Some expansion of the opportunities for non-state actors to be consulted and
participate in negotiations over GPGs could enhance their legitimacy and effective-
ness. Firstly, greater involvement of major affected groups within states, and relevant
experts, in the development of national policies and positions could help. It could
clarify the real effects of alternative measures which may result from the talks on a
particular country, help to devise a balanced and coherent national policy, and
reduce confrontations back home once international talks are underway. This is a
way to anchor international negotiation and cooperation over GPGs more firmly in
national policy objectives and consultations, and thereby enhance the prospect of
their success. When negotiators formulate positions and deals behind closed doors,
they may not be fully aware of the implications of their undertakings at the national
or local levels and moreover often lose public support. In the area of trade, the
result is then often that they revert to protectionism.
The second stage at which non-state actors, alone or in cooperation with govern-
ments, could make a real difference is in the international negotiation process itself;
43
‘Trade talks failure prompts rethink’, BBC News Online, 4 December 1999.
44
Helleiner, ‘Markets, Politics and Globalization.’
45
Wolfensohn, ‘Seattle WTO Talks Must Focus on the Poor’.
384 Cecilia Albin
for example, by providing expertise and analysis which aid in the formulation of fair
and effective solutions. The expertise of scientists has been enlisted regularly since
the early 1990s in acid rain negotiations within the UN Economic Commission for
Europe. Their computer models have played a key role in the successful negotiation
of acid rain emission reductions. They serve as a tool to generate abatement
strategies for maximum environmental protection at the lowest possible cost on a
regional scale. Parties consider agreements based on such empirical knowledge fair
and efficient. In climate change negotiations, scientists in the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) support the talks.
The International Conference on Financing for Development, launched under UN
auspices in 2001 at the initiative of LDCs to debate reform of the global financial
system, included civil society and private sector hearings from the outset.46 Elsewhere,
however, the participation of non-governmental parties has yet to be integrated. In
the WTO, members meet only informally with such representatives, and official trade
negotiations are closed to them as to the public at large and the media. During the
WTO meeting in Seattle, US President Bill Clinton held that ‘the public must see and
hear and, in a very real sense, actually join in the deliberations. . . . That’s the only
way they can know the process is fair and know their concerns were at least
considered.’47 To take another example, negotiations over nuclear non-proliferation
have been closed to representatives of non-state groups.
Finally, linkage of issues can enhance the fairness of negotiations over GPGs to
the ultimate benefit of all. It allows a party or coalition of parties to exchange
concessions on their supposedly lower-priority issues, which to another party may be
of utmost significance, for concessions on other issues they value more. It is possible
to link issues across two or more areas (for example, economic development and
environmental protection), or different issues or aspects of the same issue in a single
area. From the viewpoint of fairness and successful negotiation, there is nothing
inherently good or bad about linkage: it depends entirely on the context and the
manner in which linkage is used.
Linkage assumes that one issue or area can be traded off against another as a
result of different valuations. This is not always ethical; for example, offering economic
rewards to the needy in exchange for their acceptance of matters compromising their
safety (such as toxic wastes from DCs). The method can delay and further compli-
cate already complex negotiations, by placing additional issues on the table which
are controversial. As mentioned earlier, a major reason for the failure of the 1999
WTO meeting in Seattle was the efforts of some DCs to link labour, as well as
environmental, standards to trade on the agenda for new talks.
Linkage can help secure a balanced agenda, an evenhanded agreement, and com-
pliance with its terms. Weak parties can use this method to improve their leverage
and better terms for themselves, as required. They can tie their readiness to move
and make a deal on a particular issue to a willingness by others to concede on
matters important to themselves. Connections between economic development issues
on the one hand, and environmental protection on the other, are now made routinely
46
Kamal Malhotra, ‘The Road to the Earth Summit 2002’. Presentation at Heinrich Boell Foundation
Conference, Panel on International Conference on Financing for Development, 20 April 2001.
47
‘Clinton calls for a more transparent WTO’, India Abroad News Service, 2 December 1999.
Fairness and international cooperation 385
48
‘Declaration of Commitment on HIV/AIDS’. UN Special Session on HIV/AIDS (New York:
2 August 2001).