Economics Project 3rd Semester
Economics Project 3rd Semester
project
Topic: INDIFFERENCE CURVE ANALYSIS
Acknowledgement
In performing my project, I had to take the help and guideline of some
respected persons, who deserve my greatest gratitude. The completion
of this project gives me much pleasure.
I would like to show my gratitude to ms.Neeraj kaur, Rayat College of
Law for giving me a good guideline for project throughout numerous
consultations. His dynamism, vision, sincerity and motivation have
deeply inspired me. I would also like to extend my deepest gratitude to
all those who have directly and indirectly guided me in typing this
project.
In addition, I would like to thank our Professor for introducing me to the
Methodology of work, and whose passion for the “underlying
structures” had lasting effect. I thank all the people for their help
directly and indirectly to complete my project.
INTRODUCTION
In microeconomics, indifference curve is an important tool of analysis
in the study of consumer behavior. The concept of indifference curve
analysis was first propounded by British economist Francis Ysidro
Edgeworth and was put into use by Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto
during the early 20th century. However, it was brought into extensive
use by economists J.R. Hicks and R.G.D Allen. Hicks and Allen
criticized Marshallian cardinal approach of utility and developed
indifference curve theory of consumer’s demand.
Thus, this theory is also known as ordinal approach. Indifference curve
analysis is a modern method to analyse consumer’s behaviour. It is
based on ordinal utility. There are two concepts of utility cardinal and
ordinal. Cardinal is used to count or indicate how many while ordinal
are words that represent rank and order in a set, scale of preference and
the marginal rate of substitution. Ordinal utility refers to the level of
satisfaction. The ordinal utility function means the utilities obtained
from goods can be compared as being greater or less or equal through
the level of satisfaction. The scale of preference is the quantitative
expression of consumer’s desire for goods. It shows the way in which an
individual consumer decides to spend his money income on various
commodities.
Meaning of Indifference Curve
An indifference curve is the locus of points – particular combinations
which yield the same utility or level of satisfaction to the consumer, so
that he is indifferent as to particular combination he consumes. In other
words, IC analysis refers to the locus of points representing the various
combinations of two goods which yield the same level of satisfaction to
the consumer. Since any combination of the two goods on an
indifference curve gives equal level of satisfaction, the consumer is
indifferent to any combination he consumes. Thus, an indifference curve
is also known as ‘equal satisfaction curve’ or ‘Iso -utility curve’. On a
graph, an indifference curve is a link between the combinations of
quantities which the consumer regards to yield equal utility. Simply, an
indifference curve is a graphical representation of indifference schedule.
•According to Hicks: “It is the locus of the points representing parts of
quantities between which the individual is indifferent and so it is termed
as an indifferent curve.”
•According to Leftwhich : “A single indifference curve shows the
indifferent combination of X and Y that yield equal satisfaction to the
consumer”
Indifference Map:
The Indifference Map refers to a set of Indifference Curves that reflects
an understanding and gives an entire view of a consumer’s choices. The
below diagram shows an Indifference map with three indifference
curves. According to the indifference curve approach, it is not possible
for the consumer to say how much utility he derives from the
consumption of a commodity, because utility is not a measureable
magnitude. But a consumer can compare two or more combinations of
goods and say which of them he likes best or whether he likes them all
equally well. The Laws of Consumer Demand can be deduced from
these preferences.
On the other hand, in Figure the indifference map between the two
goods is such that the budget line BL is less steep than the indifference
curves between the two goods so that the MRSy > PX /Py for all levels
of consumption along the budget line BL. Therefore, he maximizes his
satisfaction at the corner point L where he buys only commodity X and
none of Y. In this case price of commodity Y and willingness to pay
(i.e. MRS) for it are such that he does not consider it worthwhile to
purchase even one unit of it.
the indifference curves are usually convex to the origin. Convexity of
indifference curves implies that the marginal rate of substitution of X
for Y falls as more of X is substituted for Y.Thus, indifference curves
are convex to the origin when principle of diminishing marginal rate of
substitution holds good and which is generally the case. But the
possibility of indifference curves being concave to the origin cannot be
ruled out in some exceptional cases. Concavity of the indifference
curves implies that the marginal rate of substitution of X for y increases
when more of X is substituted for Y.
It will be clear from the analysis made below that in case of
indifference curves being concave to the origin the consumer will
choose or buy only one good. In other words, concavity of indifference
curves implies that the consumer has a distaste for variety, that is, does
not like diversification in consumption. However, distaste for variety
cannot be considered a normal or model behaviour, so we regard
convexity to be the general case. But when consumers have a distaste
for variety and diversification the case of concave indifference curves
will occur.
In case of concave indifference curves, the consumer will not be in
equilibrium at the point of tangency between budget line and
indifference curve, that is, in this case interior solution will not exist.
Instead, we would have corner solution for consumer’s equilibrium. Let
us take Fig. here indifference curves are shown to be concave. The
given budget line BL is tangent to the indifference curve IC2 at point Q.
But the consumer cannot be in equilibrium at Q since by moving along
the given budget line BL he can get on to higher indifference curves
and obtain greater satisfaction than at Q. Thus by moving to K on the
given budget line BL, he will get more satisfaction than at Q since K
lies on a higher indifference curve than Q. He can increase his
satisfaction still more by moving to point Z on the budget line BL.
Thus, as he moves upward from tangency point Q on the budget line
his satisfaction will go on increasing until he reaches the extremity
point B. Likewise, if from Q he moves downward on the budget line, he
will get on to higher indifference curves and his satisfaction will go on
increasing till he reaches the other extremity point L.
In these circumstances the consumer will choose only one of two
goods: he will buy either X or Y depending upon whether L or B lies on
the higher indifference curve. In the situation depicted in Fig point B
lies on a higher indifference curve than point L. Therefore, the
consumer will choose only Y and will buy OB of Y. It should be
carefully noted that at B the budget line is not tangent to the
indifference curve IC5 , even though the consumer is here in
equilibrium. It is clear that when a consumer has concave indifference
curves, he will succumb to monomania, that is, he will consume only
one good
.
LIMITATIONS
Indifference curve analysis is claimed to be superior to utility analysis
because of its closeness to the reality. But, still it is criticised by many
economists due to some unrealistic assumptions, it is based upon.
Further, Schumpeter says, “The new technique has neither proved
anything new, nor has proved anything old, wrong”. Robertson
blamed this analysis by pointing out it as an old wine in a new bottle.
Many other economists such as F.H. Knight, Armstrong, Boulding
criticised the analysis in several ways. Some of the limitations of this
analysis are:
The indifference curve analysis is utility analysis in a new grab. It has
simply substituted new concepts and equations instead of the old ones.
The old principle of diminishing marginal utility has been replaced by
the new principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution. The old
equation of consumer equilibrium. MUA /PA = MUB /PB = MUM is
replaced by a new equation, which says that the consumer is in
equilibrium, when the marginal rate of substitution between the two
commodities, which is the ratio of their marginal utilities is equal to
their price ratio. This is nothing but the reformulation of previous
equation in a modified form.
Indifference curve analysis assumes that consumers are familiar with
their preference schedules. But, it is not possible for a consumer to have
a complete knowledge of all the combinations of the two commodities,
total satisfactions from them, rates of substitutions and total incomes.
At best he can tell his preferences in the neighbourhood of his existing
position. Moreover, the preferences of this consumer keep changing.
This analysis assumes perfect divisibility of the commodities. But,
consumer is often faced by lumpy units. So, the continuity of
indifference curves is not ensured as assumed by indifference curves
analysis, as also large number of very closed placed indifference
curves. Further, choices with extreme combinations (too much of
commodity ‘X’ and very little of ‘Y’ and vice-versa) are not observed
in the real world.
Indifference curve analysis is micro economic in character. It is not
possible to draw indifference curves indicating the choices of a group or
a country as a whole. In this respect, utility analysis has an edge over,
as it goes by a general opinion based on past experience and
observation.
Indifference curve analysis is not amenable to statistical investigation
and empirical research, as the entire analysis is based upon theoretically
formulated crosseffect relationships and not upon statistical
observations. In view of Samuelsson, indifference curves are imaginary.
Indifference curve analysis fails to explain consumer behaviour under
risk and uncertainty.
Thus, indifference curve analysis is not free from defects of its own.
Even some of these defects were appreciated by Hicks, who sought to
remove them in his later work ‘A Revision of Demand Theory’
published in 1956. The approach is a considerable improvement over
the conventional utility approach and has gained popularity among
economists.
CONCLUSION
In our analysis above, we have shown that corner solution of consumer
s equilibrium is possible even when his indifference curves between
goods are convex. It is worth noting that in case of convex indifference
curves, corner equilibrium is however not inevitable, it occurs only
when price of a commodity is too high as compared to the marginal rate
of substitution of even the first unit of the commodity. However, when
the indifference curves are concave consumer’s equilibrium will
inevitably be a corner solution. This implies that more of commodity X
a consumer has the more useful or significant in terms of satisfaction an
extra unit of it becomes. Therefore, the concave indifference curves do
not seem to be plausible or realistic. Now, as seen above, the
concavity of indifference curves for a consumer implies that the
consumer spends his entire income on a commodity and therefore buys
only one commodity. However, consumption of one good only by a
consumer which the concavity of indifference curves leads us to believe
is quite unrealistic. Observations in the real world reveal that consumers
do not spend their entire income on a single commodity and in fact
purchase a multitude of different goods and services. This rejects the
existence of concave indifference curves.