Crypto Emission
Crypto Emission
Crypto Emission
Case Study
Scott Fan, Elliot Gyllensvärd, Erich Farkas, Julian Schutzner
Department of Economics
University College London, UK
July 23, 2022
Abstract
This paper seeks to analyse the environmental effects of China’s recent regulatory steps taken
against cryptocurrencies and compare them with two policy alternatives. To evaluate the environ-
mental impact, two baseline scenarios are used - a ban scenario and a no-ban scenario - which are
then employed to compare China’s intervention with two alternative policies; an emissions trading
system or carbon taxes. It is estimated that China’s decision to ban cryptocurrencies will result
in a 25.7% reduction in CO2 emissions from the global Bitcoin network between mid-2021 and
2030. In comparison, under a hypothetical emission trading system (ETS) and carbon tax inter-
vention the most stringent scenario is estimated to reduce global Bitcoin CO2 emissions by 2.9%
and 8.5% between mid-2021 and 2030, respectively. Furthermore, this paper shows that the ETS
and carbon tax are both restricted in their absolute ability to reduce CO2 emissions due to the
difficulties associated with the practical implementation of such policies. This provides evidence
for why, in terms of an environmental perspective, a cryptocurrency ban is the most effective policy
in reducing the Bitcoin blockchain network’s CO2 emissions. However, the paper also shows that
the transition to Proof-of-Stake (PoS) blockchains may create an environment in which there is
less of an argument for active government intervention in the cryptocurrency markets due to the
protocol’s high energy efficiency.
1 Introduction
Cryptocurrencies have seen rising levels of popularity in the global financial system over the recent
years, but their regulation has remained largely heterogeneous across countries. Regulation has become
a pressing issue among governments due to various issues, including the environmental impact of
cryptocurrencies. The underlying technology can use significant amounts of energy, depending on the
consensus protocol used. As a result, Bitcoin’s Proof of Work (PoW) protocol has become a focal
point of discussion among regulators, given its substantial power consumption.
This paper aims to analyse the environmental effects of China’s recent regulatory steps against
cryptocurrencies, and compare them with two alternative intervention policies; an emissions trading
system and carbon taxes. Consequently, the environmental impact of Proof of Work (PoW) and Proof
of Stake (PoS) chains will be analysed through the examples of Bitcoin and Ethereum1 respectively.
1
Ethereum is currently transitioning from PoW to PoS. Amongst other advantages, the predicted decline
in energy usage of more than 99.95% under PoS has often been cited as one of the main considerations
for Ethereum’s transition (Beekhuizen, 2021). PoS will be further explained in Section 3.4.
Under PoW, anyone with enough computing power can participate in validating transactions on the
network. However, to successfully validate a transaction, one needs to compete against other miners
in terms of computing power to solve cryptographic puzzles to add new blocks and receive a reward.
The computing power is often referred to as hash rate which is the amount of computing power being
contributed to the network through mining to process transactions.
On the Bitcoin blockchain (and on most other blockchains), every transaction is made publicly
available for any participant to view, each participant then processes recent transactions in order of its
timestamped hash to keep a time-ordered ledger. A hash is a mathematical function that takes a file
and produces a relatively short code that can be used to identify that file. Bitcoin miners verify the
transaction and add it to the next block using the cryptographic hash value of the previous block. The
previous block’s hash value is hidden from the miner who has to solve it by brute force. Miners keep
trying over and over to generate new hashes, until they find one that fulfils the requirement. Once
the hash of the previous block is computed, it is declared to the network which verifies it and a new
block is added to the blockchain. The miner who solved the PoW puzzle then updates the blockchain
and gets a reward in Bitcoin which is created in accordance with the protocol whereby every 210,000
blocks (around every four years) the block reward is halved.
For the puzzle to be solved and rewarded, significant computing power is required to create a
hash that follows the blockchain’s format - a process which demands significant amounts of energy.
Furthermore, miners who were not successful do not receive any compensation and the energy used to
compete is essentially wasted.
Given the high energy consumption and ever-improving mining technology which has to be updated
by miners, there is a significant amount of resources required which has a corresponding impact on the
environment. According to the Cambridge Bitcoin Energy Consumption Index, the Bitcoin network
has an annualised energy consumption of 128.87 TWh as of 27 February 20222 (Cambridge, 2022), more
than the entire annual energy consumption of the Netherlands. It is not only the energy consumption
that concerns policymakers given recent turbulence in the technology supply chain. To compete in
the mining process, specialised hardware referred to as ASIC (Application Specific Integrated Circuit)
Miner is commonly used to perform the computations required for Bitcoin’s PoW consensus algorithm.
In the light of the recent “chip shortage” across the world, the demand for ASICs disrupts supply chains
while technological advancement of mining devices requires miners to update their devices (average
lifespan 1.29 years) to compete, creating 30.7 metric kilotons of e-waste per year (de Vries & Stoll,
2021). This, however, will not be tackled in this report and instead the focus will be on quantifying
the extent of electricity consumption and carbon emissions.
Whilst PoW requires a significant amount of computing resources, PoS offers a more power efficient
and scalable alternative. The consensus algorithm in PoS relies on the stakeholders within the system
to validate transactions rather than competing miners. Validators are algorithmically chosen and
don’t need to use large amounts of computing power. In the case of Ethereum, full validators have
to deposit a stake of 32 ETH (equivalent currency unit) and can then create blocks when they are
randomly chosen or validate proposed blocks when they’re not (Ethereum, 2022). If a validator attests
to a malicious block, his stake is lost.
Platt et al.(2021) find that the Bitcoin PoW algorithm’s energy consumption is “at least three orders
of magnitude higher than the highest consuming PoS system”, which will have to be considered by
policymakers going forward. To evaluate China’s policy decisions, this paper begins by understanding
China’s relevance in the world of cryptocurrency.
2 There is substantial estimation uncertainty in such estimates, given that the energy consumption information from
all nodes of the Bitcoin network, equipment and datacentres are not widely available.
2
1.2 China’s Place In The World of Cryptocurrency
In terms of cryptocurrency use, Chinese people used to lead the adoption. In 2013 China had already
surpassed the rest of the world with 84,000 Bitcoin wallets being created in a single month, about 30
percent of the global total for the month (Romann, 2013). Bitcoin exchanges such as BTC China were
also the world’s highest-volume exchanges in 2013 (Southurst, 2013).
The local popularity has largely been attributed to strict capital controls on the yuan and BTC
China’s no-fee trading. Capital controls make it difficult to invest or spend yuan abroad, while Bitcoin
can easily be transferred to a wallet in a foreign country and exchanged for local currency.
The success of Chinese cryptocurrency miners was largely driven by the abundance of cheap elec-
tricity and cheap land in north and western provinces (von Carnap, 2021) and the availability of
market-leading ASIC hardware. It has been estimated that the Chinese ASIC provider Bitmain had
a market share of 70-80 percent before the regulatory crackdown (Cheng, 2021). This combination
of cheap resources and direct access to leading technology put mining companies at a competitive
advantage. In 2018 Chinese mining pools alone accounted for more than 60% of the Bitcoin network’s
total hash power (Kaiser, Jurado, & Ledger, 2018). Table 9 in Section 2.3.8.1 demonstrates the cost
advantage Chinese miners had over the last years, with almost 40% lower energy prices in certain peri-
ods. Consequently, mining operations in China dominated the rest of the world until recent regulations
banned operators from mining in June 2021 (Shen & Galbraith, 2021b).
3
5. Comparing these approaches, and understanding if there were other alternatives for Chinese
intervention.
2 Methodology
2.1 Literature Review of Interventions
In recent years, the most popular policy interventions to successfully limit emissions and incentivise
industries and consumers to consider their consumption of carbon, have come through carbon pricing.
Before that, it is important to understand the historical Chinese energy mix and subsequently its
energy goals.
4
Key Performance indicator Targets Target Year
Energy Intensity (Energy consumed per 13.5% lower than 2020 level 2025
Yuan of GDP)
Carbon Emission Intensity (CO2 emit- 65% lower than 2005 levels 2030
ted per Yuan of GDP)
Non-fossil fuels’ share in energy con- Around 25% 2030
sumption mix
Non-fossil fuels’ share in energy con- Above 80% 2060
sumption mix
The Chinese ETS is designed to put a price on carbon to reward companies that succeed in cutting their
emissions, while punishing lagging firms and industries. CO2 -emitting firms are allocated tradable
permits that grant them permission to a certain amount of CO2 emitted over a specified period.
Importantly, the market design allows for mutual gain as firms with less emission-efficient processes
can buy permits from more emission-efficient firms. Further, an ETS is theoretically believed to
produce similar outcomes to carbon taxes, however, with potentially less associated political backslash
(Hanley, Shogren, & White, 2019). The theoretical idea is attractive, and as a result, these markets
are becoming increasingly common for regulating carbon emissions and helping markets facilitate a
shift towards alternative energy sources through technological innovation (IEA, 2020).
The permits are currently allocated for free based on the CO2 emission of each site. However, while
the Chinese ETS is in many regards similar to the European cap-and-trade system it differs in one
important regard. Namely, while the EU ETS operates with a declining annual cap on CO2 emissions
(European Commission, 2021), the current Chinese iteration does not have a cap on the total permits
allowed in the economy. China has chosen to rely on intensity-based climate goals instead of absolute
value caps of CO2 emissions.
The flexible amount of permits in the Chinese ETS poses two issues. Firstly, it is currently unclear
whether the Chinese ETS will lead to a reduction in total CO2 emissions. In a report published by the
IEA they conclude that the ETS could help China decrease CO2 emissions and achieve its ambitious
climate targets given that the permits allocated are based on emission intensities decreasing over time
(IEA, 2021). However, this has not been confirmed to be implemented in the Chinese ETS.
Furthermore, a report released by the think-tank TransitionZero argues that the current version
of the Chinese ETS will not have any significant impact on emissions. They argue that the lack of a
declining absolute cap and reliance on intensity-based permits are expected to create an oversupply of
permits which leads to inefficiently low prices (Gray, 2021). Too low prices remove the incentive for
firms to reduce their CO2 emissions.
The second issue with the flexible amount of permits is instability in the carbon permit price. As
supply constantly varies under the current iteration of the Chinese ETS, it is more likely that the
price will fluctuate more heavily compared to an absolute cap that ensures a synthetic scarcity of the
permits and thus a more stable price. In the case where permits are too volatile, firms will greatly
suffer as future investment decisions will become drastically more difficult to make. The theoretical
benefit of such a system over carbon taxes is uncertain (Hanley et al., 2019).
5
2.1.3.2 Has ETS Contributed Towards a Reduction In Emissions?
The practical success of ETS has been widely debated. Specifically, commentators have associated the
effectiveness of an ETS with current market prices as a common belief is that high prices of carbon
permits are crucial for reducing emissions. Therefore, the market price of established ETSs is often
thought to be too low as it differs markedly from most estimations of the Social Cost of Carbon (further
discussed in Section 2.1.5).
Perhaps the most widely analysed ETS is the EU ETS, where notable contributions include Laing,
Sato, Grubb, and Comberti (2013), Bayer and Aklin (2020), and recent reports published by the
European Commission (2021). The former provides a comprehensive framework for evaluating the
success of an ETS based on three aspects:
1. Has the implementation of ETS contributed towards a reduction in emissions?
2. Have the ETS induced incentives for investment in low-carbon technology?
3. What has been the impact of the ETS on profits and product prices?
For the purpose of this paper, the analysis proceeds with the literature review by only investigating
point 1 and refer readers interested in the other two to the original paper (Laing et al., 2013). Key
results are presented below in Table 2,
The studies find strong evidence that an implementation of an ETS can successfully reduce emis-
sions by putting an effective price on carbon emissions and thereby make polluting activities more
costly for regulated firms. This is withstanding the low prices commonly observed in both the EU
and Chinese ETS. Specifically for the EU ETS, Bayer and Aklin (2020) argue that low carbon per-
mit prices are compatible with a reduction in carbon emissions as firms interpret the regulation as
a strong and credible signal for future environmental intervention. The signalling has led regulated
firms to invest in green technologies and reduce their carbon intensity above what would be expected
from the current market prices of carbon. While no specific literature for China currently exists, it is
hypothesised that the reduction in emissions observed by Cui et al. (2021) can be partly driven by the
same signalling mechanism illustrated by Bayer and Aklin (2020). However, while both schemes have
seemingly achieved their primary objective of reducing emissions, it is difficult to directly attribute a
reduction to the ETS due to the many sector-specific environmental policies in place in both China
and the EU (IEA, 2020).
As previously mentioned, both the EU and Chinese ETS have received criticism for their low
prices. In the EU ETS case, the underlying cause of the low prices was a result from one or several
6
of the following reasons: 1) low demand for permits due to the economic environment, 2) competing
environmental policies deflating demand for permits, and 3) oversupply of permits (Bayer & Aklin,
2020). In response to this issue, the architects behind the interventions are continuously implementing
measures to increase the flexibility of the systems, such as the Market Stability Reserve implemented
in 2021 (Phase IV) with the purpose of reducing surplus allowances (European Commission, 2021).
Similar improvements are expected to be implemented in the Chinese ETS in the future, however, it
remains uncertain when and how.
Lastly, while the absolute reduction in carbon emissions for the Chinese and the EU ETS are shown
to be on par by Cui et al. (2021), the response has differed markedly in terms of the specific channels
firms have adopted to reduce emissions. Namely, due to China’s heavy reliance on coal for power
generation, regulated firms can switch to natural gas to reduce carbon emissions while firms covered
by the EU ETS have been shown to reduce emissions by curbing consumption of natural gas and
petroleum products altogether (Petrick & Wagner, 2014). This is achieved by low-carbon innovation
which reduces the cost of firms to comply with environmental policies, and studies have shown that
ETS intervention has led to increased production efficiency in regulated European - as well as Chinese
- firms (Calel & Dechezleprêtre, 2016; Cui et al., 2021).
7
Country Start Tax Rate Annual Revenue Distribution
Date Revenue
Government budget; accompanied
Finland 1990 US$30 per US$750 mil- by independent cuts in income
metric tonne lion taxes
of CO2
Reductions in other taxes;
Netherlands 1990 approx. US$4.819
Climate mitigation programs
US$20 per billion
metric ton of
CO2 in 1996
Norway 1991 US$15.93 to $900 million Government budget
US$61.76 per
ton CO2
Initially government
budget; Starting in 2000,
Sweden 1991 Standard US$3.665
revenue used to offset
rate: billion
labor taxes
US$104.83
per metric
ton of C02
Industry rate:
US$23.04 per
metric ton of
CO2
“The social cost of carbon is the present value of estimated environmental damages over
time caused by an additional ton of CO2 emitted today.”
8
Scenario Assumption 2015 2020 2025 2030 2050
Baseline 31.2 37.3 44.0 51.6 102.5
Base parameters
Optimal controls 30.7 36.7 43.5 51.2 103.6
Maximum 184.4 229.1 284.1 351.0 1006.2
2.5 degree maximum
Max for 100 y 106.7 133.1 165.1 203.7 543.3
The stern review discounting Uncalibrated 197.4 266.5 324.6 376.2 629.2
2.5% 128.5 140.0 152.0 164.5 235.7
3% 79.1 87.3 95.9 104.9 156.6
Alternative discount rates
4% 36.3 40.9 45.8 51.1 81.7
5% 19.7 22.6 25.7 29.1 49.2
Table 5: SCC estimates from IWG of EPA, measured in $ t/CO2 (Whitehouse, 2021).
EPA has employed a very sensible approach of combining estimates obtained from all three models,
under different discount rates (Whitehouse, 2021). As such they consider the three models under
five different scenarios, yielding 15 frequency distributions of SCC estimates for each discount rate
considered. Further, they combined the distributions under emission scenarios and selected a set of
values for cost-benefit analysis: an average value resulting from the three models under 2.5%, 3% and
5% discount rates as well as the 95th percentile of the 3% discount rate estimate. The latter value
was included to capture more severe than expected economic damages from climate change. Their
resulting values are shown in Figure 5.
As with all results from IAMs, they serve as a guide in policy decisions, but ultimately the choice
of the actual SCC is political. The values represented in Figure 5 were used by the administration of
US President Joe Biden to set the US SCC value. Within his first weeks in office, the administration
set an interim value of US$51 t/CO2 (Cleetus, 2021). The order was accompanied by the promise
of a thorough review of the SCC through an inter-agency working group that would provide updated
SCC estimates. In the previous administration of President Donald Trump, several actions caused
the dismantlement of the working group tasked with calculating the SCC and the cost was reduced to
US$1-7 t/CO2 (Krane & Finley, 2022). This was a fraction of the value set before. Ultimately, this
move was attributed to the aim of the administration to reduce environmental policies in the energy
and automobile sector.
Concluding, there exists a wide variety of SCC estimates based on theoretical aspects such as
different models and discount rates but also due to political influences. Therefore carbon taxes tend
to vary in their aggressiveness.
9
2.2 Review of Current Models
Given its relevance in academia and popular media, various estimates for calculating the electricity con-
sumption and the carbon emissions of the Bitcoin network have been developed by various researchers.
Generally, they can be broken down into either a top-down or bottom-up approach.
2.2.3 Caveats
It is important to note that most of the studies tend to produce diverging findings and provide a spec-
trum of possible outcomes, reflecting the use of different estimation techniques. Given that there is no
’ground truth’ or record of electricity consumption stored within the Bitcoin blockchain, each approach
will make different assumptions that amount to non-negligible estimation error. It is paramount that
readers are aware of these sources of differences introduced into the estimation, which in most cases
come from:
• Linear interpolation
• Non-linear interpolations
• Simple averaging
• Growth rate assumptions and projections for ‘miner-level’ factors
10
Authors Date of Title Approach
Publication
Stoll, Lena Klaaßen, and June 2019 The Carbon Footprint of Bitcoin Bottom-up
Gallersdörfer
Zade, Myklebost, March 2019 Is Bitcoin the Only Problem? A Bottom-up
Tzscheutschler, and Scenario Model for the Power
Wagner Demand of Blockchains
Krause and Tolaymat November Quantification of energy and car- Bottom-up
2018 bon costs for mining cryptocur-
rencies
Mora et al. October 2018 Bitcoin emissions alone could Top-down
push global warming above 2°C
McCook August 2018 The cost sustainability of Bitcoin Bottom-up
de Vries May 2018 Bitcoin’s Growing Energy Prob- Top-down
lem
Vranken October 2017 Sustainability of Bitcoin and Bottom-up
blockchains
Bevand February 2018 Electricity consumption of Bit- Bottom-up
coin: a market-based and tech-
nical analysis
Hayes March 2015 A Cost Production Model for Bottom-up
Bitcoin
O’Dwyer and Malone September Bitcoin Mining and its Energy Bottom-up
2014 Footprint
These estimations will also be presented in this analysis where they will be stated explicitly at each
step. Regrettably, this will also introduce a non-negligible amount of estimation error.
However, the estimation error does not render such an analysis pointless. While factors influencing
the unobserved true electricity consumption, such as the energy usage and efficiency of cooling solutions
in the mining data centres, which cannot be determined, different estimates are able to capture a similar
change in the magnitude and direction of either electricity or emissions in most circumstances. Readers
should therefore consider these estimates as a rough approximation that captures some of the effects
of electricity consumption and carbon emission of the various cryptocurrency networks. This analysis
will also be closer to a lower-bound estimate on the true emissions from the Bitcoin network given some
of the relatively conservative assumptions, which are explained fully in their respective subsections.
Next, this paper explains the Krause-Tolaymat (2018) model, and extends it to provide us with
forward projections for the network-level energy consumption of Bitcoin, and later Ethereum in Sec-
tion 3.4.
11
2.3.1 Network Power Requirement (P)
Firstly, one needs to derive the power requirement of each (PoW) blockchain. This term will be referred
to as P(MW) (measures in Megawatts) and calculated in the following form:
hashes Joules −10 MWh seconds
P(MW) = HR × PE × 2.78 × 10 × 3, 600 (1)
second Hash Joule hours
where HR is the hashrate and PE is the power efficiency of mining rigs (the computers used for
writing blocks onto the blockchain). Both factors are determined by the hardware used to mine the
coins. Hashrate has a proportional relationship with time as semiconductors become more effective at
computations, while power efficiency has an inverse relationship with time, given that the advances in
semiconductor technology imply that mining rigs are more power efficient per calculation.
which basically translates into the assumption that says: If a miner type i (either China or Row) has
made a profit over the past six months, they will be willing to upgrade or increase their mining rigs in
the hopes of making more profits further. Conversely, if a miner type is unprofitable over six months,
it is assumed that they will turn off a certain percentage of their equipment (most often the oldest
and least power-efficient) such that they can focus on reducing their excessive expenditures. This
assumption is likely realistic as miners ultimately still have to convert their cryptocurrency holdings
into local currency periodically to pay for utility bills. Miner’s profits will be subsequently explained
in Section 2.3.8.
Given that the Bitcoin network has been dominated by ASIC miners, and that estimates for the
upgrade cycle of mining rigs are 1.29 years (de Vries & Stoll, 2021), most researchers use ASIC
miner statistics for the estimation of power efficiency ratings. Historical data can be obtained from
https://www.asicminervalue.com/. In this analysis, the power efficiency of all mining equipment is
aggregated by year of release, and forecasted ahead by extrapolating with a polynomial best-fit line3 .
Since miners might not have the same upgrade cycles as the product update cycle of ASIC miners
released onto the market, these estimates would likely overestimate the power efficiency of mining
equipment, and likely be closer to the lower-bound of network power requirement estimates. These
estimates can be found in Table 7.
3 The polynomial best-fit line has the equation HR= 0.7967 × t−1.439 and R2 = 0.997.
12
Year Average of Efficiency (j/Gh)
2014 0.7555
2015 0.2730
2016 0.1780
2017 0.1150
2018 0.0993
2019 0.0542
2020 0.0412
2021 0.0554
2022 0.0250
2023 0.0290
2024 0.0253
2025 0.0223
2026 0.0199
2027 0.0179
2028 0.0162
2029 0.0147
2030 0.0135
Table 7: Power Efficiency Estimates of ASIC Mining Equipment. Forward forecast numbers are
coloured in blue.
US$ coin rewarded US$ minutes minutes
v =R × EX ÷ tB × 60 (3)
h block coin block created hours
The reward per block is clearly defined in the Bitcoin protocol, where coins are routinely issued
at a decreasing rate (on a per block basis) such that there can only ever be 21 million Bitcoins in
circulation. On average this happens every four years. Starting from 25 Bitcoins per block initially,
the first ‘halving’ happened in November 2012, the second happened in July 2016, and the most recent
in May 2020. The next two halving events are estimated to be in June 2024 and June 2028, where the
reward per block to decrease to 3.125 and 1.5625 respectively.
Later, it is shown that such halving events will lead to an adjustment period which will bring down
miner profitability, hashrate and electricity consumption in Section 3.
The BTC/USD spot exchange rate can be observed historically and will be used to inform miner profits
subsequently. It is impossible to come up with forward estimates of BTC/USD and this report does
not attempt to try and be a magical Bitcoin oracle. However, it has been noted in some papers that
the ‘fundamental price’ of Bitcoin (Jiang et al., 2021) tends to have an inverse relationship with the
halving events. That is, price of Bitcoin tends to double at every halving event (which occurs every
four years). This is just made as a working assumption for us to understand the dynamics of this
model, and very conservatively assume that Bitcoin price increases by 10% annually.
13
2.3.2.3 Block Time (tB )
Block time is the average amount of time (in minutes) it takes for a new block to be written on the
Bitcoin blockchain. This has historically hovered around the 10 minute mark and use this as a forward
estimate. Given that this is roughly the limit of the throughput for the Bitcoin blockchain, this is
likely an accurate estimate.
CO2 emitted (kg)
Ti,C = Yi × NC × % hashrate contributioni
kW h
where Yi reflects the CO2 emission from the country reflecting the usage of renewable and non-
renewable sources in each country and each miner type’s being considered through the % hashrate
contribution.
Historical estimates for the carbon emitted per unit of energy were obtained from Our World in Data4 .
Forward projections were calculated very simply for china and the US through applying the long-run
linear time trend (going back to 1965) onto the last observation (2019). The long-run time trend
for the China is −0.000975 per year and RoW is −0.000418 per year. One has to note that with
China’s nuclear energy ambitions, the estimates for China could be much lower towards the end of the
estimation period.
The estimates can be found in Table 8.
-carbon-does-it-emit-per-unit-of-energy
14
Year China USA
1965 0.3265 0.2334
··· ··· ···
2019 0.2665 0.1999
2020 0.265525 0.199482
2021 0.26455 0.199064
2022 0.263575 0.198646
2023 0.2626 0.198228
2024 0.261625 0.19781
2025 0.26065 0.197392
2026 0.259675 0.196974
2027 0.2587 0.196556
2028 0.257725 0.196138
2029 0.25675 0.19572
2030 0.255775 0.195302
BT C
Ci,C = Ti,C × rC
15
When it comes to Chinese electricity prices, some discretion was applied in finding a representative
price. Given that miners tend to migrate to where electricity is cheaper, one finds that Guangzhou
tends to have cheaper prices for industrial usage and thereby applied this number as an estimate.
When it comes to the forward projections, a linear interpolation was applied between the last observed
price and 0.075 US$/kWh, as this price reflects the long-term benefits China would benefit from when
it fully realises its nuclear energy goals. This is a discretionary choice given comparisons to other
countries which have a higher nuclear mix, and does not diverge too far from China’s long-term price
trend.
Year (CN) Price Exchange (CN) Price US$/kWh (US) Price US$/kWh
RMB/kWh Rate
2014 0.577 6.160 0.094 0.137
2015 0.870 6.280 0.139 0.138
2016 0.647 6.650 0.097 0.135
2017 0.640 6.760 0.095 0.138
2018 0.800 6.630 0.121 0.136
2019 0.588 6.910 0.085 0.136
2020 0.620 6.900 0.090 0.135
2021 0.620 6.450 0.096 0.141
2022 0.620 6.350 0.098 0.147
2023 0.095 0.137
2024 0.092 0.137
2025 0.089 0.137
2026 0.086 0.137
2027 0.083 0.137
2028 0.081 0.137
2029 0.078 0.137
2030 0.075 0.137
3 Models
Through the equations seen earlier, one can model out various dynamics between the change in elec-
tricity consumption and carbon emission of the Bitcoin network. The next part looks at various cases
of policies and interventions to quantitatively evaluate the impacts of each.
16
previously attributed to China (de Best, 2022), this means that a very immediate drop in both the
hashrate and electricity usage was observed in the later half of 2021. This also leads to the case with
the lowest projected annual and total emission from the Bitcoin network, as polluting Chinese miners
that have access to cheap electricity are removed from the network.
This leads to the following dynamic seen in Figure 2. In this case, one sees that the first peak
happens in 2022-2023. This occurs largely due to the slack provided by the departure of Chinese
miners, as RoW miners pick up mining and experience a period of high profitability. However, there
is also a sharp drop off in 2024, given the halving event in that year (explained in Section 2.3.2.1).
The model accounts for this in a very naive way, with actual transition likely being much smoother
than indicated by the model, given that such events are known. A similar dynamic is observed in 2027
and 2028, where electricity consumption and CO2 usage peak again after the drop off in hashrate from
the 2024 halving.
The model also suggests that post 2028, both electricity usage and mining should begin falling off, in
no small part due to the decline in reward of the Bitcoin network and the general increase in hashrate.
Given that the network will decreasingly contribute to global electricity consumption and emissions,
this is likely a representative base case to compare against. The total electricity consumption and the
annual CO2 emissions for the period 2014-2030 can be found in Table 10, and the estimate is 540 TWh
and 108 Mt respectively. The model estimates tend to be smaller than estimates from other scholars,
in no small part due to the conservative PE assumptions (see Section 2.3.1.2).
17
Year Global An- Global Annual Chinese Miner RoW Miner
nual Electric- CO2 Emission Profit (US$) Profit (US$)
ity Consump- (Mt)
tion (TWh)
2014 0.91 0.22 141841265 404919748
2015 0.96 0.24 130407693 101268722
2016 2.35 0.60 246052181 76491375
2017 6.23 1.58 1509792032 492267467
2018 31.42 7.99 805449265 172312191
2019 31.25 7.80 1631014292 134363295
2020 43.01 10.42 816701017 -169539279
2021 70.32 15.12 1619622014 4458026292
2022 47.57 9.45 0 3078807966
2023 70.23 13.92 0 1227907192
2024 71.05 14.05 0 -1774515150
2025 48.33 9.54 0 -56533711
2026 48.60 9.57 0 563396050
2027 55.40 10.89 0 353986311
2028 56.74 11.13 0 -1581833907
2029 39.35 7.70 0 -584700869
2030 32.89 6.42 0 780354757
Global 540.48 107.80 1619622014 6464894931
Total
(2021-
2030)
Table 10: Ban Case - China Bans Cryptocurrency Mining. Global annual estimates are for the whole
Bitcoin network.
18
Figure 3: No Base Case - China Does Not Ban Cryptocurrency Mining.
Table 11: No Ban Case - China Reverses Ban in June 2021. Global annual estimates are for the
whole Bitcoin network.
19
3.2 Implementation of Emissions Trading System
China formally introduced an emissions trading system (ETS) on the 16th of July 2021, which instantly
became the world’s biggest of its kind by effectively covering 12% of global CO2 emissions. While
currently covering 40% of China’s total CO2 emissions, President Xi has ambitiously vowed to rapidly
expand the market to 80% by 2025 in order to curtail polluting industries (Refinitiv, 2021).
The introduction of the ETS adds an additional tool in the wide array of policies that are being
implemented in China in order to achieve its dual carbon climate goal. As such, this section investigates
its potential in mitigating the environmental consequences caused by the Bitcoin mining industry.
Rest
Bitcoin
of Permit Market
Industry
Economy
3. RoE is assumed to be in constant equilibrium and can conduct its operations at the current
market price of carbon permits. The RoE will interact with the Bitcoin industry by supplying
and buying carbon permits for any excess demand or supply at the current market price.
20
3.2.2.1 Government Agent
The government’s objective is to curtail the CO2 emissions of the economy by decreasing the total
allowable permits. The dynamic modelling assumes the permit market is effectively covering 40% of
the total CO2 emissions in China, where the Bitcoin industry is fully covered by the scheme. However,
as time passes it is assumed that the ETS is linearly expanding to ultimately cover 80% of total Chinese
CO2 emissions by 2025.
Furthermore, a grandfather rule is applied for the allocation of permits based on historical carbon
emissions of the Bitcoin industry (Knight, 2013). For the purpose of this model, it is assumed that the
government has perfect insight into the exact CO2 emissions attributed to the Bitcoin industry. The
initial amount of permits allocated will be:
t−1
1 X BT C
CP ermitsBT C,t=0 = C (10)
6 i=t−6 China,i
After the initial allocation, the government decides on an emissions reduction factor σT 5 which
corresponds to the decrease in permits allocated to the Bitcoin industry at the start of every year. As
such, at month t the Bitcoin industry is endowed with the following amount of permits:
The general agent will behave similarly to the benchmark case. However, at the end of the period
the Bitcoin industry has to submit an equal amount of permits as the number of tonnes of CO2 it has
emitted. This means that any CO2 emission exceeding the CP ermitst needs to be purchased from
the market. In such a case, an additional emissions cost will be incurred:
BT C
ECosti,t = µt × (CChina,t − CP ermitsBT C,t ) (12)
where µt is the current market price of one unit CP ermit. The miner’s new profit function becomes:
US$ US$
miner profiti,t = EX × rC × % hashrate contributioni − pi,t × Ei,C − ECosti,t (13)
coin kWh
21
is a result of the continued expansion of the ETS market, as well as the continued growth of China’s
total CO2 emissions.7
Table 12: The three ETS cases and the associated yearly reduction in allocated carbon permits.
7 The forward projection for China’s total CO emissions is calculated simply by a linear regression on historical
2
log-values.
8 See Trading Economics for EU ETS Carbon trading price.
9 An integrated scenario specifying a pathway aiming at: ensuring universal access to affordable, reliable, sustainable
and modern energy services by 2030; substantially reducing air pollution; and taking effective action to combat climate
change.
22
3.2.5 Results of ETS
The result of the implementation of the ETS and subsequent effect on the global Bitcoin network’s elec-
tricity consumption and CO2 emissions can be shown for the three cases A-C in Figure 5. Furthermore,
the carbon permit price development is shown in Figure 6.
Figure 5: Electricity consumption and CO2 emissions forecasts for the global Bitcoin network for
cases A-C.
3.2.6 Analysis
Figures 5 and 6 illustrate the result of the implementation of the ETS on the global Bitcoin network’s
electricity consumption, annual CO2 emission, and market price for carbon permits. It is observed that
given a 5% yearly reduction (Case A) in endowed carbon permits to the Bitcoin industry, the global
Bitcoin CO2 emission is expected to decrease relative to the China No Ban Case with a forecasted
CO2 emission of 175 Mt between 2014-2030 vs. 177 Mt. This, rather small effect, can be ascribed to
mainly two calibrations of the model, namely 1) the initial starting price of a carbon permit being set
at US$50 and 2) the allocation rule’s initial allocation and decrease in permits year over year. While
an initial carbon permit price of US$50 is well within the observed range of actual trading schemes
it markedly differs from a firm’s average cost of carbon as the permits are allocated for free. This,
23
together with the allocation rule, will therefore ultimately determine the average cost of carbon for
the Bitcoin industry and any subsequent investment decisions.
Thus, it is not surprising to observe from Figure 5 that as the government decreases the yearly
allocated permits, so do the total CO2 emissions. However, a maximum reduction of 93% carbon
permits endowed to the Bitcoin industry (Case C) only results in a 2.89% reduction in global CO2
emissions from the Bitcoin Network compared to the No Ban Case between mid-2021 to December 2030.
This result is mainly due to the ability of Chinese Bitcoin miners to extract significant and sustainable
economic rents in current market conditions. The miners can therefore continue their business while
purchasing the required amount of carbon permits without suffering from any significant losses that
would impact their future investment decisions. Secondly, the increased demand arising from the
Bitcoin industry is relatively small compared to the entire ETS market, and as such, an increase in
demand from Bitcoin miners will only affect the market price in relation to its size. This leads to a
sluggish price that is not as responsive to changes in demand from the Bitcoin industry as perhaps
would be socially optimal, and the dynamic will aid the industry to maintain its operations even
while incurring additional costs and the endowed permits are significantly reduced year over year. For
example, a 30% yearly reduction (Case C) in allocated carbon permits results in a modest increase
in carbon permit price, reaching US$58.73 (+17.46%) in 2030. Meanwhile, the amount of permits
purchased per month by the Bitcoin industry rise from 279,255 in 2023 to 749,230 (+168.30%) in 2030
in Case C.10 .
Further, Case A results in a prolonged period where the carbon permit price µt decreases below
the initial launching price of US$50 as seen from Figure 6. This can be explained by the specified
allocation rule endowing the Bitcoin industry with an excess amount of permits which can later be
sold for additional profit to the RoE. The additional number of carbon permits being supplied to
the market decreases the market price as determined by equation (16), aptly illustrating the issue of
over-allocation mentioned in 2.1.3.2 and confirming the importance of efficient allocation and artificial
scarcity of the number of allocated permits, as highlighted by Gray (2021). Lastly, in all three scenarios
the intervention result in noticeable effects on electricity consumption and emissions starting in 2024.
This result can be ascribed to the Halving Mechanism, which will be further discussed in Section 4.1.
This additional cost is then included in the miner’s profit function as follows:
US$ US$
miner profitChina,t = EX × rC × % hashrate contributioni − pChina,t × Ei,C − τChina,t
coin kWh
(18)
10 The time period is adjusted in order to avoid including 2021-2022 which includes significant selling of carbon
permits by the Bitcoin industry. The comparison is therefore not directly applicable but should provide the reader with
an indication of the discrepancy between the increase in demand and increase in price.
24
Given this adjusted miner profit equation, one can analyze the effect of carbon taxes as an emission
reduction policy intervention. The differences in profit of Chinese Miners will have an effect on the
electricity consumption and emissions of the global Bitcoin network.
• Scenario 1 (50%): The first scenario will be referred to as the 50% case. In this case, China will
set it’s carbon prices at precisely half the price of the upper price targets required to achieve
the temperature pathway set by the Paris Agreement, thus lying at the lower bound. As one
will see in scenario 2, this price also corresponds to half the price set by the US. Given the low
price setting tendency of the 2010 carbon tax proposal described in Section 3.3, this tendency
is extended to the 50% scenario. Additionally, China will aim to set as low as possible carbon
tax prices in order not to set a precedent of high carbon taxes that could further be applicable
to other industries of higher importance to their domestic economy. Thus in this scenario, in
June 2021 the initial price will be US$40, increasing to US$50 by 2030.
• Scenario 2 (Paris Agreement): The second scenario will be referred to as the ”Paris Agreement”
case. The report of the World’s Bank High Level Commission in 2017 on carbon prices establishes
that in order to achieve the 2 degrees Celsius temperature goal of the Paris Agreement, global
carbon prices should reach between US$40-80 t/CO2 by 2020, and then increase to between
US$50-100 t/CO2 by 2030 (World Bank, 2021b). This price evolution is similar to the prices set
in the US by the Biden administration. Recall from Section 2.1.5, that studies considered a 3%
discount rate to high for the SCC. Looking at the US technical guidance document (Whitehouse,
2021) for the calculation of the SCC, at a 2.5% average discount rate, the price of the SCC
increases from US$76 t/CO2 in 2020 to US$89 t/CO2 in 2030. Thus the SCC estimated by the
Biden administration seems in line with the Paris Agreement. Hence, this scenario considers the
hypothetical Chinese implementation of a carbon tax at the upper price recommendations of the
World Bank and thus in line with the Paris Agreement and the US. In June 2021, the initial
price is set at US$80, increasing to US$100 by 2030.
• Scenario 3 (High): The last scenario will be referred to as the ”High” case. Multiple studies
suggest that the carbon prices should be set at well above US$100 t/CO2 (Carleton & Greenstone,
2021) as soon as possible, in order to truly achieve the emission reduction and temperature targets
set by the Paris Agreement. The World Bank itself mentions this fact in their 2021 report:
”State and trends in carbon pricing”, by referencing a study by Woodmac, an energy research
and consultancy founded in the UK. This study suggests that global carbon prices should reach
US$160 t/CO2 to successfully achieve the Paris Agreement pathways (Mackenzie, 2021). Since
China is one of the largest emitters of CO2 , who’s SCC should naturally be higher, this scenario
considers a price increase all the way up to US$160 t/CO2 . Thus, the initial June 2021 price is
set at US$100, increasing to US$160 by 2030.
25
Figure 7: 3 scenario carbon price evolution.
26
Figure 10: Carbon Tax High.
Figures 8 to 10 illustrate the development of annual electricity consumption and CO2 emissions of
the global Bitcoin mining network under each carbon tax scenario. The figures contrast the results
of the different scenarios to the ”No Ban” and ”Ban” cases in China previously discussed. As the
carbon prices increase towards US$160 t/CO2 , the line’s colours become progressively more red, given
starting points of US$0 t/CO2 coloured in green.
As indicated by the figures, the higher the carbon tax, the lower the CO2 emissions become. As such,
the “High” scenario carbon tax provides the greatest reduction in emissions followed by the “Paris” and
“50 %” case. As the price evolution is also greatest in the “High” scenario, more significant emission
reductions become apparent at 2025 and 2026 compared to the other two scenarios. The different
price evolutions also become apparent in the tail end of the prediction interval. In the years 2029 and
2030, for the “50%” case the carbon emission line flattens out, whilst in the other two cases the line is
downward sloping. This is because in the “50%” case, over the prediction interval price increases by
US$10 t/CO2 , compared to the US$20 t/CO2 and US$60 t/CO2 increases in the other two scenarios.
Thus the step-wise monthly increases become greater in the higher-priced carbon tax scenarios, which
leads to the aforementioned higher emission reductions at the tail end of the prediction interval.
A further notable finding presents itself in the annual electricity consumption in Figure 10. In 2026,
under the ”High” scenario, electricity momentarily falls beneath the ”China Ban” case, indicating high
effectiveness of aggressive carbon taxes in reducing electricity consumption. Also, under the other
scenarios electricity consumption is effectively reduced, especially in the described year range, further
highlighting the efficacy of carbon taxes in electricity consumption reduction.
Nevertheless, in all three scenarios, the carbon taxes only become truly effective after 2024. Up
to that year, the carbon emissions produced by Chinese miners are little to no difference between the
scenarios and the “No ban” case in which China takes no action against Bitcoin mining. After 2024,
the taxes become effective and reduces annual CO2 emissions. The reason for the occurrence of this
phenomenon is the planned Bitcoin “halving” in March in 2024, where the reward is reduced to 3.125
of new Bitcoins per block. Halvings are significant, because they decrease the supply of Bitcoins. For
miners this means that less reward is available for the same amount of costs. Therefore, the carbon
tax by further increasing costs, decreases the miner’s profitability even more which in turn leads to
less mining and therefore less CO2 emissions.
27
Scenario Chinese Annualized Annualized Annualized Annualized Annualized
Carbon Global Global Chinese Tax Rev- Tax Rev-
Price Electrcity Carbon Tax Rev- enue/Total enue/Total
Evolu- (TWh) Emission enue (M Chinese Chinese
tion (Mt/CO2 ) US$) Miner Miner
Revenue Earnings
before
Tax
50 Per- 40 to 50 61.52 14.12 371.17 9.4% 30.1%
cent
Paris 80 to 100 60.38 13.74 678.64 18.2% 55.6%
High 100 to 59.22 13.35 875.21 25.1% 74.1%
160
As apparent from the table, the larger the carbon tax, the greater the revenue generated by the
tax. As such, the revenue generated in by the “High” carbon tax is $200 trillion more than the revenue
generated by the “Paris” case for China.
Another interesting point comes when looking at the percentage that the carbon tax revenue makes
up of the Chinese miner profit. By considering the earnings before tax of the Chinese mining network
compared to the carbon tax revenue generated, it can be illustrated how penalizing different carbon
taxes are. The increase in percentages from 26.9% in the 50 % case all the way up to 65.1% nicely
illustrates how carbon taxes also manage to reduce the Chinese miner’s overall revenue. As such in
the “High” case, the high carbon price and the reduction of overall profit for miners work in tandem.
Therefore, this analysis concludes that in all three cases the government manages to recoup a significant
amount of Chinese miner’s profits.
Nevertheless, under the assumptions made and even with aggressive carbon pricing as shown by the
analysis and the revenue consideration, Chinese miners are still likely to dominate Bitcoin mining. In
all three cases, significant profits will still be available by 2030. With further price increases specifically
for coal-based energy, which is very popular in China as well as stricter international policies, in the long
run the pollution of the Chinese Bitcoin mining network could further be reduced. Simultaneously, it
can be expected the Chinese government will use the revenue generated to transition industries reliant
on high carbon fuels such as coal and oil, to cleaner energy sources such as liquefied natural gas first
and then eventually to renewable energy. In the future, it can also be foreseen that carbon-capture
will become of heightened importance. Revenue from carbon taxes could also be used to develop this
technology for application in areas with high emissions. As most policies will reduce profits for miners,
they are likely to figure out how to mine in an environmentally favourable fashion, or mine in times
where electricity costs for example are lower.
As such, there already exist select approaches to cleaner mining (Singh, 2021). Mining operations
that align with sustainability goals currently provide a great opportunity for miners globally. As such,
miners may also explore partnering with local energy companies and start-ups that provide affordable
access to renewable energy. This will allow them to avoid carbon taxed energy sources.
28
3.4 Inevitability of Proof-of-Stake (PoS)
The energy consumption of PoS blockchains should also be considered by regulators. This could be
seen in the example of Ethereum, arguably the second most notable blockchain, which is making a
transition to PoS approximately in Q3 2022. Given the difference in its security protocol, the protocol
might affect electricity consumption over a forecasted period and thus require a different modelling
approach.
Energy Per Server × Number of Servers × 24(hours per day) × 365 days (Annualization) (19)
The energy per server is simply estimated from the Thermal Design Power (TDP) of designated servers
which run as a validator for the network. TDP stands for Thermal Design Power, in watts, and refers
to the power consumption under the maximum theoretical load. This will provide one with the upper
bound for the energy use per validator. A high energy usage per server approximation is used, following
the convention from Platt et al. (2021) and Powell et al. (2021), by utilizing the TDP of representative
enterprise rack servers (see Table 14).
Table 14: Dell Server Power Rating (Proxy For All Server Used For Mining).
For the forward forecasts, the model assumes that the equipment will not be upgraded past 2022.
This is because there is no more requirement for these equipment to be on the cutting edge of com-
putational ability after the Ethereum 2.0 merge. Practically, there is no need to make an assumptions
around what the TDP of future equipment will be.
29
The next input is the number of servers. The model diverges from the Powell et al. model, where
they use actual network statistics. To make this calculation an actual upper bound, one observe the
historical number of Ethereum addresses with ≥ 32 ETH11 , which is the stake required to become a
validator on the Ethereum network.
With this, the estimates from other researchers are plotted and PoS electricity consumption statis-
tics are applied retrospectively to understand what the electricity consumption of Ethereum 2.0 would
have looked like if it were implemented at its genesis. In the plots, one see that on average, Ethereum
2.0 would have used approximate 97% less electricity compared to Ethereum 1.0 (From January 2020
to March 2022), on average, since inception. The most important thing to note here is that unlike the
previous Krause-Tolaymat model, the model calculates electricity consumption on a daily annualized
measure to make it easily comparable against all the other estimates, as done in McDonald, (2018).
30
3.4.4 Potential On-Chain Intervention
One intervention method that was not considered before was the ability to perform on-chain inter-
ventions. This report defines on-chain intervention as the application of policies by the network to
influence the electricity consumption and carbon output of the network.
This is likely the most direct and impactful method that could be implemented would be a hardware
power efficiency requirement. Through equation (19) of the Powell et al. model, it will directly reduce
the electricity consumption of the network while being fundamentally unchanged as a network. This
does not just have to target enterprise-level servers, but could also be required of consumer-grade
hardware, which is consistent with what the Ethereum 2.0 merge will allow for. This model omits
the calculation of any period, as this will simply be a linear scaling of the results seen in Figure 11.
However, this should not undermine the effectiveness of such an approach, and could potentially be
considered as one of the many methods that could bring emissions further in line with other green
agendas.
31
Figure 12: Bitcoin and World (2019) Electricity Consumption.
compared to the no ban case. But the implementation of carbon prices at the height of the carbon
tax ”high” scenario in China is ambitious, as only Lichtenstein, Switzerland, and Sweden had carbon
taxes above $100 t/CO2 in 2021 (World Bank, 2021b). For both the ETS and carbon taxes, however,
emission and electricity reductions become more significant post the 2024 Bitcoin halving, momentarily
even providing an even lower electricity consumption reduction than the ”Ban” case. The reason, as
explained in the end of Section 3.3.3, is due to halving reducing the supply of Bitcoins, thereby decreas-
ing the reward available for miners given the same amount of costs. Therefore the efficiency of both
interventions shows dependency on the state of the global Bitcoin network. Yet, it is important that
emission reductions occur sooner than later (Luz, 2022), in order to avoid compounding environmental
damages over time and the surpassing of irreversible global climate states.
Figure 13: Electricity consumption and CO2 emission forecasts for the global Bitcoin network.
The effect of the Carbon Tax intervention and the ETS on Chinese CO2 emissions from Bitcoin
mining can be seen in Table 15. Evidently, the two schemes differ markedly in the actual price that
Bitcoin mining firms are required to pay for every tonne of CO2 emitted. In the most aggressive
case, the Bitcoin mining industry is being incurred a cost of US$130.0 and US$34.2 per tonne carbon
32
dioxide emitted for the Carbon Tax and ETS respectively. This illustrates a potential benefit of
the Carbon Tax intervention as policymakers can decide and implement the exact average price of
emissions. However, this also presumes that policymakers have an adequate ability of determining the
optimal carbon price (SCC) which is a notoriously difficult task due to both theoretical and political
circumstances as discussed in Section 2.1.5.
It is worth noting the Absolute Reduction in Chinese BTC Emissions vs. No Ban for scenario CT
50 Percent and ETS Case A. While the reduction is essentially equal (-8.4% vs. -8.5% respectively), the
two cases differ markedly in the magnitude of the reduction in profit (-27.6% vs. -21.4% respectively).
This is the result of a combination of factors, such as the balancing act of production and an increasing
price of carbon emissions. For example, the exact timing of when the carbon tax increases can have
a varying effect on Bitcoin mining operations depending on the current market price of Bitcoin, hash
rate contributions, and previous investment decisions by firms. While this result is not conclusive on
which intervention can weigh those considerations most effectively, it illustrates that under current
assumptions an ETS would be able to reduce emissions with less associated economic costs.
In summary, the analysis of the three policy interventions has illustrated an important point.
While the theoretical implementation of an ETS or a carbon tax can provide significant benefits
over an outright ban, the result of a practical implementation can differ markedly due to a number
of factors. Specifically, for the ETS the relatively small share of the Bitcoin industry of the ETS
and the industry’s ability to generate large profits limit the ETS’s effectiveness in delivering a targeted
intervention and subsequent reduction in CO2 emissions. Similarly, aggressive carbon prices are needed
to counteract this profit-generating ability. As carbon taxes are based on the SCC which is calculated
using Integrated Assessment Models that capture global climate change effects, some might argue that
modelling adjustments are needed to provide specific SCC estimates in relation to Bitcoin mining.
Otherwise, carbon taxes will continue to be set according to political agendas. As agendas that
actively promote emission reductions are arguably rarer, this will likely result in low carbon taxes
that keep industrial stakeholders happy (Dyarto & Setyawan, 2020). The significant revenue carbon
taxes generate, which mustn’t be necessarily used for further climate change mitigation efforts, may
nevertheless incentive governments to set higher carbon taxes. Given the ban, China is willing to turn
its back on the Chinese Bitcoin Mining industry but will avoid setting a high carbon tax specific to
the industry in order not to set precedent for other industries in the domestic economy.
These considerations are crucial for policymakers when deciding on an adequate policy. If, as
assumed, the main objective was to reduce the negative environmental impact associated with Bitcoin
mining, then an outright ban is shown to provide the most benefit. Both the ETS and Carbon Tax
intervention under their current specifications suffers from their own shortcomings in their absolute
ability to reduce CO2 emissions, which would warrant the need for a more drastic policy solution.
Table 15: Comparative statistics for carbon tax, ETS, and ban cases for the period June 2021 to
December 2030
33
4.2 Conclusion
4.2.1 Summary
This paper investigated the environmental effects of China’s recent regulatory steps against cryptocur-
rencies and attempts to bridge a gap in today’s academic literature by offering an insight into the
varying environmental consequences of a set of hypothetical country specific regulations on the global
cryptocurrency ecosystem. The paper uses two baseline scenarios; one considered the ban scenario and
one a world without the ban taking place. They were then evaluated against two alternative policies,
an emission trading system and a carbon tax.
It is found that under China’s policy of banning cryptocurrencies, the total emissions from the
global Bitcoin network between June 2021 to December 2030 will be 25.7% lower than under the
no-ban scenario. In comparison, if the most stringent ETS case (Case C) is considered, an ETS
implementation would achieve a total reduction of 2.9% in global CO2 emissions over the same period.
The relatively low reduction in emissions stems from the inherent problem that cryptocurrency mining
will remain a small player in the permit market and given its profits will be able to keep buying permits.
Meanwhile, under the Paris Agreement carbon tax case the global Bitcoin network’s CO2 emissions
would decline by 5.9% relative to the no-ban scenario. Nevertheless, for more significant emission
reductions even higher and thus more aggressive carbon prices are needed to limit the excessive profit
generating ability of the Chinese Bitcoin network. Further if the Chinese Bitcoin network was subjected
to some of the highest carbon taxes observed globally, as seen in the carbon tax ”High” scenario, this
would only lead to a 8.5% reduction in the global Bitcoin network’s CO2 emissions.
Overall, this paper suggests that when the ban scenario is evaluated against alternative policies,
and the primary focus lies on environmental objectives, a cryptocurrency ban is the most efficient and
fastest policy option. Between June 2021 and December 2030 the total reduction in CO2 emissions is
forecasted to be 22.8% higher than under the most stringent ETS case and 19.8% higher than under
a carbon tax consistent with the Paris Agreement.
As a result, China’s cryptocurrency ban appears sensible from a solely environmental perspective
and the current state of the cryptocurrency environment. However, a ban comes at a significant
economic cost that may no longer be necessary under energy efficient protocols. Going forward the
transition towards less energy intensive protocols such as PoS will play a vital role in the decision
making process of governments. Although the proposal was rejected, the EU already signalled a
more positive stance towards more environmentally friendly protocols with its proposal to limit the
use of PoW protocols (CoinDesk, 2022). These findings could subsequently be used to investigate
the economic opportunity cost of a cryptocurrency ban to present a policy case that extends beyond
factors other than the environment.
34
economic agent commonly observed in established IAMs. Specifically, Chinese Bitcoin miners only
consider their investment decision in future production of Bitcoin and disregards considerations such
as switching to low-carbon fuels or investment in emission abating technologies. The model ultimately
tries to understand the aggregate result of these dynamics through the sensitisation of hyperparame-
ters, but acknowledges there still exist difficulty in not only fine tuning the model, but representing a
complicated process with a simple and limited set of mathematical equations.
35
References
Bayer, P., & Aklin, M. (2020). The european union emissions trading system reduced co¡sub¿2¡/sub¿
emissions despite low prices. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 117 (16), 8804-
8812. Retrieved from https://www.pnas.org/doi/abs/10.1073/pnas.1918128117 doi: 10
.1073/pnas.1918128117
BBC. (2019). Bitcoin mining ban considered by china’s economic planner. Retrieved from https://
www.bbc.co.uk/news/technology-47867031
BBC. (2021a). China declares all crypto-currency transactions illegal. Retrieved from https://
www.bbc.co.uk/news/technology-58678907
BBC. (2021b). China power cuts: Coal miners ordered to boost output, say reports. Retrieved from
https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-58839894
Beekhuizen, C. (2021). Ethereum’s energy usage will soon decrease by 99.95/. Retrieved from
https://blog.ethereum.org/2021/05/18/country-power-no-more/
Bevand, M. (2017). Electricity consumption of bitcoin: A market-based and technical analysis. Re-
trieved from http://blog.zorinaq.com/bitcoin-electricity-consumption/#fnref:refD:
1
Calel, R., & Dechezleprêtre, A. (2016). Environmental policy and directed technological change:
evidence from the european carbon market. Review of economics and statistics, 98 (1), 173–191.
Cambridge, U. (2022). Cambridge bitcoin electricity consumption index. Retrieved from https://
ccaf.io/cbeci/index/ (Accessed: 2022-02-27)
Carleton, T., & Greenstone, M. (2021, Nov). Working paper updating the united states government’s
social cost of carbon. Retrieved from https://bfi.uchicago.edu/wp-content/uploads/2021/
01/BFI WP 202104.pdf
Cheng, E. (2021). Secretive chinese bitcoin mining company may have made as much money as nvidia
last year. Retrieved from https://www.cnbc.com/2018/02/23/secretive-chinese-bitcoin
-mining-company-may-have-made-as-much-money-as-nvidia-last-year.html
ChinaPower. (2022). How is china’s energy footprint changing? Retrieved from https://chinapower
.csis.org/energy-footprint/
Cleetus, R. (2021, Jun). The social cost of carbon gets an interim update from the biden admin-
istration. Retrieved from https://blog.ucsusa.org/rachel-cleetus/the-social-cost-of
-carbon-gets-an-interim-update-from-the-biden-administration/
CoinDesk. (2022). Proposal limiting proof-of-work is rejected in eu parliament committee vote. Re-
trieved from https://www.coindesk.com/policy/2022/03/14/proposal-limiting-proof-of
-work-is-rejected-in-eu-parliament-committee-vote-sources/
Cui, J., Wang, C., Zhang, J., & Zheng, Y. (2021). The effectiveness of china’s regional
carbon market pilots in reducing firm emissions. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, 118 (52), e2109912118. Retrieved from https://www.pnas.org/doi/abs/10.1073/
pnas.2109912118 doi: 10.1073/pnas.2109912118
de Vries, A. (2020). Bitcoin’s energy consumption is underestimated: A market dynamics approach.
Energy Research Social Science, 70 , 101721. Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/
science/article/pii/S2214629620302966 doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2020.101721
de Vries, A., & Stoll, C. (2021). Bitcoin’s growing e-waste problem. Resources, Conservation and
Recycling, 175 , 105901. Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/
pii/S0921344921005103 doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2021.105901
de Best, R. (2022). Bitcoin mining by country 2021.
Dyarto, R., & Setyawan, D. (2020, Sep). Understanding the political challenges of introducing
a carbon tax in indonesia - international journal of environmental science and technology.
Springer Berlin Heidelberg. Retrieved from https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/
s13762-020-02925-4
Ethereum. (2022). Proof-of-stake (pos). Retrieved from https://ethereum.org/en/developers/
docs/consensus-mechanisms/pos/
Ethereum Foundation. (2022, Mar). Ethereum energy consumption. Author. Retrieved from https://
ethereum.org/en/energy-consumption/
European Commission. (2021). Emissions cap and allowances. https://ec.europa.eu/clima/eu
-action/eu-emissions-trading-system-eu-ets/emissions-cap-and-allowances en. (Ac-
cessed: 2022-03-10)
36
European Commission. (2021). Report from the commission to the european parliament and the
council. (962 final). Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/clima/system/files/2021-10/
com 2021 962 en.pdf
Fortune. (2021). Bitcoin mining is suddenly one of the most profitable businesses on the planet.
Retrieved 2022-04-14, from https://fortune.com/2021/08/05/bitcoin-mining-is-suddenly
-one-of-the-most-profitable-businesses-on-the-planet/
Goodkind, A. L., Jones, B. A., & Berrens, R. P. (2020). Cryptodamages: Monetary value estimates
of the air pollution and human health impacts of cryptocurrency mining. Energy Research So-
cial Science, 59 , 101281. Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/
pii/S2214629619302701 doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2019.101281
Gray, M. (2021). Turning the supertanker. ThinkZero. https://www.transitionzero.org/reports/
turning-the-supertanker.
Hanley, N., Shogren, F., & White, B. (2019). Introduction to environmental economics (3rd ed.). OUP
Oxford.
Hayes, A. (2015). A cost of production model for bitcoin. Retrieved from http://www
.economicpolicyresearch.org/econ/2015/NSSR WP 052015.pdf
Hope, C. (2011, Apr). Working paper series - cambridge judge business school. Retrieved from
https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/2020/08/wp1104.pdf
IEA. (2020). Implementing effective emissions trading systems. https://www.iea.org/reports/
implementing-effective-emissions-trading-systems. (Accessed: 2022-03-10)
IEA. (2021). The role of china’s ets in power sector decarbonisation. IEA Publications. https://
www.iea.org/reports/the-role-of-chinas-ets-in-power-sector-decarbonisation.
Jiang, S., Li, Y., Lu, Q., Hong, Y., Guan, D., Xiong, Y., & Wang, S. (2021). Policy assessments for
the carbon emission flows and sustainability of bitcoin blockchain operation in china. Nature
Communications, 12 , 1938. doi: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-021-22256-3
Kaiser, B., Jurado, M., & Ledger, A. (2018). The looming threat of china: An analysis of chinese
influence on bitcoin. arXiv preprint arXiv:1810.02466 .
Knight, C. (2013). What is grandfathering? Environmental Politics, 22 (3), 410-427. Retrieved from
https://doi.org/10.1080/09644016.2012.740937 doi: 10.1080/09644016.2012.740937
Krane, J., & Finley, M. (2022, Mar). What is the ’social cost of carbon’ ? 2 energy experts explain
after court ruling. Retrieved from https://theconversation.com/what-is-the-social-cost
-of-carbon-2-energy-experts-explain-after-court-ruling-176255
Krause, M., & Tolaymat, T. (2018). Quantification of energy and carbon costs for mining cryptocur-
rencies. Nature Sustainability, 1 , 711-718. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2019.101281
Laing, T., Sato, M., Grubb, M., & Comberti, C. (2013, January). Assessing the effectiveness of the
EU Emissions Trading System (GRI Working Papers No. 106). Grantham Research Institute
on Climate Change and the Environment. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/lsg/
lsgwps/wp106.html
Lebaron, B. (2001, 02). A builder’s guide to agent-based financial markets. Quantitative Finance, 1 ,
254-261. doi: 10.1088/1469-7688/1/2/307
Liu, Q., Zheng, X.-Q., Zhao, X.-C., Chen, Y., & Lugovoy, O. (2018). Carbon emission scenarios of
china’s power sector: Impact of controlling measures and carbon pricing mechanism. Advances
in Climate Change Research, 9 (1), 27-33. Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/
science/article/pii/S1674927817300916 (Including special topic on China Energy Modeling
Forum) doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.accre.2018.01.002
Luz, S. (2022, Apr). The evidence is clear: The time for action is now. we can halve emissions by
2030. Retrieved from https://www.ipcc.ch/2022/04/04/ipcc-ar6-wgiii-pressrelease/
Mackenzie, W. (2021, Mar). Significant increase in carbon pricing is key in 1.5-degree
world. WoodMac.Site.Features.Shared.ViewModels.Metadata.Publisher. Retrieved from
https://www.woodmac.com/press-releases/significant-increase-in-carbon-pricing
-is-key-in-1.5-degree-world/
McCook, H. (2018). The cosst amp; sustainability of bitcoin.
McDonald, K. (2021, Dec). Ethereum emissions: A bottom-up estimate.
doi: https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2112.01238
min Yu, S., Fan, Y., Zhu, L., & Eichhammer, W. (2020). Modeling the emission trading scheme from an
agent-based perspective: System dynamics emerging from firms’ coordination among abatement
37
options. European Journal of Operational Research, 286 (3), 1113-1128. Retrieved from https://
www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0377221720303131 doi: https://doi.org/10
.1016/j.ejor.2020.03.080
Mora, C., R.L., R., Taladay, K., Kantar, M., Chock, M., Shimada, M., & Franklin, E. (2018). Bitcoin
emissions alone could push global warming above 2°c. https://www.nature.com/articles/
s41558-018-0321-8.pdf. (Accessed: 2022-03-10)
Nordhaus, W. (2016, Nov). Revisiting the social cost of carbon — pnas. Retrieved from https://
www.pnas.org/doi/10.1073/pnas.1609244114
Nordhaus, W., & Sztorc, P. (2013, Oct). Dice 2013r - yale university. Retrieved from http://www
.econ.yale.edu/~nordhaus/homepage/homepage/documents/DICE Manual 100413r1.pdf
O’Dwyer, K. J., & Malone, D. (2014, Jun). Bitcoin mining and its energy footprint. ISSC .
Petrick, S., & Wagner, U. (2014). The impact of carbon trading on industry: Evidence from german
manufacturing firms (Kiel Working Papers No. 1912). Kiel Institute for the World Economy
(IfW Kiel). Retrieved from https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:zbw:ifwkwp:1912
Platt, M., Sedlmeir, J., Platt, D., Xu, J., Tasca, P., Vadgama, N., & Ibanez, J. (2021, Sep). Energy
footprint of blockchain consensus mechanisms beyond proof-of-work. arXiv . Retrieved from
https://arxiv.org/pdf/2109.03667v5.pdf
Powell, L. M., Hendon, M., Mangle, A., & Wimmer, H. (2021). Awareness of blockchain usage,
structure, generation of platform’s energy consumption: Working towards a greener blockchain.
Issues in Information Systems, 22 (1), 114–123. doi: https://doi.org/10.48009/1 iis 2021 114
-123
Refinitiv. (2021). China’s national carbon market exceeds expectations. https://
www.refinitiv.com/perspectives/future-of-investing-trading/chinas-national
-carbon-market-exceeds-expectations/. (Accessed: 2022-03-10)
Romann, A. (2013). China leading the bitcoin charge. Retrieved from https://www.chinadailyasia
.com/business/2013-11/22/content 15100696.html
Ros, D. (2013, Feb). Why we risk overinterpreting china’s carbon tax statements. Retrieved
from https://www.carbonbrief.org/why-we-risk-overinterpreting-chinas-carbon-tax
-statements#:~:text=In%202010%2C%20the%20ministry%20suggested,5)%20per%20tonne%
20by%202020.
Shen, S., & Galbraith, A. (2021a, Jun). China’s ban forces some bitcoin miners to flee overseas,
others sell out. Thomson Reuters. Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/technology/
chinas-ban-forces-some-bitcoin-miners-flee-overseas-others-sell-out-2021-06-25
Shen, S., & Galbraith, A. (2021b). Why china is leading the global rise of bitcoin.
Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/technology/chinas-ban-forces-some-bitcoin
-miners-flee-overseas-others-sell-out-2021-06-25/
Singh, R. (2021, Nov). Cop26: How to make cryptocurrency sustainable. Retrieved from
https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2021/11/how-to-make-bitcoin-and-cryptocurrency
-sustainable-renewable-energy-blockchain-crypto-mining/
Southurst, J. (2013). Why china is leading the global rise of bitcoin. Retrieved
from https://www.coindesk.com/markets/2013/11/18/why-china-is-leading-the-global
-rise-of-bitcoin/
Stern, N., Taylor, C., Karlsson, K., & Stiglitz, J. (2022, Jan). A social cost of carbon consistent with a
net-zero climate ... Retrieved from https://rooseveltinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/
2022/01/RI Social-Cost-of-Carbon 202201-1.pdf
Stoll, C., Lena Klaaßen, L., & Gallersdörfer, U. (2019, July). The carbon footprint of bitcoin. Joule(3).
doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joule.2019.05.012
The State Council. (2021). China maps path to carbon peak, neutrality under new development philos-
ophy. Retrieved from http://english.www.gov.cn/policies/latestreleases/202110/24/
content WS61755fe9c6d0df57f98e3bed.html
Trading Economics. (2022). Eu carbon permits. Retrieved 2022-04-14, from https://
tradingeconomics.com/commodity/carbon
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. (N.A.). Bureau of labor statistics data on price of electricity. U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. Retrieved from https://data.bls.gov/timeseries/APU000072610
?amp%5C%253bdata tool=XGtable&output view=data&include graphs=true
von Carnap, K. (2021). Unchaining blockchain in china. Retrieved from https://merics.org/sites/
38
default/files/2021-03/MERICS%20Primer%20Unchaining%20Blockchain%20in%20China%
202021.pdf
Vranken, H. (2017). Sustainability of bitcoin and blockchains. Current Opinion in Environmental
Sustainability, 28 , 1-9. Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/
pii/S1877343517300015 (Sustainability governance) doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cosust
.2017.04.011
Waldhoff, S., Anthoff, D., Rose, S., & Tol, R. S. J. (2014, Dec). The marginal damage costs of different
greenhouse gases: An application of fund. De Gruyter Open Access. Retrieved from https://
www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2014-31/html
Whitehouse, U. S. (2021, Feb). Technical support document: Social cost of car-
bon, methane, and nitrous oxide interim estimates under executive order 13990. In-
teragency Working Group on Social Cost of Greenhouse Gases, United States Gov-
ernment. Retrieved from https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2021/02/
TechnicalSupportDocument SocialCostofCarbonMethaneNitrousOxide.pdf
World Bank. (2021a, May). State and trends of carbon pricing 2021. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/35620
World Bank. (2021b, May). State and trends of carbon pricing 2021. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/35620
Ye, J. (2020, Feb). Options and considerations for a federal carbon tax. Retrieved from https://
www.c2es.org/document/options-and-considerations-for-a-federal-carbon-tax/
Zade, M., Myklebost, J., Tzscheutschler, P., & Wagner, U. (2019). Is bitcoin the only prob-
lem? a scenario model for the power demand of blockchains. Frontiers in Energy Research,
7 . Retrieved from https://www.frontiersin.org/article/10.3389/fenrg.2019.00021 doi:
10.3389/fenrg.2019.00021
Zhang, J. (2010, May). Retrieved from http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/china/2010-05/11/
content 9834525.htm
39