0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views

Lecture3 2021

This document discusses key concepts in finance including risk-neutral measures, the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, contingent claims, attainability, completeness, and provides an example of a stochastic volatility model and digital call option. It includes definitions of risk-neutral probability measures, states that no arbitrage exists if and only if a risk-neutral measure exists, and discusses how the number of risk-neutral measures impacts pricing.

Uploaded by

Yanjing Peng
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views

Lecture3 2021

This document discusses key concepts in finance including risk-neutral measures, the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, contingent claims, attainability, completeness, and provides an example of a stochastic volatility model and digital call option. It includes definitions of risk-neutral probability measures, states that no arbitrage exists if and only if a risk-neutral measure exists, and discusses how the number of risk-neutral measures impacts pricing.

Uploaded by

Yanjing Peng
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 16

MATH5320: Discrete Time Finance

Lecture 3

G. Aivaliotis, c University of Leeds

February 2021

1 / 16
In this lecture

• Brief Recap – Video 1


• Risk-neutral measures – Video 2
• Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing – Videos 3 and 4.
• Contingent Claims, Attainability, Completeness – Videos 5
and 6.

2 / 16
General single period market model

Ω := {ω1 , ..., ωk }, P

Assumption: P(ω) > 0 for all ω ∈ Ω.

Asset prices:

S1i : Ω → R, i = 1, . . . , n.

Money market account:

B1 = B0 (1 + r).

3 / 16
Risk neutral probability measure

A measure P̃ on Ω is called a risk neutral probability measure if


1 P̃(ω) > 0 for all ω ∈ Ω,

2 EP̃ (∆Ŝ i ) = 0 for i = 1, . . . , n.

Another way of formulating 2. is:


 
1
EP̃ S1i = S0i .
1+r

 
V1 (x, φ)
If (x, φ) is a trading strategy, then EP̃ = x.
1+r

4 / 16
Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

No arbitrage if and only if there exists a risk neutral mea-


sure.

M = the set of all risk neutral measures


• empty
• 1 element
• more than 1 element
Cardinality of M is crucial for pricing...

5 / 16
Definitions
We are working on a probability space Ω = (ω1 , . . . , ωk ) with k ≥ 2.

W := {X ∈ Rk : X = Ĝ(x, φ) for some strategy (x, φ)}


W⊥ := {Y ∈ Rk : hX, Y i = 0 forall X ∈ W}
A := {X ∈ Rk : X ≥ 0, X 6= 0}
k
X
+ k
P := {Z ∈ R : Zi = 1, Zi > 0}
i=1

Lemma 1.2.9. The set of all risk-neutral measures coincides with


P + W⊥ =: M.
T

In particular, no risk-neutal measures means M = ∅.

6 / 16
Separating hyperplane theorem

This result will be used in the proof of the Theorem 1.2.8. Recall
that a set A is called convex iff x, y ∈ A implies that
αx + (1 − α)y ∈ A for any 0 ≤ α ≤ 1.

Theorem Let A ⊂ Rk be convex and compact, H 3 0 a


hyperplane in Rk , and A H = ∅. Then there exists a vector
T

v ∈ Rk such that v ⊥ H and min(hv, zi : z ∈ A) > 0.

A standard notation for v ⊥ H is

v ∈ H⊥ .

For the proof see, e.g., [Elliott, Kopp, 2005, section 3.1].

7 / 16
Proof of the Theorem 1.2.8

I. Assume first that the no arbitrage condition holds. Let

A+ = {X ∈ A|hX, Pi = 1}

be a closed, bounded and convex subset of Rk . Since A+ ⊂ A it


follows from the Lemma 1.2.9 that

no arbitrage ⇒ W ∩ A+ = ∅.

By the separating hyperplane theorem, there exists a vector


Y ∈ W⊥ , s.t.
hX, Y i > 0 for all X ∈ A+ . (1)

8 / 16
Proof, ctd2

Let us now define Q by

Y (ωi )
Q(ωi ) = .
Y (ω1 ) + ... + Y (ωk )

Clearly, Q ∈ P + . Since Q is just a scalar multiple of Y , and W⊥ is


a linear vector space, and hX, Y i = 0, ∀X ∈ W (i,e, Y ∈ W⊥ ), it
follows that Q ∈ W⊥ . Therefore

Q ∈ P + ∩ W⊥ .

By virtue of the Lemma 1.2.9 we have that Q is a risk neutral


measure on Ω. Hence, the condition of no arbitrage implies the
existence of a risk neutral measure.

9 / 16
Proof, ctd3

II. Let us now show the converse. We assume there exists a risk
neutral measure Q. Let (x, φ) be an arbitrary trading strategy. As
in the proof of the Lemma 1.2.9,
k k
!
X X  
i i
EQ (Ĝ(x, φ)) = EQ φ ∆Ŝ = φi EQ ∆Ŝ i = 0.
i=1 i=1

If we assume that Ĝ(x, φ) ≥ 0 then the last equation clearly implies


that Ĝ(x, φ)(ω) = 0 for all ω ∈ Ω since otherwise EQ Ĝ(x, φ)
would be positive: recall that Q(ω) > 0 for each ω. Hence by the
Proposition 1.2.6 about no arbitrage condition in terms of Ĝ, there
cannot be any trading strategy that is an arbitrage. 

10 / 16
Contingent claim

Proposition: Let X be a contingent claim in our general single


period market model, and let (x, φ) be a hedging strategy for X,
i.e. a trading strategy which satisfies V1 (x, φ) = X. The only price
of X which complies with the no arbitrage principle is V0 (x, φ),
which by definition is equal to x.

11 / 16
Replication principle

A replicating strategy for the contingent claim X is a trading


strategy (x, φ) which satisfies V1 (x, φ)(ω) = X(ω) for every ω ∈ Ω.

Financial institution ←→ customer


replicating strategy ←→ contingent claim
(x, φ) ←→ X

12 / 16
Attainable claims

A contingent claim X is called attainable, if there exists a trading


strategy (x, φ) which replicates X, i.e. satisfies V1 (x, φ) = X.

Proposition: Let X be an attainable contingent claim and P̃ be an


arbitrary risk neutral measure. Then the price x of X at time t = 0
defined via a replicating strategy can be computed by the formula

 
1
x = EP̃ 1+r X .

13 / 16
Complete market model

A financial market model is called complete if all


contingent claims are attainable.

Assume the model with n risky assets is arbitrage free. This model is complete
if and only if the k × (n + 1) matrix A given by

S11 (ω1 ) · · · S1n (ω1 )


 
1+r
 1+r S11 (ω2 ) · · · S1n (ω2 ) 
 · · · 
A= 
 · · · 
· · ·
 
1+r S11 (ωk ) · · · S1n (ωk )
has the rank k, i.e. rank(A) = k. Recall that k = |Ω|.

14 / 16
Stochastic volatility model

There are two assets: the money market account Bt and one stock St (t = 0, 1). There is also a random
quantity called the volatility v which determines the size of stock price jumps. Our state space consists of 4 states:

Ω := {ω1 , ω2 , ω3 , ω4 }

and the volatility is given by n


h, if ω = ω1 , ω2
v(ω) :=
l, if ω = ω3 , ω4

The stock price S1 is then modeled by

n
(1 + v(ω))S0 , if ω = ω1 , ω3
S1 (ω) :=
(1 − v(ω))S0 , if ω = ω2 , ω4

where S0 = the initial stock price. The money market account: B0 = 1, B1 = 1 + r.

15 / 16
Digital call

Let us now consider a digital call in this model, i.e.


(
1, if S1 > K
X=
0 otherwise

Assume that the strike price K satisfies

(1 + l)S0 < K < (1 + h)S0 .

Try to find a replicating strategy.

16 / 16

You might also like