0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views15 pages

12 ProductionProfitMax

1) The document discusses the economic theory of profit maximization by firms. It assumes firms choose actions to maximize the difference between their revenue and costs. 2) Under profit maximization, firms will produce at the quantity where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. In the long run, firms with identical costs and revenues will have equal profits. 3) The document outlines the conditions, constraints, and analytical steps involved in a firm's profit maximization problem, including determining optimal prices, quantities, and inputs. It also discusses properties of demand and supply functions under this model.

Uploaded by

jared demissie
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views15 pages

12 ProductionProfitMax

1) The document discusses the economic theory of profit maximization by firms. It assumes firms choose actions to maximize the difference between their revenue and costs. 2) Under profit maximization, firms will produce at the quantity where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. In the long run, firms with identical costs and revenues will have equal profits. 3) The document outlines the conditions, constraints, and analytical steps involved in a firm's profit maximization problem, including determining optimal prices, quantities, and inputs. It also discusses properties of demand and supply functions under this model.

Uploaded by

jared demissie
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 15

Behaviour: Profit maximisation

Introduction
• Definitions: Profit; costs; revenue
• Many possible octions:
• Revenue and cost as functions of these actions as
𝑅 𝑎1 , 𝑎2 , … , 𝑎𝑛 ;
𝐶 𝑎1 , 𝑎2 , … , 𝑎𝑛 :
The basic assumption of most economic analysis of firm behaviour is profit
maximisation.; i.e
max 𝑅 𝑎1 , 𝑎2 , … , 𝑎𝑛 − 𝐶 𝑎1 , 𝑎2 , … , 𝑎𝑛
• Two basic principles emerge from the assumption of profit maximisation
at this level.
– 1. at the optimum 𝑎∗ = 𝑎1 , 𝑎2 , … , 𝑎𝑛 ; the MC = MR: If MR > MC increase
production and vice versa
– 2. Firms with identical C and R functions have equal profits in the long run.
• For further analysis we break up the R and C functions into basic parts.
– Revenue is the quantity that a firm sells and prices of the products.
– Cost is the quantity of inputs the firm used and the price of each input.
• The firm’s profit maximisation problem can then be reduced to
the determination of
– 1. the price at which the firm wants to sell its products
– 2. the prices at which it is willing to pay for its inputs
– 3. the quantity of output it wishes to supply, and
– 4. the amount of each input it wishes to use in the process of
producing the quantity it supplies.
• i.e., the firm faces both technical and market constraints in its
optimal operation
• Technical: the feasibility of the production plan.
• Market: the effect of actions of other agents (the WTP of
consumers, the WTA wages
• Price-taking behaviour: Each firm takes the prices in the market
as given
• Such behaviour is justified when we have
– a) well-informed consumers who buy a homogeneous product
– b) fairly large number of firms that supply this homogeneous product.
Profit maximisation behaviour
• A price-taker firm implies prices are exogenous to the firm:
𝜋 𝐩 = max 𝐩𝐲 s. t. 𝐲 in 𝐘
• where p is a vector of prices and y is the netput vector.
• Profit function: π(p) as a function of prices. Ways of presenting the profit function.
1. Short run costs :
𝜋 𝐩, 𝐳 = max 𝐩𝐲 s. t 𝐲 is in 𝐘(𝐳)
2. Divide the netput vector as output (one product) and inputs we can present it as
𝜋 𝑝, 𝐰 = max 𝑝𝑓 𝐱 − 𝐰𝐱
3. Restrict the function with respect to available costs such that
𝑐 𝐰, 𝑦 = min 𝐰𝐱 s. t. 𝐱 is in V(y)
4. which can, in the short run be restricted as
𝑐 𝐰, 𝑦, 𝒛 = min 𝐰𝐱 s. t. (𝑦, −𝐱) is in V(y)
• Basic profit maximisation behaviour: 1 output firm, lead to the following F. O. C.
𝜕𝜋 𝑝, 𝐰 𝜕𝑓 𝐱 𝜕𝑓 𝐱
=0→𝑝 − 𝑤𝑖 = 0 → 𝑝 = 𝑤𝑖 ∀𝑖 = 1,2, … , 𝑛
𝜕𝑥𝑖 𝜕𝑥𝑖 𝜕𝑥𝑖
• VMP (pfi) must be equal to the price of the factor. (vector algebra presentation
∗ ∗
𝜕𝑓(𝐱 ∗ ) 𝜕𝑓(𝐱 ∗ ) 𝜕𝑓(𝐱 ∗ )
𝑝𝐃𝑓 𝐱 = 𝐰, where 𝐃𝑓 𝐱 = , ,…,
𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥2 𝜕𝑥𝑛
The F. O. C. graphically (1 input case)
• The profit function is given as
𝜋 = 𝑝𝑦 − 𝑤𝑥
• The level sets (iso-profit) for fixed p
and w are straight lines of the form output
output
𝜋 = 𝑝𝑦 + 𝐰𝐱

given by
𝜋 𝑤 Slope = 𝐰/𝑝 𝑦 = 𝑓(𝐱)
𝑦 = + 𝑥
𝑝 𝑝
• The slope the iso-profit line: wage of
the input measured in units of output 𝜋/𝑝
• The vertical intercept is the profit
measured in units of output.
• The point whose vertical intercept is
the greatest and slope is tangent to input
the PF maximizes profit

𝑑𝑓 𝑥 𝑤
=
𝑑𝑥 𝑝
Second order conditions (S. O. C.)
• One input case:. At x*, the PF must lie • for the case of three inputs we have:
below its tangent line (locally concave)
𝑓11 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓12 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓13 (𝐱 ∗ )
𝑑2𝑓 𝑥
≤0 𝐃𝟐 𝑓 𝐱 ∗ = 𝑓21 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓22 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓23 (𝐱 ∗ )
𝑑𝑥 2 𝑓31 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓32 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓33 (𝐱 ∗ )
• The multiple-input case: the matrix of 2nd
partial derivatives of the production • Therefore, the conditions are
function must be negative semi-definite at ∗ 𝑓11 𝐱 ∗ 𝑓12 (𝐱 ∗ )
x*. The Hessian matrix 𝑓11 𝐱 < 0, >0
𝑓21 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓22 (𝐱 ∗ )
𝜕 2 𝑓(𝐱 ∗ )
𝟐
𝐃 𝑓 𝐱 ∗
=
𝜕𝑥𝑖 𝜕𝑥𝑗
satisfies 𝐡𝐃𝟐 𝑓 𝐱 ∗ 𝐡′ ≤ 𝟎 ∀𝐡 𝑓11 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓12 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓13 (𝐱 ∗ )
• Necessary and sufficient conditions: the and 𝑓21 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓22 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓23 (𝐱 ∗ ) < 0
leading principal minors of the Hessian must 𝑓31 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓32 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓33 (𝐱 ∗ )
alternate in sign. For the case of two inputs • If these hold solve the F. O. C’s for the
we have
𝑓11 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓12 (𝐱 ∗ ) optimal input choice, x*.
𝟐 ∗
𝐃 𝑓 𝐱 = • The optimal input choice is a function of
𝑓21 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓22 (𝐱 ∗ )
• Therefore, the conditions are price of y & w.
∗ 𝑓11 𝐱 ∗ 𝑓12 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝐱(𝑝, 𝐰)
𝑓11 𝐱 < 0 and >0
𝑓21 (𝐱 ∗ ) 𝑓22 (𝐱 ∗ ) • Supply: y made dependent on p & w
𝑦 𝑝, 𝐰 = 𝑓 𝐱(𝑝, 𝐰)
Difficulties
• Assumed well behaved input demand and supply functions: problems that may arise
if they are not.
1. The firm’s PF may not be differentiable: derivatives may not exist: Leontief
2. If interior solution: for boundary solutions. the Kuhn-Tucker conditions must hold.
𝜕𝑓 𝐱
𝑝 − 𝑤𝑖 ≤ 0 if 𝑥𝑖 = 0
𝜕𝑥𝑖
𝜕𝑓 𝐱
𝑝 − 𝑤𝑖 = 0 if 𝑥𝑖 > 0
𝜕𝑥𝑖
3. Profit maximizing plan may not exist: Say, the production function of the form
𝑓 𝒙 =𝑥
• CRS e.g. If we want to maximize
max 𝑝𝑥 – 𝑤𝑥
• when p > w, x infinity. A maximal exists when p  w, and the maximal level of profit
will be zero.
• Suppose we can find some (p, w) where optimal profits are strictly positive so that
• 𝑝𝒇 𝐱 ∗ − 𝒘𝐱 ∗ = 𝐱 ∗ > 𝟎
• Scale up the production by a factor t > 1; our profits will now be
• 𝑝𝒇(𝑡𝐱 ∗ ) − 𝒘𝑡𝐱 ∗ = 𝑡 𝑝𝑓(𝐱 ∗ ) − 𝐰𝐱 ∗ ] = 𝑡𝐱 ∗ > 𝐱 ∗ .
Properties of the demand and supply functions
Factor demand functions
• F.O.C.’s are solved to yield the ordinary factor dd functions dependent on w
and p; Let
𝑥1∗ = 𝑥1∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝)
𝑥2∗ = 𝑥1∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝)
• What happens if the one of the prices change other things constant?
(comparative statics). Assume (simplifying) two inputs we have the following
partial derivatives:
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗ 𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗
, , , , ,
𝜕𝑤1 𝜕𝑤2 𝜕𝑤1 𝜕𝑤2 𝜕𝑝 𝜕𝑝
• Substitute the demand functions back into the F.O.C.’s and derive
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗
and
𝜕𝑤1 𝜕𝑤2
to obtain
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝑓22 𝜕𝑥2∗ 𝑓12 𝜕𝑥1∗
= 2
< 0 and =− 2
⋛0
𝜕𝑤1 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓12 𝜕𝑤1 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓12 𝜕𝑤1
• Why?
• Assignment: Set p = 1 and obtain the result using matrix algebra
Hessian matrix
• The matrix of the SOC of the maximization procedure is known
as the Hessian Matrix; which is given as:
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥1∗
𝜕𝑤1 𝜕𝑤2 𝑓11 𝑓12 −1
∗ ∗ =
𝜕𝑥2 𝜕𝑥2 𝑓21 𝑓22
𝜕𝑤1 𝜕𝑤2
• The Hessian matrix is symmetric and negative definite matrix
(from the S.O.C.’s)
• The inverse of a symmetric negative definite matrix is a
symmetric negative definite matrix, therefore
1. 𝜕𝑥𝑖∗ / 𝜕𝑤𝑖 ≤ 0 for i = 1, 2,..n: Diagonal entries of a - definite
matrix must be negative.
2. 𝜕𝑥𝑖∗ / 𝜕𝑤𝑗 = 𝜕𝑥𝑗∗ / 𝜕𝑤𝑖 ≤ 0 for all 𝑖 ≠ 𝑗, by symmetry of the
matrix
• 1 is intuitive not 2 but is a result of maximization
• The supply function
i. Direct approach: substitute the demand functions into the production
function: two factor case
𝑦 ∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝 = 𝑓 𝑥1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝 , 𝑥2∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝
a. differentiate w.r.t. p to obtain
𝜕𝑦 ∗ 𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗
= 𝑓1 + 𝑓2
𝜕𝑝 𝜕𝑝 𝜕𝑝
b. differentiate F.O.C.’s with respect to p
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝜕𝑥2∗
𝑓1 + 𝑝𝑓11 + 𝑝𝑓12 =0
𝜕𝑝 𝜕𝑝

𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥2∗
𝑓2 + 𝑝𝑓21 + 𝑝𝑓22 =0
𝜕𝑝 𝜕𝑝
• From this simultaneous equations system solve for
𝜕𝑥1∗ 𝑓2 𝑓12 − 𝑓1 𝑓22 𝜕𝑥2∗ 𝑓1 𝑓12 − 𝑓2 𝑓11
= 2 and 𝜕𝑝 =
𝜕𝑝 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓21 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓21 2
• Use these in the result in a. to get
𝜕𝑦 ∗ 𝑓2 𝑓12 − 𝑓1 𝑓22 𝑓1 𝑓12 − 𝑓2 𝑓11
= 𝑓1 2 + 𝑓2
𝜕𝑝 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓21 𝑝 𝑓11 𝑓22 − 𝑓21 2
ii) Indirect approach (Hotelling’s Lema)
• Evaluated at the maximized profit
𝜕𝜋 ∗ 𝑝, 𝐰
= 𝑦∗
𝜕𝑝
• Proof
• Insert the direct factor demand equations into the profit
function
𝜋 ∗ 𝑝, 𝐰 = 𝑝𝑓 𝑥1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝 , 𝑥2∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝 − 𝑤1 𝑥1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝 − 𝑤2 𝑥2∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑝
• Take its partial derivative
𝜕𝜋∗ 𝑝,𝐰 𝑤1 𝜕𝑥1∗ ∙ 𝑤2 𝜕𝑥2∗ ∙
• = 𝑓 ∙ + 𝑝 𝑓1 − + 𝑝 𝑓2 −
𝜕𝑝 𝑝 𝜕𝑝 𝑝 𝜕𝑝
• and using the F.O.C.’s
𝜕𝜋 ∗ 𝑝, 𝐰
= 𝑓 𝑥1∗ ∙ , 𝑥2∗ ∙ = 𝑦∗
𝜕𝑝
Properties of the profit function
The profit function is
1. Non-decreasing in p and non-increasing in w, i.e.,
𝑎) 𝑝1 ≥ 𝑝0 → 𝜋 𝐰, 𝑝1 ≥ 𝜋 𝐰, 𝑝0
𝑏) 𝐰1 ≥ 𝐰 0 → 𝜋 𝐰1 , 𝑝 ≤ 𝜋 𝐰 0 , 𝑝
2. Homogeneous of degree 1 in p and w
𝜋 𝑡𝐰, 𝑝 ≤ 𝜋 𝐰, 𝑝
3. Convex in p, and i.e.,
If 𝑝2 = 𝑡𝑝0 + (1 − 𝑡)𝑝1 then 𝜋( 𝑝2 ) ≤ 𝑡𝜋(𝑝1 ) + (1 − 𝑡)𝜋(𝑝0 ).
4. Continuous.
The envelope theorem
• Taking one input-one output, the profit maximized is a function of
w and p
𝜋 ∗ 𝑤, 𝑝 = max 𝑝𝑓 𝑥 ∗ 𝑝, 𝑤 − 𝑤𝑥 ∗ 𝑝, 𝑤
Then
𝑑𝜋 ∗ 𝑤, 𝑝 𝑑𝜋 ∗ 𝑤, 𝑝
=𝑓 𝑥∗ 𝑝, 𝑤 and = −𝑥 ∗ 𝑝, 𝑤
𝑑𝑝 𝑥 ∗ =𝑥 ∗ 𝑝,𝑤
𝑑𝑤 𝑥 ∗ =𝑥 ∗ 𝑝,𝑤
Cost minimization
The problem:
min 𝐰𝐱 s. t. 𝐱 ∈ 𝑉 𝑦 0 or s. t. 𝑓 𝐱 = 𝑦 0
• To solve we use the Lagrangean
𝐿 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 , 𝜆 = 𝑤1 𝑥1 + 𝑤2 𝑥2 − 𝜆 𝑓 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 − 𝑦 0
• The F.O.C.’ are then given as
𝜕𝐿
= 0 → 𝑤1 − 𝜆𝑓1 = 0 → 𝑤1 = 𝜆𝑓1
𝜕𝑥1
𝜕𝐿
= 0 → 𝑤2 − 𝜆𝑓2 = 0 → 𝑤2 = 𝜆𝑓2
𝜕𝑥2
𝜕𝐿
= 0 → 𝑓 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 − 𝑦 0 = 0 → 𝑓 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 = 𝑦 0
𝜕𝜆
• The S.O.C.’s are:
−𝜆𝑓11 −𝜆𝑓12 −𝑓1
−𝜆𝑓21 −𝜆𝑓22 −𝑓2 ≤ 0
−𝑓1 −𝑓2 0
• All the bordered Hessians are negative.
• The solutions to the FOC’s give us the “conditional factor demand functions”
𝑥1∗ = ℎ1∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 )
𝑥2∗ = ℎ2∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 )
𝜆∗ = 𝜆∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 )
• (Indirect) cost function: Substitute ℎ1∗ into the objective
function
𝐶 ∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 = 𝑤1 ℎ1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 + 𝑤2 ℎ2∗ (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 0 )
• Minimum cost associated with the y and w.
Properties of the cost function
• The cost function is:
1. Non-decreasing in w.
𝑓 𝐰1 ≥ 𝐰 0 , then 𝐶(𝐰1 , 𝑦) ≥ 𝐶(𝐰 0 , 𝑦)
2. Homogeneous of degree 1 in w.
𝐶(𝑡𝐰, 𝑦) = 𝑡𝐶(𝐰, 𝑦) for 𝑡 > 0.
3. Concave in w. i.e,
𝐶(𝑡𝐰 + (1 − 𝑡)𝐰, 𝑦) ≥ 𝑡𝐶(𝐰, 𝑦) + (1 − 𝑡)𝐶(𝐰, 𝑦)
4. The cost function is continuous by assumption.
• The surprising property is concavity. As a factor becomes
more expensive with other input prices constant, firms will
substitute the relatively expensive one.
The Shepard’s lemma
• if the cost function is differentiable at (w, y),
and wi > 0 for I = 1, 2, ..., n then
𝜕𝐶 𝐰,𝑦
• 1. = ℎ𝑖 𝐰, 𝑦
𝜕𝑤𝑖
𝜕2 𝐶 𝐰,𝑦 𝜕ℎ𝑖 𝐰,𝑦
• 2. = ≤0
𝜕𝑤𝑖2 𝜕𝑤𝑖
𝜕ℎ𝑖 𝐰,𝑦 𝜕ℎ𝑗 𝐰,𝑦
• 3. = ≤0
𝜕𝑤𝑗 𝜕𝑤𝑖

You might also like