Bernanke and Blinder (1988)
Bernanke and Blinder (1988)
Bernanke and Blinder (1988)
Most standard models of aggregate de- credit are viewed as perfect substitutes for
mand, such as the textbook IS/LM model, auction-market credit ("bonds"), and finan-
treat bank assets and bank liabilities asym- cial markets clear only by price. Models with
metrically. Money, the bank liability, is given a distinct role for credit arise when either of
a special role in the determination of aggre- these assumptions is abandoned.
gate demand. In contrast, bank loans are Following James Tobin (1970) and Karl
lumped together with other debt instruments Brunner and Allan Meltzer (1972), we choose
in a "bond market," which is then conve- to abandon the perfect substitutability as-
niently suppressed by Walras' Law. sumption and ignore credit rationing.' Our
Much recent research provides reasons to model has three assets: money, bonds, and
question this imbalance. A growing theoreti- loans. Only the loan market needs explana-
cal literature, based on models with asym- tion. We assume that both borrowers and
metric information, stresses the importance lenders choose between bonds and loans
of intermediaries in the provision of credit according to the interest rates on the two
and the special nature of bank loans. Empiri- credit instruments. If p is the interest rate on
cally, the instability of econometric money- loans and i is the interest rate on bonds,
demand equations has been accompanied by then loan demand is: Ld = L(p, i, y). The
new interest in the credit-GNP relation- dependence on GNP (y) captures th+e trans-
ship (see especially the work of Benjamin actions demand for credit, which might arise,
Friedman). for example, from working capital or liquid-
We have developed several models of ag- ity considerations.
gregate demand which allow roles for both To understand the genesis of loan supply,
money and "credit" (bank loans). We pre- consider a simplified bank balance sheet
sent a particularly simple one, a variant of (which ignores net worth) with assets: re-
the textbook IS/LM model, in this paper. serves, R; bonds, Bb; loans, LS; and liabili-
Though it has a simple graphical represen- ties: deposits, D. Since reserves consist of
tation like IS/LM, this model permits us to required reserves, TD, plus excess reserves,
pose a richer array of questions than does E, the banks' adding-up constraint is: Bb +
the traditional money-only framework. LS + E = D(1- T). Assuming that desired
portfolio proportions depend on rates of re-
I. The Model turn on the available assets (zero for excess
reserves), we have LS = A(p, i)D(l - ), with
The LM curve is a portfolio-balance con- similar equations for the+shares of B b and
dition for a two-asset world: asset holders E. Thus the condition for clearing the loan
choose between money and bonds. Tacitly, market is
loans and other forms of customer-market
(1) L(p, i, y) =X(p, i)D(1- T).
*Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544. We are 1Blinder (1987) offers a model in which there is
grateful to the NSF for supporting this research. rationing and no substitute for bank credit.
435
This content downloaded from 151.100.22.220 on Thu, 10 Jan 2019 14:49:11 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
436 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1988
cial wealth.
The remaining market is the goods market,
which we summarize in a conventional IS we call the CC curve (for "commodities and
curve, written generically as3 credit"). It is easy to see that the CC curve is
negatively sloped like an IS curve, and for
(3) y=Y(i,P). much the same reasons. However, it is shifted
by monetary policy (R) and by credit-market
II. Graphical Representation shocks that affect either the L(-) or X(-)
functions, while the IS curve is not. The
Use (2) to replace D(1- T) on the right- CC and LM curves are shown together in
hand side of (1) by (1- T)m(i)R. Then (1) Figure 1.
can be solved for p as a function of i, y, and Our CC curve reduces to the IS curve if
R :4 loans and bonds are assumed to be perfect
substitutes either to borrowers (Lp -* - oo)
(4) p =O(il+y, R). or to lenders (Xp -* oo), or if commodity
demand is insensitive to the loan rate (Yp
Finally, substitute (4) into (3) to get = 0)-which would make the loan market
irrelevant to IS/LM. This clarifies the spe-
(5) y=Y(i, (i,y,R)) cial assumptions implicit in the money-only
view.
which, in deference to Don Patinkin (1956), The opposite extreme, or credit-only view,
would arise if money and bonds were perfect
substitutes (Di -* - xo), which would make
the LM curve horizontal. Keynes' explana-
tion for the liquidity trap is, of course, well
known. We think of high substitutability as
2For simplicity we assume that only i, not p, in-
fluences the demand for excess reserves.
more likely to arise from financial innova-
3The interest rates in (3) should be real rates. But a tions which create new money substitutes.
model of aggregate demand takes both the price level However, even with a liquidity trap, mone-
and inflation as given; so we take the expected inflation tary policy still matters because it influences
rate to be constant and suppress it.
the CC curve.
4p is an increasing function of i as long as the
interest elasticity of the money multiplier is not too Now let us turn to the intermediate cases
large. represented by Figure 1.
This content downloaded from 151.100.22.220 on Thu, 10 Jan 2019 14:49:11 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 78 NO. 2 IS IT MONEY OR CREDIT, OR BOTH, OR NEITHER? 437
III. Comparative Statics5 the model, such a shock should reduce credit,
GNP, and the interest rate on government
Most conventional shocks work in our bonds while raising the interest rate on loans.
model just as they do in IS/LM. For exam- Another notable example with the same pre-
ple, an expenditure shock shifts the CC curve dicted effects is the credit controls of
along a fixed LM curve, and a money- March-July 1980. In this instance " tight
demand shock shifts the LM curve along money" should, and apparently did, reduce
a fixed CC curve. The effects are familiar interest rates on government bonds.
and need not be discussed. The only note-
worthy difference is that a rise in bank re- IV. Implications for Monetary Policy
serves might conceivably raise the rate of
interest in the credit model. Graphically, the We turn next to the traditional target and
ambiguity arises because an increase in R indicator issues of monetary policy. The so-
shifts both the CC and LM curves outward. called monetary indicator problem arises if
Economically, the credit channel makes the central bank sees its impact on aggregate
monetary policy more expansionary than in demand only with a lag but sees its impacts
IS/LM and therefore raises the transactions on financial-sector variables like interest
demand for money by more than in the rates, money, and credit more promptly.
conventional model. What does our model say about the suitabil-
Greater interest attaches to issues that ity of money or credit as indicators?
elude the IS/LM model. An upward shift in Table 1 shows the qualitative responses of
the credit supply function, X(.) (which might GNP, money, credit, and bond interest rates
correspond, for example, to a decrease in the to a wide variety of shocks, assuming that
perceived riskiness of loans) shifts the CC bank reserves is the policy instrument. Col-
curve outward along a fixed LM curve, umns 1 and 2 display a conclusion familiar
thereby raising i and y. The interest rate on from IS/LM: money is a good qualitative
loans, p, falls, however. An upward shift in indicator of future GNP movements except
the credit demand function, L (.), which when money demand shocks are empirically
might correspond to a greater need for work- important. Columns 1 and 3 offer the corre-
ing capital, has precisely the opposite effects. sponding conclusion for credit: credit is a
We find it difficult to think of or identify good qualitative indicator except when there
major shocks to credit demand, that is, sharp are important shocks to credit demand. If
increases or decreases in the demand for money demand shocks were indeed more
loans at given interest rates and GNP. But important than credit demand shocks in the
shocks to credit supply are easy to con- 1980's, credit would have been a better indi-
ceptualize and to find in actual history. For cator than money.
example, Bernanke's (1983) explanation for What about the target question, that is,
the length of the Great Depression can be about the choice between stabilizing money
thought of as a downward shock to credit vs. stabilizing credit? Rather than try to con-
supply stemming from the increased riski- duct a complete Poole-style (1970) analysis,
ness of loans and banks' concern for liquid- we simply ask whether policymakers would
ity in the face of possible runs. According to respond "correctly" (i.e., in a stabilizing way)
to various shocks if they were targeting mon-
ey or targeting credit.
Consider first an expansionary IS shock.
Table 1 (line 5) shows that both money and
5 Most comparative statics results require no assump- credit would rise if bank reserves were un-
tions other than the ones we have already made. But, in changed. Hence a central bank trying to
a few cases, we encounter theoretical ambiguities that
stabilize either money or credit would con-
can be resolved by invoking certain elasticity assump-
tions spelled out in a longer version of this paper. If tract bank reserves, which is the correct
output is fixed on the supply side, y would be replaced stabilizing response. Either policy works, at
by P in Figure 1 and in the text discussion that follows. least qualitatively. A similar analysis applies
This content downloaded from 151.100.22.220 on Thu, 10 Jan 2019 14:49:11 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
438 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1988
This content downloaded from 151.100.22.220 on Thu, 10 Jan 2019 14:49:11 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 78 NO. 2 IS IT MONEY OR CREDIT, OR BOTH, OR NEITHER? 439
This content downloaded from 151.100.22.220 on Thu, 10 Jan 2019 14:49:11 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms