Economics of Intellectual Property Law
Economics of Intellectual Property Law
Economics of Intellectual Property Law
1
This
Chapter
will
appear
in
Francesco
Parisi
(ed.),
Oxford
Handbook
of
Law
and
Electroniccopy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2412251
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2412251
firms,
because
IP
makes
possible
arm’s
length
transactions
involving
IP-‐intensive
components
and
pure
ideas.
I
next
turn
to
the
second
major
trend
in
recent
IP
studies,
methodological
diversity.
I
describe
contributions
in
the
areas
of
empirical
IP
studies,
models
and
analytics,
and
the
emerging
field
of
experimental
IP
research.
The
richness
and
diversity
of
contemporary
studies
makes
for
a
stark
contrast
with
older
first-‐wave
research.
I
argue
in
this
section
that,
from
the
point
of
view
of
IP
policy,
this
diversity
of
research
methodologies
points
to
a
very
promising
prospect.
When
results
from
multiple,
disparate
methodologies
converge,
we
can
be
more
certain
that
we
are
seeing
evidence
of
a
policy
that
makes
solid
sense.
Out
of
the
welter
of
contemporary
approaches
to
IP
research,
then,
consensus
might
emerge.
And
when
it
does,
we
will
see
the
payoff
of
the
many
new
and
exciting
approaches
to
this
most
dynamic
of
legal
fields.
1.
Introduction
It
is
useful
once
in
a
while
to
look
at
a
complex
thing
in
whole
cloth,
instead
of
thread
by
slender
thread.
When
I
do
that
with
intellectual
property,
here
is
what
I
see.
I
see
that
IP
is
beginning
to
live
up
to
the
aspirations
of
an
earlier
generation,
which
yearned
to
make
law
a
much
more
expansive
field
of
study,
one
that
integrated
the
insights
of
sociology,
history,
psychology,
and
economics.
All
these
threads
are
in
place
in
the
IP
field
now.
Gone
are
the
days
when
virtually
every
article
on
the
subject
began
and
ended
with
a
discussion
of
case
law
and
statutes.
Now,
though
straight
doctrinal
work
is
far
from
dead,
the
pages
of
academic
journals
are
alive
with
studies
of
all
facets
of
IP
law,
informed
and
influenced
by
a
wide
range
of
academic
disciplines.
These
disciplines
supply
a
cornucopia
of
tools,
which
scholars
put
to
work
on
all
sorts
of
issues
and
problems.
Scholars
no
longer
stick
to
the
close
knitting
of
IP
statutes
and
cases.
What
we
have
now
is
a
very
lively
tapestry.
Take
for
instance
the
outlines
of
a
typical
article
from
IP’s
“classical”
period.
Starting
from
well-‐accepted
background
assumptions
–
that
IP
law
is
about
incentives,
for
example;
or
that
education
is
an
important
value
and
ought
to
be
fostered
by
IP
law
–
a
scholar
would
approach
a
recent
line
of
cases,
or
an
important
decision
by
the
Supreme
Court.2
Such
facts
as
entered
into
the
discussion
would
be
drawn
from
the
legal
record
in
the
case.
The
influence
of
older
cases
would
be
plumbed
and
dissected.
Implications
from
a
legal
holding
would
be
fleshed
out
–
incentives
are
reduced,
for
example,
by
tightening
patent
standards;
or
educational
values
will
be
undermined,
by
constricting
fair
use.
Based
on
these
observations,
the
author
would
advise
doctrinal
course
corrections
to
set
things
right.
2
See,
e.g.,
Kitch,
1966;
see
also
Adelman,
1977.
Electroniccopy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2412251
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2412251
Contemporary
work
is
very
different.
A
book
or
article
might
be
addressed
to
foundational
assumptions.
How
does
IP
work
in
the
overall
context
of
creativity
in
an
industry?
What
kind
of
growth
has
the
industry
undergone,
and
what
if
any
role
has
IP
been
shown
to
play
in
that?3
Do
firms
and
people
in
the
industry
rely
on
informal
norms
or
other
techniques
–
apart
from
formal
IP
rights
–
to
protect
investments
in
creative
works?4
And,
within
the
province
of
IP
doctrine,
how
do
courts
actually
apply
the
doctrines
found
in
IP
law?5
From
a
completely
different
perspective,
a
scholar
might
address
the
cost
side
of
IP
protection:
what
happens
in
the
market
when
IP
rights
expire
–
for
a
patented
pharmaceutical,
for
instance,
or
a
copyrighted
book?6
To
be
sure,
the
literature
continues
to
address
topics
of
interest
to
first-‐wave
scholars.
Does
IP
really
operate
as
a
viable
incentive?
In
a
particular
industry
or
field
of
creativity?
How
does
IP
compare
to
other
motivations
and
incentives
that
drive
creativity,
generally
and
in
specific
industries?
Did
a
change
in
the
law
actually
lead
to
greater
or
lesser
investment
or
activity?7
These
examples
highlight
two
major
differences
between
early
or
“first
wave”
scholarship
and
the
work
of
more
contemporary
“second
wave”
researchers:
(1)
increased
attention
to
IP
rights
in
a
broader
economic
context
(contextualization);
and
(2)
greater
methodological
diversity.
This
Chapter
is
organized
around
these
two
themes.
I
first
discuss
the
many
ways
that
second
wave
scholarship
seeks
to
show
how
IP
rights
are
embedded
in
broader
economic
contexts,
and
thus
diverges
from
first
wave
research
which
tended
to
focus
exclusively
on
IP
rights
as
the
central
determinants
of
economic
activity.
Next
I
consider
the
many
different
methodologies
now
being
deployed
to
study
issues
in
the
economics
of
IP
rights
–
from
large-‐scale
empirical
work
to
surveys
to
interviews
to
experimental
research.
II.
Contextualization
3
See,
e.g.,
Allison,
Dunn
and
Mann,
2007
(patents
and
the
software
industry);
Mann
and
Sager,
2007
(patents
and
startup
firms
in
the
software
industry).
4
See,
e.g.,
Raustiala
and
Sprigman,
2012.
5
See,
e.g.,
Beebe,
2008
(empirical
study
of
copyright’s
fair
use
factors);
Sag,
2012
(analyzing
copyright
cases
so
as
to
predict
the
outcome
of
fair
use
disputes).
6
See
Buccafusco
and
Heald,
2013.
See
also
Bechtold
and
Tucker,
2013
(court
ruling
relaxing
trademark
enforcement
against
Google
“keyword”
ad
sales
in
Europe
had
little
effect
on
user
visits
to
trademark
owners’
websites).
7
Another
type
of
study
tests
assumptions
behind
doctrine
or
doctrinal
change.
See,
e.g.,
McKenna,
2009
(testing
trademark
law’s
assumption
that
consumers
may
be
confused
when
a
trademark
owner’s
mark
is
used
in
markets
unrelated
or
ancillary
to
the
owner’s
primary
markets).
this
and
other
early
work,
see
Peter
Menell
and
Suzanne
Scotchmer,
Intellectual
Property,
chapter
in
Handbook
of
Law
and
Economics,
edited
by
A.
Mitchell
Polinsky
and
Steven
Shavell
(2007),
avail.
at
10
A
body
of
work
by
the
noted
economist
of
technological
change,
Richard
Nelson,
stands
either
as
a
glaring
exception
to
the
standing
assumptions
of
the
first
and
second
wave,
or
as
the
vanguard
of
the
third
wave;
and
perhaps
both.
See,
e.g.,
Nelson
and
Rosenberg,
1993
at
3,
4-‐5
(“[T]he
concept
[of
a
system]
is
that
of
a
set
of
institutional
actors
that,
together,
plays
the
major
role
in
influencing
innovative
performance.”).
Indeed,
the
highly
influential
original
“Yale
survey”
on
innovation
embodied
in
1987
the
assumption
that
formal
IP
rights
were
but
one
among
a
series
of
“appropriability
mechanisms”
through
which
private
firms
sought
to
recoup
the
costs
of
their
R&D
investments.
See
Levin,
Klevorick,
Nelson
and
Winter,
1987.
Nelson
deserves
far
more
credit
than
he
usually
gets
for
thoroughly
understanding
and
forcefully
arguing
for
the
“contextual”
view
of
IP
at
what
now
seems
a
very
early
date.
He
is
truly
“Il
miglior
fabbro”,
as
T.S.
Eliot
said
of
Ezra
Pound.
For
an
appreciation,
see
Dosi,
2006.
Other
early
work
by
Edwin
Mansfield
also
deserves
to
be
mentioned
here.
See
Mansfield
1985,
1986,
1986
and
Mansfield
et
al.,
1977.
11
This
particular
topic
is
very
well
presented
in
Teece,
1986.
Other
survey-‐based
studies
back
this
theory
with
empirical
findings.
See
Cohen,
Nelson
and
Walsh,
2000;
Graham,
Merges,
Samuelson
and
Sichelman,
2010.
13
Three
of
what
could
have
been
man
examples,
I
should
add.
So
for
instance
I
cold
have
added
entire
section
on
contemporary
trademark
scholarship,
which
has
shown
that
simplistic
models
of
trademarks
as
a
way
to
reduce
consumer
search
costs
are
incomplete
because
they
ignore
the
sophisticated
techniques
of
branding
experts
and
marketers.
Thus
Jeremy
Sheff
shows
that
investments
in
branding
can
actually
bias
consumer’s
perceptions
about
what
they
need
or
the
characteristics
of
a
relevant
product.
See
Sheff,
2011.
And
see
Lemley
and
McKenna,
2012
(deploying
marketing
literature
to
explore
the
complexities
of
brand
loyalty,
and
its
impact
on
the
actual
economic
effects
of
trademark
law),
and
Lee,
DeRosia
and
Christensen,
2009.
of
recorded
music
concerts
by
fans
of
“jambands
such
as
the
Grateful
Dead.
It
is
not
clear
how
large
this
genre
is
as
a
percentage
of
all
popular
music,
but
it
is
clearly
substantial.
based
on
large
aggregate
data
sources,
and
(2)
prepared
by
interest
groups
with
a
string
agenda.
See
L.A.
Times,
2013.
16
Wikipedia,
Pharmaceutical
Industry.
17
www.Chemistryviews.org.
18
Ellickson,
1993,
at
1520.
19
See
Hemphill
Suk,
2009,
at
1148
n.
1:
U.S.
apparel
sales
reached
$196
billion
in
2007.
The
U.S.
Apparel
Market
2007
Dresses
Up
...
Way
Up,
Bus.
Wire,
Mar.
18,
2008
(reporting
estimate
by
the
NPD
Group).
Among
fashion
accessories,
considering
just
one
category,
handbags,
adds
another
$5
billion
in
sales.
Tanya
Krim,
There's
Nothing
“Trivial”
About
the
Pursuit
of
the
Perfect
Bag,
Brandweek,
Mar.
29,
2007
(reporting
U.S.
sales
ex-‐ceeding
$5
billion
in
2005).
21
See,
e.g.,
Eguchi,
2011,
at
145:
“A
design
protection
bill
from
2010]
garnered
support
from
several
well-‐known
designers
and
the
Council
of
Fashion
Designers
of
America
(CFDA)—
the
creative
core
of
the
fashion
industry
.
.
.
.”
22
See,
e.g.,
Scafidi,
2008.
23
See
Merges,
2001.
2011a.
See
also
Heald,
2005;
Bar-‐Gill
and
Parchomovsky,
2009;
Virtinsky.
Perhaps
the
earliest
reference
to
this
theme
in
the
legal
literature
is
Merges,
1996
(arguing
that
weak
formal
IP
rights
forced
the
Japanese
software
industry
into
a
vertically
integrated
production
model
that
disfavored
small,
independent
firms);
but
see
Mashima,
1996
(offering
corrections
to
this
thesis).
indifferent
to
whether
large
or
small
firms
did
most
of
the
innovating,
it
has
been
suggested
that
the
enhanced
autonomy
which
accompanies
smaller
firms
provides
an
independent
social
good
(Merges,
2011a).
Hence
in
some
cases
at
least
slightly
higher
transaction
costs
ought
to
be
tolerated
for
the
sake
of
this
independent
social
good.
Research
Network
(SSRN),
edited
by
Christopher
Buccafusco
and
David
Schwartz.
See
SSRN.com.
27
See,
e.g.,
Alcacer
and
Gittelman,
2006
(use
of
patent
examiner
data
to
study
patent
examination
patterns);
Abrams,
Akcigit
and
Popadak,
2013
(sophisticated
study
of
patents
through
citation
data).
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Endowment_effect.