0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views4 pages

Notes - On - Capm HV

1. The CAPM model builds on the mean-variance model and assumes investors can borrow and lend at the risk-free rate. It predicts that the market portfolio is mean-variance efficient and that the expected return of any asset is equal to the risk-free rate plus its beta multiplied by the expected market risk premium. 2. Empirical tests of the CAPM model can be done using either a time-series approach by examining whether estimated betas equal the realized risk premiums, or a cross-sectional approach by examining whether estimated alphas equal zero across assets. 3. Both approaches have limitations, as the time-series approach requires the risk factor to be a return, while the cross-sectional approach

Uploaded by

94fqbu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views4 pages

Notes - On - Capm HV

1. The CAPM model builds on the mean-variance model and assumes investors can borrow and lend at the risk-free rate. It predicts that the market portfolio is mean-variance efficient and that the expected return of any asset is equal to the risk-free rate plus its beta multiplied by the expected market risk premium. 2. Empirical tests of the CAPM model can be done using either a time-series approach by examining whether estimated betas equal the realized risk premiums, or a cross-sectional approach by examining whether estimated alphas equal zero across assets. 3. Both approaches have limitations, as the time-series approach requires the risk factor to be a return, while the cross-sectional approach

Uploaded by

94fqbu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 4

CAPM Cheatsheet

Charlie Wang
April 29, 2009

1 CAPM Background
Builds on mean-variance model of Markowitz (1959)

– Mean-variance utility Investor chooses portfolio at t 1 with stochastic return at t.


– Rational investors choose mean-variance e¢ cient portfolios (p), satisfying the following minimum variance
condition:

E (Ri ) = E (RZP ) + iP [E (RP ) E (RZP )] 8i = 1; :::; N (1)

where E (Ri ) = expected return of any asset in the investment opportunity set, E (RP ) = expected return of any min-
imum variance frontier portfolio, E (RZP ) = expected return on an asset with 0 correlation to the portfolio, and RiP
Cov (Ri ; RP ) =V ar (RP )
Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) add 2 assumptions

– Complete Agreement: Given market clearing asset prices at t 1, investors agree on the joint distribution of asset
returns from t 1 to t, and this is the true distribution from which returns are drawn.
– Borrowing and lending at risk-free rate: All investors can borrow/lend unlimited at the risk-free.

Punchline:

– Complete agreement ) investors see the same opportunity set, and they combine the same risky tangency
portfolio with risk-free lending or borrowing.
– By market clearing of asset market, since everyone holds the same risky asset ) the tangency portfolio must be
the value-weight market portfolio of risky assets (i.e. the "Market" portfolio)!
– Unlimited borrowing and lending at risk-free ) that expected return on assets uncorrelated with market return
E (RZM ) = Rf .
– Thus we obtain the famous equation:

1
E (Ri ) = Rf + iM [E (RM ) Rf ] 8i = 1; :::; N (2)

1 There are 2 standard interpretations of CAP M


1. = sensitivity of asset’s return to variation in market return
2. It can be shown that for a portfolio p s.t. Rp = ! T R;
@V ar (Rp )
= Cov (Ri ; Rp )
@! i
So we can think of CAPM in the following way:
E (Rm ) Rf
E (Ri ) Rf = Cov (Ri ; Rm )
| {z } V ar Rf
c o ntrib u tio n o f i to p o rtfo lio risk | {z }
risk -re tu rn tra d e o ¤ in m k t

1
Black (1972) develops a version of the CAPM without risk-free borrowing or lending, but rather obtains the same result
(market portfolio is MV e¢ cient) by allowing for unrestricted short sales of risky assets.

– Black di¤ers from Sharpe-Lintner in E (RZM )


Black: E (RM ) E (RZM ) > 0
Sharpe-Lintner: E (RZM ) = Rf .
– In either case, the Sharpe-Lintner-Black CAPM ) positive premium for .

Sharpe-Lintner and Black versions of CAPM share the following predictions

– Market portfolio is mean-variance e¢ cient


– has positive premium

CAPM and SDF

– In general, beta representation with f as factors (see below) ,a¢ ne SDF: m = a+bT f: (See Cochrane p.106~108)
Beta representation takes the following form:
K
X
ei =
E R + ik k 8i (3)
|{z} |{z}
i=1
factor sens. factor risk pr

K
X
ei = ai +
R ik fek + e
"i 8i (4)
|{z} |{z}
i=1
factor sens. risk factor

"i ) = 0 and E feke


with E (e "i Cov fek ; e
"i = 0 (5)

– Form of : From the above formulation It can be shown that (See Cochrane p.108)...
if the factor fk is a gross return on a portfolio (e.g. CAPM), and there exists risk-free asset ) factor risk
premium always takes the form of a risk premium on that portfolio, i.e. k = E R ek ef
R
if the factor fk is an excess return on a portfolio ) factor risk premium always takes the form of the expected
excess return, i.e. k = E fek
– Examples:
CAPM: k=1, fe = R
em , em
=E R Rf ; = Rf ; i
ei ; R
= Cov R em =V ar R
em

FF3factors: fe1 = R
em Rf ; fe2 = R
eS eB ; fe3 = R
R eH eL ,
R k = E fek 8k
– Note on Factor Mimicking Portfolios (See Cochrane p.109)
When factors are not already returns or excess returns, it is often convenient to express a pricing model in
terms of its factor-mimicking portfolios rather than the factors themselves (FF3Factors).
That is, rather than the true factors f , use one of the following...

factor-mimicking payo¤s: f = proj (f jX) (6)

proj (f jX)
factor-mimicking gross returns: f = (7)
p (proj (f jX))
factor-mimicking excess returns: f = proj (f jRe ) (8)
e
where X is the space of payo¤s in the economy and R the space of excess returns.
m = bT f is a valid SDF, since

p = E (mx) = E (proj (f jX) x) = E (m x) (9)

2
2 Empirical Tests of CAPM
2.1 Methodology
2 Approaches for testing beta models (e.g. CAPM)

1. Time-Series Approach (FF ’93)

When factor is a excess return, then factor risk premium is = E fe so that representation in (3) reduces to

ei
E R Rf = iE fe (10)

where i de…ned through he time-series regression

Ri;t Rf;t = i + i ft + "i;t (11)

The model has one and only one implication for the data:

i = 0 8i (12)

To Test: Run time-series regressions (11) for each test asset/portfolio, then test whether all pricing errors ( i ) are
0
Problems with methodology: Requires the factor to be a return.

2. Cross-Sectional Approach (FF ’92)

Generally, if risk factors are not returns, our representation model is written as:

ei
E R Rf = i + i (13)

We can …t this model as follows:

– 1. Identify iM from time series regression for each security

regress Rit Rf t = i + iM (RM;t Rf t ) + "it (14)

– 2. Run the following cross sectional regression of (time-series) average asset returns on estimates of asset betas
^ for each stock i:
iM

regress Ri Rf = + ^ iM + ui (15)

CAPM Predictions in this model are that: = 0 and > 0 (Black) or eM


=E R Rf (Sharpe-Lintner)

Problems with above methodology

– 1. estimates for individual assets are imprecise )measurement error.


(Solution: Estimate in portfolios improve precision. Blume (1970), Friend and Blume (1970), Black, Jensen,
and Scholes (1972). )
– 2. Cross sectional regression (15) has correlated errors (e.g. common industry e¤ects in average returns) )
standard errors too small!
(Solution: Fama-MacBeth (1973) - estimate month-by-month cross-section regressions of monthly returns on s,
use the time-series means and standard errors of the means for inference. Assuming no time-series correlation, the
standard errors of coe¢ cients capture the e¤ects of residual correlations via repeated sampling of the regression
coe¢ cients. In other words, we are bootstrapping from the sampling distribution of ’s, where each bootstrap
draw comes from a monthly cross-section.)
– 3. Second stage standard errors does not account for …rst stage estimation ) standard errors too small!
(Solution: Explicitly correct for the …rst stage estimation in standard error - Shanken (1992))

3
2.2 Findings in Tests of CAPM
3 Testable Predictions of CAPM to test: 1) expected returns on all sets are linearly related to their , and no other variables
have explanatory power, 2) premium is positive, and 3) asset uncorrelated with market is Rf and premium is E (RM ) Rf
or +.

Early tests of the CAPM (Fama MacBeth (1973), Gibbons (1982), and Stambaugh (1982)) …nd...

– appears to su¢ ce in explaining expected returns and premium on is +


– too large and too small (see (15))

Later tests of the CAPM (Fama French (1992)) reject earlier …ndings, using cross-sectional Fama-MacBeth approach

– does not explain cross section of average returns. + premium does not exist in the post 1963 period.
– Size and B/M explain cross section of average returns

You might also like